Egert Juuse Tallinn University of Technology, Estonia Abstract

advertisement
THE RISKS AND FAILURES OF EXTERNAL FINANCING OF
DEVELOPMENT IN SMALL STATES – THE CASE OF BALTIC
STATES
Egert Juuse
Tallinn University of Technology, Estonia
Abstract
The article gives a synthetic overview of the financial, institutional and economic challenges
external financing of development poses for small states and their development. The theoretical
framework interrelates classical development economics traditions with Minsky-Kregel conceptual
framework and institutional set-up of financial systems to analyze the financial fragility and crisis in
the Baltic States that have been under the strong influence of neoliberal policies and Washington
Consensus regime. As the inward FDI in the Baltic States has been concentrated in limited number
of economic sectors and tend to finance the production of maturing products that face saturating
markets and diminishing profits, FDI in the Baltic States is becoming mature in terms of both
shrinking new FDI inflows and thriving FDI related income outflows. Furthermore, propensity to
consume rather to invest and domestic market orientation of FDI have eroded the margin of safety
by insufficient generation of foreign currency earnings to meet the external liabilities. Unrestricted
capital inflows have been feeding monetary expansion in these countries, which led to inflationary
trends and deteriorating real exchange currencies, all of which supported widening current account
deficits. Both fixed exchange rate systems, including currency board arrangements in Estonia and
Lithuania in the context of free capital flows that did not prevent high inflation, and overall liberal
economic policies that left policy-makers only with traditional macroeconomic policies (taxes and
expenditures) as the main tools to alleviate external imbalances, are to blamed in deteriorating
financial conditions in the Baltic States. Governments have mainly relied on different fiscal policy
measures before and after the crisis, while prudential capital-account controls, specific FDI policies,
and more elaborated regulations on banking activity have been left aside.
Key Words: Development economics, FDI, exchange rate systems, macroeconomic policies,
financial fragility and crisis.
1
“Each crisis has its own story. And the crisis that
we’re going for at the moment doesn’t really
have a clear end, to my mind, or a clear model
from which to understand it.” /McCulley 2008/
INTRODUCTION
Throughout the contemporary history one can witness the emergence of several forms and sources
of development financing: bilateral and multilateral official flows (official development assistance),
and private flows, such as remittances, portfolio flows, foreign direct investments (FDI). The
importance of high and stable capital flows from developed to developing countries is being
continually stressed by international development policies, although the central role in the process
has shifted from emphasis on multilateral and bilateral official flows to private flows, whereby FDI
has been the most important source of external finance during the last two decades. (Kregel 2004a,
1-34; Kregel 2001: 1-7; Ocampo et al. 2007, 3)
However, there is strong evidence that indicates to the failure of external development
financing, in particular with regard to „Washington Consensus” policies, applied in Latin-America
over the last two decades of the 20th century. Developing countries are not protected against
financial crises that result from negative net flows and unsustainable debt creation, even if they may
experience positive net inflows by accompanying Washington Consensus adjustment policies. As
external finance did not support resource mobilization in the 1990s, but instead triggered import
booms and spending that outpaced the expansion of productive capacity, the growing reliance on
external capital left many developing countries exposed to external policy shocks and facing
increasing burden of debt-servicing. (Kregel 2004b, 1; UN 2003, I-XII; Ocampo et al. 2007, 107)
A decade later, in 2008, the subprime crisis in the US real estate market burst out, the roots
of which can be found in over-leveraged and non-transparent capital market institutions and
complex financial innovations that resulted in the cessation of credit to entire financial system. On
top of it, households have consumed through increased borrowing, not by increased real wages
(COST 2009; Kregel 2009a, 658-661). Thereby, due to inter-relatedness of US credit market and
global financial markets, these negative developments in the US had a global contagion effect in
both developed and developing countries that brought to the fore the aspect of high external
exposure and financial fragility of small open economies, which have been either in transition or
developing phase.
The current article tries to explain the role of external finances1 in engendering financial
fragility and by that, reach an understanding of the roots and implications of financial crisis in small
open states by using the case of three Baltic States. The question to be addressed is why external
financial flows in the form of FDI have not contributed to sustainable economic development in the
Baltic States, but have caused deepening financial instability?
Although the different forms of FDI (greenfield investments, mergers and acquisitions;
equity capital flows; inter-company loans; and non-repatriated/reinvested earnings) may have
varying effects on host economy, the impact of FDI on will be studied as a whole. Due to limited
1
Focus on FDI and bank lending activities.
2
access to more detailed empirical data, the analysis will focus mainly on Estonian case, whereas
general trends and patterns will be presented on all three Baltic States.
The analysis will be based on the middle-range theory2 approach that systematically
combines and inter-relates different concepts into analytical framework or stylized conceptual model
in order to find explanatory patterns and regularities. The theoretical perspective of the article is
rather holistic with multifaceted, comprehensive framework that covers both the internal (intra-state)
and external (cross-border), and micro- (mesa3) and macro-level dimensions. In order to evaluate the
impact of external financing on development in small open states, such as the Baltic States, the
combination of Minsky-Kregel conceptual framework and theoretical concepts from development
economics will be used to study the impact of foreign capital on external and internal balance
position, and also micro(mesa)-macro level developments. Both mentioned dimensions will be
addressed in the context of specific Keynesian policy measures and possible responses that could
have been enforced by these countries. The underlying theories form the basis for addressing the
issue of domestic development process within international trade and capital flows. While balanced
growth theory as a branch of development economics is used to explain the mechanisms behind
economic development, and to analyze the effect of FDI on internal structure of economy, then
Minsky-Kregel framework is applied for studying the impact of emerging structural patterns on
financial stability and sustainable development in more detail. In this regard, the latter concept could
be considered as an extension of balanced growth theory that describes the financing positions of
these countries, which rely on external finances in their development. Therefore, the focus of the
topic tends to be more general with an emphasis on simplicity rather than accuracy. The article
endeavors to explain the dynamics in the economic and financial sphere of three Baltic States in the
light of constructed theoretical framework.
The first part of an article is devoted to the presentation of main theoretical concepts and
positions that explain the essence of external financing. Within this section the following topics will
be covered: the impact of external finances on development, advantages and disadvantages of FDI,
and negative effect of capital flows in terms of inducing financial crises. The outcome of theoretical
reasoning on external financing is lessons to be learned for specific policy measures in preventing
and dealing with deepening financial fragility as well as eventual crisis and regression in small open
economies. The second part of the study focuses on the interpretation of empirical evidence and
findings within the elaborated theoretical framework. Economic and financial situation in Central
and Eastern European (CEE) region will be briefly presented and main macro-economic as well as
FDI-related trends will be analyzed the Baltic States.
2
3
See Wyatt, Balmer 2007, 623-624; Geels 2007, 627-635
Mesa-level considered as sectoral level, while micro-level covers private entities (company, natural person)
3
I
EXTERNAL FINANCING OF ECONOMIC DEVELOPMENT
IN SMALL OPEN STATES4
Increasing value added, enhanced employment, and sound balance of payments would require a
large division of labor and strong institutions together with diverse innovative manufacturing
activities, subject to increasing returns that create synergetic mutual interdependences and spillover
effects (Reinert, Reinert 2005, 9-12; Reinert 2004, 6-7; Kattel et al. 2009, 7). Hence, economic
development can be attained by investing funds into the production of diversified goods that would
acknowledge income elasticity and provide markets for each other. In other words, meaning
balanced investments in horizontally diversified and mutually supporting industrial activities, which
enlarge market size and increase real income per head. (Nurkse 1957a, 368-371; Nurkse 1957b, 334335) Although technological innovations are the main driving forces behind economic development,
they cannot succeed without financial capital that allows industries to advance the level of
technological development (Kregel, Burlamaqui 2006, 3-16).
However, since small developing countries have insufficient income levels to produce the
savings required to finance large-scale investments, the straightforward solution would be to replace
deficient domestic savings with foreign savings in the form of capital inflows, which is also
supported by the belief that developing countries have higher prospective rates of return on domestic
investment and lower incomes than more advanced industrial countries as an incentive to direct
capital flows to developing countries (Kregel 2004a, 4). Rosenstain-Rodan (1943, 203) has admitted
that industrialization in less developed economies depends mainly on foreign investments, as
otherwise it would be slower and require more effort. Therefore, if outward-looking strategy is
followed, i.e. economic growth and development are financed by external resources, countries have
to engage in the establishment of competitive domestic manufacturing industries as well as
exporting sectors to improve balance of payments and ensure debt sustainability. Debt sustainable
development rests on three-stage development pattern, where in the first phase production and
export capacities are built up together with positive net inflows, followed by the second stage of
continuing export growth, but with diminished capital inflows, and the third stage of reversed capital
flows due to a surplus of savings above investments, accompanied by increased external surplus and
productivity. The end state of export surpluses to repay foreign debt, i.e. rate of increase of export
earnings equaling or exceeding rate of interest, would require a policy of both export promotion and
controlling foreign borrowing. (Kregel 2007b, 1-14; Kregel 2004a, 11-13; Kregel 2007c, 3-15)
4
Although it has been found that small states encompass specific characteristics, such as limited domestic resource base
and market, sensitivity to external conditions, specialization on limited number of products, openness to international
trade, and dependence on foreign capital and export earnings (Sutton, Payne 1993, 580-591; Raadschelders 1992, 27),
there are different approaches, how to categorize small states vis-à-vis great powers, while even within the category
small states, there are various ways for classifications according to size, development level and other parameters
(Thorhallsson, Wivel 2006, 651-655). One can use either population, size of area or gross domestic product (GDP) as
the criteria, but more importantly the category small states should be addressed within the spatio-temporal context (ibid.
). Hence, the article rests on more or less widely acknowledged features of small states, whereas general conclusions and
universal solutions, based on the findings, are infeasible. In this study, the Baltic States are surveyed as small states.
Thus, the conclusions might be extended to some extent to other European small states, which are in transition stage or
at the same level of development – Croatia, Bosnia and Herzegovina, Montenegro, FYR Macedonia, Czech Republic,
Slovakia, Slovenia, Hungary, Malta, (Georgia).
4
Moreover, external financing could contribute to the development process5 in developing countries
only if domestic resources are mobilized (Singer 1950, 481, 485) and complementary domestic
investments are made through balanced growth, i.e. investments in a number of mutually supporting
industries that create external economies in terms of technological progress and enlarged market size
(Nurkse 1953, 110, 118-120). It is the forming backward and forward demand linkages between
expanding input-supplying and output-using sectors that must be emphasized and supported
(Rosenstein-Rodan, 1943, Hirschmann 1958 cited in Dutt 2005, 103-109). Thus, in the context of
externally financed development, the goal of small states is to reap advantages by gaining high
volume and experience in interrelated medium- and high-technology industries, subject to increasing
returns, and to reach an end state in which net export surpluses of goods and services are sufficient
to repay foreign borrowing6. In addition, in order to succeed, small developing countries must have
the possibility to decide and direct investment decisions, when facing with the issue of external
financing of their development. Otherwise, the country with undeveloped manufacturing sector and
high reliance on imported capital goods will not achieve internal demand led growth and multiplier
effects by implementing Keynesian economic policies via increased investments, as in that case
economic gains would occur abroad (Kregel 2007b, 1-14).
Thus, countries that host FDI inflows can experience the contribution of FDI to their
development process only, if these inflows go into manufacturing and production, technological
innovations, or infrastructural sector (Dutt 2005, 124-125; Freeman, Perez 1988, 63-64). Besides
creating employment, FDI is considered as an impetus for productivity rise in FDI hosting countries
via technology, standards, skills and knowledge transfer, and an access to credit and international
markets (Ocampo et al. 2007, 30; UNCTAD 2009; Van Beers 2003, 13, 52). Theoretically, such
spillover effects should stem from the linkages between transnational companies and host country
enterprises, but also by setting up production facilities, providing training, establishing quality
standards, and expanding market reach, which would enable small open states to reap gains from
economies of scale and scope (Landesmann, Richter 2003, 33-35; Gallagher, Zarsky 2006).
Therefore, on the micro-level, new technologies, marketing opportunities, and managerial skills are
expected to accompany FDI, while on the meso-level, average productivity and value-added per
worker in the industry should increase (Javorcik 2006b, 207-208, 230).
All these mentioned advantages of FDI in terms of technology and knowledge spillover
effects through vertical integration or labor turnover would occur only in case of sound innovation
systems with sufficient level of technological and absorptive capacity by local suppliers to
internalize provided knowledge7. Another precondition is considered to be sustained growth per
capita income (low inflation) and penetration in international markets. Otherwise, the country gets
locked into labor-intensive assembly operations (maquiladoras). (Pack 2006, 32-33, 44-47;
Djankov, Hoekman 2006, 162-165, 175; Ernst, Kim 2001, 1-3, 12)
5
South-Korea could be brought as an example of a country that has used foreign capital for domestic development (Yan
1999, 283).
6
Nurkse (1953, 197) held similar position, although his primary concern was to secure a return in the domestic currency.
7
With its national science and technology (S&T) policies and efficient national innovation system, Finland has managed
to attract high technology TNC-s that cooperate with R&D institutes and establish backward linkages to Finnish
suppliers. FDI inflows to selected industries (ICT, health, forest) have been encouraged by the organization „Invest in
Finland“ with the benefits of highly educated and trained population, and income tax rebates on foreign personnel. (Van
Beers 2003, 64, 66-67, 73-75)
5
I. 1
THE CHALLENGES FOR SMALL OPEN STATES
It can be said that small economies are squeezed by two kinds of pressures: on the one hand they
need to develop extensively R&D infrastructure to keep up with advanced economies, but on the
other hand there is an intense cost-competitive pressure from countries that produce low- and
medium technology products (Van Beers 2003, 10, 20-22, 33-36; Walsh 1987, 37, 40-41, 48-53, 5661). By introducing knowledge-intensive and capital-using techniques in small states` markets, these
economies face the challenge of reaping gains from scale economies of R&D, implying the need to
expand the trade volumes by concentrating private flows into economic activities that meet the
demand of foreign countries (UNCTAD 2009; Nurkse 1957, 366-371, 381; Handel 1981, 163), but
at the same time export orientation calls for continuous adaptations in product lines and managing
the risk of exchange rate fluctuations that affect prices (Walsh 1987, 48-53, 56-61). More
importantly, as described in the previous section, a well-functioning national system of innovation is
of high significance in effective absorption of external finances (Freeman, Soete 1997, 265-276,
302; Kattel, Anton 2004, 106-128). Thus, the main obstacle for development in backward countries
stems from the incapacity to effectively exploit domestic resources and absorb foreign capital for
investments due to the lack of both technological progress and external economies in terms of
scientific and technological infrastructure. Furthermore, low levels of productivity, incomes, and
savings discourage investments in high-technology industries and create insufficient domestic
demand. (Kregel, 2004a, 4; Kregel 2009c, 39-44; Nurkse 1953, 103, 140-150) Due to technological,
human capital and financial squeeze, small states have been forced to specialize in supplying inputs
or final assembly under contractual agreements, which means that research, development,
production, and marketing activities of TNC-s are located in geographically separate areas. Such
dispersed allocation of activities has increased international integration instead of domestic
horizontal and vertical integration of industries, causing fragmentation and external dependence.
(Walsh 1987, 37, 40-41, 48-53, 56-61)
These integrated global production networks with cross-border and –firm value chains can
be explained by liberalization policies in the 1990s as well as with the concept of techno-economic
paradigms8, currently dominated by information and telecommunication technologies (ICT). Within
the current ICT-led paradigm, the globalization has been a natural outcome with complex
production profiles, resulting from networking and decentralization that has been facilitated by
information and telecommunication technologies. This has led to searching for comparative
advantages and locating value chain processes according to cost profiles (see also Ernst, Kim 2001,
1-3, 12), which can be considered as one of the factors behind the spread of productive capital from
core to peripheries in the form of outsourcing and off-shoring of production capacity to periphery
countries via FDI. However, in search for cost advantages, the transferred maturing technologies
and productive capital might provide growth for a certain length of time, but with insignificant
innovation potential due to reliance on mass production, imported intermediate goods and
standardized products. (Perez 2001, 109-129; Perez 2007, 20-23; Perez 2007a) Thus, the positive
effect of FDI in low-technology sectors in terms of productivity gains tend to be short-term and
mainly occur due to decreasing wages, as the investments made in maturing technologies and
8
The concept of techno-economic paradigms gives an insight into the best practice models within economic, social,
organisational and institutional systems that have been affected by dominating generic technologies. During one or
another techno-economic paradigm, which is divided into two periods – Installation and Deployment – and the turning
point or bubble burst between them, new firms and industries are set up as well as existing traditional economic sectors
are upgraded. (Perez 2007, 6-10)
6
industries face decreasing profit rates and diminishing returns (Saggi 2006, 52-53, 58-60; Van Beers
2003, 33-36; Khan 2005, 75-76; Ros 2005, 91). As a result, the nature of resulting production capital
in terms of investment patterns, knowledge, experience, and external networks would soon become
mature and obsolete to cause a mismatch with financial capital, as maturing investments and
obtained short-term gains would trigger financial capital outflows in search for better profits - it is
fundamentally footloose and flexible (Perez 2007a).
Therefore, FDI tends to render the structure of host open economy less complex and
knowledge-intensive, while the share of value added of both middle- and high technology industries
tends to decrease (Tiits et al. 2003, 26). Even worse, foreign capital is leaned towards consumption
financing9 rather than productive investments and does not generate positive returns or export
surplus, which creates problems in servicing debt as well as interest payments. Excessive propensity
to consume rather than produce results in inflationary pressures and balance-of-payment
disequilibrium, which all together have a reverse effect on both attracting FDI and preserving
financial stability in small open states. (Nurkse 1952, 91-92, 149-151; Nurkse 1953, 141-149;
Gallagher, Zarsky 2006)
I. 1.1 NEGATIVE CONSEQUENCES OF EXTERNAL FINANCING (FDI)
Even if premature liberalization of domestic markets of transition or developing economies can
incur economic growth by utilizing foreign capital inflows, automatic expansion of the demand for
their exports cannot be expected, as domestic producers tend to loose competitiveness in
international markets due to Vanek-Reinert effect10 (see Reinert 2008; Kregel 2002, 5). The
presence of foreign companies exerts negative pressures on domestic enterprises in the same
industry due to increased competition that can result in lost market share, lowered output, and
diseconomies of scale. (Javorcik 2006a, 180-189, 201; Pack 2006, 32-33, 44-47; Djankov, Hoekman
2006, 162-165, 175) Moreover, FDI is able to undermine the linkages and coordination mechanisms
between domestic enterprises and other institutions of national innovation system by displacing
domestic producers, which imperils competition and price stability (Lederman, Maloney 2006, 305331). Therefore, FDI is seen as a form of neo-colonial exploitation that explains the disappearance
of domestic companies by the substitution effect, including in banking sector, where aggressive (and
excessive) lending by domestic subsidiaries of foreign commercial banks can result in displacing of
domestic banks11, which in turn raises the risk of pro-cyclical lending policy of foreign banks
(Ocampo et al. 2007, 36-38; King 2008, 1-5).
Under the current techno-economic paradigm (ICT) and prevailing neo-liberal economic
policies, FDI has locked some countries into specializing in low value added exports (assembly
9
One of the factors behind this the so-called „demontration effect“ that reduces the capacity to save due to declining
relative real income levels in less advanced countries (see Nurkse 1953, 140-141).
10
Premature opening up of domestic markets of less developed economies to foreign competition causes the bankruptcy
of the most advanced economic sectors (manufacturing industry) that operate under increasing returns and absorb large
investments into technologies. The negative effect accrues from a cost advantage of foreign competitors that leads to the
drop in output volume and sales of domestic producers (Reinert 2007, 166, 327).
11
In Argentina, the drawback of the concentration of banking system into foreign ownership was related to inaccessible
credit for small and medium-size enterprises, as cheap foreign capital fed high income-elastic imports (O’Connell 2007,
51-63), while in both Korea and Taiwan, banks remained state-owned and had a critical role in development by
channeling savings into targeted economic activities (O Riain 2004, 196-199, 201, 216, 229).
7
activities) within international production networks, while core R&D activities tend to be located in
FDI-originating countries12; the off-shoring of services has meant mainly the relocation of lower
value-added functions. On the other hand, the decision of multinational companies to invest abroad
with the aim to produce for host country markets aggravates balance-of-payments situation.
Moreover, the propensity of FDI to increase foreign borrowing worsens external balance and
augments debt service in terms of the repatriation of earnings in the form of dividends and interests.
(Van Beers 2003, 13, 52; Ocampo et al. 2007, 32; UN 2003; Kregel 2007b, 16-22)
The are several other risks that are associated with FDI: 1) undermining of local savings, 2)
displacement of domestic investments by borrowing in local financial markets (the result is
deteriorated macroeconomic condition because of overvalued exchange rate due to increased interest
rates), 3) balance of payments problems due to repatriated profits and increased imports, and 4) no
backward linkages or stimulated innovativeness (Gallagher, Zarsky, 2006). The volatility of FDI in
host economy stems from adverse internal and external developments, such as shrinking profits,
plummeting stock prices, decreasing demand, or tightened credit conditions that might destabilize
FDI inflows by inducing divestments and causing layoffs (UNCTAD 2009; Ocampo et al. 2007, 2830).
I. 1.1.1
PROBLEMS FROM THE PERSPECTIVE OF DEVELOPMENT
ECONOMICS
From the perspective of development economics, and in particular balanced growth theory,
innovativeness would require participatory practices, user-producer interaction, and integrated
learning that presumes a set of backward and forward linkages within indigenous economy. Even
though backward and forward linkages support integrated learning, these linkages might turn out to
be neither stable nor sustainable in liberalized economic environment due to mobile and volatile
capital flows. (Andersen, Lundvall 1988, 11, 19, 22-33) At the same time, it is found that FDI hardly
establishes any capacity in host economy through coupling or spin-off effects (Walsh 1987, 37, 4041, 48-53, 56-61). During the current techno-economic paradigm, FDI into developing countries has
enabled extensive outsourcing activities and geographical diffusion of production, but without
significant backward or forward linkages between foreign affiliates and domestic economic agents13
(Ocampo et al. 2007, 28-30; Kattel 2009, 11-13). Even if there are any spillover effects in transition
economies, these are usually backward spillovers in the form of knowledge transfer and product
quality requirements, but not horizontal or forward (Javorcik 2006b, 208-213). As a rule, vertical
spillovers have not occurred in case of wholly owned projects that involve sophisticated
technologies, implying a negative relationship between R&D and the probability of shared
ownership. Hence, medium- and high-technology sectors, where R&D intensity plays a major role,
12
Liberalization strategies have followed the principle that markets are the best mechanisms to allocate resources and
investments. In Mexico, after the privatization and deregulation wave, locally-owned companies specialized into laborintensive assembly that depended on foreign design and components. Brazil, on the other hand, has been implementing
active policy to promote industries by constraining imports and FDI to protect indigenous infant industries. (Kraemer et
al. 2001, 1199-1203)
13
For instance, in Ireland, interaction between foreign and domestic enterprises is insignificant and most of the jobs are
created in low-skill assembly lines, while hardly any movement of labor between indigenous and foreign firms takes
place, all of which has transferred multiplier effects of investments abroad. Even in high-technology sectors, Ireland has
attracted only the production of low- and medium-technology parts. Thus, R&D spending and revenues of TNC-s have
not yet contributed to developing of local capabilities, while their operations tend to add little value. (Walsh 1987, 37,
40-41, 48-53, 56-61; O Riain 2004, 40-45, 48, 54-56; Van Beers 2003, 67-68, 77-78)
8
are dominated by wholly owned projects, whereas joint ventures are undertaken in less R&Dintensive industries. (Javorcik 2006a, 180-189, 201; Pack 2006, 32-33, 44-47; Djankov, Hoekman
2006, 162-165, 175)
Small developing countries tend to have dualistic economic structures: on one side, capitalintensive, highly productive industries that mainly export, and on the other side, domestic market
targeting sectors with low productivity, which means that export-oriented sectors, dominated by
foreign capital, have not become part of internal economic structures. The insufficient integration
has had little impact on living standard and productivity of domestic economy. Furthermore, instead
of procuring from local enterprises, these FDI-intensive industries tend to maintain high import
content that adversely affects balance of payments position14. (Nurkse 1957b, 331, 334; Nurkse
1957a, 361-368; Singer 1950, 474-477; Javorcik 2006b, 231) FDI tends to be concentrated in the
areas that respond to the capital exporting country's demand, implying a simple extension of lender's
economy with little impact on host country's development. Thus, productivity gains and increased
savings cannot be expected from FDI (Nurkse 1952, 158-163, 211). FDI-led industrialization in
developing countries has transferred cumulative multiplier effects in the form of additional
employment, capital, external economies, and know-how to investing countries due to specialization
on low value added activities and low technologies that do not pose opportunities for technological
upgrading and present deteriorating terms of trade. Thereby, industries` effects on each other are
insignificant in terms of the creation of social benefits, new skills, demand, and inventiveness
(Singer 1950, 474-477).
All things considered, FDI is not a panacea that enables to break off the vicious circle of
poverty in small developing countries, as foreign companies have disincentives to invest in
manufacturing sectors due to small markets and low productivity, but rather in primary producing
and extracting sectors, which deteriorate terms of trade for developing countries (Dutt 2005, 124125). Therefore, a strong domestic demand for the output of indigenous industries is needed to
rectify vulnerabilities stemming from the reliance on foreign affiliates or subsidiaries and the
unstable linkages created by them (Freeman, Lundvall 1988, 11, 19, 22-33).
I. 1.1.2
BALANCE OF PAYMENTS AND DEBT-DEFLATION PROBLEM –
MINSKY-KREGEL FRAMEWORK
Even if the financial liberalization has facilitated the capital flows to developing countries under the
presumption of higher marginal productivity, the consequences have been over-borrowing,
consumption volatility, pro-cyclicality of capital flows, and overvaluation of exchange rates in
developing economies. Instead of higher growth, liberalized capital flows to developing countries
14
The deregulation of financial markets in India in terms of liberalization of ceilings on foreign shareholding and
operation of FDI has resulted in skyrocketing inflow of FDI and greater expenditure of foreign exchange on imports, but
without significant improvement in exports, implying the rapid increase in the ratio of imports to exports. In addition,
profits as dividends have been repatriated, which all together will eventually cause the drain of foreign exchange and
adverse effect of balance of payments position. The problem is aggravated even more by the domestic-market
orientation of FDI companies in India that turns the foreign exchange impact of FDI negative. (Chandrasekhar, Ghosh
2009)
9
engender increased consumption of imports that widen current account deficits15. In addition, the
preference of foreign capital to finance non-tradable goods magnifies the risk of capital flight in the
context of overvalued real effective exchange rate or pressures for devaluation of domestic currency,
once the signs of some unexpected event occur. (O`Connell 2006, 3-20) Nurkse (1961, 1953 cited in
Kattel et al. 2009, 10) has argued that reliance on foreign investments tends to finance private
consumption, which causes negative financial flows and creates financial fragility in terms of
balance of payment problems.
Therefore, the analysis of financial fragility can be conducted by using Minsky-Kregel
analytical framework that proposes three financing positions for countries with regard to the balance
between financial inflows and outflows. The size of margin of safety, calculated as a difference
between cash incomes and outflows, determines the financing position of a firm or a country –
hedge, speculative or Ponzi (Kregel 2008a). Entities in hedge financing position can meet all
financial obligations by cash flow, while Ponzi units do not have sufficient cash inflows to repay
principle or interest on debt, implying the need to borrow or sell assets (Minsky 1992, 1-8).
According to Minsky-Kregel framework, endogenous financial fragility emerges as a result of
prolonged period of stability, when heightened expectations increase leverage and debt-financed
long-term positions that bring along overcapitalization, booms, and eventual financial crisis with
asset liquidation and devaluation, once debt obligations exceed cash flows16 (Minsky 1991, 15-17;
Pollock 2008). In the condition of prevailing optimistic expectations, investors and banks increase
financial system's fragility by getting more indebted and involving in riskier practices that may end
up in bank run and debt deflation once expectations change and agents try to re-establish their
liquidity positions (Arestis 1996, 120-121). Moreover, such fragile system can be subverted by some
unexpected event, such as increase in interest rates or devalued domestic currency that leads to
inability of businesses to meet their financial commitments from trade, accumulated reserves,
financial assistance, or capital inflows (Minsky 1991, 15-17; Kelso, Duman 1992, 232). The
financial fragility condition implies a high concentration of speculative or Ponzi economic units highly leveraged businesses, decreasing margins of safety in indebtedness, and low liquidity of
economy17. Insolvency of investors and the resulting financial crisis are usually triggered by a rise in
interest rates, as deepening fragility increases money demand. (Minsky 1975, 1984, 1985 cited in
Kelso, Duman 1992, 226-230; Minsky, Whalen 1996, 2, 4-6, 14) However, the root causes of
15
In Mexico, the liberalization together with tight monetary policies engendered increased capital inflows and
appreciated domestic currency in real terms, which brought about worsened trade balance. The new dynamic industries,
such as chemistry, electronics, and automobile industry, depended on imports and did not create additional employment,
while the increased competition and cheap imports repressed domestic small- and medium-sized companies. Foreign
capital was used for consumption and lending to businesses at international interest rates, all of which resulted in fallen
savings, low investment and growth, and rising unemployment. Thus, financial crisis in Mexico erupted due to credit
bubble, bad loans to households, and high foreign currency exposure. (Kregel 1998a, 3; Matrin, Schumann 1999, 49-54,
149-152)
16
The current debt deflation crisis, in which decreasing prices raise debt burdens, is a result of insufficient margins of
safety in the „originate and distribute“financial system with securitization of non-conforming adjustable rate mortgage
loans. Adjustable-interest-rate (subprime) mortgages had inbuilt declining margins of safety due to declined value of a
property or decreased ability to meet commitments as a result of non-respondent increase in income, implying a need for
increased borrowing to meet higher interest costs. The overall expansionary environment has resulted in excess
borrowing, overinvestment, and risk concentration that led to highly leveraged positions. (Kregel 2008c, 11-12, 17-23;
Minsky cited in Wray, 2008; McCulley 2008 )
17
Governments can erode cushion of safety and become eventually speculative or even Ponzi units as a result of the
overexposure to foreign exchange positions or by overestimating future cash inflows and tax receipts (Ševic 2007b, 1117).
10
Minskyian financial fragility can be derived from wrong market signals that lead to inappropriate
debt-financed investments in terms of distribution and amount because of excessive demand and
speculation-led inflation. In that case, high concentration of speculative investments results in
eventual collapse in asset prices and inability to service debt with sufficient cash flows, especially if
there are many units trying to make a position by selling out positions. (Minsky 1991, 5-6, 9, 14)
The problems of external financing of development are related to unsustainable debt creation
and eventual reversal of external capital flows, as growing capital inflows, accompanied by the
rising share of interest payments in current account deficit, set in motion Ponzi financing scheme,
where debt is sustained by ongoing borrowing. (Kregel 2002, 12; Kregel 2004a, 4-5, 11) It is
evident that debt service, i.e. the payment of amortization, dividends, and interest as an outflow of
capital from developing countries, approaches and eventually exceeds inflows in terms of new
investments from developed economies within a short period18. Those firms that operate with high
proportion of imported inputs or leverage and do not have sufficient margin of safety to absorb
changes in cash flows due to some external shock, might end up in Ponzi financing position.
Basically, this sets in motion debt-deflation process, where excessive supplies and falling prices19
are accompanied by declining demand due to decreased investments and consumption, which, in
turn, is caused by diminished incomes and increased unemployment. (Kregel 1998b, 2-7, Palley
2001, 22-23)
The morale is that the development strategy built solely on foreign lending is a Ponzi scheme
that cannot succeed on a long-term basis, because the ever-rising foreign lending translates into an
ever-rising external debt for developing countries, whether interest rates are equal or below the rate
of increase in inflows (Kregel 2004, 1-34). The Ponzi financing trap can be avoided if cash incomes
of a borrower exceed commitments on loans and interest rates as well as asset prices remain stable
(Kregel 2008a). There are several ways, how to cushion the lowering margins of safety, but the
feasibility of different options, such as accumulated reserves, positive balance of trade, low interest
rates or put options on foreign exchange in order to avoid inappropriate currency appreciation
because of excessive capital inflows (Kregel 2004a, 5, 7-10), depends on contextual circumstances.
Therefore, the Minsky-Kregel framework that explains the fragility of highly leveraged economic
units and also proposes policy measures to alleviate negative consequences of externally financed
development needs to be addressed in the context of broader financial system in terms of the impact
of exchange rate systems on capital movements and their mutual interrelatedness.
I.1.2 SOUND FINANCIAL SYSTEM AND EXCHANGE RATE SYSTEMS
From the perspective of external financing of development it is important to deliberate on the
potential effects of different exchange rate systems on country’s financial stability and effective use
18
Outward flow of foreign investment was also acknowledged by Nurkse, although he foresaw it as a gradual process –
net repayment would occur once the fundamental conditions of creditor and debtor economies reverse in terms of saving
propensity and investment needs (see Nurkse 1952, 196).
19
In East Asian case the financial fragility was engendered by cheap short-term capital inflows, which were negatively
affected by unfavorable interest and exchange rates, and a failure to optimally allocate capital for productive use that
created foreign exchange risk exposure. The resulting debt-deflation process reversed net present values of investments,
decreased asset prices, and devalued currencies. Thus, leverage should be used to the extent that is compatible with
economic stability, implying a need for controlling and rationing capital inflows. (Kregel 1998a, 4-15; Kregel 2000, 212)
11
of external finances. The sound financial system should support innovations and also maintain the
value of productive assets that enable enterprises to meet their liabilities and lower the risk of nonconformance of assets to liabilities (Drechsler et al. 2006, 20-21, 24-28). Managed, flexible
exchange rate regimes enable to preserve competitiveness and positive export balance by targeting
competitive effective exchange rates. In such system there is no need for foreign exchange rate
reserves, as external imbalances would be adjusted by appropriate changes in exchange rates, which
affect the prices of tradable goods. (Kregel 2004c, 2; O`Connell 2006, 36-41) Such maneuvering
room is of vital importance for small countries in sustaining export earnings that determine their
development potential, as these countries must acquiesce to changes in prices and trading
possibilities in the world markets, implying their role as of price-takers (Handel 1981, 157-161, 164165; Sanderson 2009, 45-49). On the premises of established and independent exporting sector,
devaluation can restore external balance, although it deteriorates terms of trade, leading in the long
run to import substitution at the expense of export industries` resources (Nurkse 1957, 361, 363-367,
375). Thereby, managed devaluation of domestic currency can operate as a hedging measure that
cushions decreasing margins of safety, which are caused by external imbalances.
On the other hand, attachment to the fixed exchange rate regimes, such as currency board
system can be explained by the limited capacities of central banks and incipient financial markets in
small open economies. Fixed exchange rate system, including the currency board arrangement,
should promote fiscal discipline that controls inflation and avoids both public debt and depletion of
foreign reserves. The sources of money creation in currency board system are international reserves,
which are related to balance of payments position. Therefore, emerging balance of payments deficit
should trigger the contraction of foreign reserves and monetary base, the adjustment of which would
require deflationary developments, especially in the context of destabilized (appreciated) real
exchange rate.(Grigonyte 2003, 111-115, 128-129; Lewis, Ševic 2000, 286, 289-290) Thus, in
theory, currency board system should automatically ensure internal and external balance by
adjusting domestic absorption to generate required resource outflows that meet external liabilities
(Kregel 2007c, 9). However, such reasoning is invalidated, if countries have liberalized financial
markets, as capital inflows offset the current account deficit and decline in money supply, which
could restore external balance and competitiveness by cutting down prices and wages (Kregel 2002,
7-9).
Under the fixed exchange rate regime, increasing foreign capital inflows, attracted by
expanded consumption spending, generate expansionary effects through reserve accumulation and
appreciated domestic currency, which worsens current account deficit due to differential inflation
rates in trading countries, implying the capital-account pro-cyclicality and an adverse effect on the
value of domestic currency in terms of country’s export competitiveness (Ocampo 2002, 2-4, 19;
Palley 2001, 2-3, 15; Havlik et al. 2001, 1/10, 3/18). Thereby, unless prevailing external imbalances
and pressures on exchange rate are not alleviated in countries with open external account and
currency board system, deflationary developments threaten to deprive a country from liquidity in
terms of depleted foreign reserves due to increased demand for foreign currencies (Vistesen 2009;
Moses 2000, 31-43). From the point of view of foreign investor, who holds domestic assets, internal
deflation, that in principle equals to devaluation, means a default on debt service20 (Kregel 2004a,
20
It is found that currency board arrangement contributed to investor panic in Hong Kong, once the currency had
become overvalued and external balance deteriorated, as an investor was faced with either exchange rate or price
collapse of financial assets, producing eventually capital flight to quality. In case of defending fixed exchange rate by
selling foreign currency against domestic currency, money supply decreases, leading to higher interest rates and internal
deflation, which would put under pressure banks that have been engaged in real estate lending (Kregel 1998a, 14).
12
6). Thus, it is the combination of appreciating domestic currency and deepening current account
deficits that cause financial instability and eventual collapse of fixed exchange rate in countries,
operating under currency board arrangement and depending on foreign capital. Free movement of
capital is simply incompatible with fixed exchange rate regimes21 (O`Connell 2006, 36-41;
Krugman cited in Grabel 2004, 3).
Intrinsic vulnerability to the financial system of countries that operate with currency board
arrangement stems from the system's inability to extend credit to government, banking system and
borrowers, unless there is an inflow of foreign capital, as monetary base is linked to foreign
exchange reserves. Under the currency board system, capital outflows and withdrawal of deposits
threaten banking system (UNCTAD 1998, 105-106), whereas previously mentioned deflationary
processes engender reduced asset earnings, which might also result in bank runs. Hence, it is the
incompatible combination of deregulated, poorly supervised, and indebted banking sector with
short-term liabilities that takes excessive risks by lending aggressively on the one side, and the
promise of a government to act as a lender of last resort and to support fixed exchange rate on the
other side, that poses problems for financial architecture of economy. Such multifaceted objectives
contradict, and should domestic banks become illiquid in the system of fixed exchange rate, either
currency or banking crisis occurs. (Marion 1999, 473-479, 486) Therefore, central banks in open
economies can either try to save banks or maintain fixed exchange rate, as currency board system
restrains from supplying additional liquidity to keep banks solvent (Chang and Velasco 1998 cited
in Marion 1999, 483-486).
Under the regime of Washington Consensus, liberalization and deregulation of financial
markets have driven exchange rates in wrong directions because of financial speculation. Capital
inflows, high leverage, and asset bubbles that keep currency stable or overvalued have created a
highly fragile ground, as reversal of such funds puts exchange rate under the pressure. Such negative
developments are amplified by lax regulation and accounting standards that incur pro-cyclicality.
(Wade 2008; Wade 2009, 551; Kregel 1998b, 9-10) When there are signs of devaluations, capital is
withdrawn by multinational companies that produce mainly for developing country market (Persaud,
2003 in Ocampo et al. 2007, 25). A rush into foreign currency devalues domestic currency, while
attempts to stabilize exchange rate by raising interest rates mark lowered creditworthiness and
would eventually aggravate debt service and force assets liquidation, which accelerates debt
deflation process and eventually leads to insolvency (UNCTAD 1998, 84-86).
I. 2
THE DYNAMICS BEHIND FINANCIAL CRISES
Considering the explanations behind deepening financial fragility in small states that operate with
rigid exchange rate systems and depend on external finances, one can use already covered Minsky’s
classification of financing units. In broader terms, the elaboration on the causes and essence of
financial crises can also rest on the concept of techno-economic paradigms that describes how the
eruption of casino economy during installation period leads to financial crisis - the installation
period passes down distortions of economy in terms of tensions between paper and real economy in
21
There are several historical blueprint cases of badly managed policies in the context of fixed exchange rates, like the
Chilean experience in 1980s, that have enabled large current account deficits, consumption boom, and real asset bubbles
as a consequence of currency appreciation and unrestrained capital inflows in the form of international bank loans
denominated in foreign currencies (UNCTAD 1998, 79-80).
13
the context of overinvestment in technologies and infrastructure, high mobility of capital and pursuit
of short-term financial gains (Perez 2006, 33-66). There is inadequate demand because of extreme
income polarization, and inability to absorb investments in stock markets, even if industries grow at
frenzy pace. Insufficient profit gains (returns on investments) and enabling ICT-s bring forth
innovative financial instruments that contribute to gigantic credit creation and hyperinflation of
assets due to their speculative and cumulative nature, leading eventually to bubble burst (Perez
2007a). The recent (financial) bubble was induced by low interest rates, excess liquidity, and the
atmosphere of excitement in the financial system, which under the circumstances of complex and
inadequately regulated financial instruments22, resulted in inflated assets - over-valued stocks (Perez
2009, 786-792).
Thus, the seeds of financial crises might be found in highly leveraged structures and
extensive use of credit for economic expansion that lead to over-investments due to expectations of
higher earnings and increasing value of collateral that mutually reinforce each other23. Such
developments create also higher demand for external financing in both financial and non-financial
sectors. However, once the expected revenues do not cover debt obligations as a result of drop in
demand, the oversupplied structures lead to excessive volatility in the value of collateral due to
massive liquidation of existing capital, and eventual capital outflow, implying debt deflationary
financial crisis. (Veblen 1934, 1938, 1958 cited in Kelso, Duman 1992, 223-226; Eichengreen 2004,
254-260; Weller, Singleton 2004, 1-4, 8; Marion 1999, 473-479) Typical predictors of imminent
financial crisis are:
• Debt accumulation – high leverage due to excess supply of cheap and volatile foreign
capital;
• Worsening current account deficit;
• Depletion of reserves;
• Overspending and misallocated investments in excessive risk taking endeavors - speculative
real estate and stock markets;
• Booming housing and equity prices;
• Overvalued domestic currency;
• Pro-cyclical policies and inadequate regulation;
• Deepening currency and maturity mismatches;
• Growing global imbalances and income inequalities (Reinhart, Rogoff 2008, 2, 11; Yan
1999, 277-279; Kregel 2009d, 4, 10; O´Connell 2006, 15, 32; UN 2009a, 12, 23-39; Weller,
Singleton 2004, 1-4, 8).
All these indicators have a cumulative effect on balance of payments problems, decreasing FDI, and
eventual withdrawal of funds together with declining asset values that induce falling exchange rate,
bank failures, borrower default, rapid depletion of reserves, increased unemployment, and decreased
output – the characteristics of the majority of financial crises in the 1990s (Cruz, Walters 2008, 665673; Cohen 2008, 1-15; UN 2009b, 4-5; Ocampo et al. 2007, 143-145; Weller, Singleton 2004, 1-4,
8; Ocampo 2002, 4; O`Connell 2006, 36-41; Eichengreen 2004, 254-260).
22
Futures, hedge funds, securitized mortgages etc.
The combination of speculative bubble in securities and real estate market, uncontrolled credit expansion,
mismanaged financial liberalization, and highly leveraged structures led to private sector indebtedness and eventually to
economic crisis in Finland in 1990 (Ylä-Anttila, Lemola 2006, 85-86).
23
14
On the other hand, the systemic risks, i.e. institutional immaturity, flawed economic
structures, and opportunistic (speculative) behavior of foreign capital, should be addressed and
juxtaposed with the inner dynamics of FDI, guided by the current techno-economic paradigm and
transitional phase from its one development stage to another. From the perspective of MinskyKregel framework, FDI can be seen following the same logic that is behind the credit-driven
business cycle, consisting of two succeeding phases (see Palley 2001, 23-24): period of increasing
loan expenditures, incomes, and demand due to availability of cheap credit, that is followed by a
period of contraction, as borrowings are to be repaid, i.e. income transfers from debtors to creditors
outweigh expansionary impact of new loans, causing raised debt burdens, restricted investment
possibilities, and fallen incomes. The same argument can be assigned to the three-stage model of
FDI dynamics (see Hunya 2008, 18-21; Hunya 2009, 16-19). From developmental and financial
stability perspective, FDI-related income (interest or dividends) of non-residents has a significant
importance, as in the current account it is presented as an outflow from host country. Therefore, FDI
dynamics can be categorized into three-stage model from the perspective of FDI-related income
balance: 1) large FDI inflows with insignificant FDI-related income outflows and FDI outflows, 2)
FDI-related income outflow, as the main source of current account deficit, matches FDI inflows in
the form of reinvested profits, and at the same time marginal FDI outflows are detected, and 3) high
FDI income outflow that exceeds FDI inflow, but FDI outflow equals FDI inflow, though income on
FDI outflow is still lower than inward FDI income. In all cases, it is the income balance of the
current account that has the relevance and needs to be accompanied by enhanced export capacities,
i.e. positive trade balance, created by FDI. Otherwise, by covering current account deficits or
financing domestic market-oriented projects, net FDI will not generate foreign exchange earnings
that increase financial fragility. Therefore, reinvested profits should be directed into exportable,
technologically more advanced, higher value-added, and R&D-intensive products.
In general, mature FDI countries attract less new FDI and loose more in terms of income to
foreign owners in the form of higher shares of repatriated incomes - FDI becomes a source of
income outflow and creates more current account deficit than it finances (ibid.). Thus, it is the issue
of maturity of FDI and the way external finances are utilized, that define country’s position in
Minsky’s classification of financing units. By contrasting the FDI income-related three-stage model
with debt sustainable „debt-cum-growth“ three-stage model (see Kregel 2007c, 13-14), mutual
relatedness and impact of both concepts on each other can be detected. Namely, successful
completion of long-term cycle of debt sustainable development, which might take up to 50 years,
would require the building up of adequate export sectors that generate sufficient returns on the use
of foreign resources. However, the first stage of this long-term cycle might get disrupted by the
reversal of capital flows in the form of repatriated FDI-related incomes, as the FDI income-related
three-stage cycle tends to come to an end within much shorter period. Difficulties arise, if by the end
of this period there are insignificant FDI outflows and weak export capacities exist. On the other
hand, in a situation, where exports grow more rapidly than the overall economy, the success of
exporting will attract more capital inflows and cause inappropriate exchange rate appreciation
(Kregel 2004a, 13-14), implying the overall growth in foreign claims and accumulation of FDIrelated incomes.
15
I. 3
POLICY RESPONSES AND MEASURES
When considering the impact of economic liberalization in terms of external financing of
development and the role of FDI, some mercantilist principles24 need to be taken into consideration
(Reinert 2004, 7, 15). Even though the deregulation of capital flows, trade liberalization, and
privatization were one of the cornerstones of Washington Consensus policies, some concessions
were considered with regard to infant industry protection and the speed of opening domestic markets
(Williamson 1990). On the other hand, for Nurkse (1952, 176-177) the priority was given to infant
creation, rather than infant protection by tariffs and other means. Even so, in order to service
accumulated foreign debt, priority should be given to continuous productivity growth and expanded
export base of manufacturing sector that would improve terms of trade as well as hedging
opportunities (Frisch 2003, 26-28; Saad-Filho 2005, 133-145; Sanderson 2009, 45-49). Furthermore,
monetary authorities need to be granted mandates to implement prudential financial regulations,
monetary policies, and capital controls in order to alleviate financial fragility (UNCTAD 1998, 8789). For small states there is a wide range of policy measures in curbing deepening crisis and
avoiding the next round of disturbances.
I. 3.1 PRUDENTIAL BANKING AND CAPITAL-ACCOUNT REGULATIONS
The promotion of financial stability in small countries would require the introduction of countercyclical measures in terms of time-varying capital-account and banking regulations. In general,
policy-makers have the option to choose between three different, but over-lapping, interventionist
modes:
• controls - price controls and quantitative restrictions on the allocation of bank portfolio in
certain sectors; restrictions or ceilings on short-term inflows and outflows; restrictions on
end use of foreign borrowings or even prohibition of some investment activities; controls
over international inter-bank lending; regulations on foreign borrowing in foreign currency
and by non-tradable sectors; taxes on foreign borrowing and debt securities; exit taxes on
investments and capital gains; restrictions on convertibility of deposits; rules concerning
repatriation;
• limits - limits on loan-to-collateral-value ratios on mortgage lending or rules on the valuation
of collateral; limitation of scope for leveraged financing; limits on equity ownership of
certain financial activities;
• requirements - adjustable capital adequacy ratio and risk weights, unremunerated reserve
requirement for capital inflows, non-interest bearing liquidity requirements for banks,
minimum stay period for foreign capital; imposition to use local currency in domestic
transactions and denominate loans in domestic currency (UNCTAD 1998, 96-105; UN
2009a, 64-128; Ocampo 2002, 4-14, 19-20; Ocampo et al. 2007, 45-52; O`Connell 2006, 3436; Wade 2008; Wade 2009, 548-550; Cruz, Walters 2008, 665-673).
The implementation of foregoing price- or quantity-based capital market regulations must be in
accordance with economic cycles. During boom periods, these adjustable measures should avoid
excessive indebtedness and risk-taking by suppressing rapid increase in lending, and deter currency
24
Include protection for industry-building, targeting and support to specific economic activities of increasing returns by
providing cheap credit, and temporary monopolies.
16
and maturity mismatches (Ocampo 2002, 4-14, 19-20). All these measures together with managed
exchange rate can mitigate financial fragility by encouraging desirable investments, maintaining
competitive exchange rates25, preventing capital flight, and avoiding the accumulation of excessive
debt and FDI (UNCTAD 1998, 96-105).
I. 3.2 MACRO-ECONOMIC POLICIES – MONETARY AND FISCAL POLICIES
One of the policy responses to financial fragility has encompassed the accumulation of foreign
exchange reserves26 to increase liquidity against output contractions, halted capital inflows, or
capital flight (Cruz, Walters 2008, 665-673). However, when financial crises accrue from heavy
indebtedness that involve a high concentration of both speculative or Ponzi finance, there is a need
for counter-cyclical (budget deficits during recession) fiscal policies after the crisis has hit (Minsky
1991, 15-16, 26-29), as both Minsky and Keynes considered stable asset prices and income growth
as essential economic targets (Parenteau 2008). Thus, fiscal and monetary policies should be aimed
at supporting asset prices and demand, i.e. income and employment (Kregel 1998b, 11-14; Kregel
2008c, 24), while accumulated reserves do not meet this requirement due to high opportunity cost
and thereby, negative impact on domestic demand. Thus, the rationale for flexible exchange rates
emanates from no need for foreign capital accumulation, which would enable to secure monetary
sovereignty and shift attention to domestic demand driven growth27 by the implementation of
Keynesian policies (Kregel 2007a, 25-31).
When considering the implementation of income policies, governments must keep a tight
rein on income growth in sheltered sector28 that can lead to cost-push inflation in whole economy
and undermine price competitiveness of exposed sector in international markets. Under the currency
board system, wage-cost increases must be absorbed as the losses in profitability or production
level, because output prices are set in international markets and small countries are unable to affect
international prices of tradable goods and services – these countries tend to be price-takers. (Fischer
2002, 4; Moses 2000, 26-28) Furthermore, as a result of inflow of cheap credit, propensity to
consume rather than enhance productive capacity would lead to inflationary pressures, implying the
need for a taxation of expenditures that would increase the propensity to save and cool off the
economy29.
By following the strategy of reliance on external financing for domestic economic
development, the leeway of using monetary policies depends on the presence of foreign investments
in either tradable or non-tradable sectors, as currency fluctuations represent higher currency risk for
investors in non-tradable goods and services that do not generate foreign exchange earnings
(Ocampo et al. 2007, 30).
25
Central banks in Asian countries have been imposing capital controls to avoid appreciating domestic currencies and
inflating asset prices by excessive liquidity (Roubini 2009).
26
After the Asian crisis in 1997-1998, developing countries have strived for strong external accounts that have reduced
external debt ratios and increased foreign exchange reserves (Ocampo et al. 2007, 155).
27
Taiwan is an example of a small state that has subordinated fiscal and monetary policies to industrial concerns –
exchange rate adjustments to lower costs of imported inputs and to increase domestic currency returns for exporting
manufacturing sector; imposition of tariffs to promote exports and promotion of more specialization by sectoral
allocating of foreign exchange and cheap credit (Wade 1992, 77-79, 85, 93-95).
28
Including sectors that focus on the production of non-tradable goods, where foreign investments might dominate.
29
Similar argument was used by Nurkse (1952, 204) for compulsory saving by fiscal methods in order to increase
capital accumulation.
17
As in the capitalist system the functioning of real economy and also financing of innovations
rely on the lending activity of banks, prevailing debt-deflationary processes or economic recession
freeze their activity on credit market. Thus, if central bank does not provide reserves for stable
lending activity of banks, interest rates will rise and borrowing terms deteriorate, which may
decrease credit and economic activity. Thus, the role of central bank as a lender of last resort cannot
be underestimated in backing the asset prices. (Lavoie 1985, 843-848) In order to prevent poverty
and involuntary unemployment, government should implement countercyclical expansionary macroeconomic policies (cuts in discount rates or even money supply at 0-interest rates) once demand is
constrained by liquidity preference as a result of deflationary processes (Minsky cited in Wray,
2008; Szentes 2005, 153-155; UN 2009b, 4-5; Kregel 2009b, 4; Eichengreen, O`Rourke 2009). In
case of excess supply of labor and declined economic activity, public policies need to focus on
directing finances towards productive investments and enhancing domestic demand by improving
the distribution of income. If necessary, government should run a deficit (dis-save) by increased
expenditures30 and/or reduced taxes or through employer of last resort program31 (Kregel 2009a,
662-663; Kregel 2009c, 46, 52; McCulley 2008). Otherwise, government’s inclination to save can
have negative effects on economy, if there is a demand gap to be filled, whereas reduced
government expenditures during the debt-deflation crisis increase the cost of borrowed stock, but
more importantly, have negative effect on domestic demand, employment, and economic growth32
(Kregel 2002, 13-16; Kregel 2004c, 3-6; Kregel 2008b, 14-15; Nersisyan, Wray 2010).
As a rule, financial crises restrict the use of counter-cyclical policies in developing (and
transition) countries due to shrinking tax revenues and constraints set by international agreements or
institutions (e.g. Stability and Growth Pact, WTO, IMF etc.) (UN 2009a, 25, 67, 80-82, 102, 112;
Papadimitriou 2008). However, more fundamental problem for small states with deregulated capitalaccount stems from the adversarial impact of Keynesian macroeconomic policies, i.e. both fiscal and
monetary policies, on attaining both internal and external balance simultaneously, as demand and
supply relations have cross-border characteristics and thereby, domestic demand targeting policies
can have negative effect on external balance (Moses 2000, 31-43). The positive effect of Keynesian
income and investment policies in confronting the scarcity of demand can be evaporated due to high
income elasticity of demand for imports that leads to balance of payments difficulties (Arestis 1996,
119-121). On the other hand, taxes and interest rates as indirect measures, used to rectify external
balance, limit the ability to direct internal economy (Moses 2000, 31-43), while direct measures,
such as tariffs and exchange rate adjustments, cannot be enforced in countries that follow rigid
exchange rate systems and have been bound by international (e.g. EU) legal framework or free-trade
agreements set up by international organizations (e.g. WTO). Thus, in small open economies strong
30
The 1997-98 Asian crisss hit less hardly those South-East Asian countries, like South-Korea, Malaysia, Hong-Kong
that implemented stabilization policies more vigorously (stimulus packages, currency depreciations, openness to FDI in
R&D etc.) (UNCTAD 2009).
31
Although fiscal discipline and implicit disdain for Keynesian budget deficits were on Washington Consensus agenda,
short-term deficits were acceptable for macroeconomic stabilization, especially, if public deficit expenditures were made
in education, health, and infrastructure (Williamson 1990).
32
After the 2001 financial crisis in Turkey, the government followed IMF prescribed contractionary fiscal and monetary
policies, which supported an overvalued exchange rate, inflow of speculative-led financial capital, and thereby deficits
on trade and current account balance, but signaled a reduced political autonomy to deal with developmental issues,
implying a jobless growth (Yeldan 2006, 1). Similarly, years before, during financial crisis in East Asia, the affected
countries suffered from imprudent private sector that could not be cured with fiscal austerity measures and tighter
monetary policies, as higher interest rates and reduced government expenditures would have had devastative effect on
domestic demand and highly indebted firms, leading to bankruptcies (Stiglitz 2000).
18
macroeconomic policies are of limited use, implying the pursuit for productive sector policies
(Ocampo 2009, 723).
I. 3.3 FDI POLICIES
There are different aspects that specific FDI policies are ascribed to target - entry conditions and
local procurement by transnational companies, creation of employment opportunities, distribution of
production and revenues between local and foreign companies etc. (UNCTAD 2009). Development
impact of FDI can be achieved with policies that are compatible with national development plans,
promote forward and backward production linkages between foreign and domestic firms, encourage
exports with higher value-added, enhance an access to foreign technology and knowledge, and
ensure appropriate size and distribution of FDI to be self-financing. FDI could be linked to domestic
economy through support to clusters33, the success of which depends on the existence of favorable
investment climate, skilled labor and infrastructure. (Ocampo et al. 2007, 33-34; Kregel 2007b, 1622) As technical change of productive sector, together with economies of scale and increasing
returns, occur only, if higher investment expenditures are expected in the future, policies should be
aimed at generating positive externalities by inducing complementary investments that are
connected to FDI, and encouraging joint ventures by imposing restrictions on operation of wholly
owned subsidiaries, as has been the case in Taiwan, Republic of Korea, and Japan. Thus, investment
control mechanisms should be implemented to deal with the constraints that are related to
insufficient innovation, unskilled labor force, lack of training, poor research etc. (Arestis 1996, 126128; Pack 2006, 32-33, 44-47; Djankov, Hoekman 2006, 162-165, 175)
Thus, both human resource development and entrepreneurial capacity enhancement to absorb
imported technologies and knowledge should be emphasized and linkages of domestic companies to
international production networks promoted by public policies - aspects that have been left out in
neo-classical economics. In addition, mergers and acquisitions that stall off domestic enterprises and
eliminate linkages need to be hindered34. All in all, emphasis should be placed on policies that create
incentives to channel FDI into projects that yield the highest return and restore current account
balance.
33
In Hungary, there are several inward FDI supportive measures, such as creation of industrial parks and clusters,
incubator houses, and R&D facilities, grants, interest subsidies, and loan guarantees. In addition, R&D expenditures are
eligible for tax deduction and (Van Beers 2003, 63, 65-66, 69-72, 74, 79).
34
In East-Asian countries FDI inflows are strictly regulated, e.g. joint ventures are encouraged with domestic public and
private companies, and exports must include a share of products that are produced by indigenous enterprises (Martin,
Schumann 1999, 153-154).
19
II
EMPIRICAL FINDINGS AND EVIDENCE – THE CASE OF
THREE BALTIC STATES
The purpose of this chapter is to explain the nature and peculiarities of economic systems in three
Baltic States, and to address the financial fragility in these countries by relying on the theoretical
concepts that were presented in previous paragraphs. The presentation of explanatory patterns and
regularities will be based on previously conducted studies about the presence of FDI in the Baltic
States. In addition, by using and interpreting statistical data on FDI, capital flows, and investment
activities, the analysis of three countries tries to compare the empirical findings with theoretical
positions that explain the dynamics behind financial crises. However, author acknowledges that
uneven coverage and insufficient revision of FDI-related legal frameworks of the mentioned
countries could be criticized, and thereby, thorough conclusions cannot be made.
At first, the region of Central and Eastern Europe (CEE) is to be observed, as in broader
terms, historical and developmental parallels could be brought out between ten new European Union
(EU) member states that joined the EU in 2004. Therefore, findings on CEE level are more or less
deductible for the Baltic States.
On the whole, CEE countries have followed the path of FDI-led growth that can be
explained by the reliance on Washington Consensus policies and the reasoning behind the current
ICT-based techno-economic paradigm. Another element behind growing inflows of foreign capital
has been relatively high nominal interest rates in CEE countries at the end of last decade (UN 2003,
11-16). Nevertheless, growing FDI in CEE countries has not engendered upgrading in economic
structures. On the contrary, after the liberalization of capital markets and prices, demand for the
products of domestic companies was cut down. This led to deindustrialization in terms of increased
unemployment in industries and declined share of industries´ value added in GDP. In addition, the
presence of FDI has negatively affected advanced industries, which has translated into reduced
demand for R&D. There are no significant technology spillovers in CEE countries - producer-user
chains are cross-border and circumvent domestic economic actors. By keeping pre- and postproduction activities at home, transnational companies have specialized in host countries mainly in
simple production activities at the lower end of value chain without significant linkages to domestic
economy. In other words, the main motives for TNC have been to gain advantage from cheap labor
and access to CEE markets. (Van Beers 2003, 63-66, 69-75) Thus, the problem for CEE countries is
related to specialization in low- and medium-technology industries or low value-added production
stages of value chains, i.e. outsourced labor-intensive economic activities that rely on imports, while
high-wage jobs, scale effects, vertical integration, and new technologies have not been attained
(Reinert et al. 2009, 16; Kattel et al. 2009, 6, 18; Kattel, Primi 2008, 10-14, 17-19; Drechsler et al.
2006, 20-21, 24-28) The afore-mentioned drawback is partly explainable by intrinsic deficiencies in
CEE countries that hinder the efficient utilization of foreign capital and technologies for upgrading.
These are: 1) fragmented institutions and lack of cooperation35, 2) emphasis on capital formation,
not on knowledge creation, and 3) technology transfer process as linear dialogue between providerreceiver that does not have wider and large-scale spillover effects. (Saad et al. 2008, 431-432)
35
In Taiwan, Government has pursued the involvement of different stakeholders in policy formation, and bringing
together domestic and foreign companies. Network institutions promoted cooperation and development, while
fragmentation and low-skill subcontracting were avoided. (O Riain 2004, 196-199; Wade 1992, 90-91, 98)
20
However, despite its negative effects, FDI penetration has entailed higher productivity, salaries, and
exports, when compared to domestic companies (Havlik et al. 2001, 3/28-3/32).
In the case of the Baltic States, the presence of foreign affiliates in Latvia and Lithuania has
not established forward or backward linkages nor induced spillover effects to domestic companies
because of the preference for imported intermediate goods. On the contrary, increased competition
has negatively affected the performance of local companies in the same industry, thereby resulting
in decreased output and diseconomies of scale. (Javorcik 2006a, 180-189, 201; Pack 2006, 32-33,
44-47; Djankov, Hoekman 2006, 162-165, 175) In Estonia, manufacturing industries have been
locked into simple production activities in international value chains that lack creative innovations
and assembly mature products for saturating markets. Enterprises in Estonia as subcontractors to
Western companies have rather strategic linkages with Scandinavian partners than with each other
domestically, implying the lack of user-producer relations and isolation. Moreover, high-technology
industries have been decoupled from traditional spheres of Estonian economy, meaning lack of
exchange of knowledge and skills (Högselius 2005, 264-266, 271-274; see also Tiits et al. 2006,
163) In general, the completion of privatization in the Baltic States, either through FDI or other
means, has resulted in overall technological downgrading and decreasing share of medium as well as
high technologies in manufacturing value-added (King, Hamm 2008, 12, 30; Kattel, Anton 2004,
106-128), which explains the export specialization of these countries in low value-added products,
produced by simple assembly activities in labor-intensive low- or medium-technology industries
(Havlik et al. 2001, iii-iv, Kattel 2009, 11-13). In addition, as FDI in CEE region is shifting towards
services at the expense of manufacturing sector (except Slovakia, the Czech Republic, Hungary,
which have strong exports by FDI companies) (Hunya 2008, 7-14, 21; Hunya 2009, 13), only few
FDI-intensive branches account for the majority of manufacturing industry output (Havlik et al.
2001, iii-iv; 3/28-3/32). Three main manufacturing industry branches for inward FDI in Estonia and
Latvia are: 1) food products, beverages and tobacco, 2) wood and wood products, and 3) nonmetallic mineral products, while in Lithuania, chemicals, refined petroleum and nuclear fuel
production, and food products absorb the majority of inward FDI in manufacturing sector (Hunya
2009, 73-81). The following charts define the distribution of inward FDI stock by economic
activities in three Baltic States and by the formed proportions, it can be concluded that in more
disadvantageous position is Latvia in terms of directing FDI into productive manufacturing sector.
On the other hand, Lithuania's better position in terms of the ability to service foreign claims in the
future can be explained by the highest share of FDI stock in manufacturing sector that has the
potential to generate foreign currency earnings.
21
Chart 1: Inward FDI stock by economic activities in three Baltic States, 2008
ESTONIA
3%
3%2%
6%
Financial intermediation
Real estate, renting & business
activities
34%
12%
Manufacturing
Wholesale, retail trade, repair of
veh. etc
Transport, storage and
communication
Electricity, gas and water supply
14%
Construction
Other sectors
26%
LATVIA
14%
Financial intermediation
28%
2%
4%
Real estate, renting & business
activities
Manufacturing
Wholesale, retail trade, repair of
veh. etc
Transport, storage and
communication
Electricity, gas and water supply
8%
Construction
14%
Other sectors
21%
9%
LITHUANIA
2%
7%
16%
Financial intermediation
8%
Real estate, renting & business
activities
Manufacturing
14%
16%
Wholesale, retail trade, repair of
veh. etc
Transport, storage and
communication
Electricity, gas and water supply
Construction
Other sectors
14%
23%
Source: Hunya, 2009.
22
By interpreting the data, presented on the charts above, it appears that the Baltic States are unable or
unwilling to direct foreign capital away from investments that do not generate foreign currency
earnings, but induce inflationary speculative-led growth. The majority of inward FDI stock is
represented in the segments that target host country market by producing non-tradable goods.
Furthermore, as already mentioned, the vulnerability for the Baltic States stems from narrow
specializations in low value-added activities that form a weak basis for exports, while the limited
number of exporting articles increases the sensitivity to fluctuations in external markets. Due to less
complexity in economy and technologies, these states face deteriorating terms of trade, which
exacerbate sustainable growth in foreign currency earnings. Hence, as the unaccomplished
upgrading of economies with malfunctioning national innovation systems and liberal economic
policies have made it unfeasible to pursue domestic demand-led growth, the Baltic States tend to
remain dependent on debt- or at best export-led growth. In such circumstances, economic
environment is prone to the realization of Minsky-Kregel moment of financial fragility and eventual
crisis, once economic agents with high foreign exposure become illiquid due to cessation of
inflowing foreign capital or other detrimental events, such as exchange rate fluctuations, changes in
interest rates, internal deflation etc.
II. 1 MACRO-LEVEL DEVELOPMENTS
The most obvious signs of disorder in the financial structures of the Baltic States and impending
turmoil came to the fore in 2008, when global financial crisis erupted. The U.S. sub-prime crisis and
the following global credit crunch affected severely CEE region via financial channels (Ocampo
2009, 719-722), as the rate of repatriated incomes to non-residents started to increase, while the
inflow of FDI into the region has been on a declining trend since 2008 because of stalling economic
growth in export markets, falling demand, declining profits, excess capacities, and also internal
problems in CEE countries. There have been production cuts and layoffs in financial services,
automotive industry, and building materials, i.e. the sectors that have been carrying forward rapid
economic expansion in CEE region. Furthermore, FDI inflows in the form of equity investments
have lost momentum due to largely completed privatization, which infers to (over)reliance on
reinvested profits and (bank) loans. For these reasons, the current dynamics of FDI reflect the
features of maturing FDI in most of the CEE countries. (Hunya 2008, i, 7; Hunya 2009, i, 6)
23
Figure 1: FDI inflows in selected CEE countries, EUR mil, 2003-2009
10000
8000
Estonia
EUR, mil
6000
Latvia
Lithuania
4000
Hungary
Czech Republic
2000
Slovenia
0
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
-2000
Years
Source: Hunya, 2009
As described in the chapter I.3, the balance between financial inflows and outflows can be
determined by the level of maturity of FDI in host country, which also could be considered as an
indicator of forthcoming financial turbulence. The high ratio of current account deficit to GDP,
caused by growing share of out-flowing FDI-related income (interest or dividends) of non-residents
in the current account, is considered to be one of the causes of financial instability. On the other
hand, net FDI tends to cover current account deficits, as it has been in the case of Baltic States
(Hunya 2008, 15, 18; Hunya 2009, 16). In more advanced new member states of the EU, like
Slovenia, net FDI finances smaller part of current account deficit because of growing outward FDI.
Nevertheless, as most of the new EU member states, including Czech Republic, Hungary, Slovakia,
and Estonia, are reaching the stage of mature FDI, i.e. high FDI income outflow that exceeds FDI
inflow, thriving outflows need to be accompanied by enhanced export capacities and positive trade
balance, created by FDI. In ideal scenario, reinvested profits should be directed into exportable,
technologically more advanced, higher value-added, and R&D-intensive products. However, the
reality presents opposite picture, as already described in previous paragraph - FDI has gone mainly
into domestic market oriented projects or weak export sectors, especially in Estonia and Latvia,
while decreasing profits have precluded from reinvesting the profits. In general terms, by 2009 FDI
has become a source of income outflow and creates more current account deficit than it finances in
CEE region (Hunya 2008, 18-21; Hunya 2009, 16-19).
24
Figure 2: FDI inflows compared to FDI-related income outflow in selected CEE countries,
EUR mil, 2003-2008
12000
11000
10000
9000
8000
7000
6000
5000
4000
3000
2000
1000
0
2003
EUR, mil
2004
2005
2006
2007
Hungary
Czech
Republic
Slovenia
Estonia
Latvia
income
outflow
inflow
income
outflow
inflow
income
outflow
inflow
income
outflow
inflow
income
outflow
inflow
income
outflow
inflow
2008
Lithuania
Source: Hunya, 2009
As seen from figures 1 and 2, FDI inflows have gradually decreased, but more importantly, FDI
income outflows have leveled FDI inflows or even exceeded, especially in more advanced CEE
countries, like Hungary and Czech Republic. Latvia and Lithuania still experience higher FDI
inflows than FDI-related income outflows. However, more important indicator of deepening
fragility is the high ratio of repatriation of FDI-related income in FDI income outflow, given that a
country is highly dependent on foreign capital, but faces decreasing FDI inflows. As it was already
mentioned, mature FDI countries get little new FDI and loose in terms of income to non-residents.
Hence, very high ratio could signal capital flight, triggered by decreasing profits or revenues. When
comparing the positions of Latvia and Slovenia in the Figure 3, one must acknowledge that
Slovenia's inward FDI stock as a percentage to outward FDI stock was 210% in 2008, while in
Latvia the same percentage was 1073% (Hunya 2009), implying much better prospects for the
conformity of FDI income outflow to inflow in Slovenia36.
36
In Estonia 244%, in Lithuania 645%.
25
Figure 3: Inward FDI stock as % of GDP, and share of repatriated FDI income in FDI income
outflow as %, in selected CEE countries, 2008
100
80
Inward FDI stock as % of GDP
40
Share of repatriated FDI income in
FDI income outflow, %
%
60
20
0
Hungary
Czech
Republic
Slovenia
Estonia
Latvia
Lithuania
Source: Hunya 2009, author's calculations
On the other hand, low level of repatriated profits and growing FDI inward stock refer to
reinvestment activities by FDI companies. Nevertheless, the reliance on reinvested profits,
especially, if these are made in the sectors that do not generate foreign currency earnings, make
these economies very sensitive to domestic disturbances, as once the prospects deteriorate for
continuing profits, disincentives for foreign investors emerge and the overall FDI stock plummets.
So far, FDI inward stock has been steadily growing in all CEE countries (see figure 4), but that
could be explained by the real appreciation of the currencies (see Figure 5) that have had a
complementary effect on the increase of FDI stock in the context of waning inflows of new FDI.
26
Figure 4: FDI inward stock in selected CEE countries, EUR mil, 2003-2008
90000
80000
70000
60000
EUR, mil
Estonia
Latvia
50000
Lithuania
Hungary
40000
Czech Republic
Slovenia
30000
20000
10000
0
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
Years
Source: Hunya, 2009.
Figure 5: Real effective exchange rates in selected CEE countries, index 1999 = 100
180
170
Index
160
150
Hungary
140
Czech
Slovenia
130
Estonia
Latvia
120
Lithuania
110
100
90
1999
2000
2001
2002
2003
2004
Years
Source: Eurostat (2010a).
27
2005
2006
2007
2008
Uncompetitive exchange rates of the Baltic States could be considered as one of the factors behind
deteriorating net trade balances until 2007/2008, as can be seen from the following figure.
Improvement in the trade balances since 2008/2009 has had a positive effect on external balance,
but in absolute numbers, both exports and imports have fallen, which in the context of growing debt
burden is insignificant achievement.
Figure 6: Net trade balance in Goods and Service in the Baltic States, 2003-2009, EUR mil
25000
20000
EUR, mil
15000
Exports
Imports
10000
Net trade balance
5000
-5000
Estonia
Latvia
2009
2008
2007
2006
2005
2004
2003
2009
2008
2007
2006
2005
2004
2003
2009
2008
2007
2006
2005
2004
2003
0
Lithuania
Source: Eurostat (2010a), Bank of Estonia, Bank of Lithuania, Bank of Latvia, author’s calculations
As already discussed, mature FDI countries tend to create current account deficit rather than finance
it. The main explanation behind deteriorating current accounts in the Baltic States during previous
years (see Figure 7) could be found in abolished trade restrictions and easy credit that drove
economic expansion by financing consumption and real estate bubble (Lucas 2009; Hugh 2009). For
years, foreign borrowing and aggressive lending policies of Scandinavian countries have deepened
trade deficits, which have made these countries highly dependent on imported goods (Hudson 2008,
74). Additionally, appreciating currencies and unsustainable wage growth (see IMF 2009, 9; Hugh
2009) have aggravated current account balances in the Baltic States by evaporating the
competitiveness of export products. In general, foreign capital in Estonia, Latvia, and Lithuania has
caused distress from both real exchange rate appreciations, as wages have been growing faster than
productivity, and worsening current account deficits that have deteriorated overall balance of
payments position (Kattel, Primi 2008, 10-14, 17-19; Havlik et al. 2001, i-ii).
28
Figure 7: Current account (bars) and net FDI inflow (lines) as % of GDP in selected member
states, 2000-2008
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
60
50
40
Estonia
Latvia
Lithuania
30
% of GDP
Czech Republic
Hungary
20
Slovenia
Estonia
10
Latvia
Lithuania
0
Czech Republic
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
Hungary
Slovenia
-10
-20
-30
Years
Source: Eurostat (2010a), World Bank 2010.
By comparing the current account balance with net FDI position as percentages of GDP in the Baltic
States, we can observe the non-compliance of these indicators in terms of much wider current
account deficit that cannot be covered by net FDI, implying the reliance on other sources, i.e. capital
flows as loans and portfolio investments, in financing negative current account. Thus, the essential
problem of the Baltic States derives from unsustainable debt-led growth, as the ratio of gross
external debt to GDP, an indicator often used to assess country's indebtedness, has increased in all
three Baltic States since 2003 and the annual growth rate of external debt has been positive until
2009 (see Figure 8). The vulnerability to the stability of financial system is added by noncorresponding increases in foreign reserves, as in the context of increasing external indebtedness,
the ability to service debt with foreign official reserves has declined or at best stagnated (see Figure
9). Even though the relative official reserves in Estonia and Latvia have been improving during last
two years, the worrisome is their relatively low level.
29
Figure 8: Gross external debt as % of GDP (bars) and annual growth rate of gross external
debt as percentage change on previous year (lines) in the Baltic States, 2003-2008
160%
140%
120%
100%
Estonia
Latvia
80%
Lithuania
Estonia
60%
Latvia
Lithuania
40%
20%
0%
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
-20%
Years
Source: Bank of Estonia, 2010, Bank of Latvia, 2010, Bank of Lithuania, 2010, author's calculations
Figure 9: Foreign official reserves as % of gross external debt in the Baltic States, 2003-2008,
annual base
45
40
35
30
Estonia
20
Latvia
Lithuania
%
25
15
10
5
0
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
Years
Source: Bank of Estonia, 2010, Bank of Latvia, 2010, Bank of Lithuania, 2010, Eurostat (2010a), author's calculations
These negative developments in terms of rapid increase in foreign indebtedness have been made
possible by negative real interest rates (see Figure 10) in three Baltic States prior to the global
financial crisis at the end of 2008 that made it cheap to borrow, and in particular in foreign currency,
as all these countries have pegged their currencies to Euro.
30
Figure 10: Money market interest rates and inflation rate in the Baltic States, 2003-2009,
Quarterly data
ESTONIA
money market interest rates
inflation rate
14
12
10
%
8
6
4
2
0
-2
Jan
Apr
Jul
Oct
Jan
Apr
Jul
Oct
Jan
Apr
Jul
Oct
Jan
Apr
Jul
Oct
Jan
Apr
Jul
Oct
Jan
Apr
Jul
Oct
Jan
Apr
Jul
Oct
-4
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
2009
Months, Years
LATVIA
money market interest rates
inflation rate
20
18
16
14
%
12
10
8
6
4
2
0
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
Jul
Oct
Oct
Jan
Apr
Jan
Apr
Jul
Apr
Jul
Oct
Jul
Oct
Jan
Oct
Jan
Apr
Jan
Apr
Jul
Apr
Jul
Oct
Jul
Oct
Jan
Jan
Apr
-2
-4
2009
Months, Years
LITHUANIA
money market interest rates
inflation rate
14
12
10
%
8
6
4
2
0
-2
2003
2004
2005
2006
2007
2008
Months, Years
Source: Eurostat (2010a), EBRD, 2010.
31
Jul
Oct
Apr
Jul
Oct
Jan
Apr
Jan
Apr
Jul
Oct
Jan
Jan
Apr
Jul
Oct
Oct
Jan
Apr
Jul
Oct
Jul
Oct
Jan
Apr
Jul
Jan
Apr
-4
2009
The same figure brings out very fast growth in price levels that has been accompanied by rising
wages, but with no productivity growth. Thus, Baltic economies can be characterized as bubble
economies, where foreign capital has been directed into services, financial intermediation, real
estate, and other businesses that target domestic markets, tend to generate imports, and boom via
inflating prices. (Hunya 2008, 7-14, 21; Hunya 2009, 13; Kattel 2007)
II. 2 THE FINANCIAL FRAGILITY IN THE BALTIC STATES
Based on empirical evidence and theoretical propositions, it can be concluded that one of the main
causes behind the financial fragility in the Baltic States, in particular in Estonia and Latvia, are the
asymmetrical relationships between these countries and the rest of the EU in terms of economic
integration, trading patterns, and exchange rate alignments. Industrialized EU countries have kept a
tight hold on research, design, development, finance, and ownership of intellectual property,
whereas the Baltic States have been engaged in lower end activities of value chain, implying the
provision of manufacturing contracting, and have to cope with the outflow of profits and wealth in
exchange for FDI (Lane 2008, 5, 8-15). While these elements were rooted already in the 1990s, the
effects of mentioned asymmetries took much larger magnitude after the EU enlargement in 2004, as
the implementation of EU legislation and liberal economic policies on national level (no property
tax, abolished trade and capital restrictions, flat tax) enabled capital inflows to increase very rapidly.
The presence of foreign capital in small Baltic States has not contributed to sustainable economic
development by supporting innovative manufacturing activities, subject to increasing returns that
create synergetic mutual interdependences and spillover effects37. The logic behind balanced growth
has not been pursued and the integration of FDI companies into the host economy has not been
achieved. On the contrary, the specialization in labor-intensive assembly operations and low valueadded products in low- or medium-technology industries has meant the transfer of cumulative
multiplier effects in terms of additional employment, productivity, externalities, and know-how to
home countries of FDI (see Kattel, Anton 2004, 106-128). In the long term these maturing
technologies have to face with decreasing potential for innovation and diminishing foreign currency
returns. Baltic economies are also made vulnerable by the displacement of domestic producers as a
result of high concentration of foreign capital in certain sectors, e.g. commercial banking sector.
Above all, the core reason behind deepening financial fragility in the Baltic States could be
ascribed to prolonged period of stability, as in the context of lowered risk-perception and aggressive
lending activity by foreign banks, markets gave wrong signals that resulted in leveraged structures
and extensive use of credit for inappropriate debt-financed investments in terms of distribution and
amount. Because of excessive demand and easy credit (see Figure 11), external financing
concentrated in limited number of economic activities that triggered speculation-led inflation. As a
result, Estonia and other Baltic States have witnessed skyrocketing asset prices and private
consumption along with increased wages that have enabled debt-led growth with current account
deficits (Lucas 2009; Kattel 2009, 11-13).
37
In East Asian case state-led industrialization together with feedback linkages and positive externalities played a major
role in the development process (Kattel et al. 2009, 14).
32
Figure 11: Domestic credit to household as % of GDP in the Baltic States, 2003-2008
50
45
40
% of GDP
35
30
other credit
mortgage
25
20
15
10
5
Estonia
Latvia
2008
2007
2006
2005
2004
2003
2008
2007
2006
2005
2004
2003
2008
2007
2006
2005
2004
2003
0
Lithuania
Source: EBRD, 2010
In the context of liberalized capital markets and lax banking regulations, one of the main factors
behind such worsening economic conditions is the exchange rate systems that have been adopted in
the Baltic States. Currency board arrangements in Estonia and Lithuania, and rigid pegged exchange
rate in Latvia have not been able to adjust external imbalances with the contraction of monetary
base, as capital inflows offset both current account deficit and decline in money supply. Estonian
currency board arrangement has entailed enormous per capita FDI, as liberalized economy with
completely free capital movements and without any restriction on the flows of currency and capital,
or restrictive provisions on depositing currency and interest rates on loans or deposits resulted in
relatively high growth of money supply due to large capital inflows (Sõrg, Vensel 2002, 37-38).
Such expansionary effects, i.e. escalating inflation, fed by increased money supply, resulted in the
ongoing real appreciation of domestic currencies that worsened current account balances. Hence,
either deflationary developments or capital outflows threaten the economic systems, especially
banking sector, in the Baltic States, as in both scenario countries could get deprived from liquidity in
terms of depleted foreign reserves due to increased demand for foreign currency. As of 2008, banks`
liabilities to non-residents in Estonia had reached 70% of GDP and the share of loans in banks`
assets 76% of GDP (Hugh 2009). Thereby, should Estonian indebted banking sector become illiquid
in the system of currency board, either currency or banking crisis occurs.
Sooner or later the payment of amortization, dividends, and interest as an outflow of capital
from developing countries approaches and eventually exceeds inflows. Even though capital outflow
is not on the agenda at the moment, there are first signs of trouble. The most distinct indicator of
financial problems in the Baltic States is the worsening net international investment position that
was -81,8% of GDP, -95,3% of GDP in Latvia, and -61,2% of GDP in Lithuania in 200938. In
addition, at least Estonia has to cope with maturing FDI, where FDI-related income outflow has
reached the level of FDI inflows. The problem is related to the structural composition of FDI38
author’s calculations, based on data provided by National Banks of the Baltic States.
33
dominated manufacturing sector that poses the danger of insufficient foreign exchange earnings in
the long run or capital flight before the first stage of long-term debt sustainable development is
concluded, as matured low- or medium-technologies face the saturation of markets, low profit
margins, and decreasing demand. Thus, the Minsky moment of financial fragility and eventual crisis
can be realized by the drop in FDI stock due to shrinking profits and plummeting stock prices that
would induce divestments and, in turn, result in increased unemployment and pressures on fixed
exchange rates. Furthermore, massive sale-offs would have a contagion effect that leads to
decreasing value of assets and shareholders` equity, implying the typical Minsky's Ponzi position,
where liabilities of indebted private entities cannot be met. In the current global economic recession
the stock prices have also declined in CEE countries, such as Estonia and Hungary, where FDI
inward stock has been the largest as a proportion to GDP (Hunya 2009, 13). In Estonia such
downtrend developments in stock markets would severely affect households, as 70,2% of their
financial assets are held in equities (Zirnask 2009).
By considering the second risk, namely deflationary developments, it can be observed from
Figure 10 that deflation hit the Baltic economies already in the middle of 2008 before the global
financial crisis. The consumption and investments fell that led to decreased demand and wages in all
sectors of economy (Kattel 2009, 11-13; Key indicators... 2010). For oversupplied and leveraged
sectors (real estate) it has meant the volatility in the value of assets due to liquidation of existing
capital to cover debt obligations, which set off debt deflation process.
Adjunct fundamental element behind the financial fragility in the Baltic States is low interest
rate on euro denominated loans and mortgage credit that has overleveraged private sector and
outpaced loans, denominated in local currencies39 (Vistesen 2008; Hudson 2008, 71; Hugh 2009).
These loans have been used for consumption or economic activities, e.g. construction, financial
services, and real estate that target domestic markets and generate local currency earnings.
Moreover, commercial banking sector in Estonia has been funded by short-term borrowing in
foreign currencies, which has been used to fund long-term euro-denominated mortgages at high
loan-to-value ratios and floating rates (IMF 2009, 5, 11-16). Thus, both commercial banks and
indebted private entities carry the risk of currency and maturity mismatch40. The difficulty stems
from decreasing margins of safety in terms of reduced capacity to service loans, as the ratio of
official foreign reserves to gross external debt is falling41. Thereby, should exchange or interest rates
move in unfavorable direction, non-export oriented sectors and indebted economic agents would be
severely affected in servicing their loans, which brings to the fore the external dimension of
Minskyian moment of financial fragility.
Pressures on fixed exchange rates would emerge, once reserves are depleted, asset values
decline, and capital is withdrawn from economy. However, for indebted economic agents,
depreciation of the currency in the form of devaluation or internal deflation would mean becoming
Ponzi financing unit.
Thus, it is the combination of several factors that has driven deepening financial fragility in the
Baltic States, the essence of which could be ascribed to typical elements that were brought out in the
chapter I.3:
39
Foreign currency loans as a percentage of total loans was 87,5% in Estonia in 2009, 89,5% in Latvia in 2009, and
70,4% in Lithuania in 2009 (Bank of Latvia, Bank of Lithuania, Bank of Estonia, author’s calculations).
40
In Latvia, external debt with original maturity below 1 year exceeded 50% of GDP in 2007 (Key indicators...2010).
41
Another indicator of deteriorating capacity to service debt, is loans as a percentage of deposits – 173,2% in Estonia in
2009, 279,6% in Latvia in 2009, and 175,3% in Lithuania in 2009 (Bank of Latvia, Bank of Lithuania, Bank of Estonia,
author’s calculations).
34
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
•
highly leveraged economic units;
appreciating currencies in real terms that deteriorated the competitiveness of exports;
worsening current account deficits;
diminishing capacity to service debt due to non-corresponding amount of reserves;
inflating assets and increasing wages without productivity gains;
inappropriate distribution of FDI – financing of non-tradable goods;
lost risk-perception that led to endogenous fragility;
currency and maturity mismatches;
growing capital outflow by FDI related income.
II. 2.1 POLICY REPSONSES
Once financial risks and vulnerabilities are identified, there should be responsive policies induced to
change the context and mitigate risks. However, failure in preventive stage would require an effort
for post-crisis stabilization. The discussion on policy measures that have been implemented to
forestall financial crisis or alleviate systemic risks is rather primitive and focuses mainly on
dominating political stance before and after the 2008 global financial crisis. The reason for that is
simple: when considering the toolbox of policy-measures that are designed to mitigate or deal with
the consequences of crises, it is evident that in the context of liberalized economy, where no
restrictions on capital and currency flows or provisions on currency transactions and interest rates
are enforced, the main tools that are available for policy-makers include traditional macroeconomic
(fiscal) or FDI policies. Although some of the banking regulations have been applied in Estonia, e.g.
reserve requirement, none of the options under the sections „controls“ or „limits“, presented in
chapter I.3, has been employed. Thus, the analysis on the imposition of time-varying capital-account
controls or wide-range of limits and requirements for banking sector in financial intermediation can
be excluded. Nevertheless, even the implementation of narrow-range regulations have been procyclical by the nature and thereby, contributed to deteriorating financing positions of economic
agents. During boom periods, policy measures should have avoided excessive indebtedness and risktaking by suppressing rapid increase in lending as well as deterring currency mismatches. Instead,
poor accounting and inadequate legal framework for lending have enabled real estate financing with
a loan-to-value ratio of 90%, which could have been avoided by tightened control of banking system
and stricter loan conditions, e.g. lower income multipliers on loans and loan-to-value ratio, more
profound documentation (Hugh, 2009). Furthermore, the risk weights on different assets have been
lowered (now 60% on mortgage) (IMF 2009, 9, 18). The absence of property tax afforded to
capitalize incomes from property sales into bank loans, which amplified lending activity (Hudson
2008, 76-77), whereas income-tax exemption of interest payment on housing loans has been a
stimulus behind increased borrowing and could be seen as a pro-cyclical measure.
One way to avoid inflationary economic growth that erodes export competitiveness and
worsens current account balance would be to enforce counter-cyclical fiscal policies, i.e. higher
taxation of consumption that would induce propensity to save and “sterilize” financial inflows into
reserves. Moreover, the overheating of economy needs to be impeded by reduced government
expenditures in spheres that lead to cost-push inflation, e.g. controls on incomes in public sector. By
taking a look at the fiscal budgets of the Baltic States within the period of 2006-2009, one can
observe that in Latvia and Lithuania, governments ran deficit budgets before and after the crisis,
35
while in Estonia, government budget was in surplus only in 2006 and 2007 (see Figure 12).
Nevertheless, exactly during these years (2006 and 2007), the capacity to service gross external debt
with foreign official reserves decreased significantly, implying the insufficient effort for the
stabilization of economy by absorbing excessive capital inflows. Furthermore, income tax was
gradually reduced in Estonia during the boom years from 2005 onwards by 1% per year (EMTA
2010), while labor costs, covered with finances from government budget, increased significantly. In
all three countries the second largest increase in government expenditures took place in the category
of compensations of employees that facilitated inflationary trends in all sectors of economy. If in
other CEE countries, labor costs increased by 13,8% on average during the period of 2006-2008,
then in Estonia, Latvia, and Lithuania these figures were 32,1%, 42,4%, and 31,5% respectively42.
In Latvia and Lithuania, fiscal discipline was not followed before as well as after the crises, which
might be one of the causes for a sudden increase in fiscal deficit in 2009, as reserves had been
decreasing since 2006 in relative terms. Moreover, unlike Estonia, Latvian and Lithuanian
governments have accumulated a significant government debt burden with a ratio of 36,2% and
29,3% of GDP respectively, which contribute to the financial instability in these countries. All these
mentioned fiscal policy measures reflect the pro-cyclical nature that contributed to deepening
financial fragility in direct or indirect way.
Figure 12: Fiscal Balance as % of GDP in the Baltic States, 2006-2009
4
2
0
% of GDP
2006
2007
2008
-2
2009
Estonia
Latvia
Lithuania
-4
-6
-8
-10
Years
Source: Eurostat (2010b)
On the other hand, counter-cyclical expansionary macro-economic policies would be required to
deal with constrained demand, after the crisis had hit the countries. Liquidity preference as a result
of deflationary processes justifies the role of the government as dis-saver. Although the figure above
might reflect the adherence to this logic, it does not tell the whole story. Even if the governments of
Latvia and Lithuania have followed the principles of Keynesian economics by running budget
deficits during economic recession, in absolute numbers, both revenues and expenditures have
significantly decreased (see Figure 13). More importantly, most of the budget cuts were made in
42
Calculations based on data from Eurostat (2010c).
36
intermediate consumption43 and capital investments. In Latvia, annual decline in capital investments
was 80,9% in 2009 (Eurostat 2010c). On top of it, Latvia has been given a conditional loan of 7,5
billion Euros by IMF, EU, and Sweden that stipulates to implement fiscal austerity in terms of
increased taxes and limits on budget deficits (Green 2009). Although in the short run the financial
support improves the current account balance as a percentage of GDP – from minus 13% in 2008 to
9,4% in 2009 -, in the long term it raises gross debt burden.
Figure 13: Fiscal revenues and expenditures in the Baltic States, 2006-2009, EUR mil
14000,00
12000,00
EUR, mil
10000,00
8000,00
Revenues
Expenditures
6000,00
4000,00
2000,00
0,00
2006
2007
2008
ESTONIA
2009
2006
2007
2008
LATVIA
2009
2006
2007
2008
2009
LITHUANIA
Source: Eurostat 2010b
In order to cool down overheating economy and on the other hand, to stimulate economy in case of
excess supply of labor and declined economic activity, governments should run counter-cyclical
macro-economic policies by being a dis-savers in the latter case. However, unwillingness or
inability by the governments in the Baltic States to act in this manner can be explained by two
factors. First, currency board arrangements in Estonia and Lithuania do not allow the financing of
fiscal deficits. Second, the aspiration to join Euro has set criteria for candidate countries that enforce
limits on budget deficits. On the other hand, even if the expansionary policies are executed to rectify
internal imbalance, the desired effect might get evaporated due to cross-border supply and demand
relations. There is a risk that stimulus policies for internal stabilization feed external imbalances as a
result of income elasticity of demand for imports. Furthermore, public procurement regulations
within the EU create the conditions for tendering opportunities by external competitors, which
jeopardizes the positive effects of liquidity shot into domestic economy. Thus, the Baltic States have
limited possibilities to use either monetary or fiscal policies to stimulate sinking internal and
external demand, leaving internal devaluation via wage cuts as the only option to improve external
balance and attract new investments (Lucas 2009). Accompanied by reduced government
expenditures these deflationary developments have a negative effect on domestic demand,
43
The value of goods and services, used as inputs for production process (Commission Regulation (EC) No 1500/2000
of 10 July 2000 implementing Council Regulation (EC) No 2223/96 with respect to general government expenditure and
revenue).
37
employment, and economic growth, which all together increase the cost of borrowed stock for
indebted entities44.
Currency board arrangement has stymied the functioning of monetary authorities as lenders
of last resort and providers of additional liquidity, if needed (IMF 2009, 11), which is of high
importance, when asset prices need to be backed and economic activity upheld with extra credit.
Thus, the system of currency board arrangement can be maintained only, if capital inflows, current
account deficits and bank lending are held under the control. None of these criteria have been
achieved in Estonia and to less extent in Lithuania for effective functioning of currency board
system. By setting low taxes and providing subsidies, the Baltic States have attracted inflows of FDI
and extensive credit that has been used rather on rent-seeking purposes than investments (Reinert,
Kattel 2007, 1-2, 24-25; Hudson 2008, 75-76). On the other hand, the prospect of growing FDI
income outflows should be addressed through fiscal policies, i.e. taxation of either dividends or
interest earnings. If we take a look at the dynamics of FDI income outflows and the share of
repatriated profits (Figures 2 and 3), it seems that the negative effect of FDI on countries` balance of
payments is something that governments have not yet acknowledged. Thereby, countries with
currency board system and open external account should consider the application of either direct
measures, such as quantitative controls on FDI flows, or indirect measures, such as targeted
subsidies or other incentives to invest in exposed sector that enable to alleviate prevailing external
imbalance and pressures on exchange rate. When considering specific FDI policies, then in the
1990s there were some restrictions in Estonia on FDI in terms of special licenses required to get
involved in some industries, such as energy, mining (Sakkeus 2001, 11-12). Currently, no active
policies have been activated to direct foreign investments in accordance with national development
strategy. Public policies in Estonia have not paid enough attention to the role of FDI in transferring
knowledge, evoking new high-technology industries, and creating spillover effects45, but have relied
mainly on fiscal policy instruments, e.g. tax burden reduction (Tiits et al. 2006, 158, 162-163).
Conclusion
Throughout the contemporary history, i.e. since the second part of the 20th century, there have been
several forms of external financing of economic development that have re-emerged time after time.
Since the 1990s FDI-led economic growth and industrialization in less developed countries obtained
more importance in Latin-America as well as post-soviet small states in Central and Eastern
European region. The reasons for FDI-led growth could be found primarily in general bias of
developing countries to adhere to so-called Washington Consensus policies, but also in the concept
of techno-economic paradigms.
Although there are several theories in the tradition of classical development economics that
explain the mechanisms behind economic development, the cornerstone of economic and
technological progress lies in the capital formation and industrialization, i.e. manufacturing
industries with synergetic interdependences, spillover effects, and increasing returns. Thus, the
44
Nersisyan and Wray (2010) have found that the imposition of fiscal austerity by nonsovereign nations with fixed
exchange rates puts breaks on the economy, which eventually leads to fallen tax revenues and risen spending on the
social security.
45
In case of FDI, there have been several entry requirements, such as enabling access to foreign new technology,
training of Taiwanese engineers, local content and expanding exports requirement for foreign companies or their
subsidiaries, access to certain industries that are important for growth, enforced agreements with local suppliers, and
performance requirements (Wade 1992, 77-79, 85, 93-95).
38
contribution of FDI to the sustainable development in host economy would require the integration of
foreign capital into indigenous economy by established supply-demand linkages and mutual
interrelatedness between domestic and foreign producers. Moreover, dependence on foreign
investments underlies the importance of building up exporting sector in order to pursue debt
sustainable development.
Country can benefit from inward foreign investments by gaining an access to foreign
markets, technologies, and knowledge. However, FDI tends to create enclaves in host countries by
focusing on narrow-range exporting articles, invest in non-tradable sectors, and increase imports that
do not have any significant positive impact on long-term development in host economy. Thus, by
exploiting cheap labor, foreign investors have laid an emphasis on maturing low- or mediumtechnology industries and low value-added production stages that tend to transfer cumulative
multiplier effects abroad. In this respect, the main motives of FDI are efficiency- and marketseeking that would yield short-term gains. On the other hand, in small developing states such
inauspicious developments can be explained by malfunctioning innovation systems and small
markets to reap gains from scale and external economies.
While FDI per se has a tendency to aggravate the financial and economic conditions, host
economies can easily contribute to the subversion of financial stability by implementing flawed
economic policies and setting up institutional framework that undermine the ability to service
foreign claims, leading to Minskyian Ponzi financing position in terms of insolvency. FDI by
definition is a debt that needs to be repaid, the ability of which is determined by the soundness of
financial system and exchange rate systems. In case of fixed exchange rates and deregulated
financial flows, the financial stability is seriously jeopardized, which might affect negatively both
internal and external balance of a country. In order to mitigate financial turmoil or to deal with the
consequences of crisis, there are different policy measures, both direct and indirect, that are required
to be counter-cyclical in nature, when implemented.
Thus, the purpose of the current article was to outline the economic and financial
developments in the Baltic States by trying to explain the financial fragility and susceptibility to
crises in these countries within the established theoretical framework. As the inward FDI in the
Baltic States has been concentrated in limited number of economic sectors and tend to finance the
production of maturing products that face saturating markets and diminishing profits, FDI in the
Baltic States is becoming mature in terms of both shrinking new FDI inflows and thriving FDI
related income outflows. Furthermore, propensity to consume rather to invest and domestic market
orientation of FDI have eroded the margin of safety by insufficient generation of foreign currency
earnings to meet the external liabilities. Unrestricted capital inflows have been feeding monetary
expansion in these countries, which led to inflationary trends and deteriorating real exchange
currencies, all of which supported widening current account deficits. Both fixed exchange rate
systems, including currency board arrangements in Estonia and Lithuania in the context of free
capital flows that did not prevent high inflation, and overall liberal economic policies that left
policy-makers only with traditional macroeconomic policies (taxes and expenditures) as the main
tools to alleviate external imbalances, are to blamed in deteriorating financial conditions in the
Baltic States. Governments have mainly relied on different fiscal policy measures before and after
the crisis, while prudential capital-account controls, specific FDI policies, and more elaborated
regulations on banking activity have been left aside. On the other hand, the effectiveness of such
indirect measures (taxes) is disputable, as the immediate sources of financial fragility might be left
untouched and fiscal policies tend to have adversarial impact on attaining simultaneously both
internal and external balance in small states. Moreover, economic policy measures in the Baltic
39
States have had a pro-cyclical inclination46. Thus, the internal devaluation via wage cuts is seen as
the only option to improve external balance and attract new investments, which under the conditions
of high indebtedness and reduced government expenditures have a negative effect on domestic
demand, employment, and economic growth. It is the combination of indebtedness, internal
deflation, current account deficits, pro-cyclical policy measures, and declining demand due to high
unemployment that results in Minskyian Ponzi financing position, i.e. being in essence insolvent, the
Baltic States have to face. And even if the financial crisis and the following economic recession in
Estonia, Latvia and Lithuania were triggered by adverse external developments – one of the risks
that Ponzi units need to bear -, the elements of financial fragility and eventual crisis were seeded in
the Baltic States during the boom years.
ACKNOWLEDGMENTS
The research was undertaken with funding from the Estonian Science Foundation (grant no.
ETF8097, Innovation Policy and Uneven Development)
The author is grateful to prof. Dr. Rainer Kattel (Tallinn University of Technology) and
prof. Dr. Jan Allen Kregel (Levy Economics Institute of Bard College; Tallinn University of
Technology) for their invaluable guidance and assistance!
46
Even though the policy measures, implemented in the Baltic States bear resemblance to Washington Consensus
policies, there are elements in economic policies that have deviated for the worse, if we consider tax reforms, trade
policy, and exchange rates.
40
REFERENCES
Andersen E. S. and B.-A. Lundvall. (1988) „Small National System of Innovation Facing
Technological Revolutions: An Analytical Framework“. In Freeman, C. & Lundvall, B.
1988. Small Countries Facing the Technological Revolution. London.
Arestis, P. (1996) „Post-keynesian economics: towards coherence“. Cambridge Journal of
Economics, nr. 20, 1996, 111-135.
Bank of Estonia (2010) Statistical Indicators. Available:
http://www.eestipank.info/pub/en/dokumendid/statistika/
Bank of Latvia (2010) Statistics. Available: http://www.bank.lv/eng/main/all/statisticss/
Bank of Lithuania (2010) Statistics. Available: http://www.lb.lt/eng/statistic/index.html
Chandrasekhar C.P & J. Ghosh (200) FDI and the Balance of Payments in the 2000s.
Cohen, N. J. (2008) “Managing Faustian Bargain: Monetary Autonomy in the Pursuit of
Development in Eastern Europe and Latin-America”. Comparative perspectives of
development experiences in South America and Eastern Europe. Development and SemiPeriphery. International Conference. Tallinn, October 9th-10th of 2008.
COST (2009) COST Action IS0902: Systemic Risks, Financial Crises and Credit - The Roots,
Dynamics and Consequences of the Subprime Crisis. January 2, 2010. Available:
http://www.worldfinancialcrisis.eu/profiles/blogs/systemic-risks-financial
Cruz, M. and B. Walters. (2008) „Is the Accumulation of International Reserves Good for
Development?“ Cambridge Journal of Economics, Volume 32, 2008, 665–681.
Djankov, S. and B. Hoekman (2006) „Foreign Direct Investment and Productivity Growth in Czech
Enterprises“. In Hoekman, B., Javorcik, B., S. (eds.) Global Integration & Technology
Transfer. 2006 The International Bank For Reconstruction and Development / World
Bank.
Domar, E. (1950) “The Effect of Foreign Investment on the Balance of Payments”. The American
Economic Review, American Economic Association, Vol. 40, No. 5 (Dec., 1950), 805-826.
Drechsler, W., Backhaus, J. G., Burlamaqui, L., Chang, H-J., Kalvet, T., Kattel, R., Kregel, J.,
Reinert, S. E. (2006) „Creative Destruction Management in Central and Eastern Europe:
Meeting the Challenges of the Techno-economic Paradigm Shift“. In Kalvet, T., Kattel, R
(eds.). Creative Destruction Management: Meeting the Challenges of the Techno-economic
Paradigm Shift. Tallinn 2006, PRAXIS Center for Policy Studies.
Dutt, K. A. (2005) „International Trade in Early Development Economics“. In Jomo KS & Erik S.
Reinert (eds.) The Origins of Development Economics. How schools of Economic Thought
Have Addressed Development, 99-127.
EBRD (2010) Regional Economic Prospects and Growth Forecasts. Available:
http://www.ebrd.com/country/sector/econo/stats/index.htm
Eichengreen, B. (2004) „Financial Instability“. In Bjorn Lomborg (ed.) Global Crises, Global
Solutions. Cambridge University Press. 2004
Eichengreen, B. and K.H. O`Rourke (2009) A Tale of Twi Depressions. Available:
http://wallstreetpit.com/3689-the-world-economy-is-tracking-or-doing-worse-than-duringthe-great-depression
EMTA (2010) Tulumaksumäär. Available:
http://www.emta.ee/?query=tulumaksum%C3%A4%C3%A4r
Ernst, D. and L. Kim. (2001) Global Production Networks, Knowledge Diffusion, and Local
Capability Formation. Paper presented at the Nelson & Winter Conference in Aalborg,
41
Denmark June 12-15, 2001, organized by DRUID. Available:
http://www.druid.dk/conferences/nw/paper1/Ernst_and_Kim.pdf
Eurostat (2010a) Statistics. Economy and Finance. Available:
http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/portal/page/portal/statistics/themes
Eurostat (2010b) Government finance statistics. Summary tables – 1/2010. Data 1996-2009.
European Commission. Available:
http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/cache/ITY_OFFPUB/KS-EK-10-001/EN/KS-EK-10-001EN.PDF
Eurostat (2010c) “Euroindicators”. Newsrelease, 55/2010 – 22 April, 2010. Available:
http://epp.eurostat.ec.europa.eu/cache/ITY_PUBLIC/2-22042010-BP/EN/2-22042010-BPEN.PDF
Freeman, C. and C. Perez (1988) "Structural Crises of Adjustment, Business Cycles and Investment
Behaviour" in Dosi et al., eds. (1988) Technical Change and Economic Theory. Pinter
Publisher, London and New York.
Freeman, C. and L. Soete (1997) The Economics of Industrial Innovation. MIT Press, 1997.
Fischer, C. (2002) “Real Currency Appreciation in Accession Countries: Balassa-Samuelson and
Investment Demand”. Discussion Paper 19/02. Economic Research Centre of the Deutsche
Bundesbank. July 2002. Available:
http://econstor.eu/bitstream/10419/19576/1/200219dkp.pdf
Frisch, H. (2993) “The Euro and its Consequences: What Makes a Currency Strong?” Atlantic
Economic Journal. March 2003, Vol. 31, No. 1, 15-31.
Gallagher, P. K. and L. Zarsky (2006) Rethinking Foreign Investment for Development. Available:
http://www.paecon.net/PAEReview/issue37/GallagherZarsky37.htm
Geels, F (2007) „Feelings of Discontent and the Promise of Middle Range Theory for STS.
Examples from the Technology Dynamics.“ Science, Technology, & Human Values.
Volume 32 Number 6, November 2007, 627-648.
Grabel, I. (2004) „Trip Wires and Speed Bumps: Managing Financial Risks and Reducing the
Potential for Financial Crises in Developing Countries“. G-24 Discussion Paper Series.
No. 33, November 2004. UNCTAD. Available:
http://www.unctad.org/en/docs/gdsmdpbg2420049_en.pdf
Green, N. (2009) Latvia bailed out by IMF and European Union. Available:
http://www.wsws.org/articles/2009/jan2009/latv-j07.shtml
Grigonyte, D. (2003) “Impact of Currency Boards on Fiscal Policy in Central and Eastern Europe
Countries”. Economics of Planning. Springer Netherlands. Volume 36, Number 2 / June,
2003, 111-133.
Handel, M.I. (1981) „Weak States in the International System“. In: Ch. Ingebritsen, I. Neumann, S.
Gstöhl and J. Baker (eds.). Small States in International Relations. Seattle: University of
Washington Press, Reykjavik: University of Iceland Press, 149-184.
Havlik, P., Landesmann, M., Römisch, R., Stehrer, R., and B. Gillsäter (2001) Competitiveness of
Industry in CEE Candidate Countries. Composite Paper. Final Report, July 2001, The
Vienna Institute for International Economic Studies (WIIW). Available:
http://www.wiiw.ac.at/pdf/competitiveness_composite.pdf
Hudson, M. (2008) “Fading Baltic Miracle: A Dangerous Dependence on the Property Bubble”. The
International Economy. The magazine of international economic policy. Winter 2008.
Available: http://www.international-economy.com/TIE_W08_Hudson.pdf
Hugh, E. (2009) Devaluation, Euro Membership and Loan Defaults – Some Thoughts for my Critics
via a Fistful of Euros. Available:
42
http://globaleconomydoesmatter.blogspot.com/2009/03/devaluation-euro-membership-andloan.html
Hunya, G. (2008) „Decline to Follow Uneven FDI Inflow Growth“. WIIW Database on Foreign
Direct Investment in Central, East and Southeast Europe, 2008. The Vienna Institute for
International Economic Studies. June 2008.
Hunya, G. (2009) „FDI in the CEECs under the Impact of the Global Crisis: Sharp Declines“. WIIW
Database on Foreign Direct Investment in Central, East and Southeast Europe, 2008. The
Vienna Institute for International Economic Studies. May 2009.
Högselius, P. (2005) The Dynamics of Innovation in Eastern Europe. Lessons from Estonia. Edward
Elgar Publishing Limited.
IMF (2009) „Republic of Estonia: Financial System Stability Assessment“. IMF Country Report No
09/89 (approved by Christopher Towe and Marek Belka), March 2009. Available:
http://imf.org/external/pubs/ft/scr/2009/cr0989.pdf
Javorcik, B. S. (2006a) „Technological Leadership and the Choice of Entry Mode by Foreign
Investors“. In Hoekman, B., Javorcik, B., S. (eds.) Global Integration & Technology
Transfer. 2006 The International Bank For Reconstruction and Development / World
Bank.
Javorcik, B. S. (2006b) „Does Foreign Direct Investment Increase the Productivity of Domestic
Firms? In Search of Spillovers Through Backward Linkages“. In Hoekman, B., Javorcik,
B., S. (eds.) Global Integration & Technology Transfer. 2006 The International Bank For
Reconstruction and Development / World Bank.
Reinert, K. S. J. and E. S. Reinert (2005) „Mercantilism and Economic Development:
Schumpeterian Dynamics, Institution-Building and International Benchmarking“. In Jomo
KS & Erik S. Reinert (eds.) The Origins of Development Economics. How schools of
Economic Thought Have Addressed Development, 1-23.
Kattel, R and R. Anton. (2004) „The Estonian genome project and economic development“.
TRAMES, 1-2/2004. Teaduste Akadeemia Kirjastus.
Kattel, R. (2007) Financial Fragility in the Baltic States. Somarka, Norway
Kattel, R. and A.-L. Primi (2008) Innovation and Innovation Policy in the Periphery: Latin America
and Eastern Europe Compared”. VI Globelics Conference at Mexico City, September 2224, 2008. Available:
http://globelics_conference2008.xoc.uam.mx/papers/Rainer_Kattel_Innov_and_Innov_Poli
cy.pdf
Kattel, R. (2009) „The Rise and Fall of Baltic States“. Development & Transition. No. 13. July
2009, UN Development Programme and the London School of Economics and Political
Sciences. Available: http://www.halduskultuur.eu/2009/KattelBalticStates.pdf
Kattel, R. Kregel, A. J. and E. S. Reinert (2009) „The Relevance of Ragnar Nurkse and Classical
Development Economics“. Working Papers in Technology Governance and Economic
Dynamics no. 21. The Other Canon Foundation, Norway, Tallinn University of
Technology, Tallinn. Available: http://hum.ttu.ee/wp/paper21.pdf
Kelso, R. P and B. L. Duman (1992) „A Veblenian View of Minsky`s Financial Crisis Theory“.
International Journal of Social Economics, Vol. 19 Nos. 10/11/12, 1992, 222-234.
Key Indicators of Latvia’s Macroeconomic and Banking Sector (2010). Available:
http://www.li.lv/index.php?Itemid=1122&id=119&option=com_content&task=view
Khan, M. H (2005) „The Capitalist Transformation“. In Jomo KS & Erik S. Reinert (eds.) The
Origins of Development Economics. How schools of Economic Thought Have Addressed
Development, 69-80.
43
King, L. (2008) “Political, Economic and Health Consequences of Different Methods of Making
Private Property”. Comparative perspectives of development experiences in South America
and Eastern Europe. Development and Semi-Periphery. International Conference. Tallinn,
October 9th-10th of 2008.
King, L. and P. Hamm (2008) “The Governance Grenade: Mass Privatization, State Capacity and
Economic Development in Post-Communist and Reforming Communist Societies”.
Working Papers in Technology Governance and Economic Dynamics no. 17. The Other
Canon Foundation, Norway, Tallinn University of Technology, Tallinn.
Kraemer, P. and B. Tigre (2001) „Economic Liberalization and the Computer Industry: Comparing
Outcomes in Brazil and Mexico“. Journal World Development. Volume 29, Issue 7, July
2001, 1199-1214.
Kregel A. J. (1998a) „East Asia in not Mexico: the Difference between Balance of Payments Crisis
and Debt Deflation“. Working Paper No. 235. Levy Economics Institute of Bard College.
Available: http://www.levyinstitute.org/pubs/wp235.pdf
Kregel A. J. (1998b) „Yes, „it“ did Happen Again – the Minsky Crisis in Asia“. Working Paper No.
234. 1998 Levy Economics Institute of Bard College. Available:
http://129.3.20.41/eps/mac/papers/9805/9805017.pdf
Kregel A. J. (1999) “Currency Stabilization Through Full Employment: Can EMU Combine Price
Stability with Employment and Income Growth?” Eastern Economic Journal, Vol. 25, No.
1, Winter 1999, 35-47.
Kregel A. J. (2000) The Brazilian Crisis: from Inertial Inflation to Fiscal Fragility. UNCTAD.
Available: http://129.3.20.41/eps/mac/papers/0004/0004040.pdf
Kregel, A. J (2001) Trade, Technology and Financing for Development. UNCTAD.
Kregel, A. J. (2002) “An Alternative View of the Argentine Crisis”. Seminar Paper No. 12,
December 2002. Available: www.cfeps.org/pubs/sp-pdf/SP12-Jan.pdf
Kregel A. J (2004a) “External Financing for Development and International Financial Instability”.
G-24 Discussion Paper No. 32. October 2004.
Kregel A. J (2004b) “Two Views on the Obstacles to Development”. Social Research, Vol 71: No 2:
Summer 2004.
Kregel A. J. (2004c) Negative Net Resource Transfers as a Minskyan Hedge Profile and the
Stability of the International Financial System. Available:
http://www.networkideas.org/featart/nov2004/IFS.pdf
Kregel, A. J., Burlamaqui, L (2006) “Finance, Competition, Instability, and Development.
Microfoundations and Financial Scaffolding of the Economy”. Working Papers in
Technology Governance and Economic Dynamics, no. 4. The Other Canon Foundations,
Norway, Tallinn University of Technology, Tallinn, January 2006.
Kregel A. J. (2007a) „Nurkse and the Role of Finance in Development Economics“. Working Paper
No. 520. The Levy Economics Institute of Bard College. Available:
http://www.levyinstitute.org/pubs/wp_520.pdf
Kregel, A. J. (2007b) Are There Alternative Development Strategies?
Kregel, A. J. (2007c) “Rethinking Debt Sustainability in the Context of the Millennium
Development Goals”. Quarterly Review – Banca Nazionale del Lavoro. 2007, Nr. 242.
Kregel, A. J (2008a) Hyman P. Minsky Conference on the state of the US and world economies.
Credit, markets, and the real economy: is the financial system working? April, 17-18,
2008, Blitherwood, Annandale-on-Hudson, New York. A Conference of the Levy
Economics Institute of Bard College.
44
Kregel, A. J. (2008b) „The discrete charm of the Washington consensus“. Working Paper No. 533.
2008 Levy Economics Institute of Bard College. Available:
http://www.levyinstitute.org/pubs/wp_533.pdf
Kregel, A. J. (2008c) „Minsky’s Cushion of Safety. Systemic Risk and the Crisis in the U.S.
Subprime Mortgage Market“. The Public Policy Brief, No 93, 2008c. The Levy Economics
Institute. Available: http://www.levyinstitute.org/pubs/ppb_93.pdf
Kregel, A. J. (2009a) „Why don’t the bailouts work? Design of a new financial system versus a
return to normalcy“. Cambridge Journal of Economics, Volume 33, Number 4, 2009, 653663.
Kregel, A. J. (2009b) “Some Simple Observations of the Reform of the International Monetary
System”. Policy Note. The Levy Economics Institute of Bard College. 2009/8.
Kregel, A. J. (2009c) „Mobilizing Domestic Resources. Employer of Last Resort as a National
Development Strategy to Achieve the Internationally Agreed on Development Goals“.
International Journal of Political Economy, Volume 38, Number 3 / Fall 2009, 39-57.
Kregel, A. J. (2009d) „The Global Crisis and the Implications for Developing Countries and the
BRICs. Is the B Really Justified?“ Public Policy Brief, No 102, 2009, The Levy
Economics Institute of Bard College.
Lane, D. (2008) “Post Socialist States in the System of Global Capitalism: A Comparative
Perspective”. Comparative perspectives of development experiences in South America and
Eastern Europe. Development and Semi-Periphery. International Conference. Tallinn,
October 9th-10th of 2008.
Landesmann, M. and S. Richter (2003) “Consequences of EU Accession: Economic Effects on
CEEs”. WIIW Research Reports No. 299. August 2003. Available:
http://www.econ.jku.at/members/Landesmann/files/Workingpapers/wiiw%20Research%20
Reports%20299.pdf
Lavoie, M. (1985) The Post Keynesian Theory of Endogenous Money: A Reply. Journal of
Economic Issues, Vol. 19, No. 3 (Sep., 1985), 843-848.
Lederman, D. and W. F. Maloney (2006) „Innovation In Mexico: NAFTA Is Not Enough“. In
Hoekman, B., Javorcik, B., S. (eds.) Global Integration & Technology Transfer. 2006 The
International Bank For Reconstruction and Development / World Bank.
Lucas, E. (2009) The Fall and Rise and Fall Again of the Baltic States. June 30, 2009. Available:
http://www.ocnus.net/artman2/publish/Dark_Side_4/The_Fall_and_Rise_and_Fall_Again_
of_the_Baltic_States.shtml
Lewis, K. M. and Ž. Ševic (2000) “Currency Boards in the Balkans. The Political Economy of
Currency Boards in the Balkans”. MOCT-MOST: Economic Policy in Transitional
Economies. Volume 10, Number 3-4 / September, 2000. Springer Netherlands, 285-310.
Martin, H-P. and H. Schumann (1999) Globaliseerumislõks. Kallaletung heaolule ja demokraatiale.
Tänapäev.
McCulley, A. P. (2008) “A reverse minsky journey. PIMCO”. 17th Annual Hyman P. Minsky
Conference on the state of the US and world economies. Credit, markets, and the real
economy: is the financial system working? April, 17-18, 2008, Blitherwood, Annandaleon-Hudson, New York. A Conference of the Levy Economics Institute of Bard College.
Minsky, P. H. (1991) „Financial Crises: Systemic or Idiosyncratic“. Working Paper No. 51, Bard
College - The Levy Economics Institute, April 1991
Minsky, P. H. (1992) “The Financial Instability Hypothesis”. Working Paper No. 74, Bard College The Levy Economics Institute, May 1992
45
Minsky, P. H. and C. J. Whalen (1996) “Economic Insecurity and the Institutional Prerequisities for
Successful Capitalism”. Working Paper No. 65, May 1996.
Moses, W. J. (2000) Open States in the Global Economy. The Political Economy of Small-State
Macroeconomic Management. New York: St. Martin`s. 2000
Nersisyan Yeva and L. Randall Wray. (2010) „Deficit hysteria redux? Why we should stop
worrying about U.S government deficit“. World Economic Review. Issue no. 53. Levy
Economics Institute and University of Missouri, K.C, USA. 2010.
Nurkse, R. (1952) “Growth in Underdeveloped Countries”. In Rainer Kattel, Jan A. Kregel, Erik S.
Reinert (eds.). Ragnar Nurkse. Trade and Development. The Anthem Other Canon Series.
Anthem Press, 2009, 85-97..
Nurkse, R. (1953) “Problems of Capital Formation in Underdeveloped Countries”. In Rainer Kattel,
Jan A. Kregel, Erik S. Reinert (eds.). Ragnar Nurkse. Trade and Development. The
Anthem Other Canon Series. Anthem Press, 2009, 99-212.
Nurkse, R. (1957a) “International Trade Theory and Development Policy”. In Rainer Kattel, Jan A.
Kregel, Erik S. Reinert (eds.). Ragnar Nurkse. Trade and Development. The Anthem Other
Canon Series. Anthem Press, 2009, 359-384.
Nurkse, R. (1957b) “Balanced Growth and Unbalanced Growth”. In Rainer Kattel, Jan A. Kregel,
Erik S. Reinert (eds.). Ragnar Nurkse. Trade and Development. The Anthem Other Canon
Series. Anthem Press, 2009, 329-357.
Ocampo, A. J. (2002) “Capital-Account and Counter-Cyclical Preduntial Regulations in Developing
Countries”. Discussion Paper No. 2002/82. UN University, World Institute for
Development Economics Research.
Ocampo, J. A, Kregel, J. A, and S. Griffith-Jones (2007) International Finance and Development.
Uniter Nations
Ocampo, A. J. (2009) „Latin America and the Global Financial Crisis“. Cambridge Journal of
Economics, 2009, Volume 33, Number 4, 703-724.
O`Connell, A. (2006) Macroeconomic Policy in Developing Countries within the Current
International Financial Architecture. Available: http://www.newrules.org/docs/bringing_balance/ArturoOconnell.pdf
O`Connell, A. (2007) The Recent Crisis and Recovery of the Argentine Economy: Some Elements
and Background. Universidad de Buenos Aires and Università di Bologna a Buenos Aires.
Argentine-Australia Economic Conference, Buenos Aires, April 2007. Available:
http://www.cei.gov.ar/seminarios/John%20Gage/argentinos/A.O'C.Crisis%20and%20Recovery,ANCLAS-RevisedVersion,%20April%202007.pdf
O Riain, S. (2004) The Politics of High-Tech Growth. Developmental Network States in the Global
Economy. Cambridge University Press. 2004.
Papadimitriou, B. D. (2008) “Welcome and Introduction”. 17th Annual Hyman P. MINKSY
CONFERENCE on the state of the US and world economies. Credit, markets, and the real
economy: is the financial system working? April, 17-18, 2008, Blitherwood, Annandaleon-Hudson, New York. A Conference of the Levy Economics Institute of Bard College.
Pack, H. (2006) „Econometric Versus case Study Approaches to Technology Transfer“. In
Hoekman, B., Javorcik, B., S. (eds.) Global Integration & Technology Transfer. 2006 The
International Bank For Reconstruction and Development / World Bank.
Palley, I. T. (2001) Endogenous Money: What it is and Why it Matters. Available:
http://www.thomaspalley.com/docs/articles/macro_theory/endogenous_money.pdf
Parenteau W. R (2008) Hyman P. Minsky Conference on the state of the US and world economies.
Credit, markets, and the real economy: is the financial system working? April, 17-18,
46
2008, Blitherwood, Annandale-on-Hudson, New York. A Conference of the Levy
Economics Institute of Bard College.
Perez, C (2001) “Technological change and opportunities for development as a moving target”.
CEPAL Review, No. 73, December 2001.
Perez, C. (2006) “Re-specialisation and the deployment of the ICT paradigm – an essay on the
present challenges of globalisation”. in R Compañó, C Pascu, A Bianchi, J-C Burgelman, S
Barrios, M Ulbrich and I Maghiros (eds.) The Future of the Information Society in Europe:
Contributions to the Debate. European Commission, Joint Research Centre, Institute for
Prospective Technological Studies.
Perez, C. (2007) “Great surges of development and alternative forms globalization.” The Other
Canon Foundation and Tallinn University of Technology Working Papers in Technology
Governance, 15.
Perez, C. (2007a) “Finance and technical change: A long-term view.” in Hanusch, H.; Pyka, A. The
Elgar Companion to Neo-Schumpeterian Economics. Cheltenham: Edward Elgar.
Perez, C. (2009) „The Double Bubble at the Turn of the Century: Technological Roots and
Structural Implications“. Cambridge Journal of Economics, 2009, Volume 33, Number 4,
779-805.
Pollock, J. A (2008) Hyman P. Minsky Conference on the state of the US and world economies.
Credit, markets, and the real economy: is the financial system working? April, 17-18,
2008, Blitherwood, Annandale-on-Hudson, New York. A Conference of the Levy
Economics Institute of Bard College.
Raadschelders, J.B. (1992) “Definitions of Smallness: A Comparative Study”. In R. Baker (eds.)
Public Administration in Small and Island States. West Hartford, CT: Kumarian Press, 2633.
Reinert, S. E. (2004) “Essay I: Mercantilism and Economic Development: Schumpeterian
Dynamics, Institution Building and International Benchmarking”. How Rich Nations got
Rich. Essays in the History of Economic Policy. Working paper Nr. 1, 2004, SUM - Centre
for Development and the Environment, University of Oslo (3 articles).
Reinert, S. E. (2007) How Rich Countries Got Rich . . . and Why Poor Countries Stay Poor, London:
Constable.
Reinert, S. E. and R. Kattel (2007) „European Eastern Enlargement as Europe’s Attempted
Economic Suicide?“ Working Papers in Technology Governance and Economic Dynamics
no. 14, Available: http://hum.ttu.ee/wp/paper14.pdf
Reinert, S. E. (2008) Mechanisms of financial crises and their effects on the real economy.
Saarbrücken, August 5, 2008. Available: http://www.european-summeruniversity.eu/media/documentation/dienstag/Reinert%20Saabruecken%2008%2008.ppt
Reinert, S. E (2009) „Mechanisms of financial crises and their effects on the real economy. Three
main mechanisms.“ Course material „History of Economic Policy and the Theory of
Uneven Development“. Tallinn, 2009.
Reinert, S. E, Amaizo, E. Y. and R. Kattel (2009) „The Economics of Failed, Failing, and Fragile
States: Productive Structure as the Missing Link “. Working Papers in Technology
Governance and Economic Dynamics no. 18. The Other Canon Foundation, Norway,
Tallinn University of Technology, Tallinn. Available: http://hum.ttu.ee/wp/paper18.pdf
Reinhart M. C. and K. S. Rogoff (2008) „Is the 2007 US Sub-Prime Financial Crisis so Different?
An International Historical Comparison“. NBER Working Paper Series. Working Paper
13761
47
Ros J. (2005) „The pioneers of Development Economics and Modern Growth Theory“. in Jomo KS
& Erik S. Reinert (eds.) The Origins of Development Economics. How schools of
Economic Thought Have Addressed Development, 81-98.
Roubini, N. (2009) Mother of all Carry Trades Faces an Inevitbale Bust. Available:
http://www.roubini.com/roubinimonitor/257912/mother_of_all_carry_trades_faces_an_inevitable_bust
Rosenstain-Rodan, P. N. (1943) “Problems of Industrialisation of Eastern and South-Eastern
Europe” The Economic Journal, Vol. 53, No. 210/211. (Jun. - Sep., 1943), 202-211
Saad, M. Zawdie, and C. G. Malairaja (2008). „The triple helix strategy for universities in
developing countries: the experiences in Malaysia and Algeria.“ Science and Public
Policy, Vol. 35, No. 6, 431-443.
Saad-Filho, A. (2005) „The Rise and Decline of Latin American Structuralism and Dependency
Theory“. In Jomo KS & Erik S. Reinert (eds.) The Origins of Development Economics.
How schools of Economic Thought Have Addressed Development, 128-145.
Saggi, K. (2006) „Foreign Direct Investment, Linkages, and Technology Spillovers“. In Hoekman,
B., Javorcik, B., S. (eds.) Global Integration & Technology Transfer. 2006 The
International Bank For Reconstruction and Development / World Bank.
Sakkeus, J. (2001) „Otsesed välisinvesteeringud“. In Barry Lesser (eds.) Majanduspoliitika
probleeme Eestis, Lätis ja Leedus. Balti Majandusjuhtide Täienduskoolitusprogramm.
Sanderson, L (2009) „Exchange Rates and Export Performance: Evidence from Micro-Data“.
Reserve Bank of New Zealand: Bulletin, Vol. 72, No. 2, June 2009, 43-52. Available:
http://www.rbnz.govt.nz/research/bulletin/2007_2011/2009jun72_2sanderson.pdf
Selgin, G. and L. H. White (2005) “Credible Currency: A Constitutional Perspective”.
Constitutional Political Economy. Springer Netherlands. Volume 16, Number 1 / March,
2005, 71-83.
Siemon, C. (2006) Endogenity of Money and Financial Entrepreneurship: Financing Innovation
from an Evolutionary Perspective. 11th ISS Conference – Nice/Sophia-Antipolis, France,
June 21-24, 2006 “Innovation, Competition and Growth: Schumpeterian Perspectives“
Singer, W. H. (1950) “The Distribution of Gains between Investing and Borrowing Countries”. The
American Economic Review, Vol. 40, No. 2. Papers and Proceedings of the Sixty-second
Annual Meeting of the American Economic Association. (May, 1950), 473-485.
Stiglitz, E. J. (2000) „The Insider: What I Learned at the World Economic Crisis“. The New
Republic, April 2000. Available:
http://www.globalexchange.org/campaigns/wbimf/stiglitz041700.html
Sutton, P and A. Payne (1993) “Lilliput under Threat: the Security Problems of Small Island and
Enclave Developing States”. Political Studies, XLI, 579-593.
Szentes, T. (2005) „Development in the History of Economics“. In Jomo KS & Erik S. Reinert
(eds.) The Origins of Development Economics. How schools of Economic Thought Have
Addressed Development, 146-158.
Sõrg, M. and V. Vensel (2002) “Development of the Banking System under the Estonian Currency
Board”. International Advances in Economic Research. Volume 8, Number 1 / February,
2002, 35-48.
Ševic, Ž (2007a) „Prologue: Managing (Successfully) the „Public Shortfalls““. In Ševic, Ž (eds.).
Debt Management in Transition Countries: Experience and Perspectives.
Ševic, Ž (2007b) „Managing Public Debt: A Central and/or Local Government Issue“. In Ševic, Ž
(eds.). Debt Management in Transition Countries: Experience and Perspectives
48
Thorhallsson, B. and A. Wivel (2006) “Small States in the European Union: What Do We Know and
What Would We Like to Know?” Cambridge Review of International Affairs, Volume 19,
Number 4, December 2006, 651-668.
Tiits, M., Kattel, R., Kalvet, T., Kaarli, R. (2003) The Estonian Economy. Competitiveness & Future
Outlooks. R&D and Innovation Policy Review. Tallinn 2003, Research and Development
Council.
Tiits, M (2006) „Industrial and Trade Dynamics in the Baltic Sea Region Since 1990s“. In Kalvet,
T., Kattel, R (eds.). Creative Destruction Management: Meeting the Challenges of the
Techno-economic Paradigm Shift. Tallinn 2006, PRAXIS Center for Policy Studies.
Tiits, M., Kattel, R., Kalvet, T. (2006) „Globalization of R&D and economic development: policy
lessons from Estonia“. Globalization of R&D and Developing Countries. Part II. United
Nations Conference on Trade and Development, Geneva, 2006.
UN (2003) Trade and Development Report, 2003. Capital Accumulation, Growth and Structural
Change. United Nations Conference on trade and development, New York and Geneva,
2003, UNCTAD/TDR/2003.
UN (2009a) Report of the Commission of Experts of the President of the UN General Assembly on
Reforms of the International Monetary and Financial System. New York, September 21,
2009. Available: http://www.un.org/ga/econcrisissummit/docs/FinalReport_CoE.pdf
UN (2009b) Conference on the World Financial and Economic Crisis and its Impact on
Development. New York, 24-26 June 2009, Available:
http://www.un.org/ga/search/view_doc.asp?symbol=A/CONF.214/3&Lang=E
UNCTAD (1998) Trade and Development Report, 1998. Financial Instability and Growth in Africa.
United Nations, New York and Geneva, 1998.
UNCTAD (2009) World Investment Report 2009. Transnational Corporations, Agricultural
Production and Development. United Nations Conference on Trade and Development.
New York and Geneva, 2009.
Vistesen, C. (2008) The CEE and The Baltics – Moving Towards the Center of the Storm. Available:
http://globaleconomydoesmatter.blogspot.com/2008/10/cee-and-baltics-moving-towardscenter.html
Vistesen, C (2009) Devaluation Imminent in the Baltics? May 28, 2009. Available:
http://fistfulofeuros.net/afoe/economics-country-briefings/devaluation-imminent-in-thebaltics/
Wade, R. (1992) Governing the Market. Economic Theory and the Role of Government in East
Asian Industrialization. Princeton University Press.
Wade, R. (2008) „Financial Regime Change?“ New Left Review, nr. 53, September-October 2008.
Available: http://www.newleftreview.org/?view=2739
Wade, R. (2009) „From Global Imbalances to Global Reorganisations“. Cambridge Journal of
Economics, 2009, Volume 33, Number 4, 539-562.
Walsh, V. (1987) „Technology and the Competitiveness of Small Countries: Review“ In Freeman,
C. & Lundvall, B. (eds.). Small Countries Facing the Technological Revolution. London,
1988.
Wray, R (2008) Hyman P. Minsky Conference on the state of the US and world economies. Credit,
markets, and the real economy: is the financial system working? April, 17-18, 2008,
Blitherwood, Annandale-on-Hudson, New York. A Conference of the Levy Economics
Institue of Bard College.
49
Wyatt, S. and B. Balmer (2007) „Home on the Range. What and Where is the Middle in Science and
Technology Studies?“ Science, Technology, & Human Values. Volume 32 Number 6,
November 2007, 619-626.
Weller, E. C. and L. Singleton (2004) “Political Freedom, External Liberalization and Financial
Stability”. International Review of Applied Economics. Volume 18, Issue 1, January 2004,
1-22.
Williamson, J. (1990) “What Washington Means by Policy Reform”. In J. Williamson (eds.) Latin
American Adjustment: How Much Has Happened? Peterson Institute for International
Economics, April 1990.
World Bank (2010) Data Catalogue. Available: http://data.worldbank.org/data-catalog
Yan, H. D. (1999) “Intertemporal Current Account Balance and the East Asian Currency Crisis”.
International Advances in Economic Research. Springer, Netherlands, Volume 5, Number
3 / August, 1999, 277-288.
Yeldan, E. (2006) “Turkey 2001-2006. Macroeconomics of Post-Crisis Adjustments”. Global Policy
Network. Available: http://www.gpn.org/data/turkey/turkey-analysis.pdf
Ylä-Anttila, P., Lemola, T. (2006) „Transformation of Innovation System in a Small Country – the
Case of Finland“. In Kalvet, T., Kattel, R (eds.). Creative Destruction Management:
Meeting the Challenges of the Techno-economic Paradigm Shift. Tallinn 2006, PRAXIS
Center for Policy Studies.
Zirnask, V. (2009) “Eestlaste kange investeerimiskokteil”. Ärileht, 3. juuni, 8.
50
Download