PII: Marine Pollution Bulletin Vol. 37, Nos. 8±12, pp. 373±382, 1998 Ó 1999 Elsevier Science Ltd. All rights reserved Printed in Great Britain S0025-326X(99)00074-0 0025-326X/99 $ - see front matter "Reports" The Socio-Economic Costs and Bene®ts of Coastal Habitat Rehabilitation and Creation JAMES SPURGEON* GIBB Environment, Gibb House, London Road, Reading RG6 1BL, UK This paper provides a comprehensive overview of the merits and limitations of using an economics based approach to assess and implement initiatives for coastal habitat rehabilitation and creation. A review of the literature indicates that habitat rehabilitation/creation costs vary widely between and within ecosystems. For coral reefs, costs range from US$ 10,000 to 6.5 million/hectare (ha); 1 for mangroves US$ 3000±510,000/ha; for seagrasses US$ 9000±680,000/ha and for saltmarshes US$ 2000±160,000/ha. A review of the economic bene®ts derived from various coastal habitats based on a ÔTotal Economic ValueÕ approach (i.e. accounting for direct and indirect uses, and Ônon-usesÕ) reveals that many thousands of US$ per hectare could ultimately accrue from their rehabilitation/creation. The paper concludes that despite its limitations, the Ôbene®t-cost analysisÕ framework can play an important role both in assessing the justi®cation of coastal habitat rehabilitation/creation initiatives, and by helping to improve the overall eectiveness of such initiatives. Ó 1999 Elsevier Science Ltd. All rights reserved Keywords: coastal habitats; economic valuation; costs; bene®ts; restoration; rehabilitation; creation; coral reefs; mangroves; seagrasses; saltmarsh; sand dunes; lagoons; shingle ridges; cost-bene®t analysis. Introduction As a means of maintaining global bio-diversity, increasing attention is being given to rehabilitating and creating a variety of coastal habitats. Is it a wise use of *Study undertaken whilst an employee of Posford Duvivier Environment, UK. E-mail: jspurgeo@gibb.co.uk\cor 1 All monetary values in the paper have been updated to 1997 US$ values using appropriate indices (to adjust for in¯ation) and currency exchange rates, unless stated otherwise. The 1997 exchange rate is US$ 1 UK£0.60. resources? This paper examines the relevance of economics and highlights the role of bene®t-cost analysis (BCA) as a decision-making tool not only to help justify habitat rehabilitation/creation, but also as a framework to help maximise overall net bene®ts. Economics can be de®ned as Ôthe study of the ecient allocation of resourcesÕ. Governments are faced with the challenge of maximising the economic returns from use of their countryÕs resources (labour, capital and natural resources). As a result, BCA has developed over the past 30 years to help prioritise the selection of public sector development schemes given the limited resources available. The technique enables all economic costs and bene®ts for alternative schemes to be weighed up and compared. The preferred scheme can then be selected based on the most ecient use of available resources. The main stages involved in BCA are to: 1. de®ne the details for each feasible scheme (including the ``do nothing option''); 2. determine the most appropriate spatial and temporal study limits; 3. identify all scheme costs and all scheme bene®ts; 4. place an economic (monetary) value, where possible, on all costs and bene®ts; 5. calculate ``present day'' costs and bene®ts through ``discounting''; 6. compare present day costs to present day bene®ts. Those schemes with a bene®t to cost ratio (BCR) greater than 1 are economically justi®ed. Generally, the higher the BCR the more ecient the use of resources. The formula for calculating the BCR is: T P BCR t0 T P t0 Bt = 1 rt Ct = 1 ÿ r t ; 373 Marine Pollution Bulletin P where is the sum of values, Bt the bene®t at time t, Ct the cost at time t, T the timescale of project, t 0 the start time of project, and r the discount rate. The application of BCA to habitat rehabilitation/ creation initiatives has only recently become worthwhile. There are three main reasons for this. Firstly, it is only when such schemes have been implemented for several years that their true economic costs and bene®ts can be comprehensively identi®ed. Secondly, only recently has our understanding of rehabilitation/creation begun to develop suciently. Thirdly, as the techniques available to place monetary values on environmental bene®ts continue to improve, more comprehensive and accurate estimates of their value become possible. This paper is the result of an initial investigation into economic aspects relating to coastal habitat rehabilitation/creation which, for the present, is limited to a brief review of available literature. Costs Categories and valuation of costs The various costs associated with habitat rehabilitation/creation schemes can be either ÔeconomicÕ, ÔfinancialÕ or both. Economic costs relate to the overall cost to society of using a resource (e.g. a material or labour). These ÔeconomicÕ costs are used in the BCA process. Economic costs are measured in terms of the Ôopportunity costÕ of using each particular resource. The opportunity cost of a resource is the value of that resource in its next best alternative use, as measured by its social value less the social value of any inputs (labour, material etc.) which could be used elsewhere. Market prices can generally be used as a basis for opportunity costs, although they often need adjusting to allow for market distortions (e.g. government subsidies and taxes). Financial costs, on the other hand, generally relate to prices set by monetary transactions made. Financial costs are critical for private sector schemes where ®nancial viability and pro®tability are vital to the success of the project and of particular interest to investors. The assessment of ®nancial costs is also important for public sector schemes to determine the necessary ®nancial resources and funding required. Financial values are generally measured using actual market prices, although they may need adjusting to take into account appropriate accounting principles (e.g. depreciation of assets). Rehabilitation/creation of coastal habitats is a complex and lengthy process involving many dierent activities and resources, each with their own economic and ®nancial implications. The main economic (and ®nancial) cost components can generally be broken down into `capital' and `operational' costs as detailed in Table 1. 374 Costs for rehabilitation/creation of coastal habitats A review of the costs associated with rehabilitating/ creating coastal habitats revealed a substantial dierence in the relative order of magnitude of costs, as illustrated in Table 2. There are several simple, yet important, reasons for the variances, which occur both within habitat types and between habitat types. A brief discussion for each habitat type and an explanation of the source of the cost data follows. Coral reefs. Coral reefs appear to be potentially the most expensive coastal habitat to rehabilitate, with costs of up to US$ 6.5 million per ha. However, this ®gure relates to extrapolated rehabilitation costs funded through compensation paid as a result of ships running aground on coral reefs. In 1989 the M/V Elpis ran aground on reefs in the Florida Keys National Marine Sanctuary and restoration funds of US$ 1.66 million (1991 price) were awarded to restore 3000 m2 of damaged reef. The rehabilitation involved removing debris, stabilising the reef substrate, importing new substrate, transplanting corals and sponges, and monitoring (NOAA, 1997a). Extrapolating coral reef rehabilitation costs relating to a similar incident, the grounding of the M/V Fortune Reefer in Puerto Rico in 1997, gives an average rehabilitation cost of US$ 2 million per ha. The US$ 1.05 million payout covered, amongst other things, the re-attachment of around 400 live pieces of elkhorn coral (NOAA, 1997b). In a study comparing the eectiveness of dierent coral reef rehabilitation techniques in the Maldives, Edwards et al. (1994) estimated costs for three dierent options. One-cubic-metre concrete blocks cost US$ 318/ m2 (US$ 1.59 m/ha using recommended maximum of 50% coverage for larger areas), concrete Armor¯ex mattresses cost US$ 100/m2 (US$ 1 m/ha) and anchored chain-link fencing cost US$ 39.4/m2 (US$ 0.4 m/ha) (all costs are in 1994 prices). At the other end of the scale, low-tech reef rehabilitation initiatives in low energy environments need only cost in the order of US$ 10,000 per ha (Lindahl, 1998 and personal communication, 1998). Mangroves. Costs for planting mangroves can range from approximately US$ 3000 to 28,500 per ha using seeds (collected or purchased), from US$ 5700 to 230,000 per ha when using seedlings, and from US$ 90,000 to 510,000 per ha using three-year-old transplants (NOAA, 1997c). It should be noted that these costs are primarily for small-scale experiments and that overheads are not included. Furthermore, the costs very much depend on density of spacing, which ultimately aects the likelihood of success. A recent Puerto Rican project to restore tidal ¯ushing to 400 ha of black mangrove cost US$ 1.6 million, representing US$ 4000 per ha. This involved topographical alterations to increase tidal ¯ow and saltwater exchange, and clearance and planting of mangroves (NOAA, 1997d). Seagrasses. Several examples are given in NOAA (1997c) for the costs of rehabilitating seagrass beds. For Volume 37/Numbers 8±12/August±December 1998 TABLE 1 Costs typically incurred in habitat rehabilitation/creation initiatives. (A) Capital costs Pre-construction Feasibility studies ± to identify appropriate sites Pilot studies ± small scale experiments to test dierent methods Existing site surveys (e.g. topographical, hydrological, chemical, physical, biological) Nearby site surveys ± to compare parameters of nearby habitats Objective setting ± to determine precisely what is wanted Design (e.g. of topography and restoration methods to be used) Tendering (i.e. speci®cation and bill of quantities) Management plans ± to devise a plan for managing the site Land purchase (e.g. from farmer or landowner) Construction Site preparation (e.g. excavation, contouring) Equipment (e.g. boats and earth diggers) Labour (e.g. wages and expenses for professionals and volunteers) Building materials (e.g. water control structures, pipes) Stock (e.g. vegetation and animals) Transport (e.g. of materials and stock) (B) Operational costs Management ± to control and enhance the development of the site (e.g. prevent disturbance to vegetation/animals, adjust chemical status) Monitoring ± to assess how the site develops (e.g. development of plant and animal communities) Maintenance ± to maintain operational structures and equipment (e.g. to repair damages to structures and re-plant vegetation) Each of the above operational costs may include: Materials (e.g. fencing, chemicals, camera ®lm and processing) Equipment (e.g. vehicles, cameras, stakes) Sta wages (full and part time) Expenses (e.g. of volunteers) Administration (e.g. telephone, postage) (C) Other costs Compensation (e.g. to farmer or landowner) Legal costs (e.g. relating to site purchase) Opportunity cost of the site (e.g. land value/loss of agricultural output/loss of existing ecological value) Damage to donor site (i.e. loss of value to site donating organisms) TABLE 2 Costs for habitat restoration/creation per ha.a Cost estimate Low (US$ 000/ha) High (US$ 000/ha) a Coral reefs Mangroves Seagrasses Saltmarshes 10 6500 3 510 9 684 2 160 Sources: See main text. Note: All costs are in 1997 prices. temperate seagrasses (e.g. eelgrass), costs range from US$ 9000 to 46,000 per ha when using plugs (i.e. where the blades, roots, rhizomes and sediment are transplanted together), and from US$ 11,500 to 74,000 per ha when using shoots on their own. The UK Steering GroupÕs Report on Bio-diversity Action Plans (English Nature, 1996) assumed an average cost of around US$ 8,600 per ha for transplanting temperate seagrasses, assuming 1000 ha are planted. A 1994 seagrass rehabilitation project in Galveston Bay, USA, cost the equivalent of US$ 1000 for 1 ha (NOAA, 1997d). However, this cost represents a minimum ®nancial cost since signi®cant amounts of manpower, supplies and equipment were provided in-kind by government departments and universities. For tropical and subtropical seagrasses, costs have been known to be in the order of US$ 22,800 to 684,000 per ha using seedlings, and US$ 228,000 using plugs (NOAA, 1997c). Saltmarshes. A considerable amount of work on rehabilitating/creating saltmarshes has been undertaken in the United States. Based on the extensive US literature available, NOAA (1997c) advises that costs for planting saltmarshes are in the order of US$ 9000 to 46,000 per ha. The lower end of the scale is for quality seeding efforts, whilst the upper end is generally for commercially grown stock. Key factors are the plant spacing and the method of establishment in terms of seeding, or transplanting nursery or wild stock. In addition to planting costs, other costs (e.g. topographical and hydrological alterations) can range from around US$ 600 to 80,000 per ha, depending on existing site conditions (NOAA, 1997c). However, two USA case studies put the overall cost of saltmarsh creation in the order of US$ 100,000 to 160,000 per ha. At the Galilee Bird Sanctuary, Rhode Island, restoration works to 14 ha of saltmarsh cost US$ 1.4 million. The rehabilitation work was primarily to restore tidal ¯ows through the re-excavation of natural channels and the installation of culverts (NOAA, 1997d). In 1997, US$ 7 million was earmarked under the US Coastal Wetlands Planning, Protection and 375 Marine Pollution Bulletin Restoration Act to create 44.5 ha of marshland at Greenhill Marsh in Louisiana, USA (NOAA, 1997e). It is interesting to compare the USA experience with that in the UK where the government is adopting a completely dierent approach to saltmarsh rehabilitation/creation. Several experiments are underway in Essex whereby agricultural land is opened up to ¯ooding by the sea. This generally involves moving back the line of sea defence and hence is referred to as `managed retreat'. Little human intervention is required other than monitoring and minor maintenance. The re-vegetation is left to occur naturally. At Northey Island, a 1991 scheme of 1 ha cost an equivalent US$ 43,000; at Horsey Island, a 1993 scheme of 2 ha cost the equivalent of US$ 1860 per ha; and at Orplands, a 1995 scheme of 40 ha cost an equivalent US$ 2600 per ha (East Midlands Environmental Consultants, 1995). In each case, the scheme costs are based on the engineering costs required to secure existing secondary defences further inland, which varied greatly for each site. All pre- and postconstruction phase costs (e.g. planning, site survey, monitoring and opportunity costs ± see Table 1) are excluded. This preliminary study has not been able to identify the range of costs relating to the rehabilitation/creation of sand dunes, lagoons and shingle ridges, although several examples are provided below. Sand dunes. Posford Duvivier was recently involved in a sand dune rehabilitation project which forms part of a coastal defence scheme at Tramore, Ireland. Estimated rehabilitation costs for almost 2.5 ha of dune were US$ 45,000, equating to US$ 17,000 per ha. The rehabilitation works were fairly intensive and included replanting marram grass and providing fencing both for preventing access and for trapping wind-blown sand. A further US$ 22,000 was required for additional gabion revetments, and overall annual maintenance costs are estimated to be, on average, US$ 830 per year (Posford Duvivier, 1997). Following a severe winter in 1991, a sand dune rehabilitation project was undertaken in Monterey, California, USA, to re-vegetate 17.8 ha of coastal dune at a cost US$ 295,000. This represents US$ 18,800 per ha and involved placing over 150,000 seedlings of 26 native dune plants (NOAA, 1997d). Lagoons. Creating marine lagoons in the UK so far has an average cost of US$ 7000/ha. This is based on creating one lagoon in Norfolk, and one in Cleveland, with combined construction (i.e. earth moving) costs of US$ 51,000 (updated from 1995 costs) for a total area of 7.2 ha (English Nature, personal communication, 1997). Shingle Ridges. No speci®c cost data was been found on rehabilitating/creating shingle ridges, although engineering costs for creating shingle beaches can be in the order of up to US$ 6000 per linear metre (Posford Duvivier, 1996a). Experiments have been undertaken assessing various techniques of establishing shingle vegetation, although costs were not readily available (e.g. Walmsley and Davy, 1997). 376 Comments on the costs of habitat rehabilitation/creation For a number of reasons, some of which are discussed below, the costs detailed above only provide an indication of the potential extent of costs that may be incurred in habitat rehabilitation/creation schemes. Table 3 presents some of the main factors that aect the magnitude of the cost components shown in Table 1. Expenditure on habitat rehabilitation/creation schemes documented in literature is often dictated by available budgets. This is especially true in the USA where signi®cant amounts of money are sometimes made available, particularly as a result of compensation payments in retribution for damages to habitats (as in the above USA coral reef and saltmarsh examples). Attempts at saving on costs, particularly on initial site surveys and design, can compromise the likely success of a project. Initial site surveys to determine existing site conditions and conditions at nearby similar habitats are often of paramount importance to a projectÕs overall success. However, the extent and expense of the dierent surveys required depends on the type of habitat to be restored/created, and the current level of general and site speci®c understanding of the relevant parameters. For example, when creating saltmarsh and mangrove habitats, the inundation (tidal) regime, elevation, and water column strati®cation of temperature and salinity should TABLE 3 Factors aecting magnitude of habitat rehabilitation/creation costs. (1) Location of the site site accessibility site remoteness closeness and links to similar and other habitats (2) Current or potential use of the site need to purchase the land/pay compensation existing use and value of the site potential for other uses of the site (3) The operation type of habitat scale complexity restoration or creation density of planting depth of planting previous experience of designer and contractors intended timescale proposed method of establishment- natural, seeding or transplanting sources of vegetation ± natural or commercial local labour and material costs (4) Conditions at the site exposure (e.g. to wind, tides, waves) existing topography (need for alteration) type of substrate (chemical and physical properties) existing habitat/species present likely need to control other plants/animals presence of contamination use of adjacent areas (5) Availability of funds Volume 37/Numbers 8±12/August±December 1998 be assessed. Other necessary surveys may include those relating to a range of water, chemical, biological and soil parameters as discussed in other papers in the Special Issue. Scheme costs are highly dependent on the method of rehabilitation/creation adopted. For example, relatively little expenditure has been used to create successful new saltmarshes in the UK because the responsible agencies have been focusing on cost-eective and practical means of creating the right physical conditions for natural vegetation re-establishment. Minimal expenditure has been necessary to create the necessary conditions, and no expenditure has been required to plant vegetation. The results so far appear encouraging, with saltmarsh plants readily establishing themselves. Many of the costs documented in the available literature provide little detail as to exactly what they include. The costs that are most often recorded relate only to the construction and/or ®nancial costs, which are relatively easily identi®ed, or they may represent a particular fund made available for the rehabilitation/creation. Invariably there will be other unrecorded costs such as sta time, facilities and materials provided by numerous organisations involved, and any o-site scheme impacts including those incurred by the donor site. As emphasised in the introduction, the overall cost of rehabilitation/creation schemes can only be fully determined on their completion. There are many uncertainties involved which can lead to complications and additional cost implications. For example, one incident of unexpectedly severe wave action or rainfall can easily impede or destroy the rehabilitation process. Monitoring of rehabilitation progress should be carried out at all stages to help ensure that the habitat develops as intended and to enable any problems to be identi®ed and recti®ed. It is also a cost-eective means of furthering our understanding of rehabilitation techniques, since each rehabilitation initiative is eectively an experiment from which others can learn. The extent of monitoring methods and their cost varies enormously depending on several factors: the techniques used; the frequency of monitoring; and who carries it out. Techniques range from basic observations to highly detailed analyses. The use of volunteers to assist can reduce the costs signi®cantly, although their opportunity costs should be accounted for. Bene®ts Coastal habitats provide a vast array of bene®ts to mankind in the form of goods (products) and services (functions). Since few of the goods and services are traded in the market-place, they rarely have a readily observable monetary or ®nancial value. However, they can have a considerable socio-economic value, particularly when utilised on a sustainable basis. Coastal habitat rehabilitation schemes should in theory be able to re-introduce many, if not all, of the bene®ts associated with each habitat. There are several ways of categorising the full range of bene®ts attributable to dierent habitats (see Barton, 1994; Pearce and Turner, 1990). Possibly the most comprehensive and appropriate is based on the notion of ÔTotal Economic ValueÕ, which comprises ÔdirectÕ and Ôindirect use valuesÕ and Ônon-use valuesÕ, as outlined in Table 4. Within the literature on environmental valuation, some authors suggest that there are other values additional to those shown in Table 4. These include for example, Ôbio-diversity valueÕ, Ôaesthetic valueÕ and Ôprimary valueÕ. However, it can be argued that these represent dierent attributes that are, or should be, accounted for within the valuation of the above uses and non-uses (i.e. they are attributes that contribute towards the use and non-use values of a habitat). On the other hand, in addition to the ÔcurrentÕ habitat values shown in Table 4, there will also be a range of ÔpotentialÕ values. For example, a coral reef may not currently be used for tourism, but it may be in the future. Similarly, a particular coral reef species may have no current use, but it may prove to be a valuable product in the future (e.g. for medicinal purposes). ÔOption valueÕ may capture humankindÕs willingness to pay now to preserve a reef in case these values may arise in the future, but it does not represent the extent of future related earnings which may be massive. Valuation of bene®ts Since economists tend to determine values based on observing market behaviour, the value of non-traded environmental goods and services needs to be measured in some other way. Over the past few decades, various economic techniques have been adopted which now enable the value of all habitat uses and non-uses (but excluding intrinsic value) to be estimated (Hufschmidt et al., 1983; Pearce and Turner, 1990). The methodologies are by no means problem-free, but they are constantly being re®ned and improved through further use and subsequent critical review. They should only ever be used when their limitations are fully acknowledged and minimised accordingly. Some of the main techniques can be summarised as follows: · Change in productivity/production function: A technique based on ``cause and eect'' which assesses direct and indirect relationships between the loss of an environmental resource and associated changes in economic output. · Replacement/relocation cost: A technique whereby the value of a habitat is assumed to be equivalent to the cost of replacing or relocating it elsewhere. · Aversive/preventative cost: A technique whereby the value of a habitat is assumed to be equivalent to previous expenditure used to avert/prevent damage to that habitat type. 377 Marine Pollution Bulletin TABLE 4 Categories of environmental bene®ts.a (A) Use values Direct use values ± goods and services directly consumed by users, for example: Products (e.g. edible, ornamental, construction, medicinal) Recreation Waste assimilation Research Education Indirect use values ± indirect bene®ts arising from ecological systems, for example: Biological support ± links to other species and habitats Physical protection (e.g. coastal defence function) Global life support ± functions which help to support life on earth (B) Non-use values Option value ± the value individuals place on expected future use and indirect use of the components of ecological systems Quasi-option value ± the value arising from expected new information which will arise from the conservation of bio-diversity for future use Existence value ± a range of values, encompassing aesthetic and cultural aspects, arising from some or all of the following human motivations: Bequest motives ± preservation for future generations Stewardship motives ± preservation for its own sake Altruism ± preservation so that it is available for others Q-Altruism ± the belief that organisms have intrinsic rights (C) Non-anthropocentric values Intrinsic value ± organisms have a worth of their own regardless of human perceptions a Source: Adapted from DoE (1996). · Hedonic pricing: A technique based on extracting the environmental value of a marketed product by analysing the eect of each attribute on the overall market price. · Travel cost: A technique whereby the travelling time and costs of a sample of visitors to a site are used to determine a demand curve and hence the recreational value for that site. · Contingent valuation: A questionnaire survey technique whereby a representative sample of individuals are asked their ``willingness to pay'' to ensure or prevent a speci®c environmental change. The responses are interpreted and aggregated to produce an overall value, potentially including option and existence value. Examples of the bene®ts for dierent habitats There are few examples in the literature providing speci®c monetary values for use and non-use values of habitats in general, let alone those to be gained from habitat rehabilitation/creation initiatives. The following paragraphs highlight some monetary values that have been estimated for bene®ts relating to coastal habitats. Meanwhile, Table 5, compiled for this study, provides an overview of the relative magnitude of bene®ts that could potentially be associated with rehabilitating/creating various coastal habitats. Coral reefs. As seen in Table 5, and detailed further in Spurgeon (1992), coral reefs provide potentially signi®cant bene®ts through the provision of products, recreation, and coastal protection, as well as potentially for their non-use value. Mattson and DeFoor (1985) esti378 mated values for the recreational bene®t provided by coral reefs in Florida. Based on direct recreational expenditure, the reefs can be argued to generate US$ 235,000 haÿ1 yrÿ1 , equivalent to US$ 11.8 million over 50 years (not discounted). When related indirect expenditure is included, the reefs can be argued to generate US$ 1.27 m haÿ1 yrÿ1 , or US$ 63.5 million over 50 years (not discounted). The natural coast protection function of reefs can be argued to be worth up to US$ 170,000 per km, based on the cost of arti®cial coast protection structures (see Posford Duvivier, 1996a). A value of US$ 79 million per year for the non-use value (relating to Australian nationals only) of the Great Barrier Reef has also been estimated (Hundloe, 1990). Mangroves. Mangroves also provide a great many products and services, as revealed in a review of their economic value undertaken by Spaninks and van Beukering (1997). The values shown in Table 6 relate to the highest values determined for various products and services provided by mangrove systems, as calculated by ®ve dierent studies. In addition, a value for the coast protection function provided by mangroves could be in the same order as that suggested for coral reefs. Given that any mangrove system could give rise to many, if not all, of these bene®ts, it can be surmised that potentially signi®cant bene®ts can be attached to the restoration of mangrove systems. Seagrasses. There appear to be few data on the economic value of seagrasses. However, a study in Australia (Watson et al., 1993) examining the relationship between prawn ®sheries and seagrasses in Cairns Harbour, Australia, estimated that the nursery function of the seagrasses ultimately yields, and is thus responsible Volume 37/Numbers 8±12/August±December 1998 TABLE 5 Relative magnitude of bene®ts associated with habitats (and thus restoration). Bene®ts Coral ReefsMangroves Seagrasses Saltmarsh Sand Dunes Lagoons Shingle Ridges Direct uses Products Edible Construction Pharmaceutical Ornamental Recreation Waste assimilation Research Education XX XX XX XX XXX ÿ XX XX XX XX XX X XX XXX XX XX XX ÿ ? X X X XX XX XX ÿ ? X XX XXX XX XX XX X ? X XXX X XX XX X ÿ ? X XX X XX XX ± X ? X XXX X XX XX Indirect uses Biological support Coastal defence Global life support XX XXX XX XXX XXX XX XXX XX X XX XXX X X XXX X X XX X X XXX X Option value Quasi-option value Existence value Intrinsic value XX XX XXX XXX XX XX XXX XXX XX XX XXX XXX XX XX XXX XXX XX XX XXX XXX XX XX XXX XXX X X XXX XXX Symbol Bene®t Description None Low Medium High Not Known Provides no bene®t Provides minor economic bene®t only Provides bene®t between low and high Potentially provides signi®cant economic value Could potentially provide large bene®ts in the future Key: ÿ X XX XXX ? TABLE 6 Valuation of selected mangrove bene®ts.a Service/product Value (US$ haÿ1 yrÿ1 ) Value (US$/ha for 50 yr) Author 126 435 756 7833 189 20 6300 21,750 37,800 391,600 9500 1000 Ruitenbeek (1992) Christensen (1982) Gammage (1994) Lal (1990) Christensen (1982) Ruitenbeek (1992) On-site sustainable ®sheries Other products (e.g. fruits, thatch) Sustainable forestry Waste assimilation O-site ®sheries Bio-diversity (capturable) a Note: All values updated to 1997 values for this study. for, commercial prawns worth in the order of US$ 1150 haÿ1 yrÿ1 . Over a 50 year period this gives a value of US$ 57,500 (not discounted). Saltmarsh. Saltmarsh systems provide a range of important products and services. In the UK, various values have been calculated for dierent widths of saltmarshes that eectively act as a form of coastal defence, leading to potentially massive savings on the cost of arti®cial coastal defences. For example, it has been estimated that an 80 m wide strip of saltmarsh could result in cost savings equivalent to an amount in the order of US$ 0.53 million to US$ 1 million per hectare (King and Lester, 1995). The same study also provided an example of a value for wildfowling of US$ 870 haÿ1 yrÿ1 and for agricultural grazing of US$ 26 haÿ1 yrÿ1 . A dierent study estimated that saltmarsh grazing in North Norfolk could be worth in the order of US$ 200 haÿ1 yrÿ1 (Posford Duvivier, 1996b). Sand dunes. A comprehensive review of the Total Economic Value of sand dune systems was undertaken by Posford Duvivier (1996a), although it did not extend to placing monetary values on each type of bene®t. However, in the coastal defence project appraisal study mentioned earlier regarding sand dunes at Tramore, Ireland (Posford Duvivier, 1997), monetary estimates were made of the economic bene®t of rehabilitating a section of sand dune. Estimated total present value bene®ts of US$ 380,000 were identi®ed assuming a 50 year timescale and a discount rate of 6%. This comprised US$ 290,000 recreational bene®t for maintaining access along the dune and US$ 90,000 coast protection bene®t for the continued protection function of the dunes acting to prevent the partial destruction of an internationally important wetland. Lagoons and shingle ridges. No values were identi®ed at this stage for the bene®ts of lagoons or shingle ridges, 379 Marine Pollution Bulletin although as Table 5 shows, there are likely to be signi®cant bene®ts. Shingle ridges, for example, could provide bene®ts potentially worth thousands of US$ as a bathing and recreational beach resource. Comments on the bene®ts of habitat rehabilitation Many factors aect the magnitude of bene®ts that potentially accrue from rehabilitating/creating coastal habitats, some of which are listed in Table 7. Prior knowledge of all of these factors, inter alia, is required before a complete valuation of the full bene®ts from rehabilitating/creating coastal habitats is possible. Despite the existence of appropriate methodologies, few attempts have been made to assess the Total Economic Value of any coastal habitats. This is partly due to the diculties encountered in assessing the true value of some of the bene®ts. However, it also re¯ects the contentious nature of attempting to value the environment, and peopleÕs aversion towards such valuations. No studies appear to have addressed the full economic bene®ts of coastal habitat rehabilitation/creation initiatives. The main diculties in bene®t valuation relate to the lack of relevant data; the relatively poor understanding of inter-relationships between neighbouring habitats and between environmental causes and eects; and problems with theoretical issues relating to the estimation of non-use values. However, development of the various methodologies is continually being advanced, as is our understanding of the underpinning natural science and economic theory. Environmental valuation is possible and the reliability and validity of estimates should improve each time an assessment is properly undertaken and subsequently reviewed. TABLE 7 Factors aecting magnitude of habitat rehabilitation/creation bene®ts. (1) Location of the site site accessibility site remoteness closeness and links to similar and other habitats number and type of species attracted to the site amount of the same habitat nearby (2) Current and potential use of the site population of local, regional and national residents likely direct and indirect use by locals number of current and potential visitors likely direct and indirect use by visitors (3) The operation scale of the operation type of habitat to be rehabilitated/created speed of habitat development (4) Conditions at the site visual attractiveness local culture local values, money and economy 380 Whilst it is sometimes useful to cite monetary values from the literature to illustrate the value of habitats, it can also be dangerous. The values can easily be misinterpreted and used elsewhere inappropriately. As will be discussed later, great care is needed in reporting bene®ts and consequently using those values for other purposes. Whilst the monetary value of most habitat bene®ts can now be estimated in some way, it is vital to realise that Ôintrinsic valueÕ will always be a component of value for which it is impossible to place a monetary ®gure on. Although it is, by its very de®nition, divorced from the concept of human welfare, it is nevertheless an important constituent value. It can thus be argued that any valuation of habitat bene®ts will only ever produce a minimum monetary value. Potential applications for a bene®t-cost analysis approach BCA can play a valuable role in the future of coastal habitat rehabilitation/creation. Firstly, it can be used in the decision-making process to choose between dierent scheme options. This is its classic role as a tool for economic appraisal. Secondly, it can be used as a valuable framework to help maximise the economic eciency of a particular rehabilitation/creation technique. An example of the practical application of BCA as a means of project appraisal is its use in assessing coastal defence options for the sand dunes of Tramore, Ireland. An assessment of the economic bene®ts and costs of dierent coastal defence options for a deteriorating sand dune system revealed dune rehabilitation (coupled with the use of small scale gabions) to be the best solution from both an environmental and economic point of view. Comparing discounted scheme costs (US$ 66,000) to discounted scheme bene®ts (US$ 380,000) produced a BCR of almost 6 (Posford Duvivier, 1997). The BCR was used to justify government funded coastal defence grant aid for the scheme on economic grounds. When one compares the potential scale of bene®ts associated with coastal habitats with the potential costs for their rehabilitation/creation it seems that there should be scope for the economic justi®cation of rehabilitating/creating the coastal habitats reviewed in this paper. However, as is explained below, there is a problem with the timing of those bene®ts, linked with the eect of ÔdiscountingÕ. As a framework to help maximise the bene®ts and eciency of rehabilitation schemes, BCA can be used both to help identify the most suitable location and to determine the best rehabilitation technique. For example, there may be a choice of potential locations for a habitat rehabilitation/creation scheme if a large volume of dredged material becomes available, or if compensation is required for an accident or development which severely damages a coastal habitat. In such cases, an holistic BCA framework can be used to assess the potential costs and bene®ts for each site, based on an appreciation of all the relevant parameters. The most ecient and preferred site can then be selected. Volume 37/Numbers 8±12/August±December 1998 There will always be a range of decisions to take regarding the precise rehabilitation/creation technique to be used and the timing of implementation. Each variation in methodology will involve its own technical, environmental and economic trade-os. The BCA philosophy can provide an invaluable framework to help assess which variation should be selected to provide the maximum overall bene®t. For example, when restoring coastal habitats, the dominant lifeform, whether vegetation or coral, can generally be re-established by transplantation, seeding, natural inter-habitat colonisation processes, or by all of these means. The cost of each technique varies considerably, as does the magnitude and timing of the potential bene®ts. Therefore, although transplanting vegetation may cost more than seeding or natural colonisation, greater economic bene®ts may arise because the annual bene®ts accruing from storm protection, biological support and recreation are generated signi®cantly earlier. On the other hand, in other circumstances, it may be that the vegetation will colonise rapidly anyway and there could even be an overall economic loss if planting or seeding were to be undertaken. Problems with the application of bene®t cost analysis Although there are strong arguments for adopting a BCA approach, a number of fundamental issues cause problems in its application. Some of the main problems are outlined below, together with potential means of overcoming them. Many habitat-related bene®ts, particularly non-use values, are both dicult and expensive to quantify in monetary terms. As suggested earlier, diculties are increasingly being overcome with more frequent application of valuation techniques. The relatively recent concept of Ôbene®t transferÕ has potential for reducing the costs associated with valuing some environmental bene®ts. Where a number of valuations have been undertaken for the same type of environmental bene®t, there is sense in drawing upon these values to indicate the value of a similar bene®t elsewhere. One of the main applications of bene®t transfer in the UK has been in the assessment of recreational and amenity bene®ts resulting from coastal and ¯ood defence schemes, in particular where environmental enhancements have been integral to the scheme design (see Penning-Rowsell et al., 1992). Several Ôstandard valuesÕ have been derived for use at a feasibility study level from a number of previously undertaken contingent valuation studies. However, it is vital that a number of site-speci®c factors are taken into consideration, otherwise there is a great danger that incorrect values will be adopted. As yet, there have been too few suciently thorough valuation studies for this approach to be widely practised. Intrinsic value will always remain an incalculable element of the bene®t accruing from habitat rehabilitation/creation schemes. However, it is possible to make an allowance for this alongside the BCA process, either qualitatively or quantitatively. The greater the diversity and abundance of organisms resulting from a rehabilitation/creation scheme, the greater the potential intrinsic value. Coupled with the diculty of assessing other non-use values, there are thus strong arguments for the use of other non-monetary decision making tools. For example, there are various Ômulti-attributeÕ techniques (e.g. multi-criteria analysis) which provide a framework for the identi®cation of a broad range of potentially aected parameters and adopt a scoring and weighting process to account for the importance of any changes. Many complex uncertainties inherent in the natural environment aect the assessment of potential costs and bene®ts of habitat restoration. They include the complex and dynamic nature of habitats and the environmental factors that in¯uence them (e.g. waves, hydrology and climate), as well as phenomena such as global warming, sea-level rise and the El Ni~ no Southern Oscillation. Such uncertainties should be taken into account within the BCA process as far as possible by means of risk and sensitivity analyses. These latter analyses make use of probabilities and a range of high to low valuation estimates to assess a full range of potential scenarios. Finally, use of the economic procedure ÔdiscountingÕ, an essential part of BCA, prejudices against restoration. In discounting, a Ôdiscount rateÕ, currently set at 6% for most UK government funded schemes, is used to convert all future ¯ows of money to an equivalent Ôpresent valueÕ. The process re¯ects the fact that future sums of money are worth less than those available today. As a result, while most costs associated with rehabilitation initiatives are incurred early on and thus have a relatively high Ôpresent valueÕ cost, rehabilitation bene®ts rarely accrue until substantially later in time, thus generating signi®cantly reduced Ôpresent valueÕ bene®ts. In order to improve the bene®t-cost ratio of a rehabilitation/creation scheme, it is therefore essential to keep costs to a minimum, perhaps staggering them over time, and to attempt to maximise bene®ts, in particular through ensuring that they accrue as early on as possible. An alternative approach is to question the recommended discount rate, and calculate several BCRs based on a range of discount rates, including a rate of zero. Conclusions and recommendations This paper has demonstrated that if the full range of bene®ts relating to coastal habitat rehabilitation/creation is valued, then low-cost habitat rehabilitation/ creation schemes can be justi®able on economic grounds. Current and future restoration initiatives should attempt to set out clearly all costs incurred using an agreed framework. This itemisation should include the identi®cation of all resources used, including, for example, that of pre-scheme planning, use and training of volunteers, and on-going monitoring requirements. More studies should be conducted to determine the economic bene®ts derived from coastal habitats and to 381 Marine Pollution Bulletin assess the economics of rehabilitation/creation initiatives. Further studies into economic bene®t valuation would help in several ways: improving the accuracy of the techniques; generating more Ôstandard valuesÕ for bene®t transfers (thereby potentially reducing the costs of future valuations); and ultimately leading to a more ecient use of resources. The concept of using a BCA framework should be considered in all rehabilitation initiatives at an early stage to ensure that the most ecient site and method of rehabilitation/creation is selected. If coastal habitat rehabilitation/creation is to be widely implemented, greater attempts should be made to: ®nd ways of reducing the overall costs of such initiatives; devise means of increasing the rate at which environmental bene®ts accrue; and to identify mechanisms for appropriating the environmental bene®ts. The author is grateful to Posford Duvivier for their support in the undertaking of this study. He would also like to thank Scottish Natural Heritage, the UK government advisory body for conservation in Scotland, who kindly contributed funds to the study. Thanks are also extended to the many people who generously provided information for the paper and to Jonathan Burney (English Nature, UK), Ronan Palmer (Environment Agency, UK) and Richard Wing®eld (Gibb Ltd, UK) who reviewed the paper. Barton, D. N. (1994) Economic Factors and Valuation of Tropical Coastal Resources. University of Bergen, Norway, Report 14/94. Christensen, B. (1982) Management and utilization of mangroves in Asia and the Paci®c. FAO Environment paper No 3. FAO, Rome. DoE (1996) Towards a Methodology for Costing Bio-diversity Targets in the UK: Report to Department of Environment, HMSO. East Midlands Environmenta Consultants Ltd. (1995) Habitat Action Plans, Habitat Cost Data. Report to English Nature. Edwards, A., Clark, S. and Brown, B. (1994) Rehabilitation of Degraded Reefs Using Arti®cial Reef Blocks. Report to UK Overseas Development Administration (R4533). English Nature (1996) Bio-diversity: The UK Steering Group Report, Vol. 2: Action Plans. London, HMSO. Gammage, S. (1994) Estimating the Total Economic Value of a Mangrove Ecosystem in El Salvador. Report to UK Overseas Development Administration. ODA, London. Hufschmidt, M. M., James, D. E., Meister, A. D., Bower, B. T. and Dixon, J. A. (1983) Environment, Natural Systems and Development: an Economic Valuation Guide. John Hopkins University Press, Baltimore. Hundloe, T. J. (1990) Measuring the value of the Great Barrier Reef. Austr. Parks and Rec. 26 (3), 11±15. King, S. E. and Lester, J. N. (1995) The value of salt marsh as a sea defence. Marine Pollution Bulletin 30 (3), 180±189. 382 Lal, P. N. (1990) Conservation or conversion of mangroves in Fiji. Occasional Papers of the East±West Environment and Policy Institute, paper No 11. EWEPI, Honolulu. Lindahl, U. (1998) Low-tech rehabilitation of coral reefs through transplantation of corals: implications for cost-eective management in developing countries. International Workshop on the Rehabilitation of Degraded Coastal Systems. Phuket Marine Biological Centre, Thailand, 1998. Mattson, J. S. and DeFoor, J. A. (1985) Natural Resource Damages: Restitution as a Mechanism to Slow Destruction of FloridaÕs Natural Resources. Journal of Land Use Environment Law 1 (3), 295±319. NOAA (1997a) Elpis coral reef restoration. http://www-orca.nos.noaa.gov/darp/seregion /elpis.htm. NOAA (1997b) Settlement speeds Puerto Rico coral reef repair. http:// www-orca.nos.noaa.gov/public-aairs/pr97/oct97/noaa97-r417. html. NOAA (1997c) Primary Restoration. Guidance Document for Natural Resource Damage Assessment under the Oil Pollution Act of 1990. National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration, Damage Assessment and Restoration Program. Silver Springs, MD. NOAA (1997d) Coastal Restoration and Protection. Lessons learned. National Oceanic and Atmospheric Administration, Damage Assessment and Restoration Program. Silver Springs, MD. Penning-Rowsell, E. C., Green, C. H., Thompson, P. M., Coker, A. M., Tunstall, S. J., Richards, C. and Parker, D. J. (1992) The economics of coastal management: a manual of bene®ts techniques, The ÔYellow ManualÕ. Belhaven press, London. Pearce, D. W. and Turner, R. K. (1990) Economics of Natural Resources and the Environment. Harvester Wheatsheaf. Posford Duvivier (1996a) The Role of Dune Management in Coastal Defence: An Environmental, Technical and Economic Evaluation. Report to Welsh Oce and Countryside Council for Wales. Posford Duvivier (1996b) Financial Values of Five Important Marine/ Coastal Wildlife Areas in England. Report to English Nature. Posford Duvivier (1997) Tramore Coastal Defence Study. Report to Waterford County Council, Ireland. Ruitenbeek, H. J. (1992) Mangrove management: an economic analysis of management options with a focus on Bintuni Bay, Irian Jaya. EMDI Environmental Reports No. 8. Environmental Management Development in Indonesia Project (EMDI), Jakarta and Halifax. Spaninks, F. and van Beukering, P. (1997) Economic Valuation of Mangroves: A Review of Techniques and Case Studies with Special Attention to the Production Function Approach. CREED Working paper series, IIED London/IVM Amsterdam. Spurgeon, J. P. G. (1992) The economic valuation of coral reefs. Marine Pollution Bulletin 24 (11), 529±536. Walmsley, C. A. and Davy A. J. (1997) The restoration of coastal shingle vegetation: eects of substrate composition on the establishment of seedlings. Journal of Applied Ecology 34 (1), 143±153. Watson, R. A., Coles, R. G. and Lee Long W. J. (1993) Simulation estimates of annual yield and landed value for commercial penaeid prawns from a tropical seagrass habitat, Northern Queensland, Australia. Australian Journal of Marine Freshwater Resources 44, 211±219.