Exercise Set 1 1) Show that Lexiogarphic preferences are transitive and complete, but not continous. 2) On a recent doctors visit, you have been told that you must watch your calorie intake and must make sure you get enough vitamin E in your diet. A. You have decided that, to make life simple, you will from now on eat only steak and carrots. A nice steak has 250 calories and 10 units of vitamins, and a serving of carrots has 100 calories and 30 units of vitamins. Your doctors instructions are that you must eat no more than 2,000 calories and consume at least 150 units of vitamins per day. a. In a graph with servings of carrots on the horizontal axis and servings of steak on the vertical axis, illustrate all combinations of carrots and steaks that make up a 2,000-calorie-a-day diet. b. On the same graph, illustrate all the combinations of carrots and steaks that provide exactly 150 units of vitamins. c. On this graph, shade in the bundles of carrots and steaks that satisfy both of your doctors requirements. d. Now suppose you can buy a serving of carrots for $2 and a steak for $6. You have $26 per day in your food budget. In your graph, illustrate your budget constraint. If you love steak and dont mind eating or not eating carrots, what bundle will you choose (assuming you take your doctors instructions seriously)? B. Continue with the scenario as described in part A, letting carrots be denoted by x1 and steak by x2 . a. Define the line you drew in A(a) mathematically. b. Define the line you drew in A(b) mathematically. 1 c. In formal set notation, write down the expression that is equivalent to the shaded area in A(c). d. Derive the exact bundle you indicated on your graph in A(d). 3) Airlines offer frequent flyers different kinds of perks that we will model here as reductions in average prices per mile flown. A. Suppose that an airline charges 20 cents per mile flown. However, once a customer reaches 25,000 miles in a given year, the price drops to 10 cents per mile flown for each additional mile. The alternate way to travel is to drive by car, which costs 16 cents per mile. a. Consider a consumer who has a travel budget of $10,000 per year, a budget that can be spent on the cost of getting to places as well as other consumption while traveling. On a graph with miles flown on the horizontal axis and other consumption on the vertical, illustrate the budget constraint for someone who only considers flying (and not driving) to travel destinations. b. On a similar graph with miles driven on the horizontal axis, illustrate the budget constraint for someone that considers only driving (and not flying) as a means of travel. c. By overlaying these two budget constraints (changing the good on the horizontal axis simply to miles traveled), can you explain how frequent flyer perks might persuade some to fly a lot more than he or she otherwise would? B. Determine where the air-travel budget from A(a) intersects the car budget from A(b). 3) A. Suppose now that your grandparents set up a trust fund that pays you $300 per week. In addition, you have up to 60 hours of leisure that you could devote to work at a wage of $20 per hour. a. On a graph with leisure hours per week on the horizontal axis and weekly consumption in dollars on the vertical, illustrate your weekly budget constraint. 2 b. How does your graph change when your wage falls to $10? c. How does the graph change if instead the trust fund gets raided by your parents, leaving you with only a $100 payment per week? B. How would you write your budget constraint described in part A? 4) Suppose you are a farmer whose land produces 50 units of food this year and is expected to produce another 50 units of food next year. (Assume that there is no one else in the world to trade with.) A. On a graph with food consumption this year on the horizontal axis and food consumption next year on the vertical, indicate your choice set assuming there is no way for you to store food that you harvest this year for future consumption. a. Now suppose that you have a barn in which you can store food. However, over the course of a year, half the food that you store spoils. How does this change your choice set? b. Now suppose that, in addition to the food units you harvest off your land, you also own a cow. You could slaughter the cow this year and eat it for 50 units of food. Or you could let it graze for another year and let it grow fatter, then slaughter it next year for 75 units of food. But you dont have any means of refrigeration and so you cannot store meat over time. How does this alter your budget constraint (assuming you still have the barn from part (a))? B. How would you write the choice set you derived in A(b) mathematically, with indicating this years food consumption and indicating next years food consumption? 5) Different Interest Rates for Borrowing and Lending: Suppose we return to the example from the text in which you earn $5,000 this summer and expect to earn $5,500 next summer. A. In the real world, banks usually charge higher interest rates for borrowing than they will give on savings. So, instead of assuming that you can borrow and lend at 3 the same interest rate, suppose the bank pays you an interest rate of 5 percent on anything you save but will lend you money only at an interest rate of 10 percent. a. Illustrate your budget constraint with consumption this summer on the horizontal and consumption next summer on the vertical axis. b. How would your answer change if the interest rates for borrowing and lending were reversed? c. A set is defined as convex if the line connecting any two points in the set also lies in the set. Is the choice set in part (a) a convex set? What about the choice set in part (b)? d. Which of the two scenarios would you prefer? Give both an intuitive answer that does not refer to your graphs and demonstrate how the graphs give the same answer. B. Suppose more generally that you earn e1 this year and e2 next year and that the interest rate for borrowing is rB and the interest rate for saving is rS . Let c1 and c2 denote consumption this year and next year. a. Derive the general expression for your intertemporal choice set under these conditions. 6) I hate grits so much that the very idea of owning grits makes me sick. I do, on the other hand, enjoy a good breakfast of Coco Puffs Cereal. A: In each of the following, put boxes of grits on the horizontal axis and boxes of cereal on the vertical. Then graph three indifference curves and number them. (a) Assume that my preferences satisfy the convexity and continuity assumptions and otherwise satisfy the description above. (b) How would your answer change if my preferences were non-convexi.e. if averages were worse 4 (c) How would your answer to (a) change if I hated both Coco Puffs and grits but we again assumed my preferences satisfy the convexity assumption. (d)What if I hated both goods and my preferences were non-convex? B: Now suppose you like both grits and Coco Puffs, that your preferences satisfy our five basic assumptions and that they can be represented by the utility function u(x1 , x2 ) = x1 x2 . (a) Consider two bundles, A=(1,20) and B=(10,2). Which one do you prefer? (b) Use bundles A and B to illustrate that these preferences are in fact convex. 7) Consider my preferences for consumption and leisure. A: Begin by assuming that my preferences over consumption and leisure satisfy MON, CONV, CONT assumptions. (a) On a graph with leisure hours per week on the horizontal axis and consumption dollars per week on the vertical, give an example of three indifference curves (with associated utility numbers) from an indifference map that satisfies our assumptions. (b) Now redefine the good on the horizontal axis as labor hours rather than leisure hours. How would the same tastes look in this graph? (c) How would both of your graphs change if tastes over leisure and consumption were nonconvex i.e. if averages were worse than extremes. B: Suppose your tastes over consumption and leisure could be described by the utility function u(l, c) = l1 /2c1 /2. (a) Do these tastes satisfy our 5 basic assumptions? 5