The Case for Long-Short Commodity Investing Joëlle Miffre and Adrian Fernandez-Perez JAI 2015, 18 (1) 92-104 doi: https://doi.org/10.3905/jai.2015.18.1.092 http://jai.iijournals.com/content/18/1/92 This information is current as of August 10, 2018. Email Alerts Receive free email-alerts when new articles cite this article. Sign up at: http://jai.iijournals.com/alerts Institutional Investor Journals Downloaded from http://jai.iijournals.com/ by guest on August 10, 2018 1120 Avenue of the Americas, 6th floor, New York, NY 10036, Phone: +1 212-224-3589 © 2017 Institutional Investor LLC. All Rights Reserved The Case for Long-Short Commodity Investing JOËLLE MIFFRE AND ADRIAN FERNANDEZ-PEREZ JOËLLE M IFFRE is a professor of finance at the EDHEC Business School in Nice, France. Joelle.Miffre@edhec.edu A DRIAN FERNANDEZ-P EREZ is a research fellow at Auckland University of Technology in Auckland, New Zealand. adrian.fernandez@aut.ac.nz 92 JAI-MIFFRE.indd 92 A cademic research has made it clear that commodity strategies that systematically buy backwardated contracts and sell contangoed contracts outperform long-only commodity indexes on a risk-adjusted basis.1 Such long-short commodity portfolios use the slope of the term structure of commodity futures prices, the positions of hedgers and speculators, or inventory levels as signals for asset allocation past performance. The contribution of this paper is with regard to the conditional volatility of these long-short commodity portfolios and their conditional correlations with traditional assets. It is well known indeed that the strategic decision to include long-short commodity futures positions in a well-diversified portfolio of stocks and bonds does not solely depend on the risk premium. It is also driven by a desire for risk diversification, and thus depends on how the long-short commodity returns correlate with the rest of the investor’s portfolio over time. The purpose of this paper is precisely to analyze the conditional volatility of long-short commodity portfolios and the conditional correlations of their returns with those of traditional assets over time and in periods of high volatility in traditional asset markets. By so doing, the paper extends the literature that focused on the diversification benefits of long-only commodity indexes (Bodie and Rosansky [1980], Erb and Harvey [2006], Gorton and Rouwenhorst [2006], Büyük şahin et al. [2010], Daskalaki and Skiadopoulos [2011]). We present five reasons why traditional asset managers who contemplate commodity investments should opt for long-short (as opposed to long-only) positions in commodity futures markets. First, in line with previous research, long-short portfolios based on momentum, term structure, or hedging pressure (Mom, TS, or HP hereafter) are found to offer better performance than their longonly counterparts. For example, over the period 1992–2011, 96.32% of the long-short commodity portfolios generate Sharpe ratios that exceed that of the S&P-GSCI. Second, the conditional volatility of long-short commodity portfolios is found to be less than that of long-only portfolios. Third, in periods of turmoil in equity and fixed income markets, as contagion spreads across markets the volatility of long-short commodity portfolios is found to rise less than that of long-only commodity portfolios. Fourth, the conditional correlations of the S&P 500 Index with long-short commodity portfolios (at −0.01 on average) are found to be lower than those measured relative to long-only commodity indexes (at 0.16), suggesting that the risk diversification benefits of commodity futures are stronger within long-short portfolios. This is particularly true following the debacle of Lehman THE CASE FOR L ONG -SHORT CDownloaded OMMODITY I NVESTING from http://jai.iijournals.com/ by guest on August 10, 2018 SUMMER 2015 24/06/15 4:03 PM Brothers in September 2008, which led to the spread of contagion across markets and thus to a rise to 0.44 in the conditional correlations between long-only commodity portfolios and the S&P 500 Index (Tang and Xiong [2012], Büyük ahin and Robe [2013]). The conditional correlations between equities and long-short commodity portfolios, however, have remained low (at 0.05 on average). Fifth, in periods of high volatility in equity markets, the conditional correlations between the S&P 500 Index and long-short hedging pressure portfolios is found to decrease. This is good news to equity investors, as it is precisely when the volatility of equity markets is high (e.g., following the demise of Lehman Brothers) that the benefits of diversification are most appreciated. In contrast, the conditional correlation between longonly commodity indexes and the S&P 500 substantially rises with the volatility of the S&P 500, suggesting that the risk reduction that comes from diversification prevails less when needed most, namely, during market downturn and periods of contagion. Next we present the dataset, the methodologies employed to capture the returns and conditional volatility of long-short commodity portfolios, and their conditional correlations with traditional assets. The following sections discuss the results and conclude the paper. DATA The dataset includes Friday settlement prices for 27 commodity futures obtained from Datastream. The cross section is chosen based on the availability of hedgers’ and speculators’ positions in the Aggregated Commitment of Traders (COT) report at the Commodity Futures Trading Commission. It includes 12 agricultural commodities (cocoa, coffee C, corn, cotton n°2, frozen concentrated orange juice, oats, rough rice, soybean meal, soybean oil, soybeans, sugar n°11, wheat), 5 energy commodities (blendstock RBOB gasoline, electricity, heating oil n°2, light sweet crude oil, natural gas), 4 livestock commodities (feeder cattle, frozen pork bellies, lean hogs, live cattle), 5 metal commodities (copper, gold, palladium, platinum, silver) and random-length lumber. Two starting dates are considered. The first is January 5, 1979, which marks the first date over which settlement prices are reported in Datastream International. SUMMER 2015 JAI-MIFFRE.indd 93 The second is October 2, 1992, which marks the first weekly reporting of the positions of hedgers and speculators in the COT report. Both samples end March 25, 2011. As proxies for traditional assets, we use the S&P 500 Composite Index and Barclays Capital U.S. Aggregate Bond Index. Futures returns are calculated by assuming that investors hold the nearest contracts up to one month before maturity and then roll their positions to the second-nearest contracts. Alternative rolling techniques could have been considered (e.g., holding distant contracts up to one month before they mature), but we see three reasons why these approaches are not necessarily optimal in the present context. First, as the forward curve is typically steeper at the front end and f lattens as maturity rises, roll-yields are likely to be more substantial front-end, thereby enhancing the performance of the strategy considered. Second, distant contracts are known to be less liquid and thus more expensive to trade, which might adversely impact net performance. Third, momentum profits have been shown to be less significant in both economic and statistical terms when distant contracts are held (Miffre and Rallis [2007]). For these reasons, we opt for front or second-nearest contracts and not for distant contracts. We also download the long and short positions of large commercial and non commercial traders from the COT report and calculate two measures, called hedging pressure, one for the hedgers and one for the speculators.2 The hedging pressure of, say, speculators is calculated as the number of long positions divided by the total number of positions taken by non commercial traders. For example, a hedging pressure of 0.2 for hedgers means that 20% of hedgers are long and thus 80% are short, a sign of a backwardated market. The hedging pressure measures thus defined are used as signals for sorting commodity futures into portfolios as explained next. METHODOLOGY Long-Short Mom, TS, and HP Portfolios All long-short strategies first and foremost shortlist the 90% most-liquid contracts at the time of portfolio formation, where liquidity is measured as average dollar open interest over the former R weeks. This is to ease taking and liquidating positions and thus to limit transaction costs. The Mom portfolios then consist THE JOURNAL Downloaded from http://jai.iijournals.com/ by guest on August 10, 2018OF A LTERNATIVE INVESTMENTS 93 24/06/15 4:03 PM of long (short) positions in the 20% futures with best (worst) performance over the previous R weeks. The positions are held over the next H weeks, when a new Mom portfolio is formed (Erb and Harvey [2006], Miffre and Rallis [2007]). R and H stand for the ranking and holding periods of the portfolios expressed in weeks. The TS portfolios consist of long (short) positions in the 20% futures with highest (lowest) average rollyields over the previous R weeks, where roll-yields are measured as the difference in the logs of the prices of nearest and second-nearest contracts. The positions are held for H weeks, when a new TS portfolio is formed (Erb and Harvey [2006], Gorton and Rouwenhorst [2006]). The HP portfolio based on the positions of hedgers consists of long positions in the 20% backwardated futures for which hedgers are the shortest over the previous R weeks, and short positions in the 20% contangoed futures for which hedgers are the longest over the previous R weeks. The positions are then held over the next H weeks, when a new long-short hedging pressure portfolio is formed. The HP portfolio based on the positions of speculators consists of long positions in the 20% backwardated futures for which speculators are the longest, and short positions in the 20% contangoed futures for which speculators are the shortest. For more on long-short HP portfolios, please refer to Basu and Miffre [2013].3 To sum up, the long-short strategies differ with regard to one characteristic only: the sorting criterion used for asset allocation. In all other aspects, the strategies follow the same following three principles. First, the ranking period (R) over which the sorting criterion is averaged out and the holding period (H) over which the long-short portfolios are held are always set to either 4, 13, 26, or 52 weeks. So we end up with 16 long-short portfolios for each of the strategies mentioned above, where these 16 series come from the permutation of the four ranking and four holding periods. Second, in line with a long-standing literature (e.g., Bodie and Rosansky [1980] for long-only portfolios or Miffre and Rallis [2007] for long-short portfolios), the constituents of the long and short portfolios are equally weighted. Third, to facilitate comparison with the fully collateralized S&P-GSCI, the long-short portfolios are also assumed to be fully collateralized, meaning that their performance equals half that of the longs minus half that of the shorts. 94 JAI-MIFFRE.indd 94 Modeling Conditional Volatility and Conditional Correlation We model conditional volatilit y via the generalized autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity GARCH(1,1) model of Bollerslev [1986]. The GARCH(1,1) variance, ht , is as follows Rt μ + εt ht = γ + αεt2−1 + βht −1 (1) Rt is the time t return of a given portfolio, εt are residuals distributed as N(0, ht ); μ is the mean return of Rt ; α, β and γ are such that γ > 0, α ≥ 0, β ≥ 0, and α + β < 1. We model the return co movements between commodities C and traditional assets T via the dynamic conditional correlation (DCC) model of Engle [2002].4 DCC time-varying correlations are estimated in two steps. The first step estimates time-varying variances as GARCH(1,1) processes and the second step models a time-varying correlation matrix using the standardized residuals from the first-stage estimation. More specifically, the covariance matrix is expressed as Ht ≡ DtRtDt , where Dt = g(√ √ hC , , √ hT ,t ) is a diagonal matrix of uni− variate GARCH(1,1) volatilities and Rt = Qt*−1 QtQt*−1 is the time varying correlation matrix, with − - Qt = (qC,T,t ) as described by Qt = (1 − a − b)Q + a(εc,t-1 εT,t-1) + bQ t-1 , where εC ,t = RC ,t hC ,t and εT ,t = RT ,t hT ,t are standardized residuals modeled from the first stage. Q is the N × N unconditional covariance matrix of standardized residuals, a and b are non negative coefficients satisfying a + b < 1, * * - and Qt = qii ,t ) = qii ,t is a diagonal matrix composed of the square root of the ith diagonal elements of Qt , where i stands for C or T. Rewriting Rt = Qt*−1QtQt*−1 , the time t conditional return correlation between commodity and traditional assets can then be expressed as ρC , ,t = qC ,T ,t qC , qT ,t (2) This framework is useful to study the conditional volatility of commodity portfolios and their conditional THE CASE FOR L ONG -SHORT CDownloaded OMMODITY I NVESTING from http://jai.iijournals.com/ by guest on August 10, 2018 SUMMER 2015 24/06/15 4:03 PM correlations with traditional assets. Regressions (3) and (4) are then estimated hC , = β0 + β hT ,t + εt ρC , ,t = β0 + β ,t + εt (3) (4) which regress the annualized conditional volatility of long-short and long-only commodity portfolios or their conditional correlation with traditional assets on the annualized conditional volatility of traditional indexes (S&P 500 or Barclays bond index). A positive and significant β coefficient in (3) indicates contagion of risk across markets or concomitant increases in volatility. This would be disappointing news to risk-adverse investors, as the spreading of risk during a crisis would increase the overall volatility of their combined portfolio. Vice versa, a negative and significant β coefficient in (3) suggests that in periods of high volatility in traditional asset markets investors can—other things being equal—decrease the overall volatility of their portfolio by treating commodities as part of their strategic asset allocation. A positive and significant β coefficient in (4) indicates that conditional correlations rise with the volatility of traditional assets. If so, the evidence of increased integration of international stock markets in periods of high equity volatility (Solnik et al. [1996], Longin and Solnik [2001]) will be extrapolated to commodity and traditional asset markets. On the other hand, a negative and significant β coefficient in (4) indicates increased segmentation between commodity and traditional asset markets in periods of high volatility in traditional asset markets. This result will be treated as welcome news to investors in traditional assets, as it implies that the usefulness of commodity futures as a diversification tool increases in periods of high volatility in traditional asset markets, namely, when investors need diversification the most. EMPIRICAL RESULTS Performance of Long-Short Commodity Portfolios For each signal (Mom, TS, or HP), we obtain 16 strategies that come from the permutation of four ranking and four holding periods. Instead of discussing all strategies, the paper focuses for a given signal solely on SUMMER 2015 JAI-MIFFRE.indd 95 the strategies with the highest and lowest Sharpe ratios and on an aggregate portfolio that equally weights and monthly rebalances the 16 strategies based on a given signal.5 Exhibit 1 presents summary statistics for the excess returns of long-short portfolios based on momentum (Panel A), term structure (Panel B), the hedging pressure of hedgers (Panel C) and that of speculators (Panel D). The samples considered are February 1979–March 2011 in Panels A and B and October 1992–March 2011 in Panels C and D. For the sake of comparison, Panel E presents summary statistics for two long-only commodity benchmarks—EW, which is a long-only equally weighted portfolio of all commodities, and the S&PGSCI. Altogether, the results of Exhibit 1 highlight the importance of taking a long-short approach to commodity investing. Over the sample 1979–2011, the annualized average excess return of a portfolio that equally weights the 16 Mom (TS) strategies equals 3.45% (4.80%) a year significant at the 1% level; over the same period, the long-only EW portfolio lost 1.87%. Likewise over the sample 1992–2011, the annualized average excess return of a portfolio that equally weights the 16 hedgers’ (speculators’) HP strategies equals 5.95% (5.89%) significant at the 1% level; over the same period, the long-only EW portfolio earned 0.70% and the S&PGSCI earned 4.28%. As the shorts provide a partial hedge against the longs, the volatility of the long-short fully collateralized portfolios (at an average of 10.5%) tends to be less than that of the long-only commodity benchmarks (12% for the EW portfolio, 21.78% for the S&P-GSCI in Exhibit 1, Panel E). As a result, the benefits of going long and short are even stronger on a risk-adjusted basis. Over the sample 1979–2011, the Sharpe ratios of the equally weighted 16-Mom and 16-TS portfolios equal 0.45 and 0.61 versus −0.16 for the long-only EW benchmark; over the period 1992–2011, the Sharpe ratios of the equally weighted 16 hedgers’ HP and 16 speculators’ HP portfolios equal 0.68 and 0.71 versus 0.06 for the long-only EW benchmark and 0.20 for the S&P-GSCI. All of the individual long-short portfolios present Sharpe ratios that are superior to that of the long-only benchmarks (EW and S&P-GSCI). These results confirm the importance of taking backwardation and contango into account when designing dynamic commodity strategies. Following a long-standing literature (e.g., Bodie and Rosansky [1980] or Miffre and Rallis [2007]), the THE JOURNAL Downloaded from http://jai.iijournals.com/ by guest on August 10, 2018OF A LTERNATIVE INVESTMENTS 95 24/06/15 4:03 PM constituents of the portfolios are equally weighted. While frequent rebalancing to equal weights has its perks in terms of potentially generating both a diversification return (Erb and Harvey [2006]) and an illiquid risk premium (Pastor and Stambaugh [2003]), that strategy also exacerbates exposure to expensive illiquid assets, which could ultimately harm net returns.6 As already mentioned, the methodology we adopt to account for potential illiquidity problems consists of systematically excluding the 10% of the cross section with the lowest dollar value of open interest averaged over the R weeks preceding portfolio formation. To further address concerns regarding transaction costs, we also study the net performance of the strategies and implement a break-even analysis. As reported on the right-hand side of Exhibit 1, the decline in performance after accounting for plausible and conservative round- trip transaction costs7 is negligible and does not alter our conclusion on the superiority of long-short strategies relative to their long-only counterparts. As part of a break-even analysis, we also calculate the required level of cost per commodity trade that sets the mean return of the strategy equal to zero. Across the 16 permutations of ranking and holding periods, break-even transaction costs equal 0.24% (Mom), 0.51% (TS), 0.67% (speculators’ HP), and 0.59% (hedgers’ HP); these are substantially higher than Locke and Venkatesh’s [1997] estimate at 0.033%. Hence, significant mean returns remain after considering plausible transaction costs. Conditional Volatility Exhibit 2 studies the conditional volatility of longshort Mom, TS, or HP portfolios (Panels A-D) and of EXHIBIT 1 Performance of Long-Short Commodity Portfolios Note: The table presents summary statistics for the excess returns of fully collateralized long-short commodity portfolios based on momentum, term structure, or hedging pressure. Mean is the annualized mean of the portfolio excess returns, SD its annualized standard deviation, SR is the Sharpe ratio of the portfolio or the ratio of Mean to SD. “EW-16 strategies” represents an aggregate portfolio that equally weights the 16 strategies generated from permuting four ranking (R) and four holding (H) periods. “Best strategy” (“Worst strategy”) is the strategy with the highest (lowest) Sharpe ratio out of the 16 strategies considered. t-statistics are in parentheses. The last two columns report annualized mean excess returns net of plausible and conservative round-trip transaction costs (T-costs of 0.033% and 0.066%). The samples considered are February 1979–March 2011 (Panels A and B) and October 1992–March 2011 (Panels C and D). 96 JAI-MIFFRE.indd 96 THE CASE FOR L ONG -SHORT CDownloaded OMMODITY I NVESTING from http://jai.iijournals.com/ by guest on August 10, 2018 SUMMER 2015 24/06/15 4:03 PM long-only commodity portfolios (EW and S&P-GSCI, Panel E). As in Exhibit 1, the samples considered are 1979–2011 in Panels A and B and 1992–2011 in Panels C and D. Under the headings H 01 and H 02, we report t-statistics for the hypothesis that the difference in the conditional volatilities of long-short and long-only commodity portfolios is zero. Note that under H 01 the longonly commodity portfolio used is EW, while under H02 it is the S&P-GSCI. The t-statistics are very often less than −1.96, indicating lower conditional volatilities for the long-short portfolios. This result adds further backing to the idea that we should take a long-short, as opposed to a long-only, approach to commodity investing. Exhibit 2 also studies how the conditional volatility of long-short and long-only commodity portfolios evolves vis-à-vis the volatility of traditional indexes. Following from (3), we present estimates of the slope coefficients β1 (β2 ) from regressions of the annualized conditional volatilities of commodity portfolios on the annualized conditional volatilities of the S&P 500 Index (Barclays bond index). Almost all β1 and β2 coefficients in Exhibit 2 are positive and significant at the 1% level. Thus a rise in volatility of traditional assets goes hand-in-hand with a rise in volatility of both long-only and long-short commodity portfolios. Yet the average β1 and β2 coefficients stand at merely 0.06 and 0.54 for the long-short commodity portfolios (in Panels A-D), and at 0.43 and 2.45 for the long-only commodity portfolios (in Panels E). Thus, the volatility of long-short portfolios rises seven times less than that of long-only commodity portfolios during equity market turmoil and five times less than that of long-only commodity portfolios in periods of high volatility in fixed income markets. Other things being equal, traditional investors are thus better off holding long-short commodity positions in periods of market turmoil. As the shorts perform better than the longs during a market crash, the overall volatility of the EXHIBIT 2 Conditional Volatility of Long-Short Commodity Portfolios Note: The table presents under H01 (H02) t-statistics for the null hypothesis that the difference in the GARCH(1,1) volatility of the fully collateralized long-short portfolios and that of the equally weighted long-only portfolio of all commodities (S&P-GSCI) equals zero. β1 (β2) is the slope coefficient of a regression of the conditional volatility of commodity portfolios on the conditional volatility of the S&P 500 Index (Barclays Capital U.S. Aggregate Bond Index). “EW-16 strategies” represents an aggregate portfolio that equally weights the 16 strategies generated from permuting four ranking (R) and four holding (H) periods. “Best strategy” (“Worst strategy”) is the strategy with the highest (lowest) Sharpe ratio out of the 16 strategies considered. “EW long-only” represents an equally weighted, monthly rebalanced portfolio of all commodities. t-statistics in parentheses. The samples considered are February 1979–March 2011 (Panels A and B) and October 1992–March 2011 (Panels C and D). SUMMER 2015 JAI-MIFFRE.indd 97 THE JOURNAL Downloaded from http://jai.iijournals.com/ by guest on August 10, 2018OF A LTERNATIVE INVESTMENTS 97 24/06/15 4:03 PM EXHIBIT 3 Conditional Correlations between Long-Short (Long-Only) Commodity Portfolios and S&P 500 Index combined long-short portfolio rises less during contagion than the overall volatility of a longonly portfolio. Conditional Correlations Over Time Note: The full lines represent the conditional correlations between the total returns of aggregate long-short portfolios and the S&P 500 Index. The dashed lines represent the conditional correlations between the total returns of long-only commodity portfolios (longonly equally weighted and S&P-GSCI) and the S&P 500 Index. The sample covers the period February 1979–March 2011 on the left-hand side and the period October 1992March 2011 on the right-hand side. 98 JAI-MIFFRE.indd 98 Notwithstanding the importance of conditional volatility, it is important from a risk management perspective to also look at cross-market linkage and at how conditional correlations evolve over time. Exhibit 3 plots the conditional returns correlations between the S&P 500 and various commodity portfolios. The long-short portfolios employed on the left-hand side are based on Mom or TS over the period 1979–2011; those on the right-hand side center on hedgers’ and speculators’ HP over the period 1992–2011. As before, instead of plotting each of the 16 long-short Mom, TS, or HP portfolios, Exhibit 3 considers for a given signal an aggregate portfolio that equally weights and monthly rebalances these 16 permutations of ranking and holding periods. This is to ease presentation. A casual look at Exhibit 3 indicates that the conditional correlations between the S&P 500 Index and long-short commodity portfolios (full lines) are lower than those with long-only commodity portfolios (dash lines). While this phenomenon applies across the whole sample, it seems more pronounced over the period 2008–2011. Exhibit 4 presents means for the conditional correlations as modeled in Equation (2) between the S&P 500 Index and long-short or long-only commodity portfolios. As in Exhibit 1, the samples considered are 1979–2011 in Panels A and B, and 1992–2011 in Panels C and D. Note that the correlations with the S&P 500 Index are modeled over the whole sample and over two consecutive sub samples that end and start with the debacle of Lehman Brothers dated September 15, 2008. The right-hand side of Exhibit 4 presents the average of the conditional correlations between the Barclays bond index and either one of the commodity portfolios; because of the availability of Barclays data, the sample considered then starts January 1989. THE CASE FOR L ONG -SHORT CDownloaded OMMODITY I NVESTING from http://jai.iijournals.com/ by guest on August 10, 2018 SUMMER 2015 24/06/15 4:03 PM EXHIBIT 4 Average Conditional Correlations between Traditional Assets and Long-Short Commodity Portfolios Note: The table presents the average of the DCC(1,1) correlations between the S&P 500 (Barclays) Index and long-short (Panels A to D) and long-only (Panel E) commodity portfolios. “EW-16 strategies” represents an aggregate portfolio that equally weights the 16 strategies generated from permuting four ranking (R) and four holding (H) periods. “Best strategy” (“Worst strategy”) is the strategy with the highest (lowest) Sharpe ratio out of the 16 strategies considered. “EW long-only” represents an equally weighted, monthly rebalanced portfolio of all commodities. t-statistics are in parentheses. The samples considered are February 1979–March 2011 (Panels A and B) and October 1992–March 2011 (Panels C and D). Three points are worth noting. First, as in, e.g., Bodie and Rosansky [1980], the means of the conditional correlations are low, confirming the strategic role of commodity portfolios as risk diversifiers. Second, the average conditional correlation between long-short commodity portfolios and the S&P 500 Index (−0.01 in Panels A-D) is much lower than that reported for the long-only indexes (0.16 in Panels E). While the former are not significantly different from zero, the latter are positive and significant at the 1% level. Third, the observed pattern is stronger since September 19, 2008; over the second period the mean of the conditional correlations between the S&P 500 Index and long-short indexes stands at a mere 0.05 and is therefore close to its historical average. In sharp contrast, the average correlation between the S&P 500 and long-only indexes rose sharply to 0.44 after the Lehman Brothers debacle. This result highlights once more the SUMMER 2015 JAI-MIFFRE.indd 99 importance of taking both long and short commodity positions as opposed to being long-only. The benefits of diversification are then much stronger.8 The right-hand side of Exhibit 4 reports averages of conditional correlations between long-short or long-only commodity portfolios and the Barclays bond index. As previously reported (e.g., Bodie and Rosansky [1980]), the correlations with long-only commodity indexes in Panels E are low (−0.06 on average) and negative at the 5% level or better in the case of the long-only EW portfolio. Albeit insignificant, the correlations between the Barclays bond index and long-short commodity portfolios are also low in Panels A-D, averaging out 0.02. Other things being equal, from solely a risk diversification perspective, bond investors shall be indifferent between the S&P-GSCI and long-short portfolios and have a slight preference for the long-only EW portfolio. THE JOURNAL Downloaded from http://jai.iijournals.com/ by guest on August 10, 2018OF A LTERNATIVE INVESTMENTS 99 24/06/15 4:03 PM EXHIBIT 5 side presents the same information using a longonly commodity portfolio, the S&P-GSCI, in The Relationship between Conditional Correlation and place of the long-short hedger-based portfolio. Conditional S&P 500 Volatility The conditional correlations between the longshort commodity index and the S&P 500 Index in Exhibit 5 tend to fall when the conditional volatility of the S&P 500 Index rises. In fact, the correlation between the two series plotted on the left-hand side is as low as −0.28 and is different from zero at the 1% level. On the other hand, the conditional correlations plotted on the right-hand side vis-à-vis a long-only commodity index tend to rise with the conditional volatility of the S&P 500 Index (the correlation between the two series is at 0.24, significant at the 1% level). This suggests that investors following a long-short (as opposed to long-only) approach to commodity investing get better diversification when it is most needed, namely, in periods of high volatility in equity markets. To put this differently, long-short HP portfolios seem to serve as a partial hedge against extreme risks in equity markets. Exhibit 6 reports slope coefficients from Equation (4), i.e., from regressions of the conditional correlations with the S&P 500 on the conditional S&P 500 volatility. To test the robustness of the results, we estimate the parameters over different samples and report them for aggregate portfolios that equally weight the 16 strategies generated by a given signal (Panel A), for the best and the worst of these 16 strategies (Panels B and C, respectively) and for long-only benchmarks (Panel D). In line with the preceding discussion, β in Exhibit 6 is negative and almost always Note: The hedging pressure portfolio considered on the left-hand side is an aggregate significant for the HP portfolios. In fact, a rise equally weighted portfolio of 16 long-short hedger-based strategies. The correlation by 1% in the volatility of the S&P 500 Index between the two series pertaining to the left-hand side graph (right-hand side graph) decreases the conditional correlations between is −0.28 (0.24), significant at the 1% level. the S&P 500 Index and the HP portfolios by an average of 0.34%. It follows that equity investors Conditional Correlations in Periods of High worried about diversification in periods of high Volatility in Traditional Asset Markets volatility in equity markets should use the positions of hedgers or speculators over the recent past as long-short Exhibit 5 plots on the left-hand side the condisignals for asset allocation. tional return correlations between the aggregate hedgerThese long-short portfolios offer enhanced diversibased portfolio and the S&P 500 Index, and on the fication benefits to equity investors in periods of severe right-hand side the annualized conditional volatility of downturns. The sub sample analysis presented on the the S&P 500 Index returns. The plot on the right-hand right-hand side of Exhibit 6 indicates that the conclusion 100 JAI-MIFFRE.indd 100 THE CASE FOR L ONG -SHORTDownloaded COMMODITY Ifrom NVESTING http://jai.iijournals.com/ by guest on August 10, 2018 SUMMER 2015 24/06/15 4:03 PM EXHIBIT 6 Conditional Correlations between Commodity Portfolios and the S&P 500 Index in Periods of High Volatility in Equity Markets Note: The table reports slope coefficients of regressions of the conditional correlation between commodity portfolios and the S&P 500 Index on the conditional volatility of the S&P 500 Index. Aggregate long-short portfolios are portfolios that equally weight the 16 strategies generated from a given signal (Panel A). “EW long-only” represents an equally weighted, monthly rebalanced portfolio of all commodities. t-statistics are in parentheses. of decreasing correlation in periods of heightened volatility for the HP portfolios, albeit stronger over the period 2002–2011, holds in both sub samples. Conversely and with a few exceptions only, the long-only benchmarks and long-short TS portfolios act as worse risk diversifiers in periods of heightened equity volatility. This is demonstrated in Exhibit 6 by estimated β coefficients that are positive and often significant for those portfolios, especially over the samples 1980–2011 and 2002–2011. For example, over the sample 2002–2011, a rise by 1% in the conditional volatility of the S&P 500 Index came hand-in-hand with a rise by 0.95% in the conditional correlation between the S&P 500 and long-only benchmarks in Panel D. When severe volatility strikes in equity markets, it contaminates long-only commodity markets too, bringing both asset classes down; subsequently their conditional return correlations go up. This is unfortunate as it is precisely when contagion spreads from one market to the next that equity investors need the benefits of diversification the most. Other things being equal, it is exactly in periods of heightened volatility SUMMER 2015 JAI-MIFFRE.indd 101 that long-only commodity investors get the benefits of diversification the least. Interestingly, the average β coefficient for longshort TS portfolios in Exhibit 6, Panels A−C stands at merely 0.20 versus 0.48 for long-only portfolios in Panel D. Thus, while the correlations with the S&P 500 Index tend to rise in periods of enhanced equity risk for both types of portfolios, the diversification properties of commodities are more preserved within the longshort TS portfolios than within the long-only portfolios. Across Panels A to C, the average of the estimated β coefficients for the long-short Mom portfolios stands at −0.03, suggesting little variation in the conditional correlations between Mom and the S&P 500 as the volatility of the S&P 500 changes. Exhibit 7 presents the weekly performance of the S&P 500 Index, of long-only and long-short commodity portfolios in the four weeks that followed Lehman Brothers’ demise (dated September 15, 2008). Over that period, the S&P 500 composite index lost an average of 8.23% a week, the S&P-GSCI lost 6.42% and the long-only EW portfolio lost 4.71%. Over the same THE JOURNAL OF A LTERNATIVE I NVESTMENTS Downloaded from http://jai.iijournals.com/ by guest on August 10, 2018 101 24/06/15 4:03 PM EXHIBIT 7 Average Total Returns of Long-Short and Long-Only Portfolios over the Four Weeks Following Lehman Brothers’ Demise (September 15, 2008) Note: For a given signal, the long-short portfolios here considered are the aggregate equally weighted portfolios of 16 strategies. EXHIBIT 8 at 0.98%, the HP portfolios particularly stand out. Conditional Correlations between Commodity Portfolios and Barclays Exhibit 8 considers the same inforBond Index in Periods of High Volatility in Fixed Income Markets mation as Exhibit 6 but from the perspective of a fixed-income investor. It reports slope coefficients from regressions of the conditional correlations with Barclays bond index on the conditional volatility of Barclays bond index. With two exceptions only, the reported slope coefficients are positive and significant at the 10% level or better. This conclusion holds irrespective of the period considered (1989–2011 in Panel A; 1993–2011 in Panel B) and of the signal used to design the long-short strategies. Note: The table reports slope coefficients of regressions of the conditional correlation between commodity portfolios and Barclays bond index on the conditional volatility of the S&P 500 Index. The average β coefficients stand at 2.02 “EW-16 strategies” represents an aggregate portfolio that equally weights the 16 strategies generfor the Mom and TS portfolios, 2.21 ated from permuting four ranking (R) and four holding (H) periods. “EW long-only” represents for the HP portfolios and 2.61 for the an equally weighted, monthly rebalanced portfolio of all commodities. t-statistics are in parentheses. long-only portfolios. This uniformly indicates concomitant rises in f ixed period, both the long and short commodity portfolios income volatility and conditional correlation. None of experienced large losses. Consequently, the long-short the commodity portfolios therefore stand out as particuportfolios performed remarkably well in relative terms, larly good diversifiers of interest rate risk in periods of suggesting that they act as partial hedges against extreme heightened volatility in fixed income markets. risk in equity markets. With an average weekly return 102 JAI-MIFFRE.indd 102 THE CASE FOR L ONG -SHORTDownloaded COMMODITY Ifrom NVESTING http://jai.iijournals.com/ by guest on August 10, 2018 SUMMER 2015 24/06/15 4:03 PM CONCLUSIONS This article takes the stand of a traditional investor who contemplates investing in commodities. Is he/she better off holding a long-only or a long-short commodity portfolio? To answer this question, we study the performance of long-short and long-only commodity portfolios, their conditional volatility and their conditional correlations with traditional asset classes over time and in periods of heightened volatility in traditional asset markets. The results highlight the superiority of long-short strategies. Relative to long-only portfolios, long-short portfolios offer better risk-adjusted performance. In periods of turmoil in traditional asset markets, as contagion spreads, the volatility of long-short commodity portfolios tends to rise less than that of long-only commodity portfolios. Likewise, long-short commodity portfolios correlate less with the S&P 500 than longonly commodity indexes and thus act as better diversifiers of equity risk. This is particularly true since the debacle of Lehman Brothers. HP strategies are particularly noteworthy in this respect as they become better risk diversifiers in periods of heightened equity risk, and thus when hedging is most needed. In contrast, the conditional correlation between long-only commodity indexes and the S&P 500 returns rises with the volatility of the S&P 500 Index, suggesting that the risk reduction that comes from diversification prevails less when needed most, namely, during equity market downturns. Following Daskalaki and Skiadopoulos [2011] in a long-only setting, it would be of interest to test whether investors can increase the out-of-sample performance of their multi-asset portfolio by adding long, as well as short, commodity positions. We see this topic as an interesting avenue for future research. ENDNOTES We would like to thank H. Till, O. Johnson, his colleagues at the Chicago Mercantile Exchange Group and participants at the 2012 EDHEC-Risk Institute Europe and Asia conferences for their useful comments. J. Miffre acknowledges financial support from the CME Group. This article presents our views and conclusions, not necessarily those of the CME Group. 1 Backwardation signals that commodity futures prices are likely to rise as maturity approaches. It occurs when hedgers SUMMER 2015 JAI-MIFFRE.indd 103 are net short and speculators are net long (Cootner [1960], Bessembinder [1992], Basu and Miffre [2013]); when the term structure of commodity futures prices slopes downward (Fama and French [1987], Erb and Harvey [2006], Gorton and Rouwenhorst [2006]); when inventories are low (Gorton et al. [2013]) or when contracts exhibit good past performance (Erb and Harvey [2006]; Miffre and Rallis [2007]). Conversely, contango signals that commodity futures prices are likely to fall as maturity approaches. The signals are then reversed. 2 We appreciate that motives of non commercial and commercial market participants are often hard to recognize and thus that the classification of traders as either speculators or hedgers might be at times inaccurate (see Ederington and Lee [2002] or Dewally et al. [2013]). This point notwithstanding, members of the Commodity Futures Trading Commission are here to check the declarations of non commercial and commercial market participants and thus we hope that their declarations as either speculators or hedgers are reliable accounts of their true positions. 3 In the spirit of Fuertes et al. [2010] and Basu and Miffre [2013] we also consider double-sort strategies that combine pairs of signals. The conclusions, similar to those pertaining to the single-sort strategies considered here, are unreported but available upon request. 4 See also Büyük ahin et al. [2010], Chong and Miffre [2010] and Büyük ahin and Robe [2013] for an analysis of conditional correlations between traditional assets and longonly commodity futures positions. 5 Detailed results on individual strategies are available upon request. 6 Equal weighting also exacerbates exposure to high volatility contracts. Alternatively, one could force each constituent to contribute equally to portfolio risk (see, for example, Anderson et al. [2012]). We see the study of the performance of risk parity strategies in commodity futures markets as an interesting avenue of research. Likewise, the study of capacity constraints and their impact on the feasibility of a trading signal is deemed of interest, as it is of prime importance to practitioners. 7 We account for a plausible round-trip transaction cost of 0.033% (Locke and Venkatesh [1997]) and for a conservative round-trip transaction cost equal to twice that amount or 0.066%. Transaction costs are incurred not only while implementing the strategy itself, but also when rebalancing the portfolio to equal weights. 8 We confirm here the findings of Tang and Xiong [2012] and Büyük ahin and Robe [2013], who show before us that the conditional correlations between long-only commodity and equity portfolios rose following the downfall of Lehman Brothers. THE JOURNAL OF A LTERNATIVE I NVESTMENTS Downloaded from http://jai.iijournals.com/ by guest on August 10, 2018 103 24/06/15 4:03 PM REFERENCES Anderson, R.M., S.W. Bianchi, and L.R. Goldberg. “Will My Risk Parity Strategy Outperform?” Financial Analysts Journal, Vol. 68, No. 6 (2012), pp. 75-93. Basu, D., and J. Miffre. “Capturing the Risk Premium of Commodity Futures: The Role of Hedging Pressure.” Journal of Banking and Finance, 37 (2013), pp. 2652-2664. Bessembinder, H. “Systematic Risk, Hedging Pressure, and Risk Premia in Futures Markets.” Review of Financial Studies, 5 (1992), pp. 637-667. Bodie, Z., and V. Rosansky. “Risk and Returns in Commodity Futures.” Financial Analysts Journal, May/June (1980), pp. 27-39. Bollerslev, T. “Generalized Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity.” Journal of Econometrics, 31 (1986), pp. 307-327. Erb, C., and C. Harvey. “The Strategic and Tactical Value of Commodity Futures.” Financial Analysts Journal, 62 (2006), pp. 69-97. Fama, E., and K. French. “Commodity Futures Prices: Some Evidence on Forecast Power, Premiums, and the Theory of Storage.” Journal of Business, 60 (1987), pp. 55-73. Fuertes, A.-M., J. Miffre, and G. Rallis. “Tactical Allocation in Commodity Futures Markets: Combining Momentum and Term Structure Signals.” Journal of Banking and Finance, 34 (2010), pp. 2530-2548. Gorton, G., F. Hayashi, and G. Rouwenhorst. “The Fundamentals of Commodity Futures Returns.” Review of Finance, 17 (2013), pp. 35-105. Gorton, G., and G. Rouwenhorst. “Facts and Fantasies about Commodity Futures.” Financial Analysts Journal, 62 (2006), pp. 47-68. Büyükşahin, B., M. Haigh, and M. Robe. “Commodities and Equities: Ever a ‘Market of One’?” The Journal of Alternative Investments, 12 (2010), pp. 76-95. Locke, P., and P. Venkatesh. “Futures Market Transaction Costs.” Journal of Futures Markets, 17 (1997), pp. 229-245. Büyükşahin, B., and M. Robe. “Speculators, Commodities and Cross-Market Linkages.” Journal of International Money and Finance, 42 (2013), pp. 38-70. Longin, F., and B. Solnik. “Extreme Correlation in International Equity Markets.” Journal of Finance, 56 (2001), pp. 649-676. Chong, J., and J. Miffre. “Conditional Correlation and Volatility in Commodity Futures and Traditional Asset Markets.” The Journal of Alternative Investments, 12 (2010), pp. 61-75. Miffre, J., and G. Rallis. “Momentum Strategies in Commodity Futures Markets.” Journal of Banking and Finance, 31 (2007), pp. 1863-1886. Cootner, P. “Returns to Speculators: Telser versus Keynes.” Journal of Political Economy, 68 (1960), pp. 396-404. Pastor, L., and R.F. Stambaugh. “Liquidity Risk and Expected Stock Returns.” Journal of Political Economy, 111 (2003), pp. 642-685. Daskalaki, C., and G. Skiadopoulos. “Should Investors Include Commodities in their Portfolios after All? New Evidence.” Journal of Banking and Finance, 35 (2011), pp. 2606-2626. Dewally, M., L., Ederington, and C. Fernando. “Determinants of Trader Profits in Commodity Futures Markets.” Review of Financial Studies, 26 (2013), pp. 2648-2683. Ederington, L., and J.H. Lee. “Who Trades Futures and How: Evidence from the Heating Oil Futures Market.” Journal of Business, 75 (2002), pp. 353-373. Solnik, B., C. Boucrelle, and Y. Le Fur. “International Market Correlation and Volatility.” Financial Analysts Journal, 52 (1996), pp. 17-34. Tang, K., and W. Xiong. “Index Investment and Financialization of Commodities.” Financial Analysts Journal, 68 (2012), pp. 54-74. To order reprints of this article, please contact Dewey Palmieri at dpalmieri@ iijournals.com or 212-224-3675. Engle, R.F. “Dynamic Conditional Correlation: A Simple Class of Multivariate Generalized Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity Models.” Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, 20 (2002), pp. 339-350. 104 JAI-MIFFRE.indd 104 THE CASE FOR L ONG -SHORTDownloaded COMMODITY Ifrom NVESTING http://jai.iijournals.com/ by guest on August 10, 2018 SUMMER 2015 24/06/15 4:03 PM