Choice, Demand and Uncertainty Topic 4 1 Revealed Preferences 2 Revealed Preferences • We get choices from preferences • Preferences are not directly observable: we have to discover preferences from choices. • Consumption choices may reveals information about the consumer’s preference. • Suppose that we can observe the demands at different budgets. 3 Revealed Preferences • Assumptions: – Preferences do not change while the choice data are gathered. – Preferences are strictly convex and monotonic (well behaved) • Convexity and monotonicity imply that the most preferred affordable bundle is unique. Revealed Preferences • Suppose that the bundle x* is chosen when the bundle y is affordable. Then x* is revealed directly preferred to y (otherwise y would have been chosen). • That x is revealed directly as preferred to y can be written as p x D y Revealed Preferences x2 The chosen bundle x* is revealed directly as preferred to the bundles y and z. x* y z x1 Revealed Preferences • Suppose x is revealed directly preferred to y, and y is revealed directly preferred to z. Then, by transitivity, x is revealed indirectly preferred to z. Write this as: p so x D I z y and y p x D z => x I z. Revealed Preferences x2 z is not affordable when x* is chosen. x* z x1 Revealed Preferences x2 x* is not affordable when y* is chosen. x* y* z x1 Revealed Preferences x2 z is not affordable when x* is chosen. x* is not affordable when y* is chosen. x* y* z x1 Revealed Preferences z is not affordable when x* is chosen. x* is not affordable when y* is chosen. So x* and z cannot be compared directly. x* y* z But x*x*D y* and y* z so x* x1 p p x2 D I z. Axioms • The Weak Axiom of Revealed Preference (WARP): – If the bundle x is revealed directly as preferred to the bundle y then it is never the case that y is revealed directly as preferred to x. • The Strong Axiom of Revealed Preference (SARP): – If the bundle x is revealed (directly or indirectly) as preferred to the bundle y and x is different from y, then it is never the case that the y is revealed (directly or indirectly) as preferred to x. Demand 13 Demand • The consumer’s demand functions give the optimal amounts of each good as a function of prices and income. • The demand functions can be used to do comparative statics: – Understand how a choice responds to change in the economics environment. 14 Own Price Changes • ๐2 and ๐ are fixed. ๐ฅ2 ๐1 ๐ฅ1 + ๐2 ๐ฅ2 = ๐ ๐1 = ๐1′ ๐ฅ1 15 Own Price Changes • ๐2 and ๐ are fixed. ๐ฅ2 ๐1 ๐ฅ1 + ๐2 ๐ฅ2 = ๐ ๐1 = ๐1′ ๐1 = ๐1′′ ๐ฅ1 16 Own Price Changes • ๐2 and ๐ are fixed. ๐ฅ2 ๐1 ๐ฅ1 + ๐2 ๐ฅ2 = ๐ ๐1 = ๐1′ ๐1 = ๐1′′′ ๐1 = ๐1′′ ๐ฅ1 17 Own Price Changes • ๐2 and ๐ are fixed. ๐ฅ2 ๐1 ๐ฅ1 + ๐2 ๐ฅ2 = ๐ ๐1 = ๐1′ ๐1 = ๐1′′′ . ๐1 = ๐1′′ ๐ฅ1 18 Own Price Changes ๐1 . ๐ฅ2 ๐1 = ๐1 = ๐1′′′ (๐ฅ1′ ๐1′ ) ๐1′ . ๐ฅ1 ๐1 = ๐1′′ ๐ฅ1′ ๐ฅ1 19 Own Price Changes ๐ฅ2 . . ๐1 = ๐1′ ๐1 = ๐1′′′ ๐1 = ๐1′′ ๐ฅ1′ ๐ฅ1 20 Own Price Changes ๐1 ๐ฅ2 .. (๐ฅ1′′ ๐1′′ ) . . ๐1 = ๐1 = ๐1′′′ ๐1′ (๐ฅ1′ ๐1′ ) ๐ฅ1 ๐1 = ๐1′′ ๐ฅ1′ ๐ฅ1 21 Own Price Changes ๐ฅ2 .. . ๐1 = ๐1′ ๐1 = ๐1′′′ ๐1 = ๐1′′ ๐ฅ1′ ๐ฅ1 22 Own Price Changes ๐1 ๐ฅ2 .. (๐ฅ1′′′ ๐1′′′ ) . (๐ฅ1′′ ๐1′′ ) .. . ๐1 = ๐1 = ๐1′′′ (๐ฅ1′ ๐1′ ) ๐1′ ๐ฅ1 ๐1 = ๐1′′ ๐ฅ1′ ๐ฅ1 23 Own Price Changes ๐1 ๐ฅ2 .. (๐ฅ1′′′ ๐1′′′ ) . (๐ฅ1′′ ๐1′′ ) .. . ๐1 = ๐1 = ๐1′′′ (๐ฅ1′ ๐1′ ) ๐1′ ๐ฅ1 Demand curve for good ๐ฅ1 ๐1 = ๐1′′ ๐ฅ1′ ๐ฅ1 24 Own Price Changes ๐ฅ2 .. . ๐1 price offer curve ๐ฅ1 25 Own Price Changes • Price Offer Curve: represents the optimal choice as the price of good 1 changes. • Demand Curve: plots the optimal choices of good 1 as a function of its price. – It typically have a downward slope (ordinary goods). – Exception: Giffen Goods. 26 Giffen Good • ๐2 and ๐ are fixed. ๐ฅ2 Demand curve has ๐1 a positively sloped part ๏ px price offer curve Good x is Giffen ๐ฅ1 ๐ฅ1 27 Income Changes • ๐1 and ๐2 are fixed. ๐ฅ2 ๐1 ๐ฅ1 + ๐2 ๐ฅ2 = ๐ ๐ = ๐′ ๐ฅ1 28 Income Changes • ๐1 and ๐2 are fixed. ๐ฅ2 ๐1 ๐ฅ1 + ๐2 ๐ฅ2 = ๐ ๐ = ๐′ ๐ = ๐′′′ ๐ = ๐′ ๐ฅ1 29 Income Changes ๐ฅ2 ๐1 ๐ฅ1 + ๐2 ๐ฅ2 = ๐ . .. ๐ = ๐′ ๐ = ๐′′′ ๐ = ๐′ ๐ฅ1 30 Income Changes – Normal Good . . . . .. ๐ ๐ฅ2 ๐ = ๐′ ๐ = ๐′′′ ๐ฅ1 Engel curve for good ๐ฅ1 ๐ = ๐′ ๐ฅ1 31 Income Changes – Normal Good ๐ฅ2 . .. Income offer curve ๐ฅ1 ๐ฅ1 32 .. . Income Changes – Inferior Good ๐ ๐ฅ2 .. . ๐ = ๐′ ๐ = ๐′′′ ๐ฅ1 Engel curve for good ๐ฅ1 ๐ = ๐′ ๐ฅ1 33 Income Changes • Income offer curve (expansion path): depicts the optimal choice at different levels of income and constant prices. • A good for which quantity demanded rises with income is called normal. • Therefore a normal good’s Engel curve is positively sloped. • A good for which quantity demanded falls as income increases is an inferior good. • Therefore an inferior good’s Engel curve is negatively sloped. 34 Income and Substitution Effects 35 Price Change • The effect of a price change of either ๐ฅ1 or ๐ฅ2 on the consumer is twofold: – First, a change in the relative price ratio. After the change of price, ๐ฅ1 is either cheaper or dearer. – Secondly, there is a change in the consumer purchasing power. 36 Price Changes • A price increase means less buying power, a price decrease means more buying power. • The reaction of the consumer to the change in relative prices only is measured by the substitution effect. • how would the consumer change his consumption if there were no accompanying change in purchasing power? 37 Income and Substitution • We decompose the total change into effects: income and substitution. • We hypothetically adjust the consumer’s income to restore him to the level of real income he enjoyed before the price change. • Let’s assume a fall in ๐1 . It implies an increase in real income. • We have to reduce the consumer’s income by drag the new budget line back until it is just tangent to the original indifference curve. 38 Fall in ๐1 ๐ฅ2 ๐/๐2 Price fall from ๐1′ to ๐1′′ E0 E1 0 ๐/๐1′ ๐/๐1′′ ๐ฅ1 39 Fall in ๐1 ๐ฅ2 ๐/๐2 Price fall from ๐1′ to ๐1′′ E0 E1 E2 0 ๐/๐1′ ๐/๐1′′ ๐ฅ1 40 Fall in ๐1 ๐ฅ2 E1-E0: Total Effect (๐ฅ11 -๐ฅ10 ) E2-E0: Substitution Effect (๐ฅ12 -๐ฅ10 ) ๐/๐2 E1-E2: Income Effect (๐ฅ11 -๐ฅ12 ) E0 E1 E2 0 ๐ฅ10 ๐ฅ12 ๐ฅ11 ๐ฅ1 41 Substitution Effect • The substitution effect is always negative (price and quantity consumed go in opposite directions). • Proof: – Let (๐ฅ1 , ๐ฅ2 ) be a bundle demanded at some prices (๐1 , ๐2 ) and let (๐ฆ1 , ๐ฆ2 ) be a demanded bundle at some other prices (๐1 , ๐2 ). – Suppose the consume is indifferent between (๐ฅ1 , ๐ฅ2 ) and (๐ฆ1 , ๐ฆ2 ) 42 Substitution Effect – The following inequalities cannot be true • ๐1 ๐ฅ1 + ๐2 ๐ฅ2 > ๐1 ๐ฆ1 + ๐2 ๐ฆ2 • ๐1 ๐ฆ1 + ๐2 ๐ฆ2 > ๐1 ๐ฅ1 + ๐2 ๐ฅ2 – So, these inequalities are true: • ๐1 ๐ฅ1 + ๐2 ๐ฅ2 ≤ ๐1 ๐ฆ1 + ๐2 ๐ฆ2 • ๐1 ๐ฆ1 + ๐2 ๐ฆ2 ≤ ๐1 ๐ฅ1 + ๐2 ๐ฅ2 43 Substitution Effect – Summing the true inequalities above and rearranging: • ๐1 − ๐1 ๐ฆ1 − ๐ฅ1 + (๐2 − ๐2 )(๐ฆ2 − ๐ฅ2 ) ≤ 0 – We want to check the effect of one price (say the price of good 1), keeping the other price constant (๐2 = ๐2 ): • ๐1 − ๐1 ๐ฆ1 − ๐ฅ1 ≤ 0 – Therefore, quantities and prices go in opposite directions. 44 Income Effect • The income effect however can be negative (normal goods) or positive (inferior goods). • A rise in the price of a normal good induces a negative substitution effect and a negative income effect, both of which act to reduce the demand for good. • A rise in the price of an inferior good, however, induces a negative substitution effect but a positive income effect, thus the overall effect is ambiguous. 45 Inferior and Giffen Goods • If, when the price of an inferior good rises, the positive income effect dominates the negative substitution effect, we have the case of a Giffen Good. • That explains why demand for a Giffen Good rises (falls) when price rises (falls). • In other words, a Giffen good is a very inferior good. 46 Normal Good A C E1 E0 E2 0 A C B 47 Inferior Good A E1 C E0 E2 0 A C B 48 Giffen Good A E1 C E0 E2 I0 0 A C B 49 Giffen Good • Think of a product which you buy a lot of (a staple diet) and which is of inferior quality. • If the price of this product rises, your initial reaction is to substitute this product with some other. • But other products are much more expensive and your staple diet is still the cheapest. • So the substitution effect is minimal. 50 Giffen Good • However, your purchasing power is less than before because of the price increase. • So you buy less of other goods and more of the product which, although now more expensive, is still the cheapest and a staple food! • Such products are known as Giffen goods. 51 Hicks Substitution Effect • When we decomposed the change in demand resulting from a change in price into an income and substitution effect, we did so by varying money income. • When the price of good ๐ฅ1 fell, we ‘varied’ the consumer’s money income to hold his real income constant. • Real income is defined as the consumer’s ability to enjoy a particular level of utility. 52 Hicks Substitution Effect • Varying money income to keep the utility constant is known as Hicks Compensating Variation in money income (HCV). • HCV allows consumer to enjoy original level of utility at the new relative price ratio. • We ‘compensate’ the consumer for the change in price. • Somehow odd for a price fall. 53 HSE – Price Fall A C B I1 I0 0 54 HSE – Price Rise B C A I1 I0 0 55 Slutsky Substitution Effect • An alternative definition of real income is the ability to consumer not a particular level of utility, but a particular bundle of goods. • We vary the consumer’s money income following a change in price to permit him to consumer his original bundle of goods at the new relative price ratio. • The is know as the Slutsky Compensating Variation (SCV) in money income. 56 SSE – Price Fall A C I0 B I1 I2 0 57 SSE – Price Rise B C I2 A I0 I1 0 58 Slutsky Substitution Effect • The Slutsky Substitution effect is also negative: – From the graph in slide 60: all the points on the dotted line where the amount of good 1 consumed is less than at bundle A where affordable before the price change. – A must be preferred to all bundles in the part of the dotted line that lies inside the original budget set. – The optimal choice of must be either A or some point of the right of A. – Price and consumption go in opposite directions. 59 Slutsky Substitution Effect • It should be clear from the above analysis that the Slutsky method over-compensates. • The consumer would be on a higher indifference curve than the original one were the compensation made following the price increase. 60 Slutsky vs Hicks • Hicks Substitution Effect: we need to know the exact position of the indifference curves in order to learn about the various effects of a price change. – Conceptually correct, but not very applicable. • Slutsky Substitution Effect: we do not need to know anything about consumer preferences to implement it and so Slutsky’s method can be implemented. – Applicable, but over-compensates. • For small change in prices the two substitution effects are virtually identical. 61 Example 1 • Susan’s preferences over pizza (x) and salad (y) are given by the utility function ๐ ๐ฅ, ๐ฆ = ๐ฅ๐ฆ. • Price of ๐ฅ, ๐๐ฅ , is £4 per unit and that of ๐ฆ, ๐๐ฆ , is £1 per unit. • Susan had a budget, m, of £120. 62 Example 1 • Compute: i. Susan’s optimal Choice. ii. Calculate the income and substitution effect of a decrease in ๐๐ฅ to £3 per unit. 63 Example 1 i. Susan’s optimal basket. • We have worked with this function before. The preferences are convex, and we can just check the tangency condition: • ๐๐ ๐ = ๐๐/๐๐ฅ ๐๐/๐๐ฆ • ๐๐ ๐ = ๐ฆ ๐ฅ = = ๐๐ฅ ๐๐ฆ 4 1 64 Example 1 • From the MRS above: • ๐ฆ = 4๐ฅ • Budget line is 4๐ฅ + ๐ฆ = 120 • Solving for ๐ฆ and ๐ฅ: • ๐ฅ ∗ = 15 and ๐ฆ ∗ = 60 (basket A) • U(15,60) = 900 65 Example 1 y Original Bundle A 60 O A 15 x 66 Example 1 ii. Income and substitution effect of a decrease in ๐๐ฅ to £3 per unit. • The decomposition basket has to satisfy the new tangency condition: • ๐๐ ๐ = ๐ฆ ๐ฅ = 3 1 • And give the same level of utility: • ๐ = 900 => ๐ฆ๐ฅ = 900 • Solving: ๐ฅ′ = 17.3 and ๐ฆ′ = 51.9 67 Example 1 Original bundle: A y Decomposition bundle: B 60 51.9 Substitution Effect: Movement A to B X changes from 15 to 17.3 Y changes from 60 to 51.9 A B m’ = 17.3*3 + 51.9*1 = 103.8 The consumer is “compensated” in 103.9 - 120= - 16.2 O 15 17.3 x 68 Example 1 • Calculate the final basket. Tangency Condition: • ๐๐ ๐ = ๐ฆ ๐ฅ = 3 1 • And budget constraint: • 3๐ฅ + ๐ฆ = 120 • Solving the two equalities above to the get the final basket: ๐ฅ′′ = 20 and ๐ฆ′′ = 60 69 Example 1 Original bundle: A Decomposition bundle: B Final bundle: C y 60 51.9 O C A B 15 17.3 20 Income Effect: Movement B to C X changes 17.3 to 20 Y changes from 51.9 to 60 x 70 Example 2 • Supply of Labour: • Leisure is a good; that is, more of it is better than less. • This means that work is bad, i.e., less work is better than more. • The consumer earns the wage rate w per hour of work, so that the ‘price’ of an hour of leisure is w. • The consumption C is ‘good’, that is, more is better. 71 Example 2 • Budget Constraint: • Let’s assume the consumer has some income M (non labour income). • The consumer consumption: • C = M + wL • Where L is the amount of labour supplied. 72 Example 2 • The budget constraint can be written as follow: – M = C - wL • Negative price as we have seem before. • Let’s assume that there is a maximum amount of labour that can be supplied ๐ฟเดค . • Adding w๐ฟเดค in each side of the budget constraint: – M + w๐ฟเดค = C + w(๐ฟเดค − ๐ฟ) 73 Example 2 • Let R denote leisure: • R = ๐ฟเดค − ๐ฟ • The total amount of time available for leisure: ๐ เดค = ๐ฟเดค • The amount of consumption the consumer can enjoy าง without working: ๐ถ=M • The budget constraint becomes: • ๐ถาง + w๐ เดค = C + wR 74 Example 2 • We can now write The consumption as a function of the hours of leisure: • C = ๐ถาง + w๐ เดค - wR • If the consume decides not work: • C = ๐ถาง • If he decides not have any leisure: • C = ๐ถาง + w๐ เดค 75 Example 2 C The slope of the budget line is –w. It represents the opportunity cost (the price of one extra hour of leisure) ๐ถาง P O ๐ เดค R 76 Example 2 C As the wage rate increases, the Budget line pivots upwards around P. ๐ถาง P O ๐ เดค R 77 Example 2 C As the wage rate increases, the supply of labour เดค เดค increases from (๐ -R’) to (๐ -R’’) P O R’’ R’ ๐ เดค R 78 Example 2 • In the figure above we can see the effect of a wage increase on the supply of labour. • We can decompose the change in price in substitution and income effects. • The analysis assumes the plausible, that leisure is a normal good. 79 Example 2 C As the wage rate increases, the supply of labour เดค เดค increases from (๐ -R’) to (๐ -R’’) P O R’’’ R’’ R’ ๐ เดค R 80 Example 2 • The income effect and the substitution effect work in opposite directions, as long as it is assumed that leisure is a normal good. • In the above case, the income effect partly neutralises the substitution effect, but not fully, so that as W goes up, leisure decreases. 81 Example 2 • The above analysis suggests that as wages go up, labour supply increases; the supply curve of labour is upward sloping. • But what if the income effect outweighed the substitution effect? 82 C Example 2 P O R’ R’’ ๐ เดค R 83 Example 2 • Empirical evidence corroborates with the theory. • At a lower wage rate, the substitution effect is stronger; if the rate increases, supply of labour increases as well. • At a higher level of wages, however, a further wage increase may well outweigh the substitution effect and the labour supply fall. 84 Example 2 Wage Rate O The backwardbending supply of labour Labour Supply 85 Example 2 • We can introduce the discussion of over-time payments here. • In the next fig., the initial equilibrium is at point 1 where the wage line is flatter. • If the individual is offered a higher over-time pay, she moves to a new equilibrium (point 2) as the wage line gets steeper and on a higher indifference curve. 86 Example 2 C 2 A possible effect of over-time on choice of leisure 1 P R 87 Intertemporal Choice 88 Intertemporal Choice • We extend consumer analysis. • We consider now the possibility of saving and borrowing. • Saving for tomorrow is a fact of life. • Equally, we often spend more than what we currently earn or have by borrowing. 89 Model • We shall consider a two-period model of consumer choice. • The amount of consumption in each period is denoted by (๐1 , ๐2 ). • Prices of consumption in each period are constant at 1. • In each period the consumer receives an amount of money denoted by (๐1 , ๐2 ). 90 No Borrowing ๐2 Budget Constraint when interest rate is zero and no borrowing is allowed. ๐2 ๐1 ๐1 91 Borrowing • Consumer can lend money at some interest rate, r. • Suppose the consumer is a saver. • She will earn interest on ๐1 − ๐1 • The amount she can consume next period: • ๐2 = ๐2 + (1 + ๐)(๐1 − ๐1 ) 92 Borrowing • Rearranging: • (1 + ๐)๐1 + ๐2 = (1 + ๐)๐1 + ๐2 • Future value expression • Alternatively: • ๐1 + ๐2 1+๐ = ๐1 + ๐2 1+๐ • Present value expression 93 Budget Constraint ๐ถ2 (1 + ๐)๐1 +๐2 The slope of the budget line =-(1+r). The negative sign represents the trade-off ๐2 ๐1 ๐2 ๐1 + 1+๐ ๐ถ1 94 Preferences • The consumer has preferences over today and tomorrow consumption. • We consider the case of well behaved preferences. • Convexity is a natural assumption. 95 Preferences • Given the preferences we can examine the optimal choice (๐1 , ๐2 ). • If the consumer chooses a point where ๐1 < ๐1 , he is a lender. • If ๐1 > ๐1 the consumer is a borrower. 96 Lending and Borrowing ๐ถ2 “Neither a borrower, nor a lender be; For loan oft loses both itself and friend, And borrowing dulls the edge of husbandry.” (1 + ๐)๐1 +๐2 ๐2 ๐1 ๐2 ๐1 + 1+๐ ๐ถ1 97 Lender ๐ถ2 (1 + ๐)๐1 +๐2 ๐2 ๐2 ๐1 ๐1 ๐2 ๐1 + 1+๐ ๐ถ1 98 Borrower ๐ถ2 (1 + ๐)๐1 +๐2 ๐2 ๐2 ๐1 ๐1 ๐2 ๐1 + 1+๐ ๐ถ1 99 Comparative Statics • We consider changes in the interest rate r. • An increase in the interest rate makes the curve steeper. • The opposite happens with decrease in the interest rate. • The effects on the consumer will be different if he is a lender or a borrower. 100 ๐ถ2 Comparative Statics (1 + ๐)๐1 +๐2 A fall in the rate of interest is a gain for the borrower but a loss to the lender (1 + ๐′)๐1 +๐2 ๐2 ๐1 ๐1 + ๐2 1+๐ ๐2 ๐1 + 1 + ๐′ ๐ถ1 101 Increase in the Interest Rate An increase in the interest rate reduces the welfare of the borrower 2 1 102 Increase in the Interest Rate An increase in the interest rate increases the welfare of the lender 2 1 In this case, as the interest rate goes up, C1 falls 103 Increase in the Interest Rate 2 1 In this case, as the interest rate goes up, so does C1. 104 Summarizing • Increase in the interest rate: • A lender will remain a lender (he will be better off for sure). • A borrower may continue a borrower (he will be worse off for sure) or may become a lender (the welfare result is unknown). • Decrease in the interest rate: • A lender may continue a lender (he will be worse off for sure) or may become a borrower (the welfare result is unknown). • A borrower will remain a borrower (he will be better off for sure). 105 Example • Susan lives for two periods, 1 and 2. She receives a cash amount of £200 in period 1 and £300 in period 2. • Her preferences over consuming today (c1) and consuming tomorrow (c2) are given by the utility function U(c1,c2 ) = 2c1c2. • Assume that price of c1 and that of c2 is £1 per unit and the interest rate is fixed at r =0.25 106 Example i. If Susan consumes c1 = 80, her saving is? • Answer: Saving = 200 -80*1 = 120 ii. If Susan consumes c1 in general, her saving is? • Answer: Saving = (200 - c1 ) iii. If Susan lends (200 - c1 ) at r = 0.25 her money in period 2 is? • Answer: Period 2 money= (200 - c1)*(1+0.25) + 300 = 550 – 1.25c1 107 Example iv. How many units of C2 can Susan buy with this money? • Answer: c2 = 550 – 1.25c1 v. So the equation of Susan’s budget constraint is? • Answer: c2 + 1.25c1 = 550 vi. The ‘price’ of c1 per unit is? • Answer: 1.25 108 Example • Problem: • max ๐(๐1 , ๐2 ) = 2๐1 ๐2 (๐1 ,๐2 ) • Using a maximization technique (Lagrange multiplier or tangency condition): • c1* = 550/(2*1.25) = 220 • c2* = 550/(2*1) = 275 109 Inflation • Now, price of c1 is different from the price of c2 • For convenience let’s assume price of c1 is £1 and price of c2 is p2 (price of consumption tomorrow). • The amount of money the consumer can spend in period 2: • ๐2 ๐2 = ๐2 ๐2 + (1 + ๐)(๐1 − ๐1 ) • The amount of consumption available in period 2: • ๐2 = 1+๐ ๐2 + (๐1 ๐2 − ๐1 ) 110 Inflation • The inflation rate, π, is rate at which prices grow. • Since ๐1 = 1: • ๐2 = 1 + π • The amount of consumption available in period 2 becomes: • ๐2 = 1+๐ ๐2 + (๐1 1+π − ๐1 ) 111 Real Interest Rate • Let’s create a new variable ρ, the real interest rate: • 1+ρ= 1+๐ 1+π • The budget constraint becomes: • ๐2 = ๐2 + (1 + ρ)(๐1 − ๐1 ) • One plus the real interest rate measures how much extra consumption the consumer can get in period 2 by given up one unit of consumption in period 1. 112 Real Interest Rate • The interest rate on dollars is called nominal rate of interest. • The relationship between the real and the nominal interest rates are given by: • 1+ρ= 1+๐ 1+π • We can rearrange to get an explicitly expression for ρ: • ρ= 1+๐ 1+π −1= 1+๐ 1+π 1+π − 1+π = ๐−π 1+π 113 Real Interest Rate • If the inflation is small, we can use the following approximation: • ρ≈๐−π • The real interest rate is nominal rate minus the inflation. • In practise, we know the nominal interest rate for the next period but not the inflation. 114 Several Periods • Three period model. • The consumer can borrow or lend at an interest rate r. • The price of consumption in period 2 in terms of consumption in period 1 is 1/(1+r). • For period 3: • If the consumer invests £1 in period 1, it will grow to (1+r) in period 2 and to (1+r)2 in period 3. • If he has 1/ (1+r)2 in period 1, it will be £1 in period 3. 115 Several Periods • The budge constraint is given by: • ๐1 + ๐2 1+๐ + ๐3 (1+๐)2 = ๐1 + ๐2 1+๐ ๐3 + (1+๐)2 • The price of consumption in period t in terms of today’s consumption is: • ๐๐ก = 1 (1+๐)๐ก−1 116 Several Periods • The interest rate may change over time: • The model before can be generalized: • ๐2 ๐3 ๐1 + + 1+๐ (1+๐1 )(1+๐2 ) ๐3 1 (1+๐1 )(1+๐2 ) = ๐2 ๐1 + 1+๐1 + • We will examine only situations with constant interest rate. 117 Several Periods • How the present value changes over time. • The present value of £1 T years in the future: Rate 1 2 5 10 15 20 25 30 .05 .95 .91 .78 .61 .48 .37 .30 .23 .10 .91 .83 .62 .39 .24 .15 .09 .06 .15 .87 .76 .50 .25 .12 .06 .03 .02 .20 .83 .69 .40 .16 .06 .03 .01 .00 118 Bonds • Bonds are used by governments and corporations to borrow money. • The agent who issues the bond, promises to pay a fixed amount of dollars x (the coupon) each period until a certain date T (the maturity date), at which the which the borrower will pay the amount F (the face value). 119 Bonds • The stream of payments is (x,x,x,…,F) • If the interest rate is constant, the present value of the bond is: • ๐๐ = ๐ฅ ๐ฅ + (1+๐) (1+๐)2 + โฏ+ ๐น (1+๐)๐ • The present value goes down if the interest rate increases: • When the interest rate goes up the price now for £1 delivered in the future goes down. 120 Bonds • Perpetuity is a type of bond that makes payments forever. • Consider a perpetuity that promises to pay £x a year forever. • The present value is: • ๐๐ = ๐ฅ (1+๐) ๐ฅ + (1+๐)2 +โฏ 121 Bonds • Factor 1/(1+r) out: • ๐๐ = 1 1+๐ ๐ฅ+ ๐ฅ (1+๐) + ๐ฅ (1+๐)2 +โฏ • This is x plus the present value: • ๐๐ = • ๐๐= ๐ฅ ๐ 1 1+๐ ๐ฅ + ๐๐ 122