Monopoly
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 2
Introduction
Monopoly is a market structure in which a single firm makes up the entire supply side of the market.
Monopoly is the polar opposite of perfect competition.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 3
Introduction
Monopolies exist because of barriers to entry into a market that prevent entry by new firms.
Barriers to entry include legal barriers such as a patent, and natural barriers such as the size of the market that can support only one firm.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 4
The Key Difference Between a Monopolist and a Perfect
Competitor
A competitive firm is too small to affect the price.
It does not have to take into account the effect of its output decision on the price it receives.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 5
The Key Difference Between a Monopolist and a Perfect
Competitor
A competitive firm's marginal revenue is the market price.
A monopolistic firm’s marginal revenue is not equal to its price – it takes into account that in order to sell more it has to decrease the price of its product.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 6
The Key Difference Between a Monopolist and a Perfect
Competitor
Monopolist as the only supplier faces the entire market demand curve.
Therefore, monopoly demand is downward sloping, and to increase output the firm must decrease its price.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 7
A Model of Monopoly
How much should a monopoly produce to maximize its profit?
The monopolist employs a two-step profit maximizing process; it chooses quantity
and price.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
The Monopolist’s Price and
Output
12 - 8
As in perfect competition, profit for the monopolist is maximized at a point where MC = MR .
What is different for a monopolist – marginal revenue does not equal price; marginal revenue is below price.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
The Monopolist’s Price and
Output
12 - 9
If a monopolist deviates from the output level at which marginal cost equals marginal revenue, profits will fall.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 10
Table 12-1, p 257
Output Price TR MR TC MC ATC Profit
0 36 0 — 47 — –47
1 33 33 33 48 1 48.00 –15
2 30 60 27 50 2 25.00 10
3 27 81 21 54 4 18.00 27
4 24 96 15 62 8 15.50 34
5 21 105 9 78 16 15.60 27
6 18 108 3 102 24 17.00 6
7 15 105 –3 142 40 20.29 –37
8 12 96 –9 196 56 24.75 –102
9 9 81 –15 278 80 30.89 –197
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
The Monopolist’s Price and
Output Graphically
12 - 11
The marginal revenue curve tells us the additional revenue the firm will get from an additional unit of output.
The marginal cost curve is a graph of the change in firm’s total cost as it changes output.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
The Monopolist’s Price and
Output Graphically
12 - 12
To determine the profit-maximizing price and quantity:
one first finds output (where MC = MR ), and then
extends a vertical line for that output, up to the demand curve to find the price.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
The Monopolist’s Price and
Output Graphically
12 - 13
If MR > MC , the monopolist gains profit by increasing output.
If MR < MC , the monopolist gains profit by decreasing output.
If MC = MR , the monopolist is maximizing profit.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
The Monopolist’s Price and
Output Graphically
12 - 14
The MR = MC condition determines the quantity a monopolist produces.
That quantity determines the price the monopolist will charge.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 15
Comparing Monopoly and
Perfect Competition
Profit-maximizing output for the monopolist, like profit maximizing output for the competitor in a perfectly competitive market is where MC = MR .
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 16
Comparing Monopoly and
Perfect Competition
Because the monopolist’s marginal revenue is below its price, its equilibrium output is less than, and price is higher than that of a perfectly competitive market.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
The Monopolist’s Price and
Output Graphically,
Fig.12-1, p 259
12 - 17
Price
$36
30
20.50
24
18
12
6
0
6
12
MC
Monopolist price and output
Perfectly competitive price and output
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
5.17
MR
D
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
Finding the monopolist’s price and output
12 - 18
Draw the firm's marginal revenue curve.
Determine the output the monopolist will produce by the intersection of the MC and MR curves.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 19
Finding the monopolist’s price and output
Determine the price the monopolist will charge for that output by finding where the quantity line intersects the demand curve.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
Finding the monopolist’s price and output,
Fig. 12-2a and b, p 260
Price
MC
12 - 20
D
MR
Quantity
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
Finding the monopolist’s price and output,
Fig. 12-2 c and d, p 260
12 - 21
Price
MC
P
M
Q
M
D
MR
Quantity
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 22
Finding the Monopolist’s
Profit
Determine the average cost at the profit-maximizing level of output.
Determine the monopolist's profit (loss) by subtracting average total cost from average revenue ( P ) at that level of output and multiply by the chosen output.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
Monopoly
A monopolist can make a profit, it can break even, or it can incur a loss.
12 - 23
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 24
A Monopolist Making a
Profit,
Fig. 12-3, p 261
MC
Price
ATC
P
M
C
M
Profit
A
B
0 Q
M
MR
D
Quantity
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 25
A Monopolist Breaking Even,
Fig. 12-4a, p 262
MC
Price
ATC
P
M
0 Q
M
MR
D
Quantity
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 26
A Monopolist Making a Loss
Fig. 12-4b, p 262
MC
Price
C
M
P
M
Loss
B
A
ATC
0 Q
M
MR
D
Quantity
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 27
The Welfare Loss from
Monopoly
A single price monopoly creates welfare losses.
Welfare losses can be illustrated by the area of consumer and producer surplus that is lost due to smaller output produced, compared to output produced in perfect competition.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 28
The Welfare Loss from
Monopoly
Compare the normal monopolist's equilibrium to the equilibrium of a perfect competitor.
Equilibrium in both market structures is determined by the MC = MR condition.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
The Welfare Loss from
Monopoly
But the monopolist's MR is below its price, thus its equilibrium output is different from a competitive market.
The welfare loss of a monopolist is represented by the triangles B and D .
12 - 29
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 30
The Welfare Loss from
Monopoly,
Fig. 12-5, p 262
Price
MC
P
M
C
P
C
0
D
B
Q
M
A
MR
Q
C
D
Quantity
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 31
The Welfare Loss from
Monopoly
Welfare loss is often called the deadweight loss or welfare loss triangle.
It is the geometric representation of the welfare cost in terms of misallocated resources that are caused by monopoly.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
The Price-Discriminating
Monopolist
Price discrimination is the ability to charge different prices to different customers.
12 - 32
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
The Price-Discriminating
Monopolist
In order to price discriminate, a monopolist must be able to:
Identify groups of customers who have different elasticities of demand;
Separate them in some way; and
Limit their ability to resell its product between groups.
12 - 33
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
The Price-Discriminating
Monopolist
A price-discriminating monopolist can charge customers with more inelastic demands a higher price.
It can charge customers with more elastic demands a lower price.
12 - 34
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 35
The Price-Discriminating
Monopolist
A perfect price discriminating monopoly can extract the most consumers are willing to pay for each unit of the product it sells.
All consumer surplus is transferred to the monopolist.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 36
The Price-Discriminating
Monopolist
A perfect price discriminating monopoly will stop expanding its output when MR
= MC, which corresponds to the perfectly competitive output.
The deadweight loss is therefore eliminated under perfect price discrimination.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 37
Perfect Price Discrimination,
Fig. 12-6, p 265
Price
4
3
6
5
10
9
8
7
2
1
MC
D=MR
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11
MR
Quantity (number of consumers)
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 38
Barriers to Entry and
Monopoly
What prevents other firms from entering the monopolist’s market in response to profits the monopolist earns?
Monopolies exist because of barriers to entry .
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 39
Barriers to Entry and
Monopoly
In the absence of barriers to entry, the monopoly would face competition from other firms, which would erode its monopoly position .
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
Barriers to Entry and
Monopoly
Some important barriers to entry are:
Economies of scale,
Set-up costs,
Legislation.
12 - 40
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 41
Barriers to Entry and
Monopoly
Economies of scale:
When production is characterized by increasing returns to scale, the larger the firm becomes, the lower its per unit costs become.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 42
Barriers to Entry and
Monopoly
Economies of scale:
If significant economies of scale are possible, it is inefficient to have two producers because if each produced half of the output, neither could take advantage of economies of scale.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 43
Barriers to Entry and
Monopoly
Economies of scale:
A natural monopoly is an industry in which one firm can produce at a lower cost than can two or more firms.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 44
Barriers to Entry and
Monopoly
Economies of scale:
In cases of natural monopoly, technology is such that minimum efficient scale is so large that average total costs fall within the range of potential output.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 45
A Natural Monopoly,
Fig. 12-7b, p 267
Price, Cost
P
M
C
M
C
C
P
C
Q
M
MR
ATC
MC
Q
C
D Quantity
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 46
Barriers to Entry and
Monopoly
Set-up costs:
In many industries high set-up costs characterize production.
The industry may be highly capitalintensive, requiring a large investment in expensive but highly specialized capital.
Examples are an oil refinery or a diamond mine.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 47
Barriers to Entry and
Monopoly
Set-up costs:
In some industries a lot of money may be spent on advertising.
Heavy advertising creates a barrier to entry in those cases, such as in the perfume industry or the automobile industry.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
Barriers to Entry and
Monopoly
Legislation:
Monopolies can also exist as a result of government charter.
Patents are another way in which government can grant a company a monopoly.
12 - 48
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 49
Barriers to Entry and
Monopoly
Legislation:
A patent is a legal protection of technical innovation that gives the inventor a monopoly on using the invention.
To encourage research and development of new products, government gives out patents for a wide variety of innovations.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
12 - 50
Barriers to Entry and
Monopoly
Other barriers to entry:
Sometimes one company can gain ownership of some essential aspect of the production process – a unique input, or control over a resource.
An example is DeBeers. By controlling the world-wide distribution network for diamonds, the company enjoys monopoly in the diamond industry.
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.
Monopoly
© 2003 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited.