Chapter Two Budgetary and Other Constraints on Choice Consumption Choice Sets • A consumption choice set is the collection of all consumption choices available to the consumer. • What constrains consumption choice? – Budgetary, time and other resource limitations. Budget Constraints • A consumption bundle containing x1 units of commodity 1, and x2 units of commodity 2 is denoted by the vector (x1, x2). • Commodity prices are p1, p2 Budget Constraints • Q: When is a consumption bundle (x1, x2) affordable at given prices p1, p2? • When p1x1 + p2 x2 m where m is the consumer’s (disposable) income. Budget Constraints • The bundles that are only just affordable form the consumer’s budget constraint. This is the set { (x1, x2 ) | such that p1x1 + p2 x2 = m }. • The budget constraint is the upper boundary of the budget set Budget Set and Constraint for Two Commodities x 2 m /p2 Budget constraint is p1x1 + p2x2 = m. m /p1 x1 Budget Set and Constraint for Two Commodities x 2 m /p2 Budget constraint is p1x1 + p2x2 = m. Just affordable m /p1 x1 Budget Set and Constraint for Two Commodities x 2 m /p2 Budget constraint is p1x1 + p2x2 = m. Not affordable Just affordable m /p1 x1 Budget Set and Constraint for Two Commodities x 2 m /p2 Budget constraint is p1x1 + p2x2 = m. Not affordable Just affordable Affordable m /p1 x1 Budget Set and Constraint for Two Commodities x 2 m /p2 Budget constraint is p1x1 + p2x2 = m. the collection of all affordable bundles. Budget Set m /p1 x1 Budget Set and Constraint for Two Commodities x 2 m /p2 p1x1 + p2x2 = m is x2 = -(p1/p2)x1 + m/p2 so slope is -p1/p2. Budget Set m /p1 x1 Budget Constraints • For n = 2 and x1 on the horizontal axis, the constraint’s slope is -p1/p2. What does it mean? p1 m x2 = x1 p2 p2 • Increasing x1 by 1 must reduce x2 by p1/p2. Budget Constraints x2 Slope is -p1/p2 -p1/p2 +1 x1 Budget Constraints x2 Opp. cost of an extra unit of commodity 1 is p1/p2 units foregone of commodity 2. -p1/p2 +1 x1 Budget Constraints x2 Opp. cost of an extra unit of commodity 1 is p1/p2 units foregone of commodity 2. And the opp. cost of an extra +1 unit of commodity 2 is -p2/p1 p2/p1 units foregone of commodity 1. x1 Budget Sets & Constraints; Income and Price Changes • The budget constraint and budget set depend upon prices and income. What happens as prices or income change? How do the budget set and budget constraint change as x2 income m increases? Original budget set x1 x2 Higher income gives more choice New affordable consumption choices Original and new budget constraints are parallel (same slope). Original budget set x1 How do the budget set and budget constraint change as x2 income m decreases? Original budget set x1 How do the budget set and budget constraint change as x2 income m decreases? Consumption bundles that are no longer affordable. New, smaller budget set Old and new constraints are parallel. x1 Budget Constraints - Income Changes • Increases in income m shift the constraint outward in a parallel manner, thereby enlarging the budget set and improving choice. Budget Constraints - Income Changes • Increases in income m shift the constraint outward in a parallel manner, thereby enlarging the budget set and improving choice. • Decreases in income m shift the constraint inward in a parallel manner, thereby shrinking the budget set and reducing choice. Budget Constraints - Income Changes • No original choice is lost and new choices are added when income increases, so higher income cannot make a consumer worse off. • An income decrease may (typically will) make the consumer worse off. Budget Constraints - Price Changes • What happens if just one price decreases? • Suppose p1 decreases. How do the budget set and budget constraint change as p1 x2 decreases from p ’ to p ”? 1 1 m/p2 -p1’/p2 Original budget set m/p1’ m/p1 ” x1 How do the budget set and budget constraint change as p1 x2 decreases from p ’ to p ”? 1 1 m/p2 New affordable choices -p1’/p2 Original budget set m/p1’ m/p1 ” x1 How do the budget set and budget constraint change as p1 x2 decreases from p ’ to p ”? 1 1 m/p2 New affordable choices -p1’/p2 Original budget set Budget constraint pivots; slope flattens from -p1’/p2 to -p1”/p2 -p ”/p 1 m/p1’ 2 m/p1 ” x1 Budget Constraints - Price Changes • Reducing the price of one commodity pivots the constraint outward. No old choice is lost and new choices are added, so reducing one price cannot make the consumer worse off. Budget Constraints - Price Changes • Similarly, increasing one price pivots the constraint inwards, reduces choice and may (typically will) make the consumer worse off. Uniform Ad Valorem Sales Taxes • An ad valorem sales tax levied at a rate of 5% increases the price by 5%, from p to (1+0 05)p = 1 05p. • An ad valorem sales tax levied at a rate of t increases the price by tp from p to (1+t)p. • A uniform sales tax is applied uniformly to all commodities. Uniform Ad Valorem Sales Taxes • A uniform sales tax levied at rate t changes the constraint from p1x1 + p2x2 = m to (1+t)p1x1 + (1+t)p2x2 = m Uniform Ad Valorem Sales Taxes • A uniform sales tax levied at rate t changes the constraint from p1x1 + p2x2 = m to (1+t)p1x1 + (1+t)p2x2 = m i.e. p1x1 + p2x2 = m/(1+t). Uniform Ad Valorem Sales Taxes x2 m p2 p1x1 + p2x2 = m m p1 x1 Uniform Ad Valorem Sales Taxes x2 m p2 m (1 t ) p2 p1x1 + p2x2 = m p1x1 + p2x2 = m/(1+t) m (1 t ) p1 m p1 x1 Uniform Ad Valorem Sales Taxes x2 m p2 m (1 t ) p2 Equivalent income loss is m t m = m 1 t 1 t m (1 t ) p1 m p1 x1 Uniform Ad Valorem Taxes x2 m p2 m (1 t ) p2 A uniform ad valorem sales tax levied at rate t is equivalent to an income t tax levied at rate . 1 t m (1 t ) p1 m p1 x1 The Food Stamp Program • Food stamps are coupons that can be legally exchanged only for food. • How does a commodity-specific gift such as a food stamp alter a family’s budget constraint? The Food Stamp Program • Suppose m = $100, pF = $1 and the price of “other goods” is pG = $1. • The budget constraint is then F + G =100. The Food Stamp Program G F + G = 100: before stamps. 100 100 F The Food Stamp Program G F + G = 100: before stamps. 100 Budget set after 40 food stamps issued. The family’s budget set is enlarged. 40 100 140 F The Food Stamp Program • What if food stamps can be traded on a black market for $0.50 each? The Food Stamp Program G F + G = 100: before stamps. Budget constraint after 40 food stamps issued. Budget constraint with black market trading. 120 100 40 100 140 F The Food Stamp Program G F + G = 100: before stamps. Budget constraint after 40 food stamps issued. Black market trading makes the budget set larger again. 120 100 40 100 140 F Budget Constraints - Relative Prices • “Numeraire” means “unit of account”. • Suppose prices and income are measured in dollars. Say p1=$2, p2=$3, m = $12. Then the constraint is 2x1 + 3x2 = 12. Budget Constraints - Relative Prices • If prices and income are measured in cents, then p1=200, p2=300, m=1200 and the constraint is 200x1 + 300x2 = 1200, the same as 2x1 + 3x2 = 12. • Changing the numeraire changes neither the budget constraint nor the budget set. Budget Constraints - Relative Prices • The constraint for p1=2, p2=3, m=12 2x1 + 3x2 = 12 is also 1.x1 + (3/2)x2 = 6, the constraint for p1=1, p2=3/2, m=6. Setting p1=1 makes commodity 1 the numeraire and defines all prices relative to p1; e.g. 3/2 is the price of commodity 2 relative to the price of commodity 1. Budget Constraints - Relative Prices • Any commodity can be chosen as the numeraire without changing the budget set or the budget constraint. Budget Constraints - Relative Prices • p1=2, p2=3 and p3=6 • price of commodity 2 relative to commodity 1 is 3/2, • price of commodity 3 relative to commodity 1 is 3. • Relative prices are the rates of exchange of commodities 2 and 3 for units of commodity 1. Shapes of Budget Constraints • Q: What makes a budget constraint a straight line? • A: If prices are constants then a constraint is a straight line. Shapes of Budget Constraints • But what if prices are not constants? • E.g. bulk buying discounts, or price penalties for buying “too much”. • Then constraints will be curved. Shapes of Budget Constraints Quantity Discounts • Suppose p2 is constant at $1 but that p1=$2 for 0 x1 20 and p1=$1 for x1>20. Shapes of Budget Constraints Quantity Discounts • Suppose p2 is constant at $1 but that p1=$2 for 0 x1 20 and p1=$1 for x1>20. Then the constraint’s slope is - 2, for 0 x1 20 -p1/p2 = - 1, for x1 > 20 and the constraint is { Shapes of Budget Constraints with a Quantity Discount x2 100 m = $100 Slope = - 2 / 1 = - 2 (p1=2, p2=1) Slope = - 1/ 1 = - 1 (p1=1, p2=1) 20 50 80 x1 Shapes of Budget Constraints with a Quantity Discount x2 100 m = $100 Slope = - 2 / 1 = - 2 (p1=2, p2=1) Slope = - 1/ 1 = - 1 (p1=1, p2=1) 20 50 80 x1 Shapes of Budget Constraints with a Quantity Discount x2 m = $100 100 Budget Constraint Budget Set 20 50 80 x1 Shapes of Budget Constraints with a Quantity Penalty x2 Budget Constraint Budget Set x1 Shapes of Budget Constraints One Price Negative • Commodity 1 is stinky garbage. You are paid $2 per unit to accept it; i.e. p1 = - $2. p2 = $1. Income, other than from accepting commodity 1, is m = $10. • Then the constraint is - 2x1 + x2 = 10 or x2 = 2x1 + 10. Shapes of Budget Constraints One Price Negative x2 x2 = 2x1 + 10 Budget constraint’s slope is -p1/p2 = -(-2)/1 = +2 10 x1 Shapes of Budget Constraints One Price Negative x2 Budget set is all bundles for which x1 0, x2 0 and x2 2x1 + 10. 10 x1 More General Choice Sets • Choices are usually constrained by more than a budget; e.g. time constraints and other resources constraints. • A bundle is available only if it meets every constraint. More General Choice Sets Other Stuff At least 10 units of food must be eaten to survive 10 Food More General Choice Sets Other Stuff Choice is also budget constrained. Budget Set 10 Food More General Choice Sets Other Stuff Choice is further restricted by a time constraint. 10 Food More General Choice Sets So what is the choice set? More General Choice Sets Other Stuff 10 Food More General Choice Sets Other Stuff 10 Food More General Choice Sets Other Stuff The choice set is the intersection of all of the constraint sets. 10 Food Chapter Three Preferences Preference Relations • Comparing two different consumption bundles, x and y: – strict preference: x is more preferred than is y. – weak preference: x is as at least as preferred as is y. – indifference: x is exactly as preferred as is y. Preference Relations • Those are ordinal relations; i.e. they state only the order in which bundles are preferred not the intensity of preference Preference Relations p p • denotes strict preference; x y means that bundle x is preferred strictly to bundle y. Preference Relations p p • denotes strict preference so x y means that bundle x is preferred strictly to bundle y. ~ denotes indifference; x ~ y means x and y are equally preferred. • f denotes weak preference; ~ x f y means x is preferred at least as ~ much as is y. Preference Relations • x f y and y f x imply x ~ y. p ~ ~ • x f y and (not y f x) imply x ~ ~ y. Assumptions about Preference Relations • Completeness: For any two bundles x and y it is always possible to make the statement that either x f y ~ or y f x. ~ • Should compare any two Assumptions about Preference Relations • Reflexivity: Any bundle x is always at least as preferred as itself; i.e. x f x. ~ Assumptions about Preference Relations • Transitivity: If x is at least as preferred as y, and y is at least as preferred as z, then x is at least as preferred as z; i.e. x f y and y f z ~ ~ • otherwise cycles x f z. ~ Indifference Curves • Take a bundle x. The set of all bundles equally preferred to x is the indifference curve containing x • Through every bundle x we can draw exactly one indifference curve Indifference Curves x2 x’ ~ x’ ~ x” x x’ x” x1 Weakly Better Set WP(x), the set of bundles weakly preferred to x. x2 x Includes indifference curve I(x). I(x) x1 Strictly Better Set SP(x), the set of bundles strictly preferred to x, does not include indifference curve I(x). x2 x I(x) x1 Indifference Curves Cannot Intersect x2 I1 I2 From I1, x ~ y. From I2, x ~ z. Therefore y ~ z. x y z x1 Indifference Curves Cannot Intersect I1 I2 From I1, x ~ y. From I2, x ~ z. Therefore y ~ z. But y z, a contradiction. p x2 x y z x1 Slopes of Indifference Curves • When more of a commodity is always preferred, the commodity is a good. • If every commodity is a good then indifference curves are negatively sloped. Slopes of Indifference Curves Good 2 Two goods a negatively sloped indifference curve. Good 1 Perfect Substitutes • If a consumer is willing to trade commodities 1 and 2 at a constant rate -the commodities are perfect substitutes For Jean only the total amount of salmon and trout matters x2 15 I2 8 I1 IC Slopes are constant at -1. Bundles in I2 all have a total of 15 units and are strictly preferred to all bundles in I1, which have a total of only 8 units in them. x1 8 15 For Jill only the nutritional content of salmon and trout matters Salmon is twice more nutritious. s IC Slopes are constant at -1/2. I2 8 4 Still perfect substitutes I1 8 16 t Perfect Complements • If commodities 1 and 2 are always consumed in fixed proportion then they are perfect complements • only the number of bundles of the two commodities determines the ordering of bundles. Perfect Complements x2 45o 9 Each of (5,5), (5,9) and (9,5) contains 5 pairs so each is equally preferred. 5 5 9 x1 Perfect Complements x2 Since each of (5,5), (5,9) and (9,5) contains 5 pairs, each is less I2 preferred than the bundle (9,9) which I1 contains 9 pairs. 45o 9 5 5 9 x1 Perfect complements • Goods that are consumed in fixed, not only one-to-one proportion, are also perfect complements Preferences Exhibiting Satiation • A bundle strictly preferred to any other is a satiation point. Preferences Exhibiting Satiation x2 Better Satiation point x1 Indifference Curves Exhibiting Satiation x2 Better Satiation (bliss) point x1 Well-Behaved Preferences • A preference relation is “well-behaved” if it is monotonic and convex. • Monotonicity: More of any commodity is always preferred (i.e. no satiation and every commodity is a good). Well-Behaved Preferences • Convexity: Mixtures of bundles are (at least weakly) preferred to the bundles themselves. • 50-50 mixture of the bundles x and y is z = (0.5)x + (0.5)y. Well-Behaved Preferences -Convexity. x x2 x+y is strictly preferred z= 2 to both x and y. x2+y2 2 y y2 x1 x1+y 1 2 y1 Well-Behaved Preferences -Convexity. x x2 z =(tx1+(1-t)y1, tx2+(1-t)y2) is preferred to x and y for all 0 < t < 1. y y2 x1 y1 Well-Behaved Preferences -Convexity. x x2 y2 x1 Preferences are strictly convex when all mixtures z are strictly z preferred to their component bundles x and y. y y1 Well-Behaved Preferences -Weak Convexity. Preferences are weakly convex if at least one mixture z is equally preferred to a component bundle. x’ z’ x z y y’ Non-Convex Preferences x2 The mixture z is less preferred than x or y. z y2 x1 y1 Counterexample: coffee and olives More Non-Convex Preferences x2 The mixture z is less preferred than x or y. z y2 x1 y1 Slopes of Indifference Curves • The slope of an indifference curve is its marginal rate-of-substitution (MRS). Marginal Rate of Substitution x2 MRS at x’ is the slope of the indifference curve at x’ x’ x1 Marginal Rate of Substitution x2 MRS at x’ is dx2/dx1 at x’ D x2 x’ Dx1 x1 Marginal Rate of Substitution x2 dx2 x’ dx1 dx2 = MRS dx1 so, at x’, MRS is the rate at which the consumer is only just willing to exchange commodity 2 for a small amount of commodity 1 x1 Good 2 a negatively sloped indifference curve MRS is negative Good 1 Diminishing Marginal Rate of Substitution Good 2 MRS = - 5 MRS always increases with x1 (becomes less negative) if and only if preferences are strictly convex MRS = - 0.5 Good 1 Intuition • If you have a lot of good 2 you are willing to sacrifice a lot of it to get some amount of good 1. MRS & Ind. Curve Properties x2 MRS is not always increasing as x1 increases nonconvex preferences. MRS = - 1 MRS = - 0.5 MRS = - 2 x1