Agricultural Issues Center University of California August 2005 DRAFT Money-Back Guarantees and the Value of Decision Time: An Empirical Analysis Amir Heiman, David R. Just, Bruce McWilliams, and David Zilberman August 2005 Draft Paper Amir Heiman is Senior Lecturer of Marketing, Faculty of Agriculture, Food and Environmental Science, The Hebrew University of Jerusalem, Rehovot 76100, Israel (email: heiman@agri.huji.ac.il). David R. Just is Assistant Professor of Applied Economics and Management, Cornell University, Ithaca, NY 14853 (e-mail: drj3@cornell.edu). Bruce McWilliams is Assistant Professor of Marketing, Insitituto Technologico Autonomo de Mexico (ITAM), Rio Hondo, No. 1, Col. Tizapan San Angel, Mexico, D.F. 01000 (e-mail: bruce@itam.mx). David Zilberman is Professor of Agricultural and Resource Economics and Member of the Giannini Foundation of Agricultural Economics, University of California, Berkeley, CA 94720 (e-mail: zilber@are.berkeley.edu). Supported in part by the Agricultural Marketing Resource Center Draft Money-Back Guarantees and the Value of Decision Time: An Empirical Analysis* Amir Heiman, David R. Just, Bruce McWilliams, and David Zilberman Amir Heiman is Senior Lecturer of Marketing, Faculty of Agriculture, Food and Environmental Science, The Hebrew University of Jerusalem, Rehovot 76100, Israel (email: heiman@agri.huji.ac.il). David R. Just is Assistant Professor of Applied Economics and Management, Cornell University, Ithaca, NY 14853 (e-mail: drj3@cornell.edu). Bruce McWilliams is Assistant Professor of Marketing, Insitituto Technologico Autonomo de Mexico (ITAM), Rio Hondo, No. 1, Col. Tizapan San Angel, Mexico, D.F. 01000 (e-mail: bruce@itam.mx). David Zilberman is Professor of Agricultural and Resource Economics and Member of the Giannini Foundation of Agricultural Economics, University of California, Berkeley, CA 94720 (e-mail: zilber@are.berkeley.edu). *The authors acknowledge support from AgMRC for their financial support of this research. Draft Money-Back Guarantees and the Value of Decision Time: An Empirical Analysis Abstract This paper uses the disappointment aversion and prospect theory to estimate consumers’ valuation of basic 30-day money-back guarantees (MBGs). We test how this valuation changes when the duration of MBGs vary, risk increases (store versus catalog), and return options change (store credit versus cash back) using data collected in Northern California. Our results confirm that individuals do not evaluate MBGs using expected benefit calculations but rather amplify its value similar to disappointment and regret anticipation effects. 3 Draft Money-Back Guarantees and the Value of Decision Time: An Empirical Analysis Tonning (1956) provides evidence of the earliest known money-back guarantee (MBG) used in 1777 by a food manufacturer. Research on returns, or MBGs, is much more recent, covering only the last 30 years. The research on MBGs has been mostly theoretical and based on the assumption of one type of full return: a 30-day MBG. We hope to provide empirical answers to two fundamental questions: What is the willingness to pay (WTP) for an MBG? And what is the incremental WTP for an MBG with extended duration? We model MBGs as a put option, where the buyer can return the item and receive a full refund. Throughout the life of the option, and beyond, the consumer faces risk as to whether the item will be useful to the consumer or not, which we call fit risk. We develop a modeling framework to address fit risk incorporating elements of Kahneman and Tversky’s (K&T 1979) (and Tversky and Kahneman’s 1992) prospect theory model of loss aversion into our option-value model. Our model assumes that individuals engage in framing, classifying the return of a product with a refund of money as a loss. In addition to the cost and hassle of returning a product, consumers experience additional costs of returning a product due to disappointment or a feeling of loss resulting in an aversion to returning a product. Finally, individuals weight probabilities of return or fit of a product in a fashion similar to cumulative prospect theory. Using data collected in Northern California, we test our model for consistency with consumer behavior. Consistent with the option theory of MBGs, we find that consumers’ valuation of MBGs depends heavily on the duration of the MBG agreement. 4 Draft Consumers value return agreements for store credit significantly less than MBGs. Further, we find that the data are highly consistent with loss-averse behavior. In fact, the magnitude of the valuations seems only to be consistent with some cost of disappointment from discovering a nonfit. Our analysis suggests that standard 30-day MBGs are evaluated by purchasers to be worth 25% of the price of a good. This premium appears to be outside of the reasonable range of valuation if calculations are held assuming that consumers valuate risky choices using the expected payoff notation. However, the phenomenon known as loss aversion (or related phenomena), if taken into account, results in a concise and reasonable explanation for this (over-)valuation of MBGs. The length of an MBG plays a significant role in the valuation of MBGs. Products sold with store credit guarantees (SCGs), which are a limited form of MBGs in which the consumer receives a refund of store credit rather than cash, are valued at nearly 10% less than MBG products. THE CURRENT LITERATURE ON MBGs One of the distinctive features of U.S. retailing is its extensive use of postpurchase guarantees, which include extended warranties, price guarantees, and varying return guarantees. The different post-purchase guarantees reduce the pre-purchase uncertainty resulting from various sources and differ in many aspects, such as duration, what events are covered, and how these events are compensated. These post-purchase guarantees share the same basic goal of reducing uncertainty. There is a natural overlap between the tools, each having its own distinct features. Warranties provide a guarantee for durability and performance, but they do not resolve price and fit uncertainty. Price and fit uncertainty are addressed by MBGs. Warranties and MBGs overlap during the 5 Draft period of MBG coverage since, with MBGs, the most comprehensive guarantee, the product can be returned for any reason, including mechanical failure for a limited duration. While the subject of duration in warranties has been studied (Blair and Innis 1996), little is known about the effect of duration of MBGs on consumer behavior. One of the goals of this study is to explore consumers’ valuation of the duration of MBGs using the concept of real-option pricing, which was first applied to MBGs in Heiman, McWilliams, and Zilberman (2001). MBGs and other return policies are natural substitutes, where MBGs offer a wider coverage, thereby increasing the possibility of moral hazard, and possibly imposing higher costs on retailers than alternative policies. The tradeoff between MBGs and returns for replacement with an identical item is discussed in Mann and Wissinik (1990), who focus on moral hazard issues. Another form of return is the store credit guarantee (SCG,) in which the relationship with MBGs has not been addressed. MBGs dominate price guarantees that provide only limited protection against the uncertainty of finding a retailer who sells the product for less. Researchers have proposed various purposes for offering low price guarantees. Most of the literature explores the influence of this tool on price strategy and its impact on the market for the purposes of price collusion and discouraging price competition (see Chatterjee, Heath, and Basuroy 2003; Edlin and Emch 1999; Logan and Lutter 1989) or on the ability to price discriminate between informed and uninformed buyers (Png and Hirshleifer 1987). Others examine the possibility of using price guarantees to signal low prices to consumers (Jain and Srivastava 2000). Alternatively, Inman, Dyer, and Jia (1997) study price guarantees as a mechanism that decreases the likelihood of regret from having 6 Draft chosen the wrong store. In this paper, we expand the notion of post-purchase regret to the context of MBGs. MBGs have been treated in the literature mainly as a signal of quality. Heal (1977) modeled MBGs as a signal for product quality, and Moorthy and Srinivasan (1995) as a signal for retailers’ quality of services. In this paper we adopt the view of Davis, Gerstner, and Hagerty (1995) that MBGs are mainly tools that enable buyers to experience the product before a final purchasing decision has been made. We ignore any aspect of quality signaling, which may play a lesser role after gaining some experience with brands or stores. Surprisingly none of the above studies on MBGs supported their arguments with empirical analysis (such as a consumer survey). Thus, we are still unaware of the basics of MBGs, e.g., what is the consumer valuation of an MBG, and how is this valuation affected by the duration of MBGs? This paper will provide an estimation of consumers’ valuation of MBGs in purchases of everyday clothing, and show how this valuation changes as the duration of the MBG option varies as well as when MBGs are replaced by SCGs. We also estimate the difference in valuation of MBGs between in-store and catalog purchases. Several studies have noted significant differences in purchasing behavior when consumers shop in stores versus through catalogs or the Internet (Bult and Wansbeek 1995; Jasper and Ouellete 1994; Van den Poel and Leunis 1999; Voss, Parasuraman, and Dhruv 1998). Here we build on this body of literature focusing on the context of an MBG contract of fixed duration. We analyze consumers’ valuation of alternative MBG arrangements within a modeling framework that builds on K&T’s prospect theory (1979). In particular, we (1) 7 Draft incorporate the notion of loss aversion (Thaler 1980) and assume that individuals place extra emphasis on avoiding losses when synthesizing value, and (2) frame the risky choices within a context, relative to an existing reference point. K&T (1979) and Thaler (1985) established the concept of loss aversion with results of experimental studies where individuals were asked to choose among lotteries. Here we assess loss aversion from data on individuals’ WTP (or accept) for better (or worse) MBG terms. Loss aversion is interpreted here as the extra cost (above product price) of being disappointed by a product that does not fit. A longer MBG contract reduces the probability of being stuck with a product as a result of a bad decision. A related concept is disappointment aversion, introduced by Bell (1982) and modified by Gul (1991), whereby individuals avoid the possibility of outcomes that fail to meet their expectations. Within the field of marketing, anticipation of regret is credited with causing consumers to buy items currently on sale, rather than wait for other more desirable items, and to buy more well-known brands (Simonson 1992). In addition to the exaggeration of losses, loss aversion also implies a systematic misperception of probabilities. It is generally found that individuals exaggerate small probabilities, and underemphasize near certainties when making decisions. This is particularly important in the context of returns, which are by nature a low probability event for most purchases. We use data collected in the San Francisco Bay area in California to estimate consumers’ valuation of an MBG and changes in valuation as the duration of the MBG increases or decreases, the form of compensation (money or store credit), and whether purchases are ordered through catalogs or bought at stores. In addition to estimating valuations of various features of MBGs using standard procedures with the data set, we 8 Draft use the data to assess the consistency of individual choices with our theoretical predictions. In the next section we explore the existing literature on MBGs. We then outline a mathematical model of MBG valuation. In the remainder of the paper, we describe our survey data and discuss the estimation results. THE MODEL Suppose a consumer is considering the purchase of a product, the value of which is unknown to the buyer. The consumer may be concerned with whether the product will fit her lifestyle or particular need. For example, a consumer shopping for an item of clothing may not be certain if it goes well with her other clothes. She may want to receive some feedback from friends before making a final assessment. The assessment of fit takes time, and the buyer may want to learn the properties of the new product and how it fits this idiosyncratic need. When buyers purchase a product without an MBG and find that it does not fit their needs, they lose money and also suffer from the disappointment of a failed choice. MBGs provide a return option within a given period of time. Let the price of the product with an MBG of duration t be denoted by Pt . The MBG allows the individual to avoid the loss of the price paid for the product and the associated disappointment. Yet, the buyer must still incur the cost of return, denoted by RC, and gets back the initial price. For simplicity, we assume that the return costs do not vary with the MBG duration (the time spent to return the product is the same no matter how long you have owned the product).1 1 Heiman et al. (2002) develop a model where return costs vary with the MBG duration. Applying their model here will add much complexity and provides little insight. 9 Draft We will consider three outcomes resulting from the purchase of a product with an MBG. • Fit: The buyer discovers that the product fits her needs and benefits from it. • Return: The buyer discovers that the product does not fit her needs during the guarantee period and returns it. • Stuck: The buyer discovers that the product does not fit after the MBG expires.2 We assume that the consumer knows the probabilities of these outcomes under various MBG arrangements. Let the probability of fit be denoted by FP, and let RPt denote the probability of return (RP) for an MBG contract with a duration of t days. This is the probability that the consumer discovers that the product does not fit his/her needs within the MBG coverage period. The probability of being stuck with an unfit product after the MBG expires is SPt = 1 ! RPt ! FP . We adopt elements of prospect theory and the disappointment aversion literature to assess two issues that are crucial for our empirical analysis: (1) The amount that consumers will be willing to pay (or receive) for extension (reduction) of the length of the MBG return period, and (2) the parameters that will lead a consumer to buy a product with an MBG of a specific duration. Following K&T (1979), we will assume that when consumers assess a new prospect with or without MBGs, they (1) simplify their choices; (2) evaluate new alternatives relative to a benchmark (reference point) reflecting initial opportunities and treat gains and losses differently; and (3) evaluate probabilities according to a probability weighting function " (#):[0,1] $ [0,1] , representing the systematic distortion of probabilities as perceived by ! 10 Draft the decision maker. While these are not subjective probabilities per se, individuals behave as if the value of the probability weights were the true probabilities. Hence, for convenience of discussing the effects of probability weighting, we will refer to " as perceived probability. According to K&T (1979), the perceived probability increases with p, small probabilities are overestimated, large probabilities are underestimated, and the sum of perceived probabilities may be smaller than 1. Thus, "' ( p) > 0 , and that for p ( ) ( ) ( ) ( ) less than some p , ! p > p , ! '' p < 0 , and ! p < p , ! '' p > 0 otherwise. For the sake of this paper, we will assume that the point p such that " ( p) = p is larger than RP (according to most estimates this should be true on average; see, for example, Wakker 1994). To assess the value of change in the MBG duration, let t0 denote the duration of a baseline MBG arrangement. Heiman et al. (2002) provide evidence that a 30-day MBG is the most common option in the United States; thus, we set this as our reference point in the empirical application. The price of the product with this MBG duration is Pt . Let 0 !Pt denote the change in the product price associated with a change in the MBG period t 0 ! from t0 to t. Let !RPtt denote the change in the RP as the duration of MBG is changed 0 from t0 to t. A longer return period (t > t0 ) is likely to result in a larger return probability ! ( !RP !tt > 0) and likely to lead to a higher price ( !Pt > 0). The higher return probability t0 0 will reduce the probability that the consumer will be stuck with the unfit product (the ! 2 We assume implicitly that it is worthwhile for the buyer not to return the good at the end of the MBG period before the extent of fit is resolved. The expected gain from discovery of fit is assumed to dominate the cost of loss because of unfit. 11 Draft change in probability is denoted by !SPtt and !SPtt = "!RPtt ). The consumer may lose 0 0 0 RC when discovering that the product is unfit, but she may still feel fortunate not to suffer the loss of the entire investment and be stuck with the unwanted product, as would occur once the MBG expires. When the MBG expires and the product does not fit, the consumer incurs extra costs reflecting loss aversion (K&T 1979) or disappointment aversion (Gul 1991). Let LC denote this extra cost of loss when the buyer is stuck with the unfit product. A marginal increase in RP will decrease the value of the purchase proportional to RC, but, through the associated marginal decline in SP, will also increase the value proportional to Pt + LC . The overall net effect of a marginal increase of RP is 0 proportional to Pt + LC ! RC . 0 Thus, the overall effect of a change in value accompanying a change of the length of the MBG duration is denoted by "NBtt = "# (RP) tt (Pt0 + LC $ RC) $ "Pt # (1 $ RPt0 ) . 0 0 t0 The consumer will prefer the new MBG arrangement if !NBtt " 0. The price 0 change that will make the consumer indifferent to a change in the MBG duration is (1) "Pt = t0 "# ( RP)tt (Pt0 + LC $ RC) 0 . # (1$ RPt ) 0 Equation (1) suggests that the maximal (minimal) amount that consumers will be willing to pay (receive) for longer (shorter) MBGs is a product of the increase (reduction) in the RP and the gain from returning an unfit product divided by the reference probability of either having a fit product or getting stuck with an unfit one. 12 Draft To illustrate the order of magnitude of the change in price, let us consider the case where the reference price of the product is $40 and the return period is 30 days. Now ( ) suppose the perceived RP under the initial arrangement, " RPt 0 , is 10% and assume that longer return periods (say, 60 days) will increase the perceived RP, "# (RP) tt , by 0 ( ) 3%. Suppose for now that the perceived probability of retaining the item, " 1# RPt 0 , is 75% (often it is assumed that " is sub-additive, or " ( p) + " (1# p) < 1 , reflecting a sort of aversion to uncertainty). If the return cost is $5.00 and the loss aversion cost is $15, then the extra amount one will be willing to pay is $2.00 (e.g., .03 x 50/.75 = 2.00). The minimum discount the consumer will demand for eliminating the MBG is $6.67 (e.g., .10 x 50/.75). Alternatively, LC and the weighting function can significantly alter the WTP for longer MBGs. For example, if LC = $30, then the extra amount the consumer will pay for the extra MBG is $2.60 (e.g., .03 x 65/.75). One of the main purposes of our empirical analysis is to estimate the order of magnitude of loss aversion. From equation (1), we can derive several hypotheses about WTP for MBGs. It is plausible to assume that the perceived probability of discovery that the product is unfit and returning the product increases with the duration of the return period, but the ! marginal effect declines, i.e., "# $ (RP) t / "t > 0, " 2 #( RP) t / "t 2 < 0. Using these t0 t0 assumptions and equation (1) suggests: ! Hypothesis 1 (Positive value of expanded MBG duration). Marginal increase in the length of the return period increases the price of the product with an MBG. "#P t / "t > 0. t0 13 Draft Hypothesis 2 (Decreasing marginal value of MBG duration). This marginal increase in price declines for longer return periods. ! 2 "Ptt / ! t 2 < 0 . 0 Since t may be negative, the first hypothesis implies that a shorter MBG duration will reduce the price the consumer will be willing to pay for a product, and the second hypothesis suggests that the marginal reduction in the value of the product increases as the guarantee duration decreases. One of the implications of Hypothesis 2 is that the WTP for an MBG arrangement that is t days longer than the base arrangement is smaller than the willingness to accept (WTA) for an MBG that is t days shorter than the base MBG. This form of WTP < WTA is the result of the declining marginal probability of discovery and return of a nonfit as duration increases. MBGs may exist in various forms. Our first two hypotheses apply to cases where buyers at a brick and mortar store receive money when returning an item. We also consider other situations. The first is bundling the return with purchases in the same retailing establishment, i.e., store credit. The second is MBGs for remote purchases (mail order, catalog, telephone, or online), which are referred to as catalog purchases. Store credit MBG option. Let PtSC denote the price consumers will be willing to 0 pay for the purchase of a good with a t 0 return period where the consumers receive store credit equivalent to the price of the product upon returning the product. The difference between store credit and cash MBG is that, in the event of return, the buyer gets store credit instead of cash. Let sc(Pt ) < Pt denote the consumer’s valuation of the store credit 0 0 received for a product with price Pt . A store credit limits the buyer’s choice to shop 0 relative to a more general MBG. 14 Draft Hypothesis 3(Store credit < cash). Consumers value store credit less than cash, the difference being given by "PtSC /C = PtSC # Pt = $ ( RPt )(sc(Pt ) # Pt ) < 0 . (2) MBG and catalog purchases. Buying via catalogs reduces search and purchase costs and increases available choices. However, purchases are riskier as buyers are not able to inspect and try the products before purchase. We will add ca to the appropriate variables to denote purchasing from catalogs. Thus, we assume (1) the probability of fit (and thus perceived probability of fit) for catalog purchases is smaller than for store purchase, i.e., FPca < FP , (2) the return probability for catalog purchases is higher than for store purchase, i.e., RPt " RPcat , and (3) the changes in perceived return probabilities in any time period is likely to be greater for catalog purchases than store purchase, i.e., t t "# (RP) t2 < " # (PRca)t 2 . It is important to remember that the weighting function is 1 1 concave over this region, and RPt " RPcat . Thus, in order for t t t "# (RP) t2 < " # (PRca)t 2 to hold, it must be the case that "PRcat 2 is significantly 1 1 1 t larger than "RPt 2 (enough to overcome the concavity of weighting). Equation (1) is 1 modified to derive the change in price that makes consumers indifferent to a change in the duration of MBG contract in the case of catalogs to be (3) "Pcat = t0 "# ( RPca)tt (Pcat0 + LCca $ RCca) 0 . #(1$ RPcat ) 0 Since we assume that perceived RP and changes in the perceived RP are larger with catalog purchases than store purchases, return probability considerations will cause the price of the products purchased through catalogs to be more responsive to changes in 15 Draft MBG duration than the price of products purchased in stores. Consider the case where Pcat0 = Pt0 and assume that LCca ! RCca is approximately equal to LC ! RC . Hypothesis 4 (MBG catalog >MBG store). Consumer valuations change more in response to changes in the duration of the MBG of products purchased through catalogs than those in stores. Namely, !Pcatt > !Ptt for!t > t 0 :!!Pcatt < !Ptt for!t < t 0 . 0 0 0 0 Our data contain information on consumers’ WTP for extending the MBG duration and their WTA for reducing the MBG duration of a product. We will use these data to assess the consistency of individual choices with Hypotheses 1-4. Our data also contain respondents’ recall of their historical RP. We will investigate whether differences in the average RP among individuals will affect their valuation of changes in MBGs. First, we derive hypotheses regarding the behavior of d!Pt / d RP under various t0 durations and conditions of the MBG arrangements, using equation (1) and assumptions about the relationships between the variables we observe, the stated average RP, which we denote RP , and variables that affect !Pt . t0 We assume that shoppers vary according to their shopping imprecision (denoted by SI) and their loss aversion (LC). 3 Among individuals with the same LC, less precise shoppers (with higher SI) have a: (1) higher average RP, ! RP/ !SI > 0 , (2) higher RP for any MBG duration, and in particular for the baseline duration, !RPt / ! SI > 0 , and (3) 0 are more responsive to changes in the duration of the MBG, " #RPt0 / "SI > 0 where is absolute value. These assumptions suggest that under plausible conditions, shoppers with 16 Draft higher average RP are likely to have higher RP with the base MBG duration, !RPt / ! RP > 0 , and larger changes in RP in response to changes in the MBG duration (a 0 larger increase in their perceived RP if the MBG duration is increasing and a larger decline if the MBG duration gets shorter), so that "#$ ( RP)tt / "RP < (> )0 for t > (< )0 . (4) 0 Our second assumption is that shoppers face products with varying fit risk and will not buy a product if the expected benefits of the purchase are not positive. If all consumers have the same perception function, shoppers with lower loss aversion (smaller LC) will buy more risky products (higher probability of a nonfit, and thus a higher RP), as the positive benefit constraint is relaxed. The effect of changes in loss aversion on the positive benefit constraint is especially strong for high levels of loss aversion. Thus, we expect to find an inverse and concave relationship between the average RP, RP , and loss aversion, LC. Thus, we suppose (see Heiman et al. 2005 for a more detailed treatment): (5) 0! "LC "RP ; 0! " 2 LC "RP 2 . To assess the impact of changes in average RP on the value of changes in MBG duration, we differentiate (1) to obtain !"Pt (6) t0 !RP ! % "# RP ' = & t / # (1 $ RP) ( *) (Pt + LC $ RC) + "# RP 0 !RP ( )t t ( )t 0 0 !LC !RP . The assumptions represented by (4) suggest that the first element in the left-hand side of (6) is positive, representing the shopper’s “imprecision” effect. Namely, the 3 Differences in return costs are assumed to be relatively less important than loss costs. 17 Draft higher average RP reflects higher imprecision which induces increased (reduced) RP when the MBG duration is increased (decreased) which, in turn, contributes to increased WTP for longer MBG duration (and reduced WTA compensation for shorter MBG duration). The second element of the right-hand side of (6) represents the loss aversion effect of an increase in the average RP. The nonpositive relationship between average RP and loss aversion, represented in (6), suggests that the impact of disappointment is likely to become increasingly negative as the average RP increases. Since the shopper’s imprecision effect is positive (for increases in the MBG duration) for all levels of RP and due to the negative effect of the loss aversion actually growing for larger levels of RP, !Pt is likely to be a nonlinear function of the average RP, which we approximate using t0 a quadratic function. Hypothesis 5: The WTP for longer duration MBGs, "Pt if t > t0 is t0 approximately an increasing concave function of the average RP. The WTA for a reduction in the MBG duration, "#P t if t < t0 , is approximately an increasing convex t0 function of the average RP, i.e., (7) !Pt ah + bh RP "ch RP 2 if t > t0 and !Pt al " bl RP +cl RP 2 if t > t0 , t0 t0 where ah " 0,bh " 0,c h " 0,and al # 0,bl " 0,c l " 0 . DATA AND ESTIMATION In order to test the five hypotheses presented in the previous section, we used a survey that was conducted between November and December, 2000. Respondents were 18 Draft randomly chosen at various shopping malls in Northern California and were instructed to assess their personal value of an item purchased with varying MBGs. On average, the survey took about 10 minutes to complete. Of the 220 consumers interviewed, 48% were male and 52% were female. The average age of respondents was 27, with 16 of them below the age of 18. The oldest respondent was 76 years old. The baseline MBG option was a 30-day MBG on a $40 item of clothing (shirt). We asked for the discount required for no MBGs and for a 7-day MBG on the same article of clothing, and the amount of money compensation they require to switch from a 30-day MBG to a 30-day SCG. We also asked for the individual’s WTP for a 60-day and infinite-length MBG. These same questions were repeated for a $40 item of clothing (shirt) ordered from a catalog. Individuals were asked to estimate the percentage of clothing purchases they return (in store and through catalogs) during the last year. Respondents on average demand a $10.43 discount to buy the $40 shirt that would otherwise be offered with a 30-day guarantee, without any guarantee. At 25% of the original product price, this assessment seems high. However, there is anecdotal evidence leading us to believe that individuals are willing to pay high prices for guarantees. Table 1 contains several examples of price differences in similar products that may be due to differences in MBGs. In all cases we find large price differences for very similar (if not identical products). In each case the MBG terms are very different and may provide an explanation for at least part of the price difference. Although we have attempted to use examples of stores with similar reputation and target customers, there are always other explanations for these price differences. Other evidence can be found during sales promotion. When items go on sale, they are typically discounted between 19 Draft 25% and 50%, and the MBG is eliminated. In this natural setting, consumers are used to being compensated at least 25% for eliminating the MBG. In support of our survey results, consumers are willing to pay very different amounts for nearly identical items differing only in the MBG agreement. The percentage of clothing items returned in stores (10.13% on average) and through catalogs (18.63% on average) is similar to that reported in the professional literature. We find that 16% of respondents report never having returned an item. The literature reports the average percent of catalog purchases that are returned is 5%, but there is a large variance between differences in product categories and customers. Most of the customers (67%) return less than 5% (Del Franco 2000a), but the return rate for first-time online shoppers can reach 35% (Del Franco 2000b). The categories of goods with the lowest return rates include CDs and books at 2%-5%. Shoes have return rates of 10%-25%, clothing 10%-20%, and tailored apparel an astounding 30% (Catalog Age 2002; Del Franco 2000a). In the latter category (apparel), returns of fitted (high fashion, designer dresses) is more than double that for casual apparel and can reach 40% for some items. A higher price is probably an additional motivation for making returns in apparel. The most common reasons for return are wrong size and color (Catalog Age 2002). These figures are very close to online returns as reported by Quick (2000), who indicated a 30% return rate in apparel, 20% in shoes, and 15% in jewelry. Figure 1 displays the great heterogeneity of behavior within our sample with respect to average RP. While the largest group returns fewer than 5% of their clothing purchases, there are still a significant number that return more than 20% of their clothing purchases. Similarly, we find significant heterogeneity in the discount required when no 20 Draft MBG is offered. While 6% of shoppers value the MBG at less than $5.00, more than 50% demanded a discount that was above $10. Such diversity underlines the notion that individuals may have very different abilities to predict fit, and adjust purchasing behavior when MBGs are altered. The discounts demanded by respondents for eliminating the MBG entirely were quite heterogeneous. The average consumer demanded $14.96 off a $40 item if there were to be no MBG, with a standard deviation of $13.56 (with 220 responses). The modal response was $0, with 47 observations, the next most frequent response demanded a $10 discount with 40 observations. Responses were highly variable with nearly every whole number between 0 and 15 represented. The maximum response was $40, suggesting that individuals would not be willing to pay anything for the shirt if the MBG were not offered. Testing for Behavioral Consistency There is a large literature documenting the failure of expected utility models, and other models of rational behavior (see Camerer 1995 for a review). For this reason, it is necessary to test our data for all available signs of consistency with our model’s predictions. If the data suggest that individuals are not behaving according to our model, it may be that individuals largely use MBGs as a simple signal and pay little attention to details such as length or conditions under which the MBG is offered. Because Hypotheses 1 through 4 are not conditional on the parameters of the model, it is possible to test these hypotheses without estimating (1). While we appeal to the specific model to justify our hypotheses, our hypotheses are stated in terms of comparing valuation to time. 21 Draft Hence, the general nature of our hypotheses allows us to investigate their truth without the use of data more specific to our model. For each individual, we have recorded changes in WTP !MBG300 , !MBG307 , log , for both in-store and catalog purchases, where the !MBG3060 , !MBG30" , !MBGtt ,cata ,store comparison group is the 30-day MBG (and, hence, !P3030 = 0 ). This information allows us to construct data on the slope of each segment. We can then check directly for violations of the four hypotheses, and use classical hypothesis testing to check for significant violations. Let Si j = !MBGi j . Then the hypotheses discussed earlier imply the following: t Hypothesis 1 (Positive Value of Time): !Pt j for all j > i. i ( ) < 0. t Hypothesis 2 (Decreasing Marginal Value of Time): ! "Pt j i !t t ,SC Hypothesis 3 (Store Credit Discount): "Pt,cash # 0 . t ,cata log Hypothesis 4 (Store versus Catalog): "Pt,store >0. K&T (1979) (among others) have noted that individuals tend to depress WTP and inflate WTA when answering survey questions. This may cause Hypothesis 2 to appear to be true, even if it is not, if we compare only line segments left of 30 days to those right of 30 days. The test we construct here overcomes this problem by also comparing different line segments on the same side of the 30-day MBG (from 0 to 7, 7 to 30, 30 to 60, and 60 to infinity). For the case of the infinite-length MBG, it is impossible to construct a slope. However, if the segment between 30 days and 60 days has positive slope, then a finite value for the infinite length MBG implies concavity. In the spirit of Camerer’s (1989) tests of models of risk and uncertainty, we examine the primary testable hypotheses of 22 Draft our model using individual data. Table 2 displays the number of violations and number of possible violations for each hypothesis. While the table shows that a significant number of individuals (37%) violate the hypotheses at least once, the violations occur less than 8% of the time. It would be hard to reject the notion that these violations were occurring due to idiosyncratic errors. By regressing the slope parameters on a constant, it is possible to test these hypotheses using traditional hypothesis testing. We employ a regression structure rather than direct means tests to take advantage of the correlated error structure from survey data. Hence, we employ Zellner’s Seemingly Unrelated Regression (SUR) technique in estimating the means. Results of this estimation appear in Table 3. We can test Hypotheses 1 through 4 by jointly testing all restrictions included in each individual hypothesis for rejection. However, this test holds little power and, indeed, cannot be rejected for any of our hypotheses. A more powerful method is to test independently for each possible failure, maintaining failure as the null hypothesis. Hypothesis 1 (Positive value of MBG duration) To test Hypothesis 1, we need only independently test the hypotheses that the marginal value of MBG duration is declining between each individual duration (both instore and using a catalog). From the results in Table 3, it is obvious that we can reject a negative slope for each possible line segment at any reasonable level of confidence (tvalues of 10.08, 10.33, 4.28, 7.72, 10.33, 12.69, 4.79, and 6.79). Hypothesis 2 (Decreasing marginal value of MBG duration) To test Hypothesis 2, we construct the Wald statistic for each of the consecutive segments, with null hypothesis Si j < S kl for j < k (implying an increasing slope). A test 23 Draft that the value of the infinite length MBG is not of infinite value is not interesting. This test produces the test statistics F(1, 1630): 32.93, 65.24, 23.69, 109.02. All of these reject at any reasonable level of significance. Hypothesis 3 (Store credit < cash) This hypothesis may be tested by using a null hypothesis that the value of the SCG is greater than the 30-day MBG. From Table 3, it can be seen that these tests are easily rejected for both in-store and catalog purchases at any level of significance (tvalues of 8.871, 11.256). Hypothesis 4 (MBG catalog > MBG store) Hypotheses 4 and 4A may be tested again using the Wald statistic to see if the null hypothesis of Si j > C Si j for all j > i can be rejected. This test produces F(1,1630) statistics of 1.02, 19.33, 1.54, and .50 in order of line segments. These produce p-values of 0.16, 0.00, 0.10, and 0.24, respectively. Hence, while there is some support for this claim, it is not as well supported by the data as are the other three hypotheses. In particular, this may not hold for very short or very long MBGs. HETEROGENEITY AND THE EFFECT OF DISAPPOINTMENT To test Hypothesis 5 requires estimation of the relationship between RP and the WTP/WTA for various length MBGs. Estimation in the previous section determines the average value of a day over different lengths of MBGs ($0.67 per day for the first seven days, $0.25 for the next 23, and $.07 for the next 30 days). In this section we wish to outline how heterogeneous buyers can have differing valuations. We approximate the relationship in equations (6) and (7) using the following form 24 Draft (8) !P30t = & t $0,7,60,% (" + " t RPt 2 ) 2 RP # t + " SCG# SCG + " + RP # t >30 + " ' RP # t (30 , where ! t is a dummy variable taking on the value 1 if the MBG duration is equal to t , and ! SCG is a dummy representing a 30-day SCG. The coefficients ! + , ! " represent the quadratic effects of RP for longer and shorter MBGs, respectively. Table 4 reports the results of the regression. Due to the nature of heterogeneity in the sample, we report standard errors using White’s (1980) consistent correction. The results in the table largely confirm Hypothesis 5. First, we find that the higher RP increases the WTP for longer MBGs (positive signs for RP, t = 60, ∞), and decreases WTA for shorter MBGs (negative signs for RP, t = 0, 7) and for SCGs. Further, we find that the relationship is significantly nonlinear, with WTP concave in RP for longer MBGs, and convex for shorter MBGs. This relationship is consistent with the prospect theory and notion of disappointment we have proposed earlier. Similar results hold for catalog purchases, with some important differences. First, in accordance with hypothesis 4, RP has a stronger interaction effect with duration on WTP for catalog purchases than with in-store purchases. However, this result only holds for shorter duration MBGs. On ! the contrary, the value of longer MBGs has less to do with RP for catalogs than in store. In fact, it appears the value of the MBG for a catalog purchase is lower for durations longer than 30 days. In other words, it appears the first few days of inspection are extremely important and valuable. The nature of risk with catalog purchases behaves somewhat differently however, resolving itself more quickly. This in itself seems a little strange and may reflect a different set of expectations from catalog purchases, thus altering the level of disappointment from a nonfit. The results from Table 4 can be can 25 Draft be combined with average reported RP (10.13% in store and 18.63% through catalog) to obtain the predicted value of various length MBGs. For example, the predicted WTA for no MBG is $10.90. Alternatively, an individual with RP of 5% would have a WTA of $10.30. Remarkably, it appears that the RP has little (yet still a significant) effect on the valuation of the MBG. This again highlights the poor ability of individuals to deal with probabilistic events, as they appear to only vaguely take account of the differences in likelihood that they will need to use the MBG. The effect of RP is somewhat larger for catalog purchases (here $12.11 vs. $12.98) but still reflects a very small impact. In calibrating the probability weighting function, K&T (1979) note that probabilities smaller than .3 tend to be overstated, in a way that would reduce the decline in perceived probability as true probability tends towards zero. Thus, this result is very similar to the prediction made by prospect theory. Table 5 contains predicted WTA and WTP amounts for the average return percentage. From the model, we can calculate both the implied loss cost for a given WTP/WTA and stated RP, as well as the change in RP over time. Equation (6) can be rearranged to find (9) LC " RC = #P t $ (1" RPt0 ) t0 # $ ( RP) tt " Pt0 . 0 If we let t = 0 , we know that " ( RP) t = #" ( RP) tt , and the stated RP. However, we 0 0 have not calibrated the probability weighting function. Other than the probability weight, all variables in the right-hand side of (9) are known. If we consider return cost to be ! negligible, and if we knew the probability weighting function, the calculation in (1) yields a reasonable gauge of the cost of disappointment aversion. Further, given our 26 Draft estimate of LC - RC , we can manipulate (6) to obtain an estimate of the change in RP over time. % # (1$ RPt ) ( 0 "RPtt = # $1' "P t + # RPt 0 * $ RPt 0 . 0 & (Pt0 + LC $ RC) t0 ) ( ) Table 6 contains estimates of both the loss cost and the RP over time predicted from our estimates for various RPs. Tables 6A and 6B show that loss cost can be substantial for the range of return probabilities found in our data. The results in the tables suggest that probability weighting must accompany loss aversion in any reasonable explanation of the ( ) survey responses. Table 6A assumes that no weighting takes place (i.e., ! p = p ), and Table 6B assumes the probability weighting function estimated in Tversky and Kahneman (1992), namely, & p# ( 1 if "Loss" ( # # # ( p + (1$ p) " + ( p,x ) = ' p% ( ( 1 if "Gain" % ( p% + (1$ p) % ) ( ) ( ) where they estimate g = 0.61 and d = 0.69. In our case, a return is considered a loss, while a fit is considered a gain. For the average range of RP from the survey (about 10%), the predicted loss costs are much more reasonable employing the weighting function, $5.30 instead of $58. The multiplicative nature of probability in the value of the option means that misperception in probability can greatly increase the option value of the MBG, while not substantially increasing the true RP. This makes MBGs an especially valuable tool to increase profits. 27 Draft CONCLUSION The importance of the MBG as a marketing tool is confirmed by their prevalence in American retailing. In this paper we attempt to outline factors affecting the value of MBGs and the size of these effects. These factors include the length of MBG, the ability to examine a product prior to purchase, conditions placed on the recovered purchase price, and the prior-return behavior. As well, we propose that many noted behavioral anomalies may have a potentially large impact on the perceived value of an MBG. We verify that the (1) length of an MBG, (2) aversion to loss, and (3) probability distortion all play a significant role in the valuation of MBGs. The results of our analysis display significant deviation from rational valuation. Our statistical analysis suggests that a MBG may be worth 25% of the value of a product on average. Because ex ante purchase values are systematically lower than ex post purchase values (due to loss aversion), it may be possible for store owners to extract this high value from the customer for purchase insurance. Table 6B suggests that for this sample, loss aversion may dominate other purchase risk considerations, inflating a modest cost of a nonfit. Individuals were asked to assess the value of an MBG for an article of clothing. Clothing seldom comes with a performance warranty like those offered with electronic equipment. One would expect an MBG to have a lower value if other marketing mechanisms were used to insure against product failure. Because the value of an MBG is increasing but concave in length, it stands to reason that there must be an optimal length MBG for a particular marketer. Various factors may affect this optimal length. We have found that higher income individuals are willing to pay more for longer MBGs. This may explain why some high-end stores (for example, Nordstrom’s) offer lifetime MBGs on their clothing. If such differences in value 28 Draft are prevalent, MBGs might be used as a tool for price discrimination. In general, loss aversion should lead marketers to provide extended-length MBG agreements, as consumers overvalue the option to return relative to the marketers’ cost of a returned item. SCGs are less valuable than MBGs, particularly among the higher income groups. Our estimates suggest the difference in value is nearly 10% of the price of the item. This would suggest that stores should only use SCGs when more than 10% of their items are returned without the customer purchasing another item. SCGs may increase the loss aversion of the buyer as the purchases with the returned money are done for unplanned and not budgeted items (Novemsky, and Kahneman 2005). This might be the case at specialty stores or gift stores with a narrow selection. MBGs appear to have increased value in shorter durations for catalog purchasing, where initial experience with the item is delayed until after purchase. Several areas of research are suggested by this study. Of prime importance is to understand the heterogeneity in individuals’ evaluations of MBGs. A more thorough analysis of socioeconomic factors affecting this valuation may allow marketers greater ability to design optimal marketing tools. The analysis of other marketing strategies, for instance, using MBGs together with performance warranties and in-store demonstrations, may yield a more accurate picture of how individuals deal with purchasing risk. Larger samples and data involving actual (rather than hypothetical) products would help eliminate some of the biases inherent in this study. Beyond this, future research should seek to quantify important variables such as return costs, and the factors affecting the ability of individuals to return an item. Such an exploration may provide better insight into the motivations of the higher income individuals we have noted here. 29 Draft Table 1 Price Differences and Length of MBGa Item description Women’s jeans, MBG Store 1 Walmart.com MBG Store 2 length Price length Price Price No. of days dollars 90 16.92 Kmart.com 30 10.19 51.11 19.99 - Sears.com 90 10.80 59.69 - No. of days dollars difference percent regular fit White dress JCPenney.com No limit shirt (plain) 25.99 Men’s short- Abercrombie sleeve cotton and Fitch pique polo online No limit 39.50 a. All prices as of March 2, 2005. 30 82.58 Gap.com 14 19.99 65.59 Draft Table 2 Violations of Hypotheses Possible Individuals Hypothesis Violations violations violating Hypothesis 1 7 1776 5 Hypothesis 2 98 1332 64 Hypothesis 3 0 444 0 Hypothesis 4 66 888 42 All hypotheses 171 4440 82 The results are based on a total of 220 respondents. 31 Draft Table 3 Estimated Values of Changes in MBG Duration and Conditions Variable Mean Standard error dollars dollars 0.25 0.02 0.07 0.02 " !P60,store * 2.62 0.34 30,SC !P30,cash -6.78 0.76 7 !P0,cat / 7 MBG/day 1-7 cat 0.73 0.07 30 !P7,cat / 23 MBG/day 23-30 cat 0.35 0.03 60 !P30,cat MBG/day 30-60 cat 0.08 0.02 " !P60,cat * 2.76 0.41 30,CSC !MBG30,cash "0 -8.95 0.79 30 !P7,store / 23 MBG/day 7-30 60 !P30,store / 30 * MBG/day 30-60 Because a slope cannot be calculated, we estimate the average rise of !MBG60" . 32 Draft Table 4 Estimation Results for Willingness to Pay Coefficient Constant (t = 0) 30-day SCG 7-day MBG 60-day MBG Infinity MBG RP (t = 0) RP (t = 7) RP, SCG (t = 30) RP (t = 60) RP (t = ∞) RP2 t < 30 RP2 t > 30 In-store estimate -9.570*** (0.904) 5.460*** (1.034) 4.705*** (1.091) 10.813*** (0.989) 13.486*** (1.105) -0.162** (0.076) -0.192*** (0.058) -0.249*** (0.070) 0.121** (0.055) 0.127** (0.062) 0.003*** (0.001) -0.002** (0.001) Catalogue estimate dollars -11.054*** (1.040) 5.674*** (1.266) 3.835*** (1.289) 12.393*** (1.141) 14.938*** (1.276) -0.233*** (0.090) -0.355*** (0.083) -0.261*** (0.089) 0.102** (0.057) 0.102 (0.067) 0.004*** (0.001) -0.001* (0.001) 33 Draft Table 5 Predicted WTA and WTP for Average Probability of Return Coefficient In stores With catalogs dollars WTA, no MBG 10.90 14.00 WTA with a 7-day MBG 6.50 10.95 WTP with a 60-day MBG 1.24 1.32 WTP with an infinite MBG 3.90 4.10 WTA with a 30-day store credit 4.11 15.69 34 Draft Table 6A Calibrated Loss Cost and Change in Probability of Return over Time for Various RP Assuming No Probability Weighting In-store products RP WTA for no MBG Loss cost 7-day MBG 60-day MBG Infinity length MBG 5.000 10.305 155.795 10.000 10.890 58.010 15.000 11.325 24.175 -0.020 0.006 0.019 -0.038 0.011 0.036 -0.054 0.016 0.052 35 Catalogue products dollars 20.000 5.000 10.000 15.000 11.610 12.169 13.184 14.099 6.440 191.211 78.656 39.894 Change in RP -0.071 -0.030 -0.055 -0.077 0.021 0.006 0.010 0.014 0.067 0.016 0.029 0.041 20.000 14.914 19.656 -0.097 0.018 0.052 Draft Table 6B Calibrated Loss Cost and Change in Probability of Return over Time for Various RP using Probability Weighting In-Store Products Catalogue Products dollars WTA for no MBG Loss cost 5.000 10.305 26.537 10.000 10.890 5.2957 15.000 11.325 -4.199 7-day MBG 60-day MBG Infinity length MBG -0.039 0.019 0.053 -0.083 0.047 0.118 -0.128 0.080 0.181 36 20.000 5.000 11.610 12.169 -10.216 38.573 Change in RP -0.175 -0.045 0.113 0.016 0.235 0.042 10.000 13.184 14.837 15.000 14.099 4.570 20.000 14.914 -1.740 -0.094 0.038 0.090 -0.144 0.064 0.135 -0.195 0.090 0.175 Draft Figure 1 Distribution of Average Probability of Return 37 Draft REFERENCES Bell, D. (1982), “Regret in Decision Making Under Uncertainty,” Operations Research, 30, 961-81. Blair, M. E. and D. E. Innis (1996), “The Effects of Product Knowledge on the Evaluation of Warranteed Brands,” Psychology and Marketing, 13, 445-56. Bult, Jan R. and Tom Wansbeek (1995), “Optimal Selection for Direct Mail,” Marketing Science, 14(4), 378-94. Camerer, Colin (1989), “An Experimental Test of Several Generalized Utility Theories,” Journal of Risk and Uncertainty 2, 61-104. ---- (1995), “Individual Decision Making,” in The Handbook of Experimental Economics, J. Kagel and A. Roth, eds. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Catalog Age (2002), “Holiday Returns Rates Hold Steady For Most Mailers,” 19(3), 1. Chatterjee, Subimal, Timothy B. Heath, and Suman Basuroy (2003), “Failing to Suspect Collusion in Price-Matching Guarantees: Consumer Limitations in Game-Theoretic Reasoning,” Journal of Consumer Psychology, 13, 255-267. Davis, Scott, Eitan Gerstner, and Michael Hagerty (1995), “Money-Back Guarantees in Retailing: Matching Products to Consumer Tastes,” Journal of Retailing, 71(1), 7-22. Del Franco, Mark (2000a), “Good News about Returns,” Catalog Age, 17(4) (March), 41-42. ---- (2000b), “Reducing Web Returns,” Catalog Age, 17(10) (September), 47. 38 Draft Edlin, A. and E. Emch (1999), “The Welfare Losses From Price Matching Policies,” Journal of Industrial Economics, 47, 145-68. Gul, Faruk (1991), “A Theory of Disappointment Aversion,” Econometrica, 59, 667-86. Heal, Geoffrey M. (1977), “Guarantees and Risk Sharing,” Review of Economic Studies, 44 (October), 549-560. Heiman, Amir, Bruce McWilliams, and David Zilberman (2001), “Demonstrations and Money-Back Guarantees: Market Mechanisms to Reduce Uncertainty,” Journal of Business Research, 54(1), 71-84. Heiman, Amir, Bruce, McWilliams, Jinhua Zhao, and David Zilberman (2002), “Consumer’s Valuation of Money Back Guarantee Option,” Journal of Retailing, 78(23), 193-205. Heiman, Amir, and David Zilberman (2005), “Incorporating MBGs with Prospect Theory,” Working paper, Department of Agricultural and Resource Economics, University of California, Berkeley. Inman, J. Jeffrey, James S. Dyer, and Jianmin Jia (1997), “A Generalized Utility Model of Disappointment and Regret Effects on Post-Choice Valuation,” Marketing Science, 16, 97-111. Jain, Sanjay and Joydeep Srivastava (2000), “An Experimental and Theoretical Analysis of Price-Matching Refund Policies,” Journal of Marketing Research, 37(3), 351-62. Jasper, C. R. and S. J. Ouellete (1994), “Consumers’ Perception of Risk and the Purchase of Apparel from Catalogs,” Journal of Direct Marketing, 8 (Spring), 23-36. 39 Draft Kahneman, Daniel, Jack L. Knetsch, and Richard H. Thaler (1990), “Experimental Tests of Endowment Effect and the Coase Theorem,” Journal of Political Economy, 98, 1325-49. Kahneman, D. and A. Tversky (1979), “Prospect Theory: An Analysis of Decision under Risk,” Econometrica, 47, 263-92. Logan, J. and R. Lutter (1989), “Guaranteed Lowest Prices: Do They Facilitate Collusion,” Economics Letters, 31, 189-92. Mann, Duncan P. and Jennifer P. Wissinik (1990), “Money-Back Warranties vs. Replacement Warranties: A Simple Comparison,” American Economic Review, 80(2), 432-36. Moorthy, Sridhar and Kannan Srinivasan (1995), “Signaling Quality with a Money-Back Guarantee: The Role of Transaction Costs,” Marketing Science, 14(4), 442-66. Novemsky, Nathan and Daniel Kahneman (2005), “The Boundaries of Loss Aversion,” Journal of Marketing Research, 42(2), 119-128. Png, I. P. L. and D. Hirshleifer (1987), “Price Discrimination Through Offers to Match Prices,” Journal of Business, 60, 365-83. Prelec, D. (1998), “The Probability Weighting Function,” Econometrica, 60, 497-528. Quick, Rebecca (2002), “E-commerce (A Special Report): The View from Above— Return to Sender: Having a Physical Store Is a Big Advantage When It Comes to Dealing with Dissatisfied Customers,” Wall Street Journal, New York (July 17). 40 Draft Simonson, Itamar (1992), “The Influence of Anticipating Regret and Responsibility of Purchasing Decisions,” Journal of Consumer Research, 19(1), 105-118. Thaler, Richard (1985), “Mental Accounting and Consumer Choice,” Marketing Science, 4, 199-214. ---- (1980), “Toward a Positive Theory Consumer Choice,” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 1(1), 39-60. Tversky, A. and D. Kahneman (1992), “Advances in Prospect Theory: Cumulative Representation of Uncertainty,” Journal of Risk and Uncertainty, 5, 297-323. Van den Poel, Dirk and Joseph Leunis (1999), “Consumer Acceptance of the Internet as a Channel of Distribution,” Journal of Business Research, 45(3), 249-56. Voss, Glenn B., A. Parasuraman, and Dhruv Grewal (1998), “The Roles of Price, Performance, and Expectations in Determining Satisfaction in Service Exchanges,” Journal of Marketing, 62(4), 46-61. Wakker, Peter P. (1994), “Separating Marginal Utility and Probabilistic Risk Aversion,” Theory and Decision, 36, 1-44. White, H. (1980), “A Heteroscedasticity Consistent Covariance Matrix Estimator and a Direct Test for Heteroscedasticity,”Econometrica, 48, 817-38. 41 Draft APPENDIX: LOSS COST AND THE PROBABILITY OF RETURN Assume consumers vary in their loss cost (LC) and shopping imprecision (SI). They face a product that costs Pt and provides value that is equivalent to X dollars when it 0 fits. The probability of discovering that a product is unfit when before or at t = t1 , conditional on an unfit product, is given by Ft (t = t1 ) , where Ft ( ) is a cumulative density function. Let Z denote the probability of an unfit product purchased by a shopper, where Z ranges in value from 0 to Z . When the product is purchased with t0 days of MBG, the RP will be Ft (t0 )Z and the probability of being stuck with an unfit product is (1" Ft (t0 ))Z . A product with MBG of t0 will be purchased if the expected benefit is greater than 0. Namely, if (A.1) ! (1 " Z )(X " Pt0 ) " ! ( Ft (t 0 )Z ) RC " ! [ (1 " Ft (t 0 ))Z ] (Pt0 + LC) > 0. For every individual, there must exist a critical Z = ZC (LC) , representing the upper bound of the probability of purchasing an unfit product. The net benefit of purchase at the critical Z is zero. This critical Z is declining with LC. Differentiation of A.1 yields (A.2) " [(1# Ft (t0 ))Zc ] dZc = <0 dLC #"' (1# Zc )(X # Pt ) # " ' (Ft (t 0 )Zc ) Ft (t0 )RC # " ' [(1# Ft (t0 ))Zc ](1# Ft (t 0 ))(Pt + LC) 0 0 [ ] The value of Z will vary for each item an individual will purchase. Let the distribution of Z be given by g( Z | SI ) where SI is the shopping imprecision. The average RP for a consumer with a particular SI is Z C (LC) (A.3) ! suggesting that RP = Ft (t0 ) " 0 42 Zg(Z | SI)dZ , Draft (A.4) Z C (LC) # & dRP = % Ft (t0 ) " ZgSI (Z | SI)dZ ( dSI % ( 0 $ ' Ft (t0 )ZC2 g(ZC | SI)* [(1) Ft (t0 ))Zc ] ) dLC * '(1) Zc )(X ) Pt0 ) + *' ( Ft (t0 )Zc ) Ft (t0 )RC + * ' [(1) Ft (t0 ))Zc ](1) Ft (t0 ))(Pt 0 + LC) [ ] Thus, Z C (LC) & dRP #% = Ft (t0 ) " ZgSI (Z | SI)dZ ( > 0 , dSI % ( 0 $ ' or, increasing SI will increase the RP for a given length MBG. We can also derive Ft (t 0 )ZC2 g(ZC | SI)# [(1" Ft (t 0 ))Zc ] dRP =" < 0. dLC # '(1" Zc )(X " Pt 0 ) + # ' ( Ft (t0 )Zc )Ft (t0 )RC + # ' [(1" Ft (t 0 ))Zc ](1" Ft (t0 ))(Pt 0 + LC) [ The relationships ] dRP < 0 and the concavity of RP over time results in Hypothesis 5. dLC 43