The Liquidity Trap Theory and Japan’s Economy ABSTRACT The Japanese economy has undergone stagnation, inflation and low interest rates for a number of decades and has been caught in a liquidity trap at some points. This paper aims to evaluate the economy’s liquidity trap while being mindful of the structure and economic performances. It is herein contended that the Keynesian perspective and Krugman’s insights are still relevant as the Keynesian perspective aids the understanding of a country’s liquidity trap as well as devising and effecting policies that could potentially help overcome this and promote renewed economic development and growth. Risk of low inflation and deflation rates have been identified as the main causes of liquidity traps by Paul Krugman and Ben Bernanke. Accordingly, it has been suggested by them that central banks should make a trustworthy commitment to sustain monetary easing as the key to reigniting inflation which would allow for an escape from this trap by virtue of low interest rates and quantitative easing. On the contrary, John Maynard Keynes assumes that the probability of a liquidity trap arises due to a sharp rise in investors’ liquidity preference and the anxiety regarding capital losses which come about due to the uncertainty about the bearing of interest rates. Accordingly, he advocated for an integrated strategy so as to alleviate the repercussions. This integrated strategy thereby consists of robust fiscal policy and boosting employment which would lead to the creation of a higher expected marginal efficiency of capital, while the central bank stabilises the yield curve and reduces interest rate unpredictability to lessen investors’ expectancies of capital loss. INTRODUCTION According to the Keynesian school of thought, the ability of a monetary policy to promote economic activity by driving down interest rates may be compromised by the occurrence of a liquidity trap.1 This phenomenon is described as a situation wherein the interest rate has fallen to a certain level such that liquidity preferences could potentially become absolute in the sense that people would prefer holding cash rather than investing which provides a low 1 Grandmont, Jean-Michel, and Guy Laroque. “The Liquidity Trap.” Econometrica, vol. 44, no. 1, 1976, pp. 129–135. JSTOR, JSTOR, www.jstor.org/stable/1911386. 1 rate of interest.2 Essentially, it is a situation where people begin to store cash based on their expectation of an adverse event such as deflation, insufficient aggregate demand etc. “Liquidity Trap” describes a special property of demand for money which is supposed to increase in an unlimited fashion as long as the long-term interest rate declines to zero. It has been argued by some economists that this situation will be prevalent even when the interest rate reaches a low, however, positive level.3 As per the standard economic theory, an economy should not experience a problem of insufficient demand – this view is regarded as Say’s Law. Consequently so, aggregate supply and aggregate demand must be in equilibrium. The basis of this is the idea that production and sale of commodities will generate income which will either be saved or consumed. The amount that is saved will then be spent on investment. Essentially, the production of commodities will raise income that is either devoted to either purchasing commodities or saving that is equal to investment. Subsequently, no problem arises when aggregate demand is less than aggregate supply.4 Keynes furthers Malthus’ critique of Say’s Law in The General Theory. According to Keynes, there is an intrinsic problem in the modern capitalist economy that can experience shortfalls on aggregate demand, regardless of the time period and gravity, due to which the level of employment will always remain below the maximum potential level of employment. In such an economy, speculators have a disposition towards liquidity as a result of the fundamental uncertainty regarding what the future holds. Psychological and social factors also play an important role in the speculators’ predilection. They may keep cash at hand or hold other types of financial assets as a store of value as a result of which savings may not be invested. Consequently, the economy will not attain full employment. Changes in interest rates may not be enough to effect investment and reach the goal of full employment.5 EXISTENCE OF LIQUIDITY TRAPS Predominantly, the existence of liquidity traps is based on two theories. Primarily, when interest rates are at a low and declining rate in an economy, there is an expectation that the Keynes, John Maynard. “The General Theory of Employment, Interest and Money”. United Kingdom: Palgrave Macmillan, 2007 edition, ISBN 978-0-230-00476-4 3 Grandmont, Jean-Michel, and Guy Laroque. “The Liquidity Trap.” Econometrica, vol. 44, no. 1, 1976, pp. 129–135. JSTOR, JSTOR, www.jstor.org/stable/1911386. 4 Baumol, William J. “Say's (at Least) Eight Laws, or What Say and James Mill May Really Have Meant.” Economica, vol. 44, no. 174, 1977, pp. 145–161. JSTOR, JSTOR, www.jstor.org/stable/2553717. 2 5 Sowell, Thomas. Say's Law: An Historical Analysis. Princeton University Press, 1972. JSTOR, www.jstor.org/stable/j.ctt13x0w9s. 2 interest rate will cease to fall but rather it would begin to rise. Due to this rise, capital losses will accumulate for those who sell bonds and those who hold cash will obtain increased earnings. Therefore, in order to avoid the former and pursue the latter, speculators would much rather hold money as cash than invest. At some low interest rate, the demand for money would be perfectly elastic. This is known as the expectation argument. The latter argues that at any given interest rate, some people would hold onto cash rather than invest as “the trouble of making a transaction may offset the gain in interest.”6 The number of people unwilling to invest and the interest rate have an inversely proportional relationship: the lower the interest rate, the greater the number of people who would want to keep cash at hand. Ostensibly, there is a particular positive rate at which all individuals would rather not invest – at this rate, the demand for money becomes perfectly elastic. This is known as the cost of acquiring bonds argument. CRITIQUE OF THE LIQUIDITY TRAP THEORY In the General Theory, Keynes provided for three types of traps – weak, strong and extreme. Under the weak version, elasticity of liquidity preference becomes considerably high at low levels of interest, it does not become infinite. In the strong version, liquidity preference is perfectly elastic in a finite segment. In the extreme case, the rate of interest cannot be reduced by increasing money supply in the economy. The weak version cannot be classified as a true trap since the equilibrium interest rate can be lowered by implementing appropriate monetary supply tools. Empirical investigations have shown that the weak version of the trap has very little practical significance.7 JAPAN: MACROECONOMIC SCENARIO AND LIQUIDITY TRAP Japan’s economy plunged into stagnation and experienced price deflation after the bubble economy broke down in 1991 up till 2001. Due to this, the Japanese economy went through periods of near zero growth which was quite a drastic change in comparison to its previous 4 percent growth in the 1980s. The nation’s GDP growth fell to less than half its rate of 3.89% (during the 1980s) to 1.14% (post 1991). One of the major reasons for this occurrence was that its equity ad real estate bubble began to decline in wherein values plunged by 70% by Hicks, J. R. “Value and Capital” Oxford University Press, 2 nd ed., 1946, pp 164-165 Beranek, William, and Richard H. Timberlake. “The Liquidity Trap Theory: A Critique.” Southern Economic Journal, vol. 54, no. 2, 1987, pp. 387–396. JSTOR, JSTOR, www.jstor.org/stable/1059323. 6 7 3 2001.8 To add to this, Japan’s central bank may have made some mistakes that could have prolonged its effect and made matters worse. This was known as “Japan’s Lost Decade.”9 Japan’s industrial productions slowed down during the 1990s to early 2000s and after the 2001 recession, it improved moderately. However, it took a plunge during the Global Financial Crisis of 2007-08. This caused a slowdown in growth which led to a fall in income and thus reduced rates of consumption. The private investment rates have also been fairly flat since 1990s whereas public investment rates have fallen. Mid-1990s, the economy’s share of global exports had also seen a decline. This was due to the combinations of other rising Asian economies as well as an appreciation in the Japanese Yen which led a loss of its export competitiveness.10 The characteristics experienced through this decade make it difficult to resist that there is a liquidity trap at play. The characteristics being very low interest rates, Japan’s central banks’ inability to induce aggregate demand by adopting expansionary monetary policy, additionally, Japan’s consistent below capacity performance. The liquidity trap theory proposes that such a trap can occur when current productive capacity is actually more than future productive capacity. This can be explained by way of Japan’s demographic trends – it is the oldest country in the world and its declining birth rate along with a lack of immigration indicates why this might be so.11 Such a declining trend also affects the economy’s future investment – an increase in the proportion of dependents and retirees decreases output and investment and accordingly, the return on investments.12 Some other explanations of the trap look into Japan’s capital market inefficiencies and its institutional peculiarities. ESCAPING FROM THE LIQUIDITY TRAP Once an economy is in a liquidity trap situation, it is very difficult to implement traditional monetary policy tools in order to get out of the same. The solutions to a liquidity trap can be broadly categorised into: structural reform, fiscal expansion and alternative monetary policy. Leigh, Daniel. “Monetary Policy and the Lost Decade: Lessons from Japan.” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, vol. 42, no. 5, 2010, pp. 833–857. JSTOR, JSTOR, www.jstor.org/stable/40732615. 9 Krugman, Paul R., et al. “It's Baaack: Japan's Slump and the Return of the Liquidity Trap.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, vol. 1998, no. 2, 1998, pp. 137–205. JSTOR, JSTOR, www.jstor.org/stable/2534694. 10 “Japan - OECD Data.” TheOECD, data.oecd.org/japan.htm. 11 “Japan Population 2018.” Japan Population 2018 (Demographics, Maps, Graphs), worldpopulationreview.com/countries/japan-population/. 12 Basso, Henrique, and Bank of Spain. “How Will an Ageing Population Affect the Economy?” World Economic Forum, www.weforum.org/agenda/2015/04/how-will-an-ageing-population-affect-the-economy/. 8 4 It is pertinent to note that Japan’s problem is one of demand and not supply, structural reform may aid in inducing people to increase their consumption. Structural reform of the private sector may help in increasing investment. Such a reform could also positively influence future expectations, thus causing higher spending today. The basic idea of an expansionary fiscal policy is that the government purchases goods and services and this could lead to an increase in the economy’s aggregate demand and thus output, even though it will be partially offset by reduction in private consumption. This policy has however proved to unsuccessful in Japan’s scenario.13 Alternative monetary policy suggests that the economy can break out of this situation through the help of increased inflationary expectations. Since the real interest rate is difference between nominal interest rate and expected inflation, even if the nominal interest rate reaches zero, the central bank can further reduce the rate if they can create private section inflationary expectation. This can be done by explicitly committing to a higher future price level. Therefore, this policy is reliant on the central bank’s credibility and that it would indeed allow inflation rates to increase after which aggregate demand will increase.14 CONCLUSION According to Krugman and Bernanke the real cause of a liquidity trap is that the real interest rate remains high. Even if nominal interest rates decline, if inflation does not decline at the same time, or the economy experiences deflation, then real interest rates may still remain high or could even rise. This hampers business investment and spending. Hence, the solution must lie in raising inflation and expected inflation through strict monetary policy. Krugman and Bernanke emphasize accommodative monetary policy as the principal tool for resolving a liquidity trap. Modern mainstream macroeconomics has made courageous attempts to cope and come to terms with a liquidity trap and has made some advances. However, it is still entrapped by the limitations of the quantity theory of money, as is evident in the primary emphasis on monetary expansion to generate inflation in the works of Krugman, Paul R., et al. “It's Baaack: Japan's Slump and the Return of the Liquidity Trap.” Brookings Papers on Economic Activity, vol. 1998, no. 2, 1998, pp. 137–205. JSTOR, JSTOR, www.jstor.org/stable/2534694. 13 Svensson, Lars E.O. “Escaping From a Liquidity Trap and Deflation: The Foolproof Way and Others, Journal of Economic Perspectives, vol. 17, 2003, pp 145-166 14 5 Krugman, Bernanke, and the majority of contemporary macroeconomics theorists. In contrast, Keynes’s analysis in the General Theory still provides a solid basis for understanding many aspects of a liquidity trap. The Keynesian perspective offers a richer understanding by applying it when analysing the causes of a liquidity trap and appropriate policy measures for reviewing growth. Keynesian measures of keeping interest rates low and mitigating interest rate volatility through monetary policy actions and targeting the yield curve, in tandem with countercyclical and activist fiscal policies, proactive employment policies (including direct public-sector employment and state-backed privatesector employment), and efforts to raise the expected marginal efficiency of capital and labour would be appropriate for countries stuck in a liquidity/investment trap. 6