Uploaded by cathyuiuc

Chaney-2008-AER-Distorted gravity intensive and extensive margin

advertisement
American Economic Review 2008, 98:4, 1707–1721
http://www.aeaweb.org/articles.php?doi=10.1257/aer.98.4.1707
Distorted Gravity: The Intensive and Extensive Margins
of International Trade
By Thomas Chaney*
By considering a model with identical firms, Paul Krugman (1980) predicts that a higher elasticity of substitution between goods magnifies the impact of trade barriers on trade flows. In this
paper, I introduce firm heterogeneity in a simple model of international trade. When the distribution of productivity across firms is Pareto, which is close to the observed size distribution of US
firms, the predictions of the Krugman model with representative firms are overturned: the impact
of trade barriers on trade flows is dampened by the elasticity of substitution, and not magnified.
In Krugman (1980), identical countries trade differentiated goods despite the presence of trade
barriers because consumers have a preference for variety. If goods are less substitutable, consumers are willing to buy foreign varieties even at a higher cost, and trade barriers have little
impact on bilateral trade flows. Total exports from country A to country B are given by the following expression:
GDPA 3 GDPB
ExportsAB 5 Constant 3 s ,
1Trade barriersAB2
where s is the elasticity of substitution between varieties. A crucial assumption in this model is
that all firms are identical, and that the only form of transportation cost is a variable cost. Under
these assumptions, every firm exports to every country in the world. Trade barriers have a strong
impact on trade flows when the elasticity of substitution between goods is high. Competition is
fierce when the elasticity of substitution is high, and any cost disadvantage translates into large
losses of market share.
In this paper, I add firm heterogeneity in productivity, as well as fixed costs of exporting.
These simple amendments introduce a new margin of adjustment: the extensive margin. When
transportation costs vary, not only does each exporter change the size of its exports (the intensive
margin), but the set of exporters varies as well (the extensive margin). The main finding of this
paper is that the elasticity of substitution has opposite effects on each margin. A higher elasticity makes the intensive margin more sensitive to changes in trade barriers, whereas it makes the
extensive margin less sensitive. The reason is the following. When trade barriers decrease, new
and less productive firms enter the export market. When the elasticity of substitution is high, a
low productivity is a severe disadvantage. These less productive firms can capture only a small
market share. The impact of those new entrants on aggregate trade is small. On the other hand,
when the elasticity is low, each firm is sheltered from competition. The new entrants capture a
* Chaney: Department of Economics, University of Chicago, 1126 East 59th Street, Chicago, IL 60637 (e-mail:
tchaney@uchicago.edu). I am grateful to Xavier Gabaix, Marc Melitz, and Daron Acemoglu for their encouragement and advice. I also thank the editor, three anonymous referees, and Richard Rogerson for their comments. For
their suggestions and comments, I also wish to thank Sylvain Chassang, Sam Kortum, David Sraer, and participants
at the Federal Reserve Board of Governors, Boston College, Boston University, Columbia University, University of
Chicago, Chicago GSB, Harvard University, INSEAD, LSE, MIT, the New York Fed, New York University, University
of Pennsylvania, University of California–Berkeley, University of California–San Diego, University of Wisconsin–
Madison, the World Bank, and on the REStud Tour 2005. All remaining errors are mine.
1707
1708
THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW
September 2008
large market share. The impact of those new entrants on aggregate trade is large. So a higher
elasticity of substitution magnifies the sensitivity of the intensive margin to changes in trade barriers, whereas it dampens the sensitivity of the extensive margin.
Which effect dominates? I prove that when the distribution of productivity across firms is
Pareto, which is a good approximation of the observed distribution of US firms, the effect on
the extensive margin dominates. My augmented model predicts that total exports from country
A to country B are given by the following expression:
GDPA 3 GDPB
ExportsAB 5 Constant 3 with e91s2 , 0.
1Trade barriersAB2 e 1s2
The elasticity of aggregate trade with respect to trade barriers (both variable and fixed), e, is
negatively related to the elasticity of substitution, s. Variable trade barriers enter the gravity
equation with an exponent that depends only on the distribution of productivity and not on the
elasticity of substitution, and fixed trade barriers with an exponent that is inversely related to the
elasticity of substitution.
The model with heterogeneous firms also predicts that the same trade barriers will have a
larger impact on trade flows than in the model with representative firms. When trade barriers
decrease, each firm exports more. In addition, new firms start exporting. This adjustment on the
extensive margin is quantitatively important. Given the observed distribution of firm size in the
United States, I predict that the elasticity of trade flows with respect to variable trade barriers
such as tariffs is twice as large as it would be in the absence of firm heterogeneity.
The prediction, that the effect of trade barriers on trade flows is magnified by the elasticity of
substitution, is not specific to Krugman’s model of trade. Maurice Obstfeld and Kenneth Rogoff
(2001), for example, explain the six major puzzles in International Macroeconomics by the existence of trade barriers. The simple model they spell out to illustrate how plausible values for
trade barriers can have a large impact on trade flows relies on the magnification by the elasticity
of substitution. James E. Anderson (1979) presents a theoretical foundation for the gravity equation based on the Armington assumption of competitive trade in goods differentiated by country
of origin. In both models, a higher elasticity of substitution will magnify the effect of trade barriers on trade flows, even in the absence of increasing returns or monopolistic competition.
The main contribution of this paper is to introduce the extensive margin of trade in a simple and
tractable model with multiple countries and asymmetric trade barriers. The elasticity of aggregate
trade flows with respect to trade barriers is larger than what traditional models would predict. It is
not equal to the elasticity of substitution; it is inversely related to the elasticity of substitution.
In the remainder of this section, I review previous work related to this model, and existing
empirical evidence that supports the predictions of this model.
Marc Melitz (2003) introduces firm heterogeneity in a general equilibrium model of international trade. I expand Melitz’s model in the following way. I consider a world with many asymmetric countries, separated by asymmetric trade barriers. I then study the strategic choice of
firms to export or not, and if they export, which countries to target. I embed my model in a global
equilibrium. Such a model generates predictions for the structure of bilateral trade flows. I can
pin down which firm from which country is able to enter a given market, and how it is affected
by competition from local and other foreign firms, even in the presence of asymmetric bilateral
trade barriers. The presence of fixed costs associated with entering foreign markets provides a
simple foundation for the extensive margin of trade.
See Erzo G. J. Luttmer (2007) for the most recent evidence, and this introduction for further references.
VOL. 98 NO. 4
chaney: Distorted Gravity
1709
Elhanan Helpman, Melitz, and Yona Rubinstein (forthcoming) develop a similar extension to
the Melitz model with multiple countries. Using bounded support for the productivity shocks,
they can make use of the information contained in the zeros of the trade matrices and improve
on the traditional gravity regressions. They do not, however, generate analytical solutions for the
extensive margin of trade. This gives them more flexibility in estimating empirically the probability that exporters enter a given foreign market. But it prevents them from deriving precise
predictions for the role of variable and fixed costs in explaining both the intensive and the extensive margins of international trade.
Kim J. Ruhl (2005) builds a dynamic version of the Melitz model to explain the so-called
elasticity puzzle. He argues that in response to high frequency transitory shocks, most of the
adjustments of exports happen at the intensive margin, whereas in response to permanent shocks
such as trade liberalization, both the intensive and the extensive margins adjust. I abstract from
any dynamic considerations and build a model of the steady-state trade flows between many
countries. Costas Arkolakis (2007) offers an extension to the current model to explain the existence of small exporters, even in the presence of fixed trade barriers. He proposes that firms can
decide what fraction of a market they want to access, where the fixed entry cost increases with
the number of consumers reached.
Jonathan Eaton, Sam Kortum, and Francis Kramarz (2007) find that the current model provides a good description of firm-level trade using data on French exporters. Among others, the
current model predicts correctly many of the patterns of entry of heterogeneous firms into different markets, and the relationship between the size of a firm on its domestic market, and the
number of foreign markets it enters. The assumption that productivity shocks are Pareto distributed provides a good fit for the firm-level data: it describes precisely the distribution of firm size
within France, as well as which foreign markets a given firm enters.
There is wide empirical evidence that the Pareto distribution is a good approximation of the
upper tail of the distribution of firm sizes. Since exporters are overwhelmingly large firms, and
therefore in the upper tail of the size distribution, this distribution is a good candidate for a
theoretical model of firm selection into export markets. Herbert A. Simon and Charles P. Bonini
(1958) first noted that the size distribution of firm sizes is well described by a Pareto distribution. Recent evidence on this empirical regularity for the United States include Robert L. Axtell
(2001) and Luttmer (2007). Xavier Gabaix (2008) provides a survey on the prevalence of “power
law” distributions for firms in the United States and in Europe. Helpman, Melitz, and Stephen
Yeaple (2004) estimate a Pareto distribution for both US and European firms to predict foreign
direct investment in different sectors.
The closest evidence in support of the predictions of the current model are James E. Rauch
(1999), Martin Andersson (2007), Matthieu Crozet and Pamina Koenig (2007), and Koenig
(2005). Rauch finds that trade barriers have a milder impact on trade volumes for goods that
are more homogenous. He defines homogenous goods as goods that are traded on organized
exchanges, or goods that have a reference price. He argues that acquiring information about
differentiated goods is costly, so that effectively differentiated goods face a higher trade barrier.
This reasoning can, however, explain why there should be more trade in homogenous goods, but
not why given trade barriers should have a bigger impact. The current model offers an alternative
explanation for the interaction between product differentiation and trade barriers. I spell out a
clear theoretical channel through which product differentiation affects trade barriers. Andersson
(2007) uses firm-level export data on Swedish firms. He separates out the impact of variable
trade barriers and the impact of fixed trade barriers (proxied by measures of “familiarity” of
markets), and separates out their impact on the intensive and extensive margins of trade. First,
he finds that fixed costs have a larger impact on the extensive margin than on the intensive
margin of trade. Moreover, the impact of fixed trade barriers on the extensive margin is larger
1710
September 2008
THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW
for ­differentiated goods than for homogenous goods. Crozet and Koenig (2007) use firm-level
export data on French firms to structurally estimate the current model. The panel dimension
of the data allows them to separate out the distance elasticity of trade costs from the elasticity
of exports with respect to trade barriers. Koenig (2005) uses the same firm-level export data
on French firms. As the current model predicts, she finds that the distance elasticity of individual firm exports (the intensive margin) is larger in sectors where goods are more homogenous,
whereas the distance elasticity of the number of firms (the extensive margin) is smaller in sectors
where goods are more homogenous. In addition, she finds that the share of exports explained by
the extensive margin is larger in sectors with more differentiated goods. At the aggregate level,
unlike the predictions of this model, she finds that in sectors with homogenous goods, the distance elasticity of total exports is mildly larger than in sectors with differentiated goods, but this
difference is not significant.
Finally, several authors have stressed the quantitative importance of the extensive margin in
explaining aggregate trade flows. David Hummels and Peter J. Klenow (2005) find that larger
and wealthier countries trade more, and that 60 percent of the difference in aggregate trade flows
comes from differences in the number of goods traded. Along a slightly different line, Kei-Mu Yi
(2003) argues that the increase in trade in intermediate goods, which amounts to trade in more
goods, can help explain the observed increase in international trade in the last decades. All find
a strong response of the extensive margin to changes in trade barriers or country size that are
consistent with the current model.
The remainder of the paper is organized as follows. Section I introduces a simple model of
international trade with heterogeneous firms and derives partial equilibrium results. In Sec­tion II,
I compute the general equilibrium of the world economy. Finally, Section III identifies separately
the adjustments of the intensive and the extensive margins of trade, in response to changes in
both variable and fixed trade barriers.
I. Setup
In this section, I introduce the basic ingredients of the model. I define preferences and
technologies, and I characterize the optimal strategies of both firms and consumers in partial
equilibrium.
There are N potentially asymmetric countries that produce goods using only labor. Country n
has a population Ln. Consumers in each country maximize utility derived from the consumption
of goods from H 1 1 sectors. Sector 0 provides a single homogenous good. The other H sectors
are made of a continuum of differentiated goods. If a consumer consumes qo units of good 0, and
qh 1v 2 units of each variety v of good h, for all varieties in the set V h (determined in equilibrium),
she gets a utility U,
U;
(1) qom0
q q3 qh 1v 2
H
h51
Vh
1sh212/sh
dvr
3sh / 1sh212 4 mh
,
where m0 1 g h51 mh 5 1, and where sh . 1 is the elasticity of substitution between two varieties
of good h. I assume that H . 1 so that I can compare sectors characterized by different degrees
of product substitutability.
H
The impact of distance is also larger, which suggests that distance proxies for both variable and some fixed costs.
It is empirically more relevant to compare sectors with different degrees of product substitutability than to compare different economies.
VOL. 98 NO. 4
chaney: Distorted Gravity
1711
Trade Barriers and Technology.—The homogenous good 0 is freely traded and is used as
the numeraire. It is produced under constant returns to scale with one unit of labor in country n
producing wn units of good 0. Its price is set equal to 1 so that if country n produces this good,
the wage in country n is wn. I shall consider only equilibria where every country produces some
of the numeraire. This assumption greatly simplifies the analysis. It allows countries to differ
both in size 1Ln 2 and in productivity 1wn 2. There are two types of trade barriers, a variable and
a fixed cost. The variable cost takes the form of an “iceberg” transportation cost. If one unit of
any differentiated good h is shipped from country i to country j, only a fraction 1/t hij arrives. The
rest melts on the way. The higher t, the higher the variable trade cost. In addition, if a firm from
country i in sector h exports to country j, it must pay a fixed cost fijh, in units of the numeraire.
All countries have access to the same technology. Due to the presence of fixed costs, firms
in the differentiated sectors operate under increasing returns-to-scale technology. Each firm in
sector h draws a random unit labor productivity w. The cost of producing q units of a good and
selling them in country j for a firm with productivity w is
(2) cijh
w ithij
1q 2 5
q 1 fijh.
w
Firms are price setters. Given that demand functions are isoelastic, the optimal price charged in
country j by firm w from country i is a constant mark-up over the unit cost (including transportation costs): pijh 1w 2 5 sh / 1sh 2 12 3 wi t hij /w.
As in Helpman, Melitz, and Yeaple (2004), I assume that productivity shocks are drawn from a
Pareto distribution with shape parameter gh : productivity is distributed over 31, 1 `2 according to
(3) P 1w̃h , w 2 5 Gh 1w 2 5 1 2 w2gh,
with gh . sh 2 1. An inverse measure of the heterogeneity in sector h is given by gh. Sectors with
a high g are more homogenous, in the sense that more output is concentrated among the smallest
and least productive firms. The assumption that productivity shocks are Pareto distributed is
made first for analytical tractability, and second because it provides a good approximation of the
distribution of firm sizes in the United States.
I assume that the total mass of potential entrants in country n in each differentiated sector is
proportional to wn Ln , so that larger and wealthier countries have more entrants. This assumption
greatly simplifies the analysis. It is similar to Eaton and Kortum (2002), where the set of goods
is exogenously given. Since I do not impose free entry, firms generate net profits that have to be
redistributed. I assume that each worker owns wn shares of a global fund. The fund collects profits from all firms and redistributes them in units of the numeraire good to its shareholders.
Demand for Differentiated Goods.—The total income spent by workers in country j, Yj , is
the sum of their labor income 1wj Lj 2 and of the dividends they get from their portfolio 1wj Lj p2 ,
where p is the dividend per share of the global mutual fund. Given the optimal pricing of firms,
As long as the share of the homogenous good, m 0 , is large enough, or trade barriers in the other sectors are large
enough, this condition will hold.
h
t ij . 1 for any i Z j and t hii 5 1. I also impose a triangular inequality to prevent transportation arbitrages: 5 1i, j, k 2 ,
tik # tij 3 tjk.
ln w has a standard deviation equal to 1/g. The assumption g . s 2 1 ensures that, in equilibrium, the size distribution of firms has a finite mean.
See Luttmer (2002) for the most recent evidence.
1712
September 2008
THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW
and the demand by consumers, exports from country i to country j in sector h, by a firm with a
labor productivity w, are
phij 1 w 2 1 2 sh
(4) x hij 1w 2 5 phij 1w 2 q hij 1w 2 5 mhYj a h b
,
Pj
where P hj is the ideal price index for good h in country j. If only those firms above the productiv–h in country k and sector h export to country j, the ideal price index for good h in
ity threshold w
kj
country j, Pj, and dividends per share, p, are defined as
(5) P hj 5 q a wk Lk 3
N
`
k 51
wkjh
p5
h
1/ 11 2 sh 2
sh w k tkj 1 2 sh
b
dGh 1w 2r
;
sh 2 1 w
h
a a w k L k a 3 h pkl 1 w 2 dGh 1 w 2 b
H
(6) a
N
h51 k, l51
`
wkl
a w nL n
N
,
n51
where phkl 1w 2 5 1 p hkl 1w 2 2 c hkl 1w 2 2 q hkl 1w 2 2 f klh are the net profits that a firm with productivity w
in country k and sector h earns from exporting to country l.
For now, I will consider only sector h. The other sectors are analogous. For notational clarity,
I drop the h subscript and all sectoral variables will refer to sector h when there is no ambiguity.
II. Trade with Heterogeneous Firms
In this section, I compute the global equilibrium of this world economy. To do so, I solve for
the selection of firms into different export markets. I generate predictions for aggregate bilateral
trade flows.
A firm chooses a subset of countries where it sells its output, and sets prices for its good in
each market, taking the strategies of other firms and of consumers as given. Consumers chose
the quantity consumed of each variety available domestically, given prices. All agents move
simultaneously, and an equilibrium is a fixed point to their strategies. Firms decide whether to
enter a given market depending on how much competition they expect to face in that market.
The toughness of competition in turn depends on which firms enter. I derive the solution to this
selection problem, which turns out to be quite tractable.
Productivity Threshold.—Less productive firms are not able to generate enough profits abroad
to cover the fixed cost of entering foreign markets. Exporters are therefore only a subset of
domestic firms. This subset varies with the characteristics of the foreign market. The profits firm
w earns when exporting from i to j are pij 1w 2 5 m/s Yj 3s/ 1s 2 12 1wi tij /w 2 / Pj 4 12s 2 fij. Define
– from p 1w
– 2 5 0 as the productivity of the least productive firm in country i
the threshold w
ij
ij
ij
able to export to country j:
(7) – 5l a
w
ij
1
f ij
Yj
b
1/ 1s212
w itij
Pj
,
– . 1.
with l1 a constant. I assume that trade barriers are always high enough so that 5k, l, w
kl
l1 5 1s/m 2 1/ 1s212 1s/ 1s212 2 .
chaney: Distorted Gravity
VOL. 98 NO. 4
1713
Equilibrium Price Indices.—Until now, I have considered aggregate prices as given. They
do adjust, however, depending on country characteristics. Thanks to two simplifying assumptions—wages are exogenously pinned down in the homogenous sector, and the number of potential entrants (not the number of actual entrants) is exogenously given—the set of firms that export
to country j depends only on country j’s characteristics. Plugging the productivity thresholds
from equation (7) into the price index from equation (5), I can solve for the equilibrium price
index:
Pj 5 l2 3 Yj1/g21/ 1s212 3 uj,
(8) where uj2g ; g k 51 1Yk / Y 2 3 1wk tkj 2 2g 3 f kj2 3g/ 1s212214 , Y is world output, and l2 is a constant.
An aggregate index of j’s remoteness from the rest of the world is given by uj.10 It is reminiscent of the “multilateral resistance variable” introduced by Anderson and Eric Van Wincoop
(2003). In addition to their measure, it takes into account the impact of fixed costs and of firm
heterogeneity on aggregate prices.
N
Equilibrium Exports, Thresholds, and Profits.—Exports by an individual firm depend on its
productivity, the trade barriers it must overcome, aggregate demand, the set of competitors it is
facing, and the price they set. Plugging the general equilibrium price index from equation (8) into
the demand function, and into the productivity threshold from equation (7), I can solve simultaneously for firm level exports the productivity thresholds and total world profits. In general equilibrium, exports xij 1w 2 from country i to country j by an individual firm with productivity w, the
– above which firms in i export to j, aggregate output Y , and dividends
productivity threshold w
ij
j
per share p, are given by
Y j 1s212 / g
u j s21
–
(9) x 1w 2 5 • l3 3 a b
3a
b
3 ws21, if w $ w
ij
w itij
ij
Y
0 otherwise,
µ
– 5 l 3 aY b
w
ij
4
Yj
1/g
3a
Yi 5 11 1 l52 3 wi Li,
w itij
uj
b 3 fij1/ 1s212 ,
p 5 l5,
lg2 5 a
g
g 2 1 s 2 1 2 s g/ 1s21221
s
11p
ba b
a
b a
b.
g
m
s21
Y
Note that there is a slight abuse of notations, as dividends per share 1p2 and world output (Y) will be endogenously
determined in equilibrium. However, firms as well as consumers take total world profits and output as a constant. I will
solve for 1p, Y2 in equilibrium.
10
A simple way to interpret this aggregate index is to look at a symmetrical case: when wk tkj 5 wtj and f kj 5 fj for
all k’s, uj 5 fj1/ 1s212 2 1/g 3 wtj. In asymmetric cases, uj is a weighted average of bilateral trade barriers.
1714
THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW
September 2008
with l3, l4, and l5 as constants.11 Equilibrium variables are functions of fundamentals only: the
size Lj ,12 the productivity wi, the trade barriers fij and tij, and the measure of j ’s remoteness from
the rest of the world, uj.
As expected from this simple monopolistic competition model, exports by individual firms
depend on the transportation cost tij with an elasticity s 2 1. Firm-level trade is very similar to
what a traditional model of trade with representative firms would predict for aggregate bilateral
trade flows. In contrast, because of the selection of firms into the export market, aggregate bilateral trade in the present model will look radically different.
Proposition 1 (Aggregate Trade): Total exports (f.o.b.) X hij in sector h from country i to
country j are given by
(10) Xhij 5 mh 3
Yi 3 Yj
Y
3a
w ithij
u hj
2gh
b
3 1 fijh 2 2 3gh / 1sh212214 .
Exports are a function of country sizes 1Yi and Yj 2 ,13 workers’ productivity 1wi 2 , the bilateral
trade costs, variable 1t hij 2 and fixed 1 fijh 2 , and the measure of j’s remoteness from the rest of the
world 1uhj 2.14
Proof:
See the Appendix.
The gravity structure of trade has been dramatically distorted by the presence of firm
heterogeneity.
First note that the elasticity of exports with respect to variable trade barriers, g, is larger than
in the absence of firm heterogeneity, and larger than the elasticity for each individual firm (both
equal to s 2 1). A reduction in variable costs not only causes an increase in the size of exports
of each exporter, but also allows some new firms to enter. The extensive margin comes on top of
the intensive margin and amplifies the impact of variable costs. This amplification effect is quantitatively important. Anderson and Van Wincoop (2004) argue that if one assumes that trade is
governed by an underlying model of trade with identical firms, trade barriers between the United
States and Canada must be equivalent to a 46 percent tariff in order to explain the observed
bilateral trade flows (for a benchmark case with s 5 8). In the presence of firm ­heterogeneity,
11
l3 5 sl412s, l4 5 3s/m 3 g/ 3g 2 1s 2 12 4 3 1/ 11 1 l 52 4 1/g, and
aa
s h 2 1 mh
b
gh
sh
h51
l5 5
.
H
s h 2 1 mh
12 aa
b
gh
sh
h51
H
I am grateful to Sebastian Krautheim for helpful suggestions on computing aggregate profits.
12
The elasticity of individual firms’ exports with respect to the destination market Yj is less than one. This is due to
the impact of market size on the degree of price competition: as the size of the market grows, more firms enter, which
eat up part of the market shares of existing exporters.
13
GDP is proportional to labor income: Yi 5 11 1 l 52 wi Li.
14
Note that the ratio of i’s market share in k, and j ’s market share in k, depends only on the ratio of i’s trade barriers and j ’s trade barriers. If I define the composite measure of trade barriers kik 5 1wi tik 2 2g 3 f ik2 3g2 1s212 4 / 1s212 , I get:
1Xik / Yi 2 / 1Xjk /Yj 2 5 kik /kjk . Similarly, i ’s market share in k depends only on trade barriers from i relative to trade barriers
from other countries: Xik / Xk 5 3 1Li / L2 kik / gj 1Lj / L2 kjk 4 .
chaney: Distorted Gravity
VOL. 98 NO. 4
1715
and using a heterogeneity parameter estimated from firm-level data 1g/1s 2 12 < 22 ,15 I would
infer from the same trade volume data that trade barriers are equivalent to a 21 percent tariff
11.21 5 !1.462.16 This is far below their 46 percent estimate.
Second, the elasticity of exports with respect to transportation costs depends on the degree of
firm heterogeneity, g. In more homogenous sectors 1g high2 , large productive firms represent a
smaller fraction of firms. The productivity threshold moves in a region where most of the mass
of firms lies. In those sectors, aggregate exports are sensitive to changes in transportation costs
because many firms exit and enter when variable costs fluctuate.
Third and most important, the elasticity of exports with respect to variable costs does not
depend at all on the elasticity of substitution between goods, s,17 and the elasticity of exports
with respect to fixed costs is negatively related to the elasticity s. This prediction is in stark contrast with models with representative firms. In such models, the elasticity of exports with respect
to transportation costs would be equal to s 2 1.
III. Intensive versus Extensive Margins of Trade
In this section, I describe how the elasticity of substitution magnifies the sensitivity of the
intensive margin to trade barriers and dampens the sensitivity of the extensive margin. I prove
that the dampening effect on the extensive margin dominates the magnifying effect on the intensive margin.
Thus far, I have shown that in the presence of firm heterogeneity, the selection of firms into the
export market becomes a key feature of the adjustment of trade flows. The main prediction of the
model is that the extensive margin and the intensive margin are affected in opposite directions by
the elasticity of substitution. If the elasticity of substitution is high, then the impact of trade barriers is strong on the intensive margin and mild on the extensive margin. The reverse holds true
when the elasticity of substitution is low. The dampening effect of the elasticity of substitution on
the extensive margin dominates the magnifying effect on the intensive margin.
Proposition 2 (Intensive and Extensive Margins): The elasticity of substitution 1s2 has no
effect on the elasticity of trade flows with respect to variable trade costs 1z2 , and a negative
effect on the elasticity of trade flows with respect to fixed costs 1j2:
if z ; 2
d ln X ij
d ln tij
and j ; 2
d ln X ij
d ln f ij
, then
'z
'z
5 0 and
, 0.
's
's
15
I measure g/ 1s 2 12 as the regression coefficient of the log of rank (ordering US firms according to their sales in
the United States) on the log of sales, using Compustat data on US listed firms. With an alternative method using the
propensity of French firms to export to multiple markets, Eaton, Kortum, and Kramarz (2007) find a smaller number,
g/ 1s 2 12 < 1.5.
16
To make the two models comparable, despite the presence of fixed entry costs, I assume the entry cost into any
Canadian province is the same for US and Canadian firms.
17
Eaton and Kortum (2002) derive a similar prediction from a different setup. In a Ricardian model of trade, they
find that bilateral trade flows do not depend on the elasticity of substitution between goods, but only on the scaling
parameter of the underlying distribution of productivity shocks. They use Fréchet distributions, which approach Pareto
2u
distributions in their right tails: the distribution for shocks they consider is 1 2 F 1z2 5 1 2 e2Tz
5 Tz2u 1 o 1z2u 2 .
z S 1`
In equilibrium, they predict that the elasticity of trade flows with respect to trade barriers (variable only) is equal to u.
1716
September 2008
THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW
Proof:
To prove this proposition, I introduce formally the intensive and the extensive margins of
trade. I describe the adjustment of each margin, and the sensitivity of these adjustments to the
elasticity of substitution.
The impact of trade barriers, both variable and fixed, on aggregate trade flows can be decomposed into two different margins. The intensive margin is defined by how much each existing
exporter changes the size of its exports. The extensive margin is defined by how much new
entrants export (in the case of a reduction in trade barriers).
`
Differentiating the expression for aggregate exports, Xij 5 wi Li ewij xij 1w 2 dG 1w 2 , I get the fol18
lowing expressions for each margin:
dXij 5 awi Li 3
`
wij
1 awi Li 3
`
'x ij 1 w 2
'tij
'x ij 1 w 2
–ij 2 G9 1w
–ij 2 3
dG 1w 2 b dtij 2 awi Li x 1w
–ij 2 G9 1w
–ij 2 3
dG 1w 2 b d fij 2 awi Li x 1w
'f ij
8
wij
'wij
'tij
b dtij
'wij
b d fij .
'f ij
8
Intensive margin
Extensive margin
–ij 2 exports more. This is the
Following a reduction of trade barriers, each existing exporter 1w . w
–ij goes down2.
intensive margin. At the same time, higher potential profits attract new entrants 1w
This is the extensive margin.
In elasticity notations, I get the following expression for each margin for changes in the variable cost, tij:19
z;2
d ln X ij
d ln tij
5
1s 2 12
3
Intensive margin
Elasticity
1
1g 2 1s 2 12 2 5 g .
3
Extensive margin
Elasticity
When variable costs move 1s 2 1 increases with s2 , s magnifies the intensive margin, whereas
it dampens the extensive margin 1g 2 1s 2 12 decreases with s2.20 The effect of s on each margin cancels out, so that
'z
5 0.
's
18
I use Leibniz rule to separate the intensive from the extensive margin. I apply Lebesgue’s monotone convergence
theorem to ensure the existence of, and to compute, the intensive margin.
19
See the Appendix for a complete derivation.
20
I have implicitly assumed that changes in both tij and f ij have no significant impact on the general equilibrium.
That is, I have assumed that 0uj /0tij 5 0uj /0 f ij 5 0. This is a fair approximation as long as country i is not too large
compared to the rest of the world 1Yi / Y small). Relaxing this assumption would reinforce my results, but it would make
calculations cumbersome. See the Technical Appendix (available at http://www.aeaweb.org/articles.php?doi=10.1257/
aer.98.4.1707 for a derivation of the general case.
chaney: Distorted Gravity
VOL. 98 NO. 4
1717
In elasticity notation, I get the following expression for each margin for changes in the fixed
costs, fij:
j;2
d ln X ij
d ln f ij
5
0
1
3
Intensive margin
Elasticity
g
21
s21
3
5
g
2 1.
s21
Extensive margin
Elasticity
When only fixed costs move, s has no impact on the intensive margin, whereas it dampens the
impact on the extensive margin 1g / 1s 2 12 2 1 decreases with s2. The impact of s on the elasticity of trade flows with respect to fixed costs is always negative:
'j
, 0.
's
The intuition for these results is the following. When goods are highly differentiated 1s is
low2 , the demand for each individual variety is relatively insensitive to changes in trade costs.
In other words, when s is low, trade barriers have little impact on the intensive margin of trade.
This margin is the only one in the Krugman model of trade with representative firms.
The interaction between the elasticity of substitution and the extensive margin is more complex. When s is low, the market share that each firm is able to capture is relatively insensitive to
differences in productivity. Less productive firms are still able to capture a relatively large market share, despite having to charge a higher price than other firms. As trade barriers decrease,
some firms with a low level of productivity are able to enter. When goods are highly differentiated 1s is low2 , these new entrants are relatively large compared to the firms that are already
exporting. Therefore, the extensive margin is strongly affected by trade barriers when s is low.
The reverse holds when s is high.
In this section, I have explained why the elasticity of substitution has opposite effects on the
intensive and the extensive margins of trade. A higher elasticity of substitution makes the intensive margin more sensitive to changes in trade barriers, whereas it makes the extensive margin
less sensitive. What is the net impact of s on the two margins? I prove in Proposition 2 that with
Pareto distributed productivity shocks, the extensive margin always dominates. Contrary to the
predictions of the Krugman model with representative firms, the elasticity of substitution s
always dampens the impact of trade barriers on trade flows.
IV. Conclusion
Introducing firm heterogeneity leaves many of the predictions of the Krugman (1980) model
of international trade unaffected. Most important, the gravity structure of bilateral trade flows
is preserved. In this paper, I have identified a key difference between the Krugman model with
representative firms and a model with firm heterogeneity. The impact of trade barriers is dampened by the elasticity of substitution, and not magnified by it. I introduce fixed export costs and
adjustments on the extensive margin in a simple model of international trade. A high elasticity
of substitution translates productivity differences into large differences in size. As firm sizes
get more dispersed, fixed costs have a lesser impact on exports: large firms can easily overcome
those fixed costs. Aggregate trade flows are less sensitive to trade barriers when goods are more
substitutable.
1718
September 2008
THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW
Appendix
Proposition 1 (Reminded): Total exports (f.o.b.) X hij in sector h from country i to country j
are given by
X hij 5 mh 3
Yi 3 Yj
Y
3a
w ithij
u hj
2gh
b
3 1 f hij 2 2 1gh / 1sh212212 .
Exports are a function of country sizes 1Yi and Yj 2 , workers’ productivity 1wi 2 , the bilateral
trade costs, variable 1t hij 2 and fixed 1 f hij 2 , and the measure of j’s remoteness from the rest of the
world 1uhj 2.
Proof:
Aggregate exports from i to j are defined as the sum of export of each individual firm with
–ijh:
productivity w $ w
X hij 5 wi Li 3 x hij 1w 2 dGh 1w 2.
`
w hij
–ijh 2 and the productivity
From equation (9) we know the size of firm-level exports x hij 1w Z w $ w
h
–
threshold wij . Using the specific assumption about the distribution Gh of productivity shocks
from equation (3), we can rewrite aggregate exports as
X hij
5 wi Li 3
`
w hij
l3h
Yj
3a b
Y
1s 2 12 / g
3a
u hj
w ithij
b
s21
3 wsh21 3
w2gh21
dw,
gh
1/g
wt
–ijh 5 lh4 3 a Y b 3 a i ij b 3 fijh 11/ 1s212 2 ,
with w
Yj
u hj
h
where lh3 and lh4 are some constants.21 Given the assumption of Pareto distributed productivity
and isoelastic preferences, we get a simple solution for the integral. After solving the integral
and rearranging, we get
X hij
5 lh 3
w i L i Yj
Y
3a
w ithij
u hj
2gh
b
3 1 f hij 2 2 1gh / 1sh212212 ,
with lh 5 11 1 l52 3 mh. Noting that Yi 5 11 1 l52 wiLi, we get
X hij
5 mh 3
Yi 3 Yj
Y
3a
w ithij
u hj
2gh
b
3 1 f hij 2 2 1gh / 1sh212212 .
Proposition 2 (Reminded):
(i) The elasticity of the intensive margin of trade with respect to variable trade costs is 1s 2 12.
(ii) The elasticity of the extensive margin of trade with respect to variable costs is 1g 2
1s 2 122.
21 h
l 3 5 s 1lh42 12s, lh4 5 3sh /mh 3 gh / 1gh 2 1sh 2 12 2 3 1/ 11 1 l 52 4 1/gh , and l 5 5 5 3 gHh51 1 1sh 2 12 / gh 2 1mh /sh 2 4 /
312gHh51 1 1sh 2 12 / gh 2 1mh /sh 2 4 6.
chaney: Distorted Gravity
VOL. 98 NO. 4
1719
(iii) The elasticity of the intensive margin of trade with respect to fixed costs is 0.
(iv) The elasticity of the extensive margin of trade with respect to fixed costs is 3g 2
1s 2 124 / 1s 2 12.
Proof:
(i) The definition of the intensive and the extensive margins from Proposition 2 gives us
2
2
d ln X ij
d ln tij
d ln X ij
d ln f ij
5
5
2dX ij/dtij
X ij/tij
2dX ij/df ij
X ij/f ij
tij
awiLi 3
`
'x ij 1 w 2
–ij 2 G9 1w
–ij 2 3
awi Li x 1w
'wij
b
X ij
'tij
8
Intensive margin elasticity
Extensive margin elasticity
f ij
awiLi 3
`
'x ij 1 w 2
dG 1w 2 b 1
tij
X ij
'tij
wij
8
52
dG 1w 2 b 1
f ij
–ij 2 G9 1w
–ij 2 3
awi Li x 1w
'wij
X ij
'f ij
wij
8
b.
X ij
'f ij
8
Intensive margin elasticity
Extensive margin elasticity
52
Using the definition of equilibrium individual exports from equation (9), and assuming that
country i is small enough and/or remote enough, so that 0uj /0tij 5 2g 1Yi / Y2 3 wi2g tij2g21 3
f ij2 3g2 1s212 4/ 1s212 < 0, we get
'x ij 1 w 2
'tij
Integrating over all exporters, we get
5 2 1s 2 12
x ij 1 w 2
.
tij
`
Elasticity of the intensive margin
tij
'x ij 1 w 2
with respect to variable costs 5 2 awiLi 3
dG 1w 2 b
X ij
'tij
wij
wiLi 3 xij 1w 2 dG 1w 2
`
5 1s 2 12
5 1s 2 12
tij
X ij
wij
tij
tij X ij
X ij tij
5 1s 2 12.
(ii) Using the definition of the equilibrium productivity threshold from equation (9), we get
'wij
'tij
5
wij
.
tij
1720
September 2008
THE AMERICAN ECONOMIC REVIEW
Using the definition of firm-level exports xij(w) 5 lijws21 from equation (9), and the definition
of the distribution of productivity shocks G9(w) 5 w2g21 /g from equation (3), we can rewrite
aggregate exports in the following way:
Xij 5 wi Li 3 xij 1w 2 dG 1w 2
`
w hij
5 wi Li 3 lijws21
`
wij
5
5
w 2g21
dw
g
1
–ij1s2122g
w L l s21 w
1 g 2 1 s 2 1 2 2 g i i ij
1
–ij2 G9 1w
–ij2 3 w
–ij .
3 wiLi xij 1w
1
g 2 s 2 12
We therefore get the simple solution for the elasticity:
Elasticity of the extensive margin
tij
'w
–ij2 G9 1w
–ij2 3 ij b
with respect to variable costs 5
awiLi x 1w
X ij
'tij
5
tij w i L i x 1 wij 2 Gr 1 wij 2 3 wij
a
b
tij
X ij
5 1g 2 1s 2 12 2
tij X ij
X ij tij
5 1g 2 1s 2 12 2.
(iii) Using the definition of the equilibrium firm-level exports from equation (9), we get
'x ij 1 w 2
'f ij
5 0.
We directly derive that the elasticity of the intensive margin of trade with respect to fixed costs
is 0.
(iv) Using the definition of the equilibrium productivity threshold from equation (9), we get
'wij
'f ij
5
wij
1
3 ,
s21
f ij
and using the same procedure as in (ii), we prove that the elasticity of the extensive margin with
respect to fixed trade costs is g/ 1s 2 12 2 1.
VOL. 98 NO. 4
chaney: Distorted Gravity
1721
References
Anderson, James E. 1979. “A Theoretical Foundation for the Gravity Equation.” American Economic
Review, 69(1): 106–16.
Anderson, James E., and Eric van Wincoop. 2003. “Gravity with Gravitas: A Solution to the Border Puz-
zle.” American Economic Review, 93(1): 170–92.
Anderson, James E., and Eric van Wincoop. 2004. “Trade Costs.” Journal of Economic Literature, 42(3):
691–751.
Andersson, Martin. 2007. “Entry Costs and Adjustments on the Extensive Margin—An Analysis of How
Familiarity Breeds Exports.” Unpublished.
Arkolakis, Costas. 2007. “Market Access Costs and the New Consumers Margin in International Trade.”
Unpublished.
Axtell, Robert L. 2001. “Zipf Distribution of U. S. Firm Sizes.” Science, 293(5536): 1818–20.
Crozet, Matthieu, and Pamina Koenig. 2007. “Structural Gravity Equation with Extensive and Intensive
Margins.” Unpublished.
Eaton, Jonathan, and Samuel Kortum. 2002. “Technology, Geography, and Trade.” Econometrica, 70(5):
1741–79.
Eaton, Jonathan, Samuel Kortum, and Francis Kramarz. 2007. “An Anatomy of International Trade: Evi-
dence from French Firms.” Unpublished.
Gabaix, Xavier. 2008. “Power Laws.” In The New Palgrave Dictionary of Economics. 2nd edition, ed.
­Steven N. Durlauf and Lawrence E. Blume. New York: Palgrave Macmillan.
Helpman, Elhanan, Marc J. Melitz, and Yona Rubinstein. Forthcoming. “Estimating Trade Flows: Trad-
ing Partners and Trading Volumes.” Quarterly Journal of Economics.
Helpman, Elhanan, Marc J. Melitz, and Stephen R. Yeaple. 2004. “Export versus FDI with Heterogeneous
Firms.” American Economic Review, 94(1): 300–16.
Hummels, David, and Peter J. Klenow. 2005. “The Variety and Quality of a Nation’s Exports.” American
Economic Review, 95(3): 704–23.
Koenig, Pamina. 2005. “The Intensive and Extensive Margins of Trade: Evidence from French Firms.”
Unpublished.
Krugman, Paul. 1980. “Scale Economies, Product Differentiation, and the Pattern of Trade.” American
Economic Review, 70(5): 950–59.
Luttmer, Erzo G. J. 2007. “Selection, Growth, and the Size Distribution of Firms.” Quarterly Journal of
Economics, 122(3): 1103–44.
Melitz, Marc J. 2003. “The Impact of Trade on Intra-Industry Reallocations and Aggregate Industry Pro-
ductivity.” Econometrica, 71(6): 1695–1725.
Obstfeld, Maurice, and Kenneth Rogoff. 2001. “The Six Major Puzzles in International Macroeconom-
ics: Is There a Common Cause?” In NBER Macroeconomics Annual 2000, ed. Ben S. Bernanke and
­Kenneth Rogoff, 339–90. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press.
Rauch, James E. 1999. “Networks versus Markets in International Trade.” Journal of International Economics, 48(1): 7–35.
Ruhl, Kim J. 2005. “The Elasticity Puzzle in International Economics.” Unpublished.
Simon, Herbert A., and Charles P. Bonini. 1958. “The Size Distribution of Business Firms.” American
Economic Review, 48(4): 607–17.
Yi, Kei-Mu. 2003. “Can Vertical Specialization Explain the Growth of World Trade?” Journal of Political
Economy, 111(1): 52–102.
This article has been cited by:
1. Diego Daruich, William Easterly, Ariell Reshef. 2019. The surprising instability of export
specializations. Journal of Development Economics 137, 36-65. [Crossref]
2. Joseph B. Steinberg. 2019. Brexit and the macroeconomic impact of trade policy uncertainty. Journal
of International Economics 117, 175-195. [Crossref]
3. Elisabeth Christen, Michael Pfaffermayr, Yvonne Wolfmayr. 2019. Decomposing service exports
adjustments along the intensive and extensive margin at the firm-level. Review of International
Economics 27:1, 155-183. [Crossref]
4. Peter H. Egger, Sergey Nigai, Nora M. Strecker. 2019. The Taxing Deed of Globalization. American
Economic Review 109:2, 353-390. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
5. Alessandra Bonfiglioli, Rosario Crinò, Gino Gancia. 2019. Trade, Finance, and Endogenous Firm
Heterogeneity. Journal of the European Economic Association 17:1, 79-130. [Crossref]
6. Manoj Atolia. 2019. Trade Costs and Endogenous Nontradability in a Model with Sectoral and FirmLevel Heterogeneity. Computational Economics 53:2, 709-742. [Crossref]
7. Thibault Fally. 2019. Generalized separability and the gains from trade. Economics Letters . [Crossref]
8. Eva Hasiner, Xiaohua Yu. 2019. When institutions matter: a gravity model for Chinese meat imports.
International Journal of Emerging Markets 14:1, 231-253. [Crossref]
9. Hege Medin. 2019. Trade barriers or trade facilitators? The heterogeneous impact of food standards
in international trade. The World Economy 3. . [Crossref]
10. Cecilia Hammarlund, Anna Andersson. 2019. What’s in it for Africa? European Union fishing
access agreements and fishery exports from developing countries. World Development 113, 172-185.
[Crossref]
11. Jae Wook Jung, Ina Simonovska, Ariel Weinberger. 2019. Exporter heterogeneity and price
discrimination: A quantitative view. Journal of International Economics 116, 103-124. [Crossref]
12. Andrea Ariu, Holger Breinlich, Gregory Corcos, Giordano Mion. 2019. The interconnections between
services and goods trade at the firm-level. Journal of International Economics 116, 173-188. [Crossref]
13. Ana Cuadros, Joan Martín-Montaner, Jordi Paniagua. 2019. Migration and FDI: The role of job
skills. International Review of Economics & Finance 59, 318-332. [Crossref]
14. Bernardo S. Blum, Sebastian Claro, Kunal Dasgupta, Ignatius J. Horstmann. 2019. Inventory
Management, Product Quality, and Cross‑Country Income Differences. American Economic Journal:
Macroeconomics 11:1, 338-388. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
15. Robin Visser. 2019. The effect of diplomatic representation on trade: A panel data analysis. The
World Economy 42:1, 197-225. [Crossref]
16. Jiao Shi. 2019. Vertical FDI and exchange rates over the business cycle: The welfare implications of
openness to FDI. Journal of Development Economics . [Crossref]
17. Aksel Erbahar. 2018. Market knowledge: Evidence from importers. The World Economy 6. . [Crossref]
18. Chaoping Xie, Jianfeng Gao, Jason H. Grant, Sven Anders. 2018. Examining the Canada-China agrifood trade relationship: Firms, trading partners, and trading volumes. Canadian Journal of Agricultural
Economics/Revue canadienne d'agroeconomie 66:4, 539-555. [Crossref]
19. Festus Ebo Turkson. 2018. How well does observable trade data measure trade friction costs? Evidence
from member countries within the Economic Community of West African States (ECOWAS). Journal
of African Trade 5:1-2, 69-86. [Crossref]
20. Christopher M. Meissner, John P. Tang. 2018. Upstart Industrialization and Exports: Evidence from
Japan, 1880–1910. The Journal of Economic History 78:04, 1068-1102. [Crossref]
21. Robin Visser. 2018. The effect of the internet on the margins of trade. Information Economics and
Policy . [Crossref]
22. ANGELA ABBATE, LUCA DE BENEDICTIS, GIORGIO FAGIOLO, LUCIA TAJOLI. 2018.
Distance-varying assortativity and clustering of the international trade network. Network Science 6:4,
517-544. [Crossref]
23. Wojciech W Szewerniak, Yilan Xu, Sandy Dall’erba. 2018. The effects of diesel price on regional trade
in the USA. Journal of Economic Geography 5. . [Crossref]
24. Angela Cheptea, Charlotte Emlinger, Karine Latouche. 2018. Exporting firms and retail
internationalization: Evidence from France. Journal of Economics & Management Strategy 98. .
[Crossref]
25. Jianhong Qi, Zhaoyong Zhang, Hui Liu. 2018. Credit constraints and firm market entry decision:
Firm-level evidence from internationalizing Chinese multinationals. The North American Journal of
Economics and Finance 46, 272-285. [Crossref]
26. Nguyen Xuan Trung, Nguyen Duc Hung, Nguyen Thi Hien. 2018. Exploiting the Trade Potential
from Integration: Analysing the Impact of Free Trade Agreements between ASEAN and India and
China. China Report 54:4, 442-466. [Crossref]
27. Scott L. Baier, Jeffrey H. Bergstrand, Matthew W. Clance. 2018. Heterogeneous effects of economic
integration agreements. Journal of Development Economics 135, 587-608. [Crossref]
28. Lionel Fontagné, Angelo Secchi, Chiara Tomasi. 2018. Exporters’ product vectors across markets.
European Economic Review 110, 150-180. [Crossref]
29. Larry D. Qiu, Mohan Zhou, Xu Wei. 2018. Regulation, innovation, and firm selection: The porter
hypothesis under monopolistic competition. Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 92,
638-658. [Crossref]
30. Chuantian He, Chunding Li, John Whalley. 2018. General equilibrium trade modelling with Canada–
US transportation costs. The Journal of International Trade & Economic Development 27:7, 806-829.
[Crossref]
31. Jing Yan. 2018. Do mergers and acquisitions promote trade? Evidence from China. The Journal of
International Trade & Economic Development 27:7, 792-805. [Crossref]
32. Zhi-lu SUN, Xian-de LI. 2018. The trade margins of Chinese agricultural exports to ASEAN and
their determinants. Journal of Integrative Agriculture 17:10, 2356-2367. [Crossref]
33. Faqin Lin, Cui Hu, Andreas Fuchs. 2018. How do firms respond to political tensions? The
heterogeneity of the Dalai Lama Effect on trade. China Economic Review . [Crossref]
34. Paras Kharel. 2018. Dissecting Gains from Trade: Changes in Welfare Cost of Autarky*. East Asian
Economic Review 22:3, 275-306. [Crossref]
35. Rebecca Freeman, Samuel Pienknagura. 2018. Are all trade agreements equal? The role of distance
in shaping the effect of economic integration agreements on trade flows. Review of World Economics
93. . [Crossref]
36. Shaista Alam. 2018. The trade integration and Pakistan’s export performance. International Journal
of Development Issues 17:3, 326-345. [Crossref]
37. Antoine Gervais. 2018. Estimating the impact of country-level policy restrictions on services trade.
Review of International Economics 26:4, 743-767. [Crossref]
38. Stephen Devadoss, Jeff Luckstead. 2018. Implications of the Comprehensive Economic and Trade
Agreement for Processed Food Markets. Canadian Journal of Agricultural Economics/Revue canadienne
d'agroeconomie 66:3, 415-440. [Crossref]
39. David S. Jacks, Dennis Novy. 2018. Market Potential and Global Growth over the Long Twentieth
Century. Journal of International Economics 114, 221-237. [Crossref]
40. A. Kerem Coşar, Banu Demir. 2018. Shipping inside the box: Containerization and trade. Journal of
International Economics 114, 331-345. [Crossref]
41. Calin-Vlad Demian, Filippo di Mauro. 2018. The exchange rate, asymmetric shocks and asymmetric
distributions. International Economics 154, 68-85. [Crossref]
42. Massimo Del Gatto. 2018. The revealed cost competitiveness of changing trade patterns: A countrysector exercise. International Economics 154, 3-22. [Crossref]
43. Costas Arkolakis, Natalia Ramondo, Andrés Rodríguez-Clare, Stephen Yeaple. 2018. Innovation and
Production in the Global Economy. American Economic Review 108:8, 2128-2173. [Abstract] [View
PDF article] [PDF with links]
44. Wyatt J. Brooks, Pau S. Pujolas. 2018. Capital accumulation and the welfare gains from trade. Economic
Theory 66:2, 491-523. [Crossref]
45. Jens Wrona. 2018. BORDER EFFECTS WITHOUT BORDERS: WHAT DIVIDES JAPAN'S
INTERNAL TRADE?. International Economic Review 59:3, 1209-1262. [Crossref]
46. Eddy Bekkers, Hugo Rojas-Romagosa. 2018. The welfare effects of free trade agreements in
quantitative trade models: A comparison of studies about Transatlantic Trade and Investment
Partnership. The World Economy 93. . [Crossref]
47. Hildegunn Kyvik Nordås. 2018. What drives trade in services? Lessons from the Nordics. Applied
Economics 50:33, 3532-3545. [Crossref]
48. Aleksandar Stojkov, Thierry Warin. 2018. EU Membership and FDI: Is There an Endogenous
Credibility Effect?. Journal of East-West Business 24:3, 144-169. [Crossref]
49. Minyu Zhou, Ian Sheldon, Jihyun Eum. 2018. The role of intellectual property rights in seed
technology transfer through trade: evidence from U.S. field crop seed exports. Agricultural Economics
49:4, 423-434. [Crossref]
50. Andrew B. Bernard, Andreas Moxnes, Karen Helene Ulltveit-Moe. 2018. Two-Sided Heterogeneity
and Trade. The Review of Economics and Statistics 100:3, 424-439. [Crossref]
51. Céline Carrère, Maria Masood. 2018. Cultural proximity: A source of trade flow resilience?. The
World Economy 41:7, 1812-1832. [Crossref]
52. Sofia Gouveia, João Rebelo, Lina Lourenço-Gomes. 2018. Port wine exports: a gravity model
approach. International Journal of Wine Business Research 30:2, 218-242. [Crossref]
53. Peter Wankuru Chacha, Lawrence Edwards. 2018. Exporting to fragile states in Africa: Firm-level
evidence. Review of Development Economics 84. . [Crossref]
54. Farkhondeh Jabalameli, Ehsan Rasoulinezhad. 2018. BRICS-United Nations regional groups’ trade
patterns: a panel-gravity approach. Journal of Chinese Economic and Foreign Trade Studies 11:2,
151-179. [Crossref]
55. Juan Blyde, Gonzalo Iberti, Micaela Mussini. 2018. When does innovation matter for exporting?.
Empirical Economics 54:4, 1653-1671. [Crossref]
56. Konstantins Benkovskis, Julia Wörz. 2018. What drives the market share changes? Price versus nonprice factors. Structural Change and Economic Dynamics 45, 9-29. [Crossref]
57. Andrew B. Bernard, J. Bradford Jensen, Stephen J. Redding, Peter K. Schott. 2018. Global Firms.
Journal of Economic Literature 56:2, 565-619. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
58. Yaghoob Jafari, Wolfgang Britz. 2018. Modelling heterogeneous firms and non-tariff measures in free
trade agreements using Computable General Equilibrium. Economic Modelling 73, 279-294. [Crossref]
59. Yan Dong, Chunding Li. 2018. Economic sanction games among the US, the EU and Russia: Payoffs
and potential effects. Economic Modelling 73, 117-128. [Crossref]
60. Sarah Adelman, Katherine Schmeiser. 2018. Infant formula trade and the family-friendly workplace.
Applied Economics Letters 25:8, 527-530. [Crossref]
61. Mark J. Gibson, Tim A. Graciano. 2018. Using imported intermediate goods: Selection and
technology effects. Review of International Economics 26:2, 257-278. [Crossref]
62. Ignacio del Rosal. 2018. Power laws in EU country exports. Empirica 45:2, 311-337. [Crossref]
63. Paolo Bertoletti, Federico Etro, Ina Simonovska. 2018. International Trade with Indirect Additivity.
American Economic Journal: Microeconomics 10:2, 1-57. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with
links]
64. Robert C. Feenstra. 2018. Alternative Sources of the Gains from International Trade: Variety, Creative
Destruction, and Markups. Journal of Economic Perspectives 32:2, 25-46. [Abstract] [View PDF article]
[PDF with links]
65. Lota D. Tamini, Zakaria Sorgho. 2018. Trade in Environmental Goods: Evidences from an Analysis
Using Elasticities of Trade Costs. Environmental and Resource Economics 70:1, 53-75. [Crossref]
66. Anirudh Shingal, Martin Roy, Pierre Sauvé. 2018. Do WTO+ commitments in services trade
agreements reflect a quest for optimal regulatory convergence? Evidence from Asia. The World
Economy 41:5, 1223-1250. [Crossref]
67. Robert Lundmark. 2018. Analysis and projection of global iron ore trade: a panel data gravity model
approach. Mineral Economics 31:1-2, 191-202. [Crossref]
68. Maria Tsiapa. 2018. Adjustment mechanisms of Greek regions in export activity during the economic
crisis of 2008-2012. Papers in Regional Science 22. . [Crossref]
69. Gabriele Spilker, Thomas Bernauer, In Song Kim, Helen Milner, Iain Osgood, Dustin Tingley. 2018.
Trade at the margin: Estimating the economic implications of preferential trade agreements. The
Review of International Organizations 7. . [Crossref]
70. Dave Donaldson. 2018. Railroads of the Raj: Estimating the Impact of Transportation Infrastructure.
American Economic Review 108:4-5, 899-934. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
71. Juyoung Cheong, Do Won Kwak, Kam Ki Tang. 2018. The trade effects of tariffs and non-tariff
changes of preferential trade agreements. Economic Modelling 70, 370-382. [Crossref]
72. James E. Anderson, Ingo Borchert, Aaditya Mattoo, Yoto V. Yotov. 2018. Dark Costs, Missing Data:
Shedding Some Light on Services Trade. European Economic Review . [Crossref]
73. Badi H. Baltagi, Peter H. Egger, Michaela Kesina. 2018. Contagious exporting and foreign ownership:
Evidence from firms in Shanghai using a Bayesian spatial bivariate probit model. Regional Science and
Urban Economics . [Crossref]
74. Honggue Lee. 2018. Equivalence between Increasing Returns and Comparative Advantage as the
Determinants of Intra-industry Trade: An Industry Analysis for Korea. East Asian Economic Review
22:1, 75-114. [Crossref]
75. Simba Mutsvangwa, Craig R. Parsons, Nagendra Shrestha. 2018. Japan’s trade agreements aren’t
“window dressing” after all. The International Trade Journal 11, 1-21. [Crossref]
76. Güzin Bayar. 2018. Estimating export equations: a survey of the literature. Empirical Economics 54:2,
629-672. [Crossref]
77. Robert C. Feenstra, Philip Luck, Maurice Obstfeld, Katheryn N. Russ. 2018. In Search of the
Armington Elasticity. The Review of Economics and Statistics 100:1, 135-150. [Crossref]
78. Margherita Scoppola, Valentina Raimondi, Alessandro Olper. 2018. The impact of EU trade
preferences on the extensive and intensive margins of agricultural and food products. Agricultural
Economics 49:2, 251-263. [Crossref]
79. Haichao Fan, Yao Amber Li, Chen Carol Zhao. 2018. Margins of imports, forward-looking firms,
and exchange rate movements. Journal of International Money and Finance 81, 185-202. [Crossref]
80. Sang-Wook (Stanley) Cho, Julián P. Díaz. 2018. The new goods margin in new markets. Journal of
Comparative Economics 46:1, 78-93. [Crossref]
81. Marco Bee, Stefano Schiavo. 2018. Powerless: gains from trade when firm productivity is not Pareto
distributed. Review of World Economics 154:1, 15-45. [Crossref]
82. Anders Akerman. 2018. A theory on the role of wholesalers in international trade based on economies
of scope. Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d'économique 51:1, 156-185. [Crossref]
83. Kichun Kang. 2018. The effect of immigrants on the extensive and intensive margins of trade. Applied
Economics Letters 25:2, 92-95. [Crossref]
84. Everett B Peterson, Jason H Grant, Jeta Rudi-Polloshka. 2018. Survival of the Fittest: Export
Duration and Failure into United States Fresh Fruit and Vegetable Markets. American Journal of
Agricultural Economics 100:1, 23-45. [Crossref]
85. Paul S. Segerstrom, Ignat Stepanok. 2018. Learning How To Export. The Scandinavian Journal of
Economics 120:1, 63-92. [Crossref]
86. Olim Latipov, Christine McDaniel, Simon Schropp. 2018. The de minimis threshold in international
trade: The costs of being too low. The World Economy 41:1, 337-356. [Crossref]
87. Costas Arkolakis, Theodore Papageorgiou, Olga A. Timoshenko. 2018. Firm learning and growth.
Review of Economic Dynamics 27, 146-168. [Crossref]
88. Robert C. Feenstra. 2018. Restoring the product variety and pro-competitive gains from trade
with heterogeneous firms and bounded productivity. Journal of International Economics 110, 16-27.
[Crossref]
89. Lionel Fontagné, Gianluca Orefice. 2018. Let’s try next door: Technical Barriers to Trade and multidestination firms. European Economic Review 101, 643-663. [Crossref]
90. Klaus Schmerler. Drivers of Medical Travel at the National Level 119-171. [Crossref]
91. Ana Fernandes, Peter Klenow, Sergii Meleshchuk, Martha Denisse Pierola, Andres Rodriguez-Clare.
2018. The Intensive Margin in Trade. IMF Working Papers 18:259, 1. [Crossref]
92. Yang Yang. 2018. Transport Infrastructure, City Productivity Growth and Sectoral Reallocation:. IMF
Working Papers 18:276, 1. [Crossref]
93. Andrzej Cieślik, Jan Jakub Michałek. 2018. Firm-level determinants of direct and indirect exports:
empirical evidence for C.E.E. and M.E.N.A. countries. Economic Research-Ekonomska Istraživanja
31:1, 982-996. [Crossref]
94. Tongsheng Xu, Xiao Liang. 2017. Measuring aggregate trade costs and its empirical effects on
manufacturing export composition in China. China Finance and Economic Review 5:1. . [Crossref]
95. Sushanta Mallick, Helena Marques. 2017. Export prices, selection into exporting and market size:
Evidence from China and India. International Business Review 26:6, 1034-1050. [Crossref]
96. Mehmet Huseyin Bilgin, Giray Gozgor, Chi Keung Marco Lau. 2017. Institutions and gravity model:
the role of political economy and corporate governance. Eurasian Business Review 7:3, 421-436.
[Crossref]
97. Greg Morrison, Sergey V. Buldyrev, Michele Imbruno, Omar Alonso Doria Arrieta, Armando Rungi,
Massimo Riccaboni, Fabio Pammolli. 2017. On Economic Complexity and the Fitness of Nations.
Scientific Reports 7:1. . [Crossref]
98. Kichun Kang. 2017. Identifying the dispersion of the Pareto productivity distribution in international
trade. Economics Letters 161, 108-111. [Crossref]
99. Mahfuz Kabir, Ruhul Salim, Nasser Al-Mawali. 2017. The gravity model and trade flows: Recent
developments in econometric modeling and empirical evidence. Economic Analysis and Policy 56, 60-71.
[Crossref]
100. Chunding Li, John Whalley. 2017. How close is Asia already to being a trade bloc?. Journal of
Comparative Economics 45:4, 847-864. [Crossref]
101. Keith Head, Barbara J. Spencer. 2017. Oligopoly in international trade: Rise, fall and resurgence.
Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d'économique 50:5, 1414-1444. [Crossref]
102. Holger Görg, Philipp Henze, Viroj Jienwatcharamongkhol, Daniel Kopasker, Hassan Molana, Catia
Montagna, Fredrik Sjöholm. 2017. Firm size distribution and employment fluctuations: Theory and
evidence. Research in Economics 71:4, 690-703. [Crossref]
103. Federico Etro. 2017. Research in economics and monopolistic competition. Research in Economics
71:4, 645-649. [Crossref]
104. Mark J. Gibson, Jeff Luckstead. 2017. Coupled Vs. Decoupled Subsidies with Heterogeneous Firms
in General Equilibrium. Journal of Applied Economics 20:2, 271-282. [Crossref]
105. Sena Kimm Gnangnon. 2017. Impact of trade facilitation reforms on tax revenue. Journal of Economic
Studies 44:5, 765-780. [Crossref]
106. Karyne B. Charbonneau. 2017. Multiple fixed effects in binary response panel data models. The
Econometrics Journal 20:3, S1-S13. [Crossref]
107. Katharina Erhardt. 2017. On home market effects and firm heterogeneity. European Economic Review
98, 316-340. [Crossref]
108. Karsten Mau. 2017. US policy spillover(?) – China’s accession to the WTO and rising exports to the
EU. European Economic Review 98, 169-188. [Crossref]
109. Kyle Handley, Nuno Limão. 2017. Policy Uncertainty, Trade, and Welfare: Theory and Evidence for
China and the United States. American Economic Review 107:9, 2731-2783. [Abstract] [View PDF
article] [PDF with links]
110. Pol Antràs, Teresa C. Fort, Felix Tintelnot. 2017. The Margins of Global Sourcing: Theory and
Evidence from US Firms. American Economic Review 107:9, 2514-2564. [Abstract] [View PDF article]
[PDF with links]
111. Maria Bas, Thierry Mayer, Mathias Thoenig. 2017. From micro to macro: Demand, supply, and
heterogeneity in the trade elasticity. Journal of International Economics 108, 1-19. [Crossref]
112. Thi Anh-Dao Tran, Minh Hong Phi, Diadié Diaw. 2017. Export diversification and real exchange rate
in emerging Latin America and Asia: A South–North vs. South-South decomposition. The Journal
of International Trade & Economic Development 26:6, 649-676. [Crossref]
113. Andrew B. Bernard, Andreas Moxnes, Karen Helene Ulltveit-Moe. 2017. Two-Sided Heterogeneity
and Trade. The Review of Economics and Statistics 2004. . [Crossref]
114. Timothy J. Kehoe, Pau S. Pujolàs, Jack Rossbach. 2017. Quantitative Trade Models: Developments
and Challenges. Annual Review of Economics 9:1, 295-325. [Crossref]
115. Erik van der Marel. 2017. Explaining Export Performance through Inputs: Evidence from Aggregated
Cross-country Firm-level Data. Review of Development Economics 21:3, 731-755. [Crossref]
116. Marina Murat. 2017. Foreign education and international trade: empirical evidence from selected
Latin American countries. International Review of Applied Economics 83, 1-20. [Crossref]
117. Faqin Lin, Wenshou Yan, Xiaosong Wang. 2017. The impact of Africa-China's diplomatic visits on
bilateral trade. Scottish Journal of Political Economy 64:3, 310-326. [Crossref]
118. Jiangyong Lu, Yi Lu, Yi Sun, Zhigang Tao. 2017. Intermediaries, Firm Heterogeneity and Exporting
Behaviour. The World Economy 40:7, 1381-1404. [Crossref]
119. Federica DeMaria, Sophie Drogue. 2017. EU Trade Regulation for Baby Food: Protecting Health or
Trade?. The World Economy 40:7, 1430-1453. [Crossref]
120. Hang T. Nguyen, Olga A. Timoshenko. 2017. Entry assumptions and welfare gains from trade.
Economics Letters . [Crossref]
121. Wanling Chen, Chi Keung Marco Lau, David Boansi, Mehmet Huseyin Bilgin. 2017. Effects of trade
cost on the textile and apparel market: evidence from Asian countries. The Journal of The Textile
Institute 108:6, 971-986. [Crossref]
122. Myoung-jae Lee. 2017. Extensive and intensive margin effects in sample selection models: racial
effects on wages. Journal of the Royal Statistical Society: Series A (Statistics in Society) 180:3, 817-839.
[Crossref]
123. Per Botolf Maurseth, Hege Medin. 2017. Market-specific Sunk Export Costs: The Impact of
Learning and Spillovers. The World Economy 40:6, 1105-1127. [Crossref]
124. Rishav Bista, Rebecca Tomasik. 2017. Time Zone Effect and the Margins of Exports. The World
Economy 40:6, 1053-1067. [Crossref]
125. Hege Medin. 2017. The reverse home-market effect in exports: a cross-country study of the extensive
margin of exports. Review of World Economics 153:2, 301-325. [Crossref]
126. Hiroyuki Nishiyama. 2017. The effect of exchange rate fluctuation on intra-industry reallocation in a
firm heterogeneity model with trade and foreign direct investment. The Quarterly Review of Economics
and Finance 64, 32-43. [Crossref]
127. Scott French. 2017. Revealed comparative advantage: What is it good for?. Journal of International
Economics 106, 83-103. [Crossref]
128. Jing Yan. 2017. Privatisation and trade performance: evidence from China. Asian-Pacific Economic
Literature 31:1, 66-78. [Crossref]
129. Tim Kelly, Aleksandra Liaplina, Shawn W. Tan, Hernan Winkler. Digital Trade 117-150. [Crossref]
130. Felipa de Mello-Sampayo. 2017. Testing competing destinations gravity models – evidence from BRIC
International. The Journal of International Trade & Economic Development 26:3, 277-294. [Crossref]
131. Ana M Fernandes, Esteban Ferro, John S Wilson. 2017. Product Standards and Firms’ Export
Decisions. The World Bank Economic Review 91. . [Crossref]
132. Marianne Matthee, Maria Santana-Gallego. 2017. Identifying the determinants of South Africa’s
extensive and intensive trade margins: A gravity model approach. South African Journal of Economic
and management Sciences 20:1. . [Crossref]
133. Juyoung Cheong, Do Won Kwak, Haishan Yuan. 2017. Trade to aid: EU's temporary tariff waivers
for flood-hit Pakistan. Journal of Development Economics 125, 70-88. [Crossref]
134. Stefano Costa, Carmine Pappalardo, Claudio Vicarelli. 2017. Internationalization choices and Italian
firm performance during the crisis. Small Business Economics 48:3, 753-769. [Crossref]
135. Eliav Danziger. 2017. Skill Acquisition and the Dynamics of Trade-Induced Inequality. Journal of
International Economics . [Crossref]
136. Tibor Besedeš, Matthew T. Cole. 2017. Distorted Trade Barriers: A Dissection of Trade Costs in a
“Distorted Gravity” Model. Review of International Economics 25:1, 148-164. [Crossref]
137. Maria Cipollina, David Laborde Debucquet, Luca Salvatici. 2017. The tide that does not raise all
boats: an assessment of EU preferential trade policies. Review of World Economics 153:1, 199-231.
[Crossref]
138. Xiaoheng Zhang, Yingheng Zhou, Xianhui Geng, Xu Tian. 2017. The Intensive and Extensive
Margins of China's Agricultural Trade. Canadian Journal of Agricultural Economics/Revue canadienne
d'agroeconomie 117. . [Crossref]
139. Carmine Pappalardo, Claudio Vicarelli. 2017. Euro introduction and the behaviour of Italian exporting
firms. Oxford Economic Papers gpw068. [Crossref]
140. Zakaria Sorgho, Bruno Larue. 2017. Do Geographical Indications Really Increase Trade? A Conceptual
Framework and Empirics. Journal of Agricultural & Food Industrial Organization, ahead of print.
[Crossref]
141. Sergey Nigai. 2017. A tale of two tails: Productivity distribution and the gains from trade. Journal of
International Economics 104, 44-62. [Crossref]
142. Tomohiro Hirano, Noriyuki Yanagawa. 2017. Asset Bubbles, Endogenous Growth, and Financial
Frictions. The Review of Economic Studies 84:1, 406-443. [Crossref]
143. Catherine Thomas. 36, 49. [Crossref]
144. Wilhelm Kohler, Benjamin Jung. 2017. Wie vorteilhaft ist internationaler Handel?. Perspektiven der
Wirtschaftspolitik 18:1. . [Crossref]
145. Somesh K. Mathur, Rahul Arora, Sarbjit Singh, Amrita Roy. Developments in International Trade
Theory and Gravity Modelling 9-35. [Crossref]
146. Somesh K. Mathur, Sarbjit Singh, Gaurav Doshi, Abhishek Srivastava. Trade Growth Accounting in
Goods and Services: An Empirical Exercise 101-113. [Crossref]
147. Jang Sujin, Song E. Young. 2017. Gravity with Intermediate Goods Trade. East Asian Economic Review
21:4, 295. [Crossref]
148. Andreas Hatzigeorgiou, Magnus Lodefalk. 2016. Migrants’ Influence on Firm-level Exports. Journal
of Industry, Competition and Trade 16:4, 477-497. [Crossref]
149. Cui Hu, Yong Tan. 2016. Export spillovers and export performance in China. China Economic Review
41, 75-89. [Crossref]
150. Farrukh Suvankulov. 2016. Revisiting national border effects in foreign trade in goods of Canadian
provinces. The Journal of International Trade & Economic Development 25:8, 1045-1070. [Crossref]
151. Pamela J. Smith, Erik S. Katovich. 2016. Are GMO Policies “Trade Related”? Empirical Analysis of
Latin America. Applied Economic Perspectives and Policy ppw021. [Crossref]
152. Subhajit Chakrabarty, Biswajit Nag, Pinaki Dasgupta, Siddhartha K. Rastogi. 2016. Determinants and
Relationships in Sectoral Trade: A Bilateral Model for Knitwear Clothing. Thunderbird International
Business Review 58:6, 565-574. [Crossref]
153. Joseph S. Shapiro. 2016. Trade Costs, CO2, and the Environment. American Economic Journal:
Economic Policy 8:4, 220-254. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
154. Alessandra Bonfiglioli. 2016. Comments on “Liquidity constrained exporters” by T. Chaney. Journal
of Economic Dynamics and Control 72, 155-158. [Crossref]
155. Jose Asturias, Sewon Hur, Timothy J. Kehoe, Kim J. Ruhl. 2016. The interaction and sequencing of
policy reforms. Journal of Economic Dynamics and Control 72, 45-66. [Crossref]
156. Michael E. Waugh, B. Ravikumar. 2016. Measuring openness to trade. Journal of Economic Dynamics
and Control 72, 29-41. [Crossref]
157. Jeff Luckstead, Stephen Devadoss. 2016. Impacts of the Transatlantic Trade and Investment
Partnership on Processed Food Trade under Monopolistic Competition and Firm Heterogeneity.
American Journal of Agricultural Economics 98:5, 1389-1402. [Crossref]
158. Charles Regnacq, Ariel Dinar, Ellen Hanak. 2016. The Gravity of Water: Water Trade Frictions in
California. American Journal of Agricultural Economics 98:5, 1273-1294. [Crossref]
159. José A.F. Machado, J.M.C. Santos Silva, Kehai Wei. 2016. Quantiles, corners, and the extensive margin
of trade. European Economic Review 89, 73-84. [Crossref]
160. Natalia Ramondo, Andrés Rodríguez-Clare, Milagro Saborío-Rodríguez. 2016. Trade, Domestic
Frictions, and Scale Effects. American Economic Review 106:10, 3159-3184. [Abstract] [View PDF
article] [PDF with links]
161. Lauren Bresnahan, Ian Coxhead, Jeremy Foltz, Tewodaj Mogues. 2016. Does Freer Trade Really Lead
to Productivity Growth? Evidence from Africa. World Development 86, 18-29. [Crossref]
162. Andrew J. Cassey, Katherine N. Schmeiser, Andreas Waldkirch. 2016. Exporting Spatial Externalities.
Open Economies Review 27:4, 697-720. [Crossref]
163. Sushanta Mallick, Helena Marques. 2016. Pricing strategy of emerging market exporters in alternate
currency regimes: The role of comparative advantage. International Review of Economics & Finance
45, 68-81. [Crossref]
164. Timothy J. Kehoe, Pau S. Pujolàs, Kim J. Ruhl. 2016. The opportunity costs of entrepreneurs in
international trade. Economics Letters 146, 1-3. [Crossref]
165. Abhishek Gaurav, Somesh K. Mathur. 2016. Determinants of Trade Costs and Trade Growth
Accounting between India and the European Union during 1995-2010. The World Economy 39:9,
1399-1413. [Crossref]
166. Sushanta Mallick, Helena Marques. 2016. Does quality differentiation matter in exporters' pricing
behaviour? Comparing China and India. China Economic Review 40, 71-90. [Crossref]
167. Holger Breinlich, Alejandro Cuñat. 2016. Tariffs, Trade and Productivity: A Quantitative Evaluation
of Heterogeneous Firm Models. The Economic Journal 126:595, 1660-1702. [Crossref]
168. Jan I. Haaland, Anthony J. Venables. 2016. Optimal trade policy with monopolistic competition and
heterogeneous firms. Journal of International Economics 102, 85-95. [Crossref]
169. Matthias Helble, Boon-Loong Ngiang. 2016. From global factory to global mall? East Asia’s changing
trade composition and orientation. Japan and the World Economy 39, 37-47. [Crossref]
170. Xavier Gabaix, David Laibson, Deyuan Li, Hongyi Li, Sidney Resnick, Casper G. de Vries. 2016.
The impact of competition on prices with numerous firms. Journal of Economic Theory 165, 1-24.
[Crossref]
171. Anna Andersson. 2016. Export Performance and Access to Intermediate Inputs: The Case of Rules
of Origin Liberalisation. The World Economy 39:8, 1048-1079. [Crossref]
172. Aslihan Atabek Demirhan. 2016. To be exporter or not to be exporter? Entry–exit dynamics of
Turkish manufacturing firms. Empirical Economics 51:1, 181-200. [Crossref]
173. Jeremiás Máté Balogh. 2016. A földrajzi távolság, a kulturális hasonlóság és a szabadkereskedelem
hatása a borkereskedelemre. Közgazdasági Szemle 63:7-8, 858-881. [Crossref]
174. Sébastien Jean, Jean-Christophe Bureau. 2016. Do regional trade agreements really boost trade?
Evidence from agricultural products. Review of World Economics 152:3, 477-499. [Crossref]
175. Matthieu Crozet, Emmanuel Milet, Daniel Mirza. 2016. The impact of domestic regulations on
international trade in services: Evidence from firm-level data. Journal of Comparative Economics 44:3,
585-607. [Crossref]
176. Hyun-Hoon Lee, John Ries. 2016. Aid for Trade and Greenfield Investment. World Development 84,
206-218. [Crossref]
177. Benedikt Heid, Mario Larch. 2016. Gravity with unemployment. Journal of International Economics
101, 70-85. [Crossref]
178. Mario Larch, Wolfgang Lechthaler. 2016. BUY NATIONAL AND THE BUSINESS CYCLE.
Macroeconomic Dynamics 20:05, 1196-1218. [Crossref]
179. JEAN-FRANÇOIS ARVIS, YANN DUVAL, BEN SHEPHERD, CHORTHIP UTOKTHAM,
ANASUYA RAJ. 2016. Trade Costs in the Developing World: 1996–2010. World Trade Review
15:03, 451-474. [Crossref]
180. Grigorios Spanos. 2016. Organization and export performance. Economics Letters . [Crossref]
181. Dudley Cooke. 2016. Optimal monetary policy with endogenous export participation. Review of
Economic Dynamics 21, 72-88. [Crossref]
182. Luis Castro, Ben G. Li, Keith E. Maskus, Yiqing Xie. 2016. Fixed Export Costs and Export Behavior.
Southern Economic Journal 83:1, 300-320. [Crossref]
183. Lota D. Tamini, Maurice Doyon, Rodrigue Simon. 2016. Analyzing Trade Liberalization Effects in
the Egg Sector Using a Dynamic Gravity Model. Canadian Journal of Agricultural Economics/Revue
canadienne d'agroeconomie 64:2, 383-411. [Crossref]
184. Altan Aldan, Olcay Yücel Çulha. 2016. The role of the extensive margin in export of Turkey: A
comparative analysis. Central Bank Review 16:2, 59-64. [Crossref]
185. Qian Xuefeng, Mahmut Yaşar. 2016. Export Market Diversification and Firm Productivity: Evidence
from a Large Developing Country. World Development 82, 28-47. [Crossref]
186. Dieter Pennerstorfer. 2016. Export, Migration and Costs of Trade: Evidence from Central European
Firms. Regional Studies 50:5, 848-863. [Crossref]
187. Dongwen Tian, Na Hu, Xin Wang, Li Huang. 2016. Trade margins, quality upgrading, and China’s
agri-food export growth. China Agricultural Economic Review 8:2, 277-298. [Crossref]
188. Alan Spearot. 2016. Unpacking the Long-Run Effects of Tariff Shocks: New Structural Implications
from Firm Heterogeneity Models. American Economic Journal: Microeconomics 8:2, 128-167.
[Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
189. Achim Schmillen. 2016. The Exporter Wage Premium Reconsidered-Destinations, Distances and
Linked Employer-Employee Data. Review of Development Economics 20:2, 531-546. [Crossref]
190. Péter Harasztosi. 2016. Export spillovers in Hungary. Empirical Economics 50:3, 801-830. [Crossref]
191. Stefano Bolatto, Massimo Sbracia. 2016. Deconstructing the Gains from Trade: Selection of Industries
vs Reallocation of Workers. Review of International Economics 24:2, 344-363. [Crossref]
192. Rishav Bista, Josh Ederington, Jenny Minier, Brandon J. Sheridan. 2016. Austerity and Exports.
Review of International Economics 24:2, 203-225. [Crossref]
193. Dave Donaldson, Richard Hornbeck. 2016. Railroads and American Economic Growth: A “Market
Access” Approach. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 131:2, 799-858. [Crossref]
194. James E. Anderson, Mykyta Vesselovsky, Yoto V. Yotov. 2016. Gravity with scale effects. Journal of
International Economics 100, 174-193. [Crossref]
195. Yuko Imura. 2016. Endogenous trade participation with price rigidities. Journal of International
Economics 100, 14-33. [Crossref]
196. Natalie Chen, Luciana Juvenal. 2016. Quality, trade, and exchange rate pass-through. Journal of
International Economics 100, 61-80. [Crossref]
197. Cécile Bastidon, Yusuf Kocoglu. 2016. Accès au financement et dynamique des exportations des
pays MENA méditerranéens. Canadian Journal of Development Studies / Revue canadienne d'études du
développement 37:2, 178-196. [Crossref]
198. Zheng Jiang, Huimin Shi. 2016. The selection of firms based on productivity: different roles of entry
and overhead cost. Economic Modelling 54, 537-544. [Crossref]
199. Kwok Tong Soo. 2016. Intra-industry trade: A Krugman-Ricardo Model and Data. Economica 83:330,
338-355. [Crossref]
200. Ben Shepherd. 2016. Did APEC's Trade Facilitation Action Plans deliver the goods?. Journal of Asian
Economics 43, 1-11. [Crossref]
201. Juyoung Cheong, Do Won Kwak, Kam Ki Tang. 2016. The distance effects on the intensive and
extensive margins of trade over time. Empirical Economics 50:2, 253-278. [Crossref]
202. Emanuele Bacchiega, Antonio Minniti, Arsen Palestini. 2016. Quality, distance and trade: A strategic
approach. Papers in Regional Science 95, S165-S191. [Crossref]
203. Jean-François Arvis, Ben Shepherd. 2016. Measuring Connectivity in a Globally Networked Industry:
The Case of Air Transport. The World Economy 39:3, 369-385. [Crossref]
204. Pierre Sauvé, Anirudh Shingal. 2016. Why Do Economies Enter into Preferential Agreements on
Trade in Services? Assessing the Potential for Negotiated Regulatory Convergence in Asian Services
Markets. Asian Development Review 33:1, 56-73. [Crossref]
205. Concepción Betrán, Michael Huberman. 2016. International competition in the first wave of
globalization: new evidence on the margins of trade. The Economic History Review 69:1, 258-287.
[Crossref]
206. Yoke Fong Kong, Richard Kneller. 2016. Measuring the Impact of China's Export Growth on its
Asian Neighbours. The World Economy 39:2, 195-220. [Crossref]
207. Desislava Dikova, Andreja Jaklič, Anže Burger, Aljaž Kunčič. 2016. What is beneficial for first-time
SME-exporters from a transition economy: A diversified or a focused export-strategy?. Journal of
World Business 51:2, 185-199. [Crossref]
208. Maria Persson, Fredrik Wilhelmsson. 2016. EU Trade Preferences and Export Diversification. The
World Economy 39:1, 16-53. [Crossref]
209. Robert C. Feenstra. 2016. Gains from Trade Under Monopolistic Competition. Pacific Economic
Review 21:1, 35. [Crossref]
210. Priya Ranjan, Jibonayan Raychaudhuri. The “New-New” Trade Theory: A Review of the Literature
3-21. [Crossref]
211. Kenneth S. Chan, Miaojie Yu. 2016. Introduction to the Special Issue of China's Growing Trade and
its Role to the World Economy. Pacific Economic Review 21:1, 32. [Crossref]
212. Antoine Berthou, Lionel Fontagné. 2016. Variable Trade Costs, Composition Effects and the Intensive
Margin of Trade. The World Economy 39:1, 54-71. [Crossref]
213. N. Limão. Preferential Trade Agreements 279-367. [Crossref]
214. Scott French. 2016. The composition of trade flows and the aggregate effects of trade barriers. Journal
of International Economics 98, 114-137. [Crossref]
215. Ron Alquist, Rahul Mukherjee, Linda Tesar. 2016. Fire-sale FDI or business as usual?. Journal of
International Economics 98, 93-113. [Crossref]
216. María Santana-Gallego, Francisco J. Ledesma-Rodríguez, Jorge V. Pérez-Rodríguez. 2016.
International trade and tourism flows: An extension of the gravity model. Economic Modelling 52,
1026-1033. [Crossref]
217. Andrew J. Cassey. 2015. The Destinations of State Trade Missions. CESifo Economic Studies ifv026.
[Crossref]
218. Eliane Choquette, Philipp Meinen. 2015. Export Spillovers: Opening the Black Box. The World
Economy 38:12, 1912-1946. [Crossref]
219. Patrik Karpaty, Patrik Gustavsson Tingvall. 2015. Service Offshoring and Corruption: Do Firms
Escape Corrupt Countries?. Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade 15:4, 363-381. [Crossref]
220. Pascal Mossay, Takatoshi Tabuchi. 2015. Preferential Trade Agreements Harm Third Countries. The
Economic Journal 125:589, 1964-1985. [Crossref]
221. Andreas Hatzigeorgiou, Magnus Lodefalk. 2015. Trade, Migration and Integration - Evidence and
Policy Implications. The World Economy 38:12, 2013-2048. [Crossref]
222. Jing Wang, Hyun Hoon Lee, Kyung Tae Kim, Dong Hyun Park. 2015. Firm and Product
Heterogeneity in China's Automotive Exports. The Asian Journal of Shipping and Logistics 31:4,
449-457. [Crossref]
223. Arman Mazhikeyev, T. Huw Edwards, Marian Rizov. 2015. Openness and isolation: The trade
performance of the former Soviet Central Asian countries. International Business Review 24:6, 935-947.
[Crossref]
224. ANDREW JIA-YI KAM. 2015. DETERMINANTS OF INTERNATIONAL PRODUCTION
FRAGMENTATION:
MALAYSIA’S
EXPERIENCE
IN
THE
INFORMATION,
COMMUNICATIONS AND TELECOMMUNICATIONS (ICT) INDUSTRY. The Singapore
Economic Review 60:05, 1550042. [Crossref]
225. Kyle Handley, Nuno Limão. 2015. Trade and Investment under Policy Uncertainty: Theory and Firm
Evidence. American Economic Journal: Economic Policy 7:4, 189-222. [Abstract] [View PDF article]
[PDF with links]
226. Christian Hepenstrick, Alexander Tarasov. 2015. Per capita income and the extensive margin of
bilateral trade. Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d'économique 48:4, 1561-1599.
[Crossref]
227. Johannes Van Biesebroeck, Emily Yu, Shenjie Chen. 2015. The impact of trade promotion services on
Canadian exporter performance. Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d'économique 48:4,
1481-1512. [Crossref]
228. Gabriel Felbermayr, Benjamin Jung, Mario Larch. 2015. The welfare consequences of import tariffs:
A quantitative perspective. Journal of International Economics 97:2, 295-309. [Crossref]
229. Costas Arkolakis. 2015. A Unified Theory of Firm Selection and Growth. The Quarterly Journal of
Economics qjv039. [Crossref]
230. Chris Edmond, Virgiliu Midrigan, Daniel Yi Xu. 2015. Competition, Markups, and the Gains from
International Trade. American Economic Review 105:10, 3183-3221. [Abstract] [View PDF article]
[PDF with links]
231. Ina Simonovska. 2015. Income Differences and Prices of Tradables: Insights from an Online Retailer.
The Review of Economic Studies 82:4, 1612-1656. [Crossref]
232. Alfonso Irarrazabal, Andreas Moxnes, Luca David Opromolla. 2015. The Tip of the Iceberg: A
Quantitative Framework for Estimating Trade Costs. Review of Economics and Statistics 97:4, 777-792.
[Crossref]
233. Lionel Fontagné, Gianluca Orefice, Roberta Piermartini, Nadia Rocha. 2015. Product standards and
margins of trade: Firm-level evidence. Journal of International Economics 97:1, 29-44. [Crossref]
234. Thibault Fally. 2015. Structural gravity and fixed effects. Journal of International Economics 97:1,
76-85. [Crossref]
235. Karine Latouche, Emmanuelle Chevassus-Lozza. 2015. Retailer Supply Chain and Market Access:
Evidence From French Agri-food Firms Certified with Private Standards. The World Economy 38:8,
1312-1334. [Crossref]
236. Antoine Gervais. 2015. Product quality and firm heterogeneity in international trade. Canadian
Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d'économique 48:3, 1152-1174. [Crossref]
237. Dave Donaldson. 2015. The Gains from Market Integration. Annual Review of Economics 7:1, 619-647.
[Crossref]
238. Rafael Cezar. 2015. The gravity of financial development. The Journal of International Trade &
Economic Development 24:5, 696-723. [Crossref]
239. Tomohiko Inui, Keiko Ito, Daisuke Miyakawa. 2015. OVERSEAS MARKET INFORMATION
AND FIRMS' EXPORT DECISIONS. Economic Inquiry 53:3, 1671-1688. [Crossref]
240. Hirokazu Ishise, Miwa Matsuo. 2015. TRADE IN POLARIZED AMERICA: THE BORDER
EFFECT BETWEEN RED STATES AND BLUE STATES. Economic Inquiry 53:3, 1647-1670.
[Crossref]
241. Jordi Paniagua, Erik Figueiredo, Juan Sapena. 2015. Quantile regression for the FDI gravity equation.
Journal of Business Research 68:7, 1512-1518. [Crossref]
242. Cecília Hornok, Miklós Koren. 2015. Administrative barriers to trade. Journal of International
Economics 96, S110-S122. [Crossref]
243. Wei Liao, Ana Maria Santacreu. 2015. The trade comovement puzzle and the margins of international
trade. Journal of International Economics 96:2, 266-288. [Crossref]
244. Bassem Kahouli, Samir Maktouf. 2015. The determinants of FDI and the impact of the economic
crisis on the implementation of RTAs: A static and dynamic gravity model. International Business
Review 24:3, 518-529. [Crossref]
245. Michele Battisti, Filippo Belloc, Massimo Del Gatto. 2015. Unbundling Technology Adoption and
tfp at the Firm Level: Do Intangibles Matter?. Journal of Economics & Management Strategy 24:2,
390-414. [Crossref]
246. Antoine Gervais. 2015. Product quality, firm heterogeneity and trade liberalization. The Journal of
International Trade & Economic Development 24:4, 523-541. [Crossref]
247. Christian Hepenstrick, Alexander Tarasov. 2015. Trade Openness and Cross-country Income
Differences. Review of International Economics 23:2, 271-302. [Crossref]
248. Ivan Cherkashin, Svetlana Demidova, Hiau Looi Kee, Kala Krishna. 2015. Firm heterogeneity and
costly trade: A new estimation strategy and policy experiments. Journal of International Economics
96:1, 18-36. [Crossref]
249. Laura Hering, Rodrigo Paillacar. 2015. Does Access to Foreign Markets Shape Internal Migration?
Evidence from Brazil. The World Bank Economic Review lhv028. [Crossref]
250. Ariel Burstein, Javier Cravino. 2015. Measured Aggregate Gains from International Trade. American
Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 7:2, 181-218. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
251. Michael Jetter, Andrés Ramírez Hassan. 2015. WANT EXPORT DIVERSIFICATION?
EDUCATE THE KIDS FIRST. Economic Inquiry n/a-n/a. [Crossref]
252. Olga A. Timoshenko. 2015. Product switching in a model of learning. Journal of International
Economics 95:2, 233-249. [Crossref]
253. Soojae Moon. 2015. The Losses from Trade Restrictions: Policy Dynamics with Firm Selection and
Endogenous Markup. Review of International Economics 23:1, 86-110. [Crossref]
254. Katharina Eck, Martina Engemann, Monika Schnitzer. 2015. How trade credits foster exporting.
Review of World Economics 151:1, 73-101. [Crossref]
255. Julian di Giovanni, Andrei A. Levchenko, Francesc Ortega. 2015. A GLOBAL VIEW OF CROSSBORDER MIGRATION. Journal of the European Economic Association 13:1, 168-202. [Crossref]
256. Anne-Célia Disdier, Lionel Fontagné, Mondher Mimouni. 2015. Tariff Liberalization and Trade
Integration of Emerging Countries. Review of International Economics 23:5, 946. [Crossref]
257. Eugene Bempong Nyantakyi, Steven Husted, Shuichiro Nishioka. 2015. Trade Frictions and Market
Access of Developing Countries: A Product-level Empirical Investigation. Review of International
Economics 23:5, 924. [Crossref]
258. Meixin Guo, Huiran Pan. 2015. Can cross-listing relax financial frictions in trade and equity holdings?
A sector-level analysis. Applied Economics 47:19, 2012. [Crossref]
259. W. Mark Brown, William P. Anderson. 2015. How thick is the border: the relative cost of Canadian
domestic and cross-border truck-borne trade, 2004–2009. Journal of Transport Geography 42, 10-21.
[Crossref]
260. Gabriel Felbermayr, Volker Grossmann, Wilhelm Kohler. Migration, International Trade, and Capital
Formation 913-1025. [Crossref]
261. L. Caliendo, F. Parro. 2015. Estimates of the Trade and Welfare Effects of NAFTA. The Review of
Economic Studies 82:1, 1. [Crossref]
262. Anne-Célia Disdier, Lionel Fontagné, Olivier Cadot. 2015. North-South Standards Harmonization
and International Trade. The World Bank Economic Review 29:2, 327-352. [Crossref]
263. Douglas R. Nelson. Migration and Networks 141-164. [Crossref]
264. Jana Šimáková, Daniel Stavárek. 2015. An Empirical Sector-Specific Gravity Model for Hungarian
International Trade. Acta Universitatis Agriculturae et Silviculturae Mendelianae Brunensis 63:6,
2145-2150. [Crossref]
265. Song E. Young. 2014. Trade Finance and Trade Collapse during the Global Financial Crisis: Evidence
from the Republic of Korea. Journal of East Asian Economic Integration 18:4, 395-423. [Crossref]
266. Faqin Lin. 2014. Estimating the effect of the Internet on international trade. The Journal of
International Trade & Economic Development 1-20. [Crossref]
267. Rossana Mastrandrea, Tiziano Squartini, Giorgio Fagiolo, Diego Garlaschelli. 2014. Reconstructing
the world trade multiplex: The role of intensive and extensive biases. Physical Review E 90:6. .
[Crossref]
268. Francesco Serti, Chiara Tomasi. 2014. Export and import market-specific characteristics. Empirical
Economics 47:4, 1467-1496. [Crossref]
269. Sébastien Miroudot, Ben Shepherd. 2014. The Paradox of ‘Preferences’: Regional Trade Agreements
and Trade Costs in Services. The World Economy 37:12, 1751-1772. [Crossref]
270. Alex Sander Souza do Carmo, Maurício Vaz Lobo Bittencourt. 2014. O efeito da volatilidade da taxa
de câmbio sobre o comércio internacional: uma investigação empírica sob a ótica da margem extensiva.
Estudos Econômicos (São Paulo) 44:4, 815-845. [Crossref]
271. Andrea Fracasso. 2014. A gravity model of virtual water trade. Ecological Economics 108, 215-228.
[Crossref]
272. Thomas Chaney. 2014. The Network Structure of International Trade. American Economic Review
104:11, 3600-3634. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
273. Nuria Gallego, Carlos Llano. 2014. The Border Effect and the Nonlinear Relationship between Trade
and Distance. Review of International Economics 22:5, 1016-1048. [Crossref]
274. George Alessandria, Horag Choi. 2014. Do falling iceberg costs explain recent U.S. export growth?.
Journal of International Economics 94:2, 311-325. [Crossref]
275. Peter H. Egger, Katharina Erhardt, Andrea Lassmann. 2014. Productivity and R&D as Drivers of
Exports and Domestic Sales: Semi-parametric Evidence from French Firm-level Data. The World
Economy n/a-n/a. [Crossref]
276. Ina Charlotte Jäkel. 2014. Import-push or export-pull? An industry-level analysis of the impact of
trade on firm exit. Empirica 41:4, 747-775. [Crossref]
277. Filippo di Mauro, Francesco Pappadà. 2014. Euro area external imbalances and the burden of
adjustment. Journal of International Money and Finance 48, 336-356. [Crossref]
278. Kristian Behrens, Giordano Mion, Yasusada Murata, Jens Südekum. 2014. TRADE, WAGES, AND
PRODUCTIVITY. International Economic Review 55:4, 1305-1348. [Crossref]
279. Yves Bourdet, Maria Persson. 2014. Expanding and Diversifying South Mediterranean Exports
through Trade Facilitation. Development Policy Review 32:6, 675-699. [Crossref]
280. Jakob R. Munch, Daniel X. Nguyen. 2014. Decomposing firm-level sales variation. Journal of
Economic Behavior & Organization 106, 317-334. [Crossref]
281. Dimitri Bellas, Vincent Vicard. 2014. French Firms' Exports During Downturns: Evidence from Past
Crises. The World Economy 37:10, 1410-1423. [Crossref]
282. MARK J. McCABE, CHRISTOPHER M. SNYDER. 2014. IDENTIFYING THE EFFECT OF
OPEN ACCESS ON CITATIONS USING A PANEL OF SCIENCE JOURNALS. Economic Inquiry
52:4, 1284-1300. [Crossref]
283. Kyle Handley. 2014. Exporting under trade policy uncertainty: Theory and evidence. Journal of
International Economics 94:1, 50-66. [Crossref]
284. Ana P. Fernandes, Heiwai Tang. 2014. Learning to export from neighbors. Journal of International
Economics 94:1, 67-84. [Crossref]
285. Loris Rubini. 2014. Innovation and the trade elasticity. Journal of Monetary Economics 66, 32-46.
[Crossref]
286. Ioannis K. Dassios, Grigoris Kalogeropoulos. 2014. On the stability of equilibrium for a reformulated
foreign trade model of three countries. Journal of Industrial Engineering International 10:3. . [Crossref]
287. Bo Xiong, Sixia Chen. 2014. Estimating gravity equation models in the presence of sample selection
and heteroscedasticity. Applied Economics 46:24, 2993-3003. [Crossref]
288. JaeBin Ahn. 2014. A welfare analysis of unilateral trade and FDI liberalization. Canadian Journal of
Economics/Revue canadienne d'économique 47:3, 758-774. [Crossref]
289. Martina Lawless, Karl Whelan. 2014. Where Do Firms Export, How Much and Why?. The World
Economy 37:8, 1027-1050. [Crossref]
290. Li-juan Yang. Harmonized standards, heterogeneous firms and dual margins of China's export growth
833-844. [Crossref]
291. Chang-Tai Hsieh, Peter J. Klenow. 2014. The Life Cycle of Plants in India and Mexico *. The
Quarterly Journal of Economics 129:3, 1035-1084. [Crossref]
292. Justin Caron, Thibault Fally, James R. Markusen. 2014. International Trade Puzzles: A Solution
Linking Production and Preferences *. The Quarterly Journal of Economics 129:3, 1501-1552.
[Crossref]
293. Treb Allen, Costas Arkolakis. 2014. Trade and the Topography of the Spatial Economy *. The
Quarterly Journal of Economics 129:3, 1085-1140. [Crossref]
294. Takayuki Mizuno, Wataru Souma, Tsutomu Watanabe. 2014. The Structure and Evolution of BuyerSupplier Networks. PLoS ONE 9:7, e100712. [Crossref]
295. Laura Márquez-Ramos, Inmaculada Martínez-Zarzoso. 2014. Trade in intermediate goods and EuroMed production networks. Middle East Development Journal 6:2, 215-231. [Crossref]
296. Julian di Giovanni, Andrei A. Levchenko, Jing Zhang. 2014. The Global Welfare Impact of China:
Trade Integration and Technological Change. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 6:3,
153-183. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
297. F. Rauch. 2014. Cities as spatial clusters. Journal of Economic Geography 14:4, 759-773. [Crossref]
298. Holger Breinlich. 2014. Heterogeneous firm-level responses to trade liberalization: A test using stock
price reactions. Journal of International Economics 93:2, 270-285. [Crossref]
299. BO XIONG, JOHN BEGHIN. 2014. DISENTANGLING DEMAND-ENHANCING AND
TRADE-COST EFFECTS OF MAXIMUM RESIDUE REGULATIONS. Economic Inquiry 52:3,
1190-1203. [Crossref]
300. Scott L. Baier, Jeffrey H. Bergstrand, Michael Feng. 2014. Economic integration agreements and the
margins of international trade. Journal of International Economics 93:2, 339-350. [Crossref]
301. Kai Xu. 2014. Barriers to labor mobility and international trade: The case of China. China Economic
Review 29, 107-125. [Crossref]
302. Armando J. Garcia Pires. 2014. Beyond Trade Costs: Firms’ Endogenous Access to International
Markets. Journal of Industry, Competition and Trade 14:2, 229-257. [Crossref]
303. 박박박, Soonchan Park. 2014. The Impact of Monetary Policy on the Foreign Exchange Rate: An
Empirical Evidence from Korea. KUKJE KYUNGJE YONGU 20:2, 49-70. [Crossref]
304. Nicholas Sheard. 2014. Learning to Export and the Timing of Entry to Export Markets. Review of
International Economics n/a-n/a. [Crossref]
305. Robert C. Feenstra, John Romalis. 2014. International Prices and Endogenous Quality. The Quarterly
Journal of Economics 129:2, 477-527. [Crossref]
306. J.M.C. Santos Silva, Silvana Tenreyro, Kehai Wei. 2014. Estimating the extensive margin of trade.
Journal of International Economics 93:1, 67-75. [Crossref]
307. Kazunobu Hayakawa, Fukunari Kimura, Kaoru Nabeshima. 2014. Nonconventional Provisions in
Regional Trade Agreements: Do They Enhance International Trade?. Journal of Applied Economics
17:1, 113-137. [Crossref]
308. Philipp J. H. Schröder, Allan Sørensen. 2014. A Welfare Ranking of Multilateral Reductions in Real
and Tariff Trade Barriers when Firms are Heterogenous. Review of International Economics n/a-n/
a. [Crossref]
309. Keisaku Higashida, Shunsuke Managi. 2014. Determinants of trade in recyclable wastes: evidence from
commodity-based trade of waste and scrap. Environment and Development Economics 19:02, 250-270.
[Crossref]
310. Joel Rodrigue. 2014. Multinational production, exports and aggregate productivity. Review of
Economic Dynamics 17:2, 243-261. [Crossref]
311. Ari Kokko, Patrik Gustavsson Tingvall. 2014. Distance, Transaction Costs, and Preferences in
European Trade. The International Trade Journal 28:2, 87-120. [Crossref]
312. Gita Gopinath, Brent Neiman. 2014. Trade Adjustment and Productivity in Large Crises. American
Economic Review 104:3, 793-831. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
313. Mariya Aleksynska, Giovanni Peri. 2014. Isolating the Network Effect of Immigrants on Trade. The
World Economy 37:3, 434-455. [Crossref]
314. Harald Badinger, Kemal Türkcan. 2014. Currency Unions, Export Margins, and Product
Differentiation: An Empirical Assessment for European Monetary Union. Review of International
Economics 22:1, 13-30. [Crossref]
315. Erik van der Marel, Iana Dreyer. 2014. Beyond Dutch disease. Economics of Transition n/a-n/a.
[Crossref]
316. Marc J. Melitz, Stephen J. Redding. Heterogeneous Firms and Trade 1-54. [Crossref]
317. 2014. Information Frictions in Trade. Econometrica 82:6, 2041-2083. [Crossref]
318. Sjoerd Beugelsdijk, Ram Mudambi. MNEs as Border-Crossing Multi-location Enterprises: The Role
of Discontinuities in Geographic Space 8-34. [Crossref]
319. Arnaud Costinot, Andrés Rodríguez-Clare. Trade Theory with Numbers: Quantifying the
Consequences of Globalization 197-261. [Crossref]
320. M. Riccaboni, S. Schiavo. 2014. Stochastic trade networks. Journal of Complex Networks 2:4, 537.
[Crossref]
321. Lawrence Edwards, Rhys Jenkins. 2014. The margins of export competition: A new approach to
evaluating the impact of China on South African exports to Sub-Saharan Africa. Journal of Policy
Modeling 36, S132-S150. [Crossref]
322. Keith Head, Thierry Mayer. Gravity Equations: Workhorse,Toolkit, and Cookbook 131-195.
[Crossref]
323. Pol Antràs, Stephen R. Yeaple. Multinational Firms and the Structure of International Trade 55-130.
[Crossref]
324. Armando Silva, Oscar Afonso, Ana Paula Africano. 2013. Economic performance and international
trade engagement: the case of Portuguese manufacturing firms. International Economics and Economic
Policy 10:4, 521-547. [Crossref]
325. Bruce A. Blonigen, Wesley W. Wilson. 2013. The growth and patterns of international trade.
Maritime Policy & Management 40:7, 618-635. [Crossref]
326. Chunding Li, John Whalley. 2013. China and the Trans-Pacific Partnership: A Numerical Simulation
Assessment of the Effects Involved. The World Economy n/a-n/a. [Crossref]
327. Matthieu Crozet, Federico Trionfetti. 2013. Firm-level comparative advantage. Journal of International
Economics 91:2, 321-328. [Crossref]
328. Kristie Briggs. 2013. Institutional quality as a barrier to trade. Applied Economics Letters 20:16,
1453-1458. [Crossref]
329. Keith Head, Thierry Mayer. 2013. What separates us? Sources of resistance to globalization. Canadian
Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d'économique 46:4, 1196-1231. [Crossref]
330. Pushan Dutt, Ilian Mihov, Timothy Van Zandt. 2013. The effect of WTO on the extensive and the
intensive margins of trade. Journal of International Economics 91:2, 204-219. [Crossref]
331. Xuebing Yang. 2013. The relative importance of distance in restricting international trade. Applied
Economics Letters 20:17, 1548-1552. [Crossref]
332. Sebastian Krautheim. 2013. Export-supporting FDI. Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne
d'économique 46:4, 1571-1605. [Crossref]
333. Yi Lu, Zhigang Tao, Yan Zhang. 2013. How do exporters respond to antidumping investigations?.
Journal of International Economics 91:2, 290-300. [Crossref]
334. Amit K. Khandelwal,, Peter K. Schott,, Shang-Jin Wei. 2013. Trade Liberalization and Embedded
Institutional Reform: Evidence from Chinese Exporters. American Economic Review 103:6, 2169-2195.
[Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
335. Mario Larch, Wolfgang Lechthaler. 2013. Whom to send to Doha? The shortsighted ones!. Review
of Economic Dynamics 16:4, 634-649. [Crossref]
336. Iza Lejárraga, Peter Walkenhorst. 2013. Economic policy, tourism trade and productive diversification.
International Economics 135-136, 1-12. [Crossref]
337. SÉBASTIEN MIROUDOT, JEHAN SAUVAGE, BEN SHEPHERD. 2013. Measuring the cost of
international trade in services. World Trade Review 12:04, 719-735. [Crossref]
338. Ina Simonovska, Michael E. Waugh. 2013. The elasticity of trade: Estimates and evidence. Journal
of International Economics . [Crossref]
339. Andrew J. Cassey, Katherine N. Schmeiser. 2013. The agglomeration of exporters by destination. The
Annals of Regional Science 51:2, 495-513. [Crossref]
340. Rinaldo Brau, Anna Maria Pinna. 2013. Movements of People for Movements of Goods?. The World
Economy 36:10, 1318-1332. [Crossref]
341. Juan Carlos Hallak, Jagadeesh Sivadasan. 2013. Product and process productivity: Implications for
quality choice and conditional exporter premia. Journal of International Economics 91:1, 53-67.
[Crossref]
342. Olivier Cadot, Céline Carrère, Vanessa Strauss-Kahn. 2013. TRADE DIVERSIFICATION,
INCOME, AND GROWTH: WHAT DO WE KNOW?. Journal of Economic Surveys 27:4, 790-812.
[Crossref]
343. Rasyad A. Parinduri, Shandre M. Thangavelu. 2013. Trade liberalization, free trade agreements, and
the value of firms: Stock market evidence from Singapore. The Journal of International Trade &
Economic Development 22:6, 924-941. [Crossref]
344. Benjamin Bridgman. 2013. Market entry and trade weighted import costs. Canadian Journal of
Economics/Revue canadienne d'économique 46:3, 982-1013. [Crossref]
345. Maria Persson. 2013. Trade facilitation and the extensive margin. The Journal of International Trade
& Economic Development 22:5, 658-693. [Crossref]
346. Jürgen Meckl, Benjamin Weigert. 2013. Occupational Choice, Aggregate Productivity, and Trade.
Review of Development Economics 17:3, 549-558. [Crossref]
347. Emmanuelle Chevassus-Lozza, Carl Gaigné, Léo Le Mener. 2013. Does input trade liberalization
boost downstream firms' exports? Theory and firm-level evidence. Journal of International Economics
90:2, 391-402. [Crossref]
348. Katherine N. Schmeiser. 2013. The firm export and FDI choice in the context of gravity. International
Review of Economics & Finance 27, 592-596. [Crossref]
349. C. C. Coughlin, D. Novy. 2013. Is the International Border Effect Larger than the Domestic Border
Effect? Evidence from US Trade. CESifo Economic Studies 59:2, 249-276. [Crossref]
350. Joseph Francois, Miriam Manchin. 2013. Institutions, Infrastructure, and Trade. World Development
46, 165-175. [Crossref]
351. C. Arkolakis, M.-A. Muendler. 2013. Exporters and Their Products: A Collection of Empirical
Regularities. CESifo Economic Studies 59:2, 223-248. [Crossref]
352. Hyun-Hoon Lee, Donghyun Park, Jing Wang. 2013. Different types of firms, different types of
products, and their dynamics: An anatomy of China's imports. China Economic Review 25, 62-77.
[Crossref]
353. J. H. Bergstrand. 2013. Measuring the Effects of Endogenous Policies on Economic Integration.
CESifo Economic Studies 59:2, 199-222. [Crossref]
354. Sjoerd Beugelsdijk, Ram Mudambi. 2013. MNEs as border-crossing multi-location enterprises: The
role of discontinuities in geographic space. Journal of International Business Studies 44:5, 413-426.
[Crossref]
355. Fernando Ferreira, Joel Waldfogel. 2013. Pop Internationalism: Has Half a Century of World Music
Trade Displaced Local Culture?. The Economic Journal 123:569, 634-664. [Crossref]
356. Ermias Weldemicael. 2013. Technology, Trade Costs and Export Sophistication. The World Economy
n/a-n/a. [Crossref]
357. Seema Sangita. 2013. The Effect of Diasporic Business Networks on International Trade Flows.
Review of International Economics 21:2, 266-280. [Crossref]
358. Daniel Berger,, William Easterly,, Nathan Nunn,, Shanker Satyanath. 2013. Commercial
Imperialism? Political Influence and Trade During the Cold War. American Economic Review 103:2,
863-896. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
359. Ariel Burstein,, Javier Cravino,, Jonathan Vogel. 2013. Importing Skill-Biased Technology. American
Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 5:2, 32-71. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
360. Fernando Parro. 2013. Capital-Skill Complementarity and the Skill Premium in a Quantitative Model
of Trade. American Economic Journal: Macroeconomics 5:2, 72-117. [Abstract] [View PDF article]
[PDF with links]
361. Raphael A. Auer, Kathrin Degen, Andreas M. Fischer. 2013. Low-wage import competition,
inflationary pressure, and industry dynamics in Europe. European Economic Review 59, 141-166.
[Crossref]
362. Julian di Giovanni, Andrei A. Levchenko. 2013. Firm entry, trade, and welfare in Zipf's world. Journal
of International Economics 89:2, 283-296. [Crossref]
363. Jiandong Ju, Li Su. 2013. Market structure in the Chinese steel industry. Asia-Pacific Journal of
Accounting & Economics 20:1, 70-84. [Crossref]
364. Dennis Novy. 2013. International trade without CES: Estimating translog gravity. Journal of
International Economics 89:2, 271-282. [Crossref]
365. Francesc Ortega, Giovanni Peri. 2013. The effect of income and immigration policies on international
migration. Migration Studies 1:1, 47-74. [Crossref]
366. Inmaculada Martínez-Zarzoso, Sami Bensassi. 2013. THE PRICE OF MODERN MARITIME
PIRACY. Defence and Peace Economics 1-22. [Crossref]
367. Gal Hochman, Chrysostomos Tabakis, David Zilberman. 2013. The impact of international trade on
institutions and infrastructure. Journal of Comparative Economics 41:1, 126-140. [Crossref]
368. Wei-Chih Chen. 2013. The Extensive and Intensive Margins of Exports: The Role of Innovation.
The World Economy no-no. [Crossref]
369. Yan Zhou, Jiadong Tong, Puyang Sun. 2013. What's special about the extensive and intensive margins
in Chinese manufacturing exports?. Journal of Chinese Economic and Foreign Trade Studies 6:1, 19-34.
[Crossref]
370. Armando Silva, Oscar Afonso, Ana Paula Africano. 2013. ¿Las empresas más productivas se
autoseleccionan para exportar? Aplicación de una prueba para el caso de Portugal. Investigación
Económica 72:283, 135-161. [Crossref]
371. Richard Fabling, Arthur Grimes, Lynda Sanderson. 2013. Any port in a storm: Impacts of new port
infrastructure on exporter behaviour. Transportation Research Part E: Logistics and Transportation
Review 49:1, 33-47. [Crossref]
372. DENNIS NOVY. 2013. GRAVITY REDUX: MEASURING INTERNATIONAL TRADE COSTS
WITH PANEL DATA. Economic Inquiry 51:1, 101-121. [Crossref]
373. Wataru Johdo. 2013. Corporate Tax Reductions, Cross-Border Ownership and Welfare. Japanese
Economic Review 64:4, 484. [Crossref]
374. Russell Hillberry, David Hummels. Trade Elasticity Parameters for a Computable General
Equilibrium Model 1213-1269. [Crossref]
375. Mark Vancauteren. 7 The Role of EU Harmonization in Explaining the Export-Productivity Premium
of Food Processing Firms 165-185. [Crossref]
376. Charles Ackah. 2013. Measuring Trade Costs in Economic Community of West African States
(ECOWAS). Modern Economy 04:01, 56-65. [Crossref]
377. Irene Brambilla,, Daniel Lederman,, Guido Porto. 2012. Exports, Export Destinations, and Skills.
American Economic Review 102:7, 3406-3438. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
378. H. Tang, Y. Zhang. 2012. Exchange Rates and the Margins of Trade: Evidence from Chinese
Exporters. CESifo Economic Studies 58:4, 671-702. [Crossref]
379. Peter Egger, Valeria Merlo. 2012. BITs Bite: An Anatomy of the Impact of Bilateral Investment
Treaties on Multinational Firms*. The Scandinavian Journal of Economics 114:4, 1240-1266.
[Crossref]
380. Massimiliano Bratti, Giulia Felice. 2012. Are Exporters More Likely to Introduce Product
Innovations?. The World Economy 35:11, 1559-1598. [Crossref]
381. José de Sousa, Thierry Mayer, Soledad Zignago. 2012. Market access in global and regional trade.
Regional Science and Urban Economics 42:6, 1037-1052. [Crossref]
382. Tomohiro Machikita, Yasushi Ueki. 2012. The geographic extent of global supply chains: evidence
from Southeast Asia. Asian-Pacific Economic Literature 26:2, 72-87. [Crossref]
383. Juan Blyde, Gonzalo Iberti. 2012. Trade Costs, Resource Reallocation and Productivity in Developing
Countries. Review of International Economics 20:5, 909-923. [Crossref]
384. Stefanie A. Haller. 2012. Intra-firm trade, exporting, importing, and firm performance. Canadian
Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d'économique 45:4, 1397-1430. [Crossref]
385. Francesco Serti, Chiara Tomasi. 2012. Self selection among different export markets. Economics Letters
117:1, 102-105. [Crossref]
386. E. Young Song, Chen Zhao. 2012. Does Specialization Matter for Trade Imbalance at Industry Level?.
Journal of East Asian Economic Integration 16:3, 227-247. [Crossref]
387. Andrés Artal-Tur, Vicente J. Pallardó-López, Francisco Requena-Silvente. 2012. The trade-enhancing
effect of immigration networks: New evidence on the role of geographic proximity. Economics Letters
116:3, 554-557. [Crossref]
388. Maksim Belenkiy, David Riker. 2012. Face-to-Face Exports. Journal of Travel Research 51:5, 632-639.
[Crossref]
389. Kristian Behrens, Cem Ertur, Wilfried Koch. 2012. ‘DUAL’ GRAVITY: USING SPATIAL
ECONOMETRICS TO CONTROL FOR MULTILATERAL RESISTANCE. Journal of Applied
Econometrics 27:5, 773-794. [Crossref]
390. Alberto Behar, Philip Manners, Benjamin D. Nelson. 2012. Exports and International Logistics*.
Oxford Bulletin of Economics and Statistics no-no. [Crossref]
391. Hartmut Egger, Peter Egger, James R. Markusen. 2012. INTERNATIONAL WELFARE AND
EMPLOYMENT LINKAGES ARISING FROM MINIMUM WAGES*. International Economic
Review 53:3, 771-790. [Crossref]
392. Giulia Bettin, Alessia Lo Turco. 2012. A Cross-Country View on South-North Migration and Trade:
Dissecting the Channels. Emerging Markets Finance and Trade 48:4, 4-29. [Crossref]
393. NATALIE CHEN, DENNIS NOVY. 2012. On the measurement of trade costs: direct vs. indirect
approaches to quantifying standards and technical regulations. World Trade Review 11:03, 401-414.
[Crossref]
394. MARIE-AGNÈS JOUANJEAN. 2012. Standards, reputation, and trade: evidence from US
horticultural import refusals. World Trade Review 11:03, 438-461. [Crossref]
395. Oscar Afonso, Armando Silva. 2012. Non-scale endogenous growth effects of subsidies for exporters.
Economic Modelling 29:4, 1248-1257. [Crossref]
396. Andrew B. Bernard, J. Bradford Jensen, Stephen J. Redding, Peter K. Schott. 2012. The Empirics of
Firm Heterogeneity and International Trade. Annual Review of Economics 4:1, 283-313. [Crossref]
397. Pierre-Louis Vézina. 2012. How migrant networks facilitate trade: Evidence from Swiss exports. Swiss
Journal of Economics and Statistics 148:3, 449-476. [Crossref]
398. Gregory Corcos, Massimo Del Gatto, Giordano Mion, Gianmarco I.P. Ottaviano. 2012. Productivity
and Firm Selection: Quantifying the ‘New’ Gains from Trade. The Economic Journal 122:561,
754-798. [Crossref]
399. Sebastian Krautheim. 2012. Heterogeneous firms, exporter networks and the effect of distance on
international trade. Journal of International Economics 87:1, 27-35. [Crossref]
400. Matilde Bombardini, Christopher J. Kurz, Peter M. Morrow. 2012. Ricardian trade and the impact
of domestic competition on export performance. Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne
d'économique 45:2, 585-612. [Crossref]
401. Jeffrey H. Bergstrand, Peter Egger, Mario Larch. 2012. Gravity Redux: Estimation of gravity-equation
coefficients, elasticities of substitution, and general equilibrium comparative statics under asymmetric
bilateral trade costs. Journal of International Economics . [Crossref]
402. Andrea Finicelli, Patrizio Pagano, Massimo Sbracia. 2012. Ricardian selection. Journal of International
Economics . [Crossref]
403. Philipp J.H. Schröder, Allan Sørensen. 2012. Firm exit, technological progress and trade. European
Economic Review 56:3, 579-591. [Crossref]
404. Alexander Tarasov. 2012. Per capita income, market access costs, and trade volumes. Journal of
International Economics 86:2, 284-294. [Crossref]
405. Ines Buono, Guy Lalanne. 2012. The effect of the Uruguay round on the intensive and extensive
margins of trade. Journal of International Economics 86:2, 269-283. [Crossref]
406. Costas Arkolakis,, Arnaud Costinot,, Andrés Rodríguez-Clare. 2012. New Trade Models, Same Old
Gains?. American Economic Review 102:1, 94-130. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
407. Paul De Grauwe, Romain Houssa, Giulia Piccillo. 2012. African trade dynamics: is China a different
trading partner?. Journal of Chinese Economic and Business Studies 10:1, 15-45. [Crossref]
408. Eric Sheppard. 2012. Trade, globalization and uneven development. Progress in Human Geography
36:1, 44-71. [Crossref]
409. N. Berman, P. Martin, T. Mayer. 2012. How do Different Exporters React to Exchange Rate
Changes?. The Quarterly Journal of Economics . [Crossref]
410. K. Manova, Z. Zhang. 2012. Export Prices Across Firms and Destinations. The Quarterly Journal of
Economics . [Crossref]
411. Joachim Wagner. 2012. International trade and firm performance: a survey of empirical studies since
2006. Review of World Economics . [Crossref]
412. Paul R. Bergin, Ching-Yi Lin. 2012. The dynamic effects of a currency union on trade. Journal of
International Economics . [Crossref]
413. Maria Persson. 2012. From Trade Preferences to Trade Facilitation: Taking Stock of the Issues.
Economics: The Open-Access, Open-Assessment E-Journal 6:2012-17, 1. [Crossref]
414. Paulo Bastos, Joana Silva. 2012. Networks, firms, and trade. Journal of International Economics .
[Crossref]
415. Gábor Békés, Balázs Muraközy. 2012. Temporary trade and heterogeneous firms. Journal of
International Economics . [Crossref]
416. Julian di Giovanni, Jing Zhang, Andrei A. Levchenko. 2012. The Global Welfare Impact of China:
Trade Integration and Technological Change. IMF Working Papers 12:79, 1. [Crossref]
417. Vincenzo Verardi, Joachim Wagner. 2011. Productivity Premia for German Manufacturing Firms
Exporting to the Euro-Area and Beyond: First Evidence from Robust Fixed Effects Estimations. The
World Economy no-no. [Crossref]
418. Daniel X. Nguyen. 2011. Demand Uncertainty: Exporting Delays and Exporting Failures. Journal of
International Economics . [Crossref]
419. Carlos Llano-Verduras, Asier Minondo, Francisco Requena-Silvente. 2011. Is the Border Effect an
Artefact of Geographical Aggregation?. The World Economy 34:10, 1771-1787. [Crossref]
420. Harold Creusen, Henk Kox, Arjan Lejour, Roger Smeets. 2011. Exploring the Margins of Dutch
Exports: A Firm-Level Analysis. De Economist . [Crossref]
421. Sébastien Miroudot, Jehan Sauvage, Ben Shepherd. 2011. Trade costs and productivity in services
sectors. Economics Letters . [Crossref]
422. Matthew T. Cole. 2011. Not all trade restrictions are created equally. Review of World Economics
147:3, 411-427. [Crossref]
423. Stephen J. Redding. 2011. Theories of Heterogeneous Firms and Trade. Annual Review of Economics
3:1, 77-105. [Crossref]
424. James E. Anderson. 2011. The Gravity Model. Annual Review of Economics 3:1, 133-160. [Crossref]
425. Mario Larch, Wolfgang Lechthaler. 2011. Why ‘Buy American’ is a bad idea but politicians still like
it. Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d'économique 44:3, 838-858. [Crossref]
426. Holger Breinlich, Alessandra Tucci. 2011. Foreign market conditions and export performance: does
‘crowdedness’ reduce exports?. Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d'économique 44:3,
991-1019. [Crossref]
427. Francesco Pappadà. 2011. Real Adjustment of Current Account Imbalances with Firm Heterogeneity.
IMF Economic Review 59:3, 431-454. [Crossref]
428. Luca De Benedictis, Lucia Tajoli. 2011. The World Trade Network. The World Economy 34:8,
1417-1454. [Crossref]
429. A. B. Bernard, S. J. Redding, P. K. Schott. 2011. Multiproduct Firms and Trade Liberalization. The
Quarterly Journal of Economics . [Crossref]
430. Natalie Chen, Dennis Novy. 2011. Gravity, trade integration, and heterogeneity across industries.
Journal of International Economics . [Crossref]
431. Maria Bejan. 2011. Trade agreements and international comovements: The case of NAFTA (North
American Free Trade Agreement). Review of Economic Dynamics . [Crossref]
432. José Antonio Rodríguez-López. 2011. Prices and Exchange Rates: A Theory of Disconnect. The
Review of Economic Studies 78:3, 1135-1177. [Crossref]
433. Julian di Giovanni, Andrei A. Levchenko, Romain Rancière. 2011. Power laws in firm size and
openness to trade: Measurement and implications. Journal of International Economics . [Crossref]
434. SEMIH TUMEN. 2011. MEASURING EARNINGS INEQUALITY: AN ECONOMIC
ANALYSIS OF THE BONFERRONI INDEX. Review of Income and Wealth no-no. [Crossref]
435. E. Chevassus-Lozza, K. Latouche. 2011. Firms, markets and trade costs: access of French exporters
to European agri-food markets. European Review of Agricultural Economics . [Crossref]
436. Gabriel Felbermayr, Julien Prat. 2011. PRODUCT MARKET REGULATION, FIRM
SELECTION, AND UNEMPLOYMENT. Journal of the European Economic Association 9:2,
278-317. [Crossref]
437. Yushi Yoshida. 2011. An Empirical Examination of Export Variety: Regional Heterogeneity within a
Nation. The World Economy 34:4, 602-622. [Crossref]
438. K. Head, T. Mayer. 2011. Gravity, market potential and economic development. Journal of Economic
Geography 11:2, 281-294. [Crossref]
439. Edward J. Balistreri, Russell H. Hillberry, Thomas F. Rutherford. 2011. Structural estimation and
solution of international trade models with heterogeneous firms. Journal of International Economics
83:2, 95-108. [Crossref]
440. David S. Jacks, Christopher M. Meissner, Dennis Novy. 2011. Trade booms, trade busts, and trade
costs. Journal of International Economics 83:2, 185-201. [Crossref]
441. Gábor Békés, Balázs Muraközy, Péter Harasztosi. 2011. Firms and products in international trade:
Evidence from Hungary. Economic Systems 35:1, 4-24. [Crossref]
442. Ferdinando Monte. 2011. Skill bias, trade, and wage dispersion박. Journal of International Economics
83:2, 202-218. [Crossref]
443. Rod Falvey, David Greenaway, Zhihong Yu. 2011. Catching Up or Pulling Away: Intra-Industry Trade,
Productivity Gaps and Heterogeneous Firms. Open Economies Review 22:1, 17-38. [Crossref]
444. Gonzague Vannoorenberghe. 2011. Trade between symmetric countries, heterogeneous firms, and
the skill premium. Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d'économique 44:1, 148-170.
[Crossref]
445. M. J. Gibson, T. A. Graciano. 2011. The Decision to Import. American Journal of Agricultural
Economics . [Crossref]
446. Allen Dennis, Ben Shepherd. 2011. Trade Facilitation and Export Diversification. The World Economy
34:1, 101-122. [Crossref]
447. Luca Antonio Ricci, Federico Trionfetti. 2011. Evidenceon Productivity, Comparative Advantage, and
Networks in the Export Performance of Firms. IMF Working Papers 11:77, 1. [Crossref]
448. George Alessandria,, Joseph P. Kaboski,, Virgiliu Midrigan. 2010. Inventories, Lumpy Trade, and
Large Devaluations. American Economic Review 100:5, 2304-2339. [Abstract] [View PDF article]
[PDF with links]
449. L. D. Tamini, J.-P. Gervais, B. Larue. 2010. Trade liberalisation effects on agricultural goods at
different processing stages. European Review of Agricultural Economics 37:4, 453-477. [Crossref]
450. Kichun KANG, Jong-Ho KIM. 2010. EXPLORING THE SPECTRUM OF EXPORT
DESTINATION: THE GEOGRAPHIC SPREAD OF KOREAN EXPORTS, ITS
DETERMINANTS, AND POLICY IMPLICATIONS. The Developing Economies 48:4, 421-449.
[Crossref]
451. Martina Lawless. 2010. Deconstructing gravity: trade costs and extensive and intensive margins.
Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d'économique 43:4, 1149-1172. [Crossref]
452. Giovanni Peri, Francisco Requena-Silvente. 2010. The trade creation effect of immigrants: evidence
from the remarkable case of Spain. Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d'économique
43:4, 1433-1459. [Crossref]
453. Octavio R. Escobar Gamboa. 2010. The (un)lucky neighbour: Differences in export performance
across Mexico's states. Papers in Regional Science 89:4, 777-799. [Crossref]
454. Philipp J. H. Schröder, Allan Sørensen. 2010. Ad valorem versus unit taxes: monopolistic competition,
heterogeneous firms, and intra-industry reallocations. Journal of Economics 101:3, 247-265. [Crossref]
455. D’Artis Kancs. 2010. Structural Estimation of Variety Gains from Trade Integration in Asia. Australian
Economic Review 43:3, 270-288. [Crossref]
456. R. S. Grossman, C. M. Meissner. 2010. International aspects of the Great Depression and the crisis of
2007: similarities, differences, and lessons. Oxford Review of Economic Policy 26:3, 318-338. [Crossref]
457. Kichun Kang, Byung Chul Ahn. 2010. China's Penetration of the Korean Market: Stylized Facts and
Welfare Effect. China & World Economy 18:5, 54-71. [Crossref]
458. Henk L. M. Kox, Hugo Rojas-Romagosa. 2010. Exports and Productivity Selection Effects for Dutch
Firms. De Economist 158:3, 295-322. [Crossref]
459. Itai Agur. 2010. Trade Liberalization, Firm Selection, and Variety Growth. Review of International
Economics 18:3, 582-594. [Crossref]
460. Keith Head, Thierry Mayer, John Ries. 2010. The erosion of colonial trade linkages after
independence. Journal of International Economics 81:1, 1-14. [Crossref]
461. Richard Frensch. 2010. Trade Liberalization and Import Margins. Emerging Markets Finance and
Trade 46:3, 4-22. [Crossref]
462. Andreas Moxnes. 2010. Are sunk costs in exporting country specific?. Canadian Journal of Economics/
Revue canadienne d'économique 43:2, 467-493. [Crossref]
463. Massimo Del Gatto, Adriana Di Liberto, Carmelo Petraglia. 2010. MEASURING
PRODUCTIVITY. Journal of Economic Surveys no-no. [Crossref]
464. Kei-Mu Yi. 2010. Can Multistage Production Explain the Home Bias in Trade?. American Economic
Review 100:1, 364-393. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
465. Davide Castellani, Francesco Serti, Chiara Tomasi. 2010. Firms in International Trade: Importers’
and Exporters’ Heterogeneity in Italian Manufacturing Industry. World Economy 33:3, 424-457.
[Crossref]
466. Robert C. Feenstra. 2010. Measuring the gains from trade under monopolistic competition. Canadian
Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d'économique 43:1, 1-28. [Crossref]
467. Matthieu Crozet, Pamina Koenig. 2010. Structural gravity equations with intensive and extensive
margins. Canadian Journal of Economics/Revue canadienne d'économique 43:1, 41-62. [Crossref]
468. Massimo Riccaboni, Stefano Schiavo. 2010. Structure and growth of weighted networks. New Journal
of Physics 12:2, 023003. [Crossref]
469. Anne-Célia Disdier, Silvio H. T. Tai, Lionel Fontagné, Thierry Mayer. 2010. Bilateral trade of cultural
goods. Review of World Economics 145:4, 575-595. [Crossref]
470. Andrei A. Levchenko, Julian di Giovanni, Romain Ranciere. 2010. Power Laws in Firm Size and
Openness to Trade: Measurement and Implications. IMF Working Papers 10:109, 1. [Crossref]
471. M.-L. Rau, F. van Tongeren. 2009. Heterogeneous firms and homogenising standards in agri-food
trade: the Polish meat case. European Review of Agricultural Economics 36:4, 479-505. [Crossref]
472. Pascal L. Ghazalian, Bruno Larue, Jean-Philippe Gervais. 2009. Exporting to new destinations and
the effects of tariffs: the case of meat commodities. Agricultural Economics 40:6, 701-714. [Crossref]
473. Betina Dimaranan, Elena Ianchovichina, Will Martin. 2009. How will growth in China and India
affect the world economy?. Review of World Economics 145:3, 551-571. [Crossref]
474. Raphael Auer. 2009. Taste Heterogeneity, Trade, and the Within-Industry Home Market Effect.
Swiss Journal of Economics and Statistics 145:4, 387-403. [Crossref]
475. Xavier Gabaix. 2009. Power Laws in Economics and Finance. Annual Review of Economics 1:1, 255-294.
[Crossref]
476. Silvio H. T. Tai. 2009. Market structure and the link between migration and trade. Review of World
Economics 145:2, 225-249. [Crossref]
477. Martina Lawless. 2009. Firm export dynamics and the geography of trade. Journal of International
Economics 77:2, 245-254. [Crossref]
478. International Monetary Fund. 2009. Elasticity Optimism. IMF Working Papers 09:279, 1. [Crossref]
479. Andrew Atkeson,, Ariel Burstein. 2008. Pricing-to-Market, Trade Costs, and International Relative
Prices. American Economic Review 98:5, 1998-2031. [Abstract] [View PDF article] [PDF with links]
480. Fan Zhai. Chapter 2 Trade Liberalization and the Extensive Margin of Trade in a CGE Model with
Heterogeneous Firms 27-40. [Crossref]
481. Ishita Ghosh, Sukalpa Chakrabarti. Inward and Outward Foreign Investments of the Asian Economies
in Transition and India 212-237. [Crossref]
Download