Child Support and Educational Outcomes - Evidence from the British Household Panel Survey Ian Walker University of Warwick and Institute for Fiscal Studies and Yu Zhu University of Kent and Centre for the Economics of Education Keywords: parental separation, educational outcomes JEL Code: parental incomes, child support, D13, D31, J12, J13, J22 Abstract It is widely accepted that Child support (CS) has played a positive role in reducing child poverty among non-intact families. But little research has been done on the role of CS on the real educational outcomes of the children concerned. Using a sample of dependent children in non-intact families from the British Household Panel Survey (BHPS), we find that CS received has an effect which is at least 10 times as large as that associated with variations in total household net income for two key educational outcomes, namely school leaving at the age of 16 and attaining 5 or more good GCSEs. This result is robust with respect to adding controls for characteristics of the child and the custodial mother. We then instrument average CS receipt using the retrospective information on the mother’s fertility, relationship and unemployment, to investigate the causality of the relationship. We find that the strong CS effect found in probit models carries through when we allow CS, and other variables, to be endogenous. Moreover, applying the predicted CS, from the first-stage coefficients from IV model for non-intact children, does not seem to affect the educational outcomes for children living in intact families. This natural “non-experiment” lends further support to the causal interpretation of the CS effect. 1 I. Introduction The impact of parental separation on children has been a longstanding concern of social scientists. While there has been a general consensus that parental separation is associated with adverse outcomes for children (for surveys, see e.g. Amato and Keith (1991), Haveman and Wolfe (1995) and Amato (2001)), the extent to which this correlation is causal is far from clear. Causality becomes difficult to infer if there are important omitted variables that are likely to be correlated with separation. Despite the considerable evidence that income does affect child outcomes (see e.g. Dahl and Lochner (2005), Plug and Vijverberg (2003, 2005), Chevalier et al. (2005) and Francesconi et al. (2005)), many studies typically omit income while even fewer studies have attempted to separate out the effects of one parent (mostly the father) leaving on the outcomes for the children, from the effects of that parent's money leaving. Child support (CS) is the monetary transfer made by the non-custodial parent (usually the father) to the custodial parent (usually the mother), for the care and support of children of a relationship that has broken down. In most countries there is a system of CS that both reduces the financial effects of separation on children and raises the costs of separation to the non-custodial parent1. It is widely believed that CS has played a positive role in reducing child poverty among non-intact families (see e.g. Meyer and Hu (1999))2. Despite the attention given to child poverty because of its apparent adverse effects on outcomes for children, and to the role that CS plays in reducing child poverty, little research has been done on the role of CS on the real educational outcomes of the children concerned. This vacuum is particularly troublesome at a time when the system of CS in the UK is about to be reformed in a way which seems likely to reduce CS 1 See Cancian et al (2003) for US evidence and González (2005) for evidence from across 16 countries. 2 CS not only affects child outcomes through a direct income effect, it may also cause indirect incentive effects on maternal quality selection, fertility decisions, prenatal investments, and birth outcomes. Walker and Zhu (2006) find that an increase in CS liabilities arising from the introduction of complex CS rules in 1993 significantly reduced the risk of partnership dissolution for couples in the UK. Aizer and McLanahan (2006) find that stricter state CS enforcement leads to fewer out-of-wedlock births and an increase in both the average education of mothers and investment of prenatal care in the US. 2 payments3 unless compliance can be radically improved by moving to a system that will entail a great deal more idiosyncratic variation in CS. Notable exceptions are Knox (1996) and Argys et al. (1998), both of which are based on the National Longitudinal Survey of Youth (NLSY). The sample in Knox (1996) contains relatively young mothers aged between 23 and 31 and disproportionately from lower socioeconomic status and minority families. Knox shows that the positive effect of CS on achievement test scores for 5-8 year olds in single-parent families is one order of magnitude higher than that from other income sources. In contrast, while increases in overall family income improves the level of cognitive stimulation in children’s home environments, CS does not appear to have any additional effect over and above other forms of income. Moreover, the CS coefficient in the instrumental variables model using state average CS levels and other indicators of local economic environment remains statistically significant at the 10% level. Knox also shows that CS levels predicted by economic conditions and state average CS levels do not help explain variations in achievement test scores for children living with both parents. Argys et al. (1998) revisit the NLSY data a few years later, as the sample becomes more representative of children who will ever be born to NLSY mothers. Using this more representative sample, they find that CS coefficient is no longer statistically significant under the Knox (1996) specification. Argys et al. show that it is important to control for race and out-of-wedlock births and to distinguish between cooperative and non-cooperative awards. The additional positive effect of CS on children’s cognitive outcomes is only found for blacks in the divorced/separated sample and for whites in the non-marital birth sample. Instrumenting CS and total family income using local economic and demographic indicators as well as policy variables relating to divorce, CS and welfare generosity of the state, the authors find that the effects of CS persist, but only for blacks in the divorced sample. Researchers have hypothesized the following mechanisms through which CS may have beneficial effects on children over and above income from other sources (Knox (1996), Aizer and McLanahan (2006)): 3 The system of CS in the UK was reviewed by David Henshaw for the DWP in July 2006. His recommendations can be found at http://www.dwp.gov.uk/childsupport/henshaw_report.asp. 3 1) A “labelling effect”, i.e. CS may improve children’s outcomes more than other sources of income, if mothers feel obliged to spend it directly on children. Del Boca and Flinn (1994) find that coefficients associated with CS and alimony income are significantly higher than those for other income in Engel curves for expenditures on child-specific goods. Kooreman (2000) presents empirical evidence that the marginal propensity to consume child clothing out of exogenous child benefits is much larger than that out of other income sources for households with one child in the Netherland. He interprets this finding as evidence of the labelling effect of a child benefit system. 2) Improved family dynamics. CS may affect relationships between the noncustodial father and the custodial mother and between the absent father and the child differently than income from other sources. The effect of increased visitation, theoretically ambiguous a priori (e.g. Ermisch (2005), Del Boca and Ribero (2001)). Both Knox (1996) and Argys et al. (1998) have allowed for contact of the child with the absent father and found little evidence that it matters. 3) Absence of any adversary effects that are often associated with other income sources on child outcomes. It is possible that other types of income may bring consequences for families that CS does not, i.e. stigma and work disincentives associated with benefit income. For instance, maternal employment might have negative effects through poor childcare (Gregg et al. (2005), Rhum (2004)) while income from step-fathers might have separate negative effect. 4) A signal effect (reverse causality). Aughinbaugh (2001) finds that measures of child achievement have a significant positive effect on both the possibility of any CS being paid and the amount paid. She suggests that the results imply that custodial mothers invest more in the child as a signal to the absent father in order to secure future CS payments. However, a plausible alternative to the above explanations is that the relationship between CS receipts and child’s educational outcomes might reflect a selection effect (unmeasured heterogeneity among families) rather than a causal effect. For instance, payment of child support by an absent father might be correlated with his commitment to the well-being of the child. From a policy point of view, it is extremely important to be able to discriminate between these two explanations. 4 Our empirical work is based on the British Household Panel Survey (BHPS). Unlike the NLSY which is overrepresented by younger mothers, our sample is representative of all non-intact families. Using a sample of dependent children under 16 in non-intact families whose real educational outcomes are observable, we find that CS received has an effect which is at least 10 times as large as that of total household net income for two key educational outcomes, namely school leaving at the age of 16 and attaining 5 or more GCSEs4. This result is robust with respect to adding controls for characteristics of the child and the custodial mother5. We then instrument current CS receipt using retrospective information on mother’s fertility, relationship and employment before the birth of the child, to investigate the causality of the relationship. We find that the strong CS effect found in probit models carries through to the IV modelling. This strongly suggests that the apparent simple correlation between CS and children’s educational outcomes is causal rather than (entirely) driven by selection by some important unobservables that are associated with CS compliance. II. Data The British Household Panel Survey (BHPS) is a nationally representative sample of some 10,000 original sample members (OSMs) recruited in 1991. These OSMs and all adult members of their families are interviewed in each following year. The BHPS collects information on household organisation, housing, employment, education, health and incomes in all waves. It is a particularly rich dataset with lifetime histories of marriage, cohabitation, and fertility and employment transitions. This allows us to match all children to their natural parents and establish the time of departure of any absent parents, even for partnerships dissolved before the first wave. We focus on school leaving and attainment of 5+ GCSE6s by the age of 16 for all children in non-intact families in this paper. Figure 1 reports the two outcomes and 4 These are arguably the two most important measures of educational achievements in the UK: the former captures the dropout rate at the minimum school leaving age while the latter is a key quality indicator of the standard the pupil has achieved. 5 Moreover, allowing for endogeneity of separation arising from the 1993 CS reform and non-random attrition of absent fathers makes little difference to the strong effect of CS received on both outcomes. 6 The General Certificate of Secondary Education (GCSE) is the principal means of assessing pupil attainment at the end of compulsory secondary education since 1988. The GCSE examinations are set according to nationally agreed criteria; with a quality assurance framework ensuring standards are maintained between awarding bodies and syllabuses year on year (http://www.dfes.gov.uk/qualifications/mainSection.cfm?sId=1). 5 CS receipts by family types, where non-intact families are further divided into two groups depending on whether or not parents were living together when the child was born (denoted as separated and single mothers in Table 1). A child is defined as living in a non-intact family, if he or she does not live with both natural parents at any point in time until he/she reaches the age of sixteen. Note that the way the family type is defined means that children living in the same family can be classified into different categories. It is apparent that the outcomes and CS receipts differ substantially across intact and non-intact families, and between children whose parents separated and children born out-of-wedlock within non-intact families7. For instance, the dropout rates at 16 is below 18% for children living with both natural parents, as opposed to 28% for children whose parents have separated and a staggering 38% for children living in non-intact families since birth. In contrast, the probability of attaining 5+ good GCSEs for children born-out-wedlock is only about half of that for children living in intact families, with children in separated families in between. There are 1540 distinct youths whose age 16 educational outcomes are observable in the first fourteen waves of the BHPS, of which 414 (or 26.9%) live in non-intact families. Table 1 reports summary statistics by family types which confirms the importance of distinguishing between in-wedlock and out-of-wedlock births. While over half of all separated mothers have received any CS, only less than one-in-three single mothers do so. Conditional on receiving any CS, separated mother received on average 51.9 pounds per week, almost twice as much as the 27.0 pounds received by single mothers. Table 1 reports child and mother characteristics which will be controlled for in the regression analysis later. As might be expected, there is little difference in the chance that the youth concerned is a boy or a twin across family types. On the other hand, the differences in the average number of dependent children in the sample period and birth order might reflect complex interactions of fertility and repartnership. Recent studies suggest that family size and birth order are potentially important for children’s educational attainment (see e.g. Booth and Kee (2005) and Lundberg (2005)). Single mothers have significantly lower education than either separated or intact mothers, while there is nothing to distinguish between the latter two groups. 7 The sample size does not allow us to further distinguish between (previously) married and cohabiting couples, who are treated symmetrically for social security and child support purposes in the UK. 6 Table 1 also summarizes the retrospective information on the mother’s fertility, relationship and employment history up to the point the child concerned was born and her own experience of parental separation when she was sixteen. It turns out that nonintact mothers, and single mothers in particular, are more likely to start a relationship and fertility at an early age, less likely to have any work experience and more likely to have experience parental separation herself. Our identification strategy relies on these lifetime event which predate the birth of the child. 0 .2 .4 .6 Figure 1: Educational Outcomes and CS receipts by Family Type Intact Father at birth School Leaving at 16 Ever Received CS No Father at birth 5+ Good GCSEs Table 1: Summary Statistics by Family Types Family Type School leaving at 16 (%) 5+ Good GCSEs (%) Proportion of time mother repartnered (%) Ever Repartnered (%) Ever received CS CS Received conditional on receiving (£/week) Total Net Income (£/week) Child’s characteristics Child being boy (%) Number of kids in the family Child being twin (%) 1st natural child of mother 2nd natural child of mother 3rd natural child of mother 4th or higher order natural child of mother Intact 17.9 57.5 478.4 Separated mothers 28.1 44.0 38.0 51.4 50.2 51.9 312.7 Single mothers 37.9 29.9 36.9 54.0 31.0 27.0 258.2 50.7 1.9 2.3 43.4 37.6 14.0 5.0 53.5 1.9 1.8 43.4 37.3 14.4 4.9 55.2 2.4 3.4 78.2 11.5 6.9 3.5 7 Mother’s characteristics Mother’s age left school Mother non-white (%) Retrospective information of the mother: Mother’s age at 1st birth Mother’s age at 1st relationship Mother ever worked before birth of child Mother not living with both parents when 16 (%) Proportion of time child not living with dad (%) Number of waves observed in sample Obs 17.4 4.7 17.5 4.0 16.7 5.7 24.9 21.6 86.3 14.9 6.2 1126 23.0 20.2 84.1 19.0 42.9 5.4 327 20.5 17.6 60.9 36.8 100.0 6.8 87 Note: CS and income are in Jan 2006 prices. III. Analysis and Results 1) Probit Models We focus on the impact of CS on child educational outcomes in this paper. Following Knox (1996) and Argys et al (1998), our main specification contains both the mean CS receipts and mean total net family income in non-intact years during the sample period8. Hence the coefficient of CS measures the extent to which CS has larger effects than those from all income sources. However, unlike Argys et al (1998), we do not control for pre-separation family income, as we only observe one third of the separations taking place in the sample period for the non-intact families. Table 2 presents the marginal effects for the probit models of both outcomes for the sample of non-intact families. Model 1 is the simplest model specification which only controls for repartnership, CS and total net income, all averaged over nonintact years in the sample period. While repartnerships are associated with increases in family income, they are also likely to have an independent effect on child outcomes. Model 2 adds such child characteristics as gender, number of dependent children in the family, a twin indicator and dummies for birth order of the child. Finally, Models 3 controls for two important characteristics of the mother: her age left full-time education and an indicator for being non-white. It is clear that of the three key variables of interest; only CS is significant in explaining the differences in child educational outcomes. An increase in CS receipt from zero to the mean level of £51.9 (conditional on receiving) will decrease dropout rates by 16.5 percentage points and increase GCSE pass rates by 11.9 percentage points respectively, large enough to offset the difference in educational achievements 8 Table 1 shows that this window of observation is 5.4 years for separated mothers and 6.8 years for single mothers on average. 8 between intact and separated families. Moreover, the size of the CS effects is remarkably robust with respect to the successive inclusion of child and mother characteristics. If the observed correlation between CS and educational outcomes are driven by a selection election, we would expect the size of the CS coefficients to decrease in absolute value as we add more controls. Hence we interpret the robustness of the CS effect in the simple probit models as evidence against the pure selection story. Table 2: Marginal Effects (Robust standard errors9 are given in brackets) Left school at 16 = 1 Mother Repartnered CS Receipt (£100/week) Total Net Income (£100/week) Child Characteristics Mother characteristics N χ2(d.f.) Log likelihood Attained 5+ GCSEs = 1 Model 1 -0.007 (0.070) -0.302 (0.100) -0.015 (0.021) No Model 2 -0.052 (0.069) -0.311 (0.094) -0.006 (0.020) Yes Model 3 -0.053 (0.066) -0.318 (0.096) 0.003 (0.018) Yes Model 1 -0.056 (0.081) 0.241 (0.096) 0.038 (0.021) No Model 2 -0.018 (0.080) 0.228 (0.105) 0.028 (0.020) Yes Model 3 -0.016 (0.079) 0.229 (0.103) 0.023 (0.020) Yes No No Yes No No Yes 414 12.71 (3) -243.85 405 41.91 (8) -225.91 405 52.32 (10) -216.47 414 14.20 (3) -265.01 414 33.71 (9) -250.25 414 38.34 (11) -248.65 Notes: Child characteristics include gender, number of dependent children, dummy for twins, dummies for order of births. Mother characteristics include age left full-time education and dummy for being non-white. Bold figures indicate statistical significance at the 5% level. 2) Instrumental Variable Estimation Child support estimates presented in Table 2 will suffer from the endogeneity bias if the unobserved heterogeneity across households affect both CS receipts (and payments) and children’s outcomes. Besides, measurement errors in CS and total net income arising from misreporting and aggregating will also lead to biased results in probit models. The standard approach to deal with endogeneity and errors-in-variables is two-stage least squares. 9 Throughout the paper we report robust standard errors which account for possible hetroskedasticity caused by the inclusion of siblings. Our sample size does not allow us to fully exploit the differences between siblings (see e.g. Bjorklund and Sundstrom (2007)). 9 We allow total family income to be endogenous as well in our main specification since CS is its component. We also treat proportion of time in repartnerships as endogenous. In the absence of convincing natural experiments we base our identification strategy on lagged values. This is not entirely satisfactory and we therefore spend some time establishing the validity of our choices. The set of instruments we use is based on events that took place before the birth of the child, i.e. retrospective information on mother’s fertility, relationship and employment. To maximize efficiency, we also carry out statistical tests which checks for redundancy of (combinations of) instruments. The preferred parsimonious specification includes the following five excluded variables: an indicator for in-wedlock births; a quadratic in the log of mother’s age at first birth; a quadratic in the log of mother’s age at first relationship; an indicator for partnership still at risk by 1993 (i.e. Wave 3 of BHPS), the year the CS reform was introduced10; and an indicator for mother ever worked before the birth of the child. Table 3A presents the second stage IV estimates for the main model specification which controls for child and mother characteristics as outlined in Model 3 in Table 2. As in the probit models, neither repartnership nor total net income has a significant effect on the two educational outcomes. On the other hand, the CS effect found in the probit models remains statistically significant for both outcomes. While the CS effect has increased substantially in size in comparison to the probit specification, so has the standard error11. Indeed, given the large standard errors, one can not reject the null hypothesis that the coefficients are the same across the two different specifications. In interpreting these findings, more emphasis should be placed on the direction and statistical significance rather than the exact size of the coefficients for CS and total net income. It is also worth noting that the IV models easily pass both the Anderson IV relevance test and the Hansen over-identification test of all instruments at any conventional level of significance. 10 There was almost no CS paid pre 1993. The idea of including this dummy was to allow for endogenous separation in response to the 1993 reform. 11 This is a common feature of the IV approach in general, given the trade-off between consistency and efficiency. Moreover, least square estimate has a persistent bias towards zero when the regressor concerned is measured with error. This is known as the attenuation effect (see e.g. Greene (2000)). However, it could also be consistent with a Local Average Treatment Effect (LATE) or a credit constraint story. 10 Table 3B presents the first stage results for the excluded variables used as instruments. Note that the three endogenous variables are identified by different sets of instruments which ensure that the predicted variables should retain some independent variation in the second stage. Moreover, we can reject the joint insignificance of the 7 IVs at the 1% level for all three endogenous variables. Table 3A IV Estimates Second Stages (robust s.e.’s in brackets), N=414 Outcomes Mother Repartnered CS Receipt (£100/week) Total Net Income (£100/week) R-squared Anderson canon corr statistic Chi-sq (df) P-value Hansen J stat Chi-sq (df) P-value Leaving School at 16 -0.184 (0.236) -0.567 (0.231) 0.015 (0.073) 0.323 5+ GCSEs -0.035 (0.257) 0.687 (0.258) 0.030 (0.081) 0.382 17.363 (5) 0.004 LR 6.234 (4) 0.182 3.170 (4) 0.530 Note: Other regressors include child and mother characteristics as outlined in Table 2. Bold figures indicate statistical significance at the 5% level. Table 3B First Stage IV Results (robust s.e.’s in brackets), N=414 Endogenous variables Log mother’s age at 1st birth Square of log mother’s age at 1st birth In-wedlock birth Log mother’s age at 1st relationship Square of log mother’s age at 1st relationship Partnership still at risk by 1993 Mother Ever worked before birth of child Shea’s Partial R2 P-value (joint significance of IVs) Repartnership CS Receipt (£100/week) Total Net Income (£100/week) 2.117 (4.304) -0.366 (0.670) 0.119 (0.071) 0.057 (0.284) 0.000 (0.090) -0.199 (0.060) -0.178 (0.067) 0.073 0.0001 -2.134 (5.293) 0.447 (0.834) 0.095 (0.059) -0.323 (0.230) 0.112 (0.073) -0.125 (0.069) -0.052 (0.061) 0.061 0.0002 38.113 (13.995) -5.492 (2.198) 0.074 (0.241) 1.365 (1.068) -0.415 (0.338) -0.557 (0.252) -0.264 (0.226) 0.047 0.0059 Note: Bold figures indicate statistical significance at the 5% level. Only excluded instruments are reported. While CS is highly endogenous under all specifications, a formal test fails to reject the exogeneity of repartnership and total net income. Tables A3A and A3B in 11 the Appendix present two-stage least squares estimates when repartnership and total net income are treated as exogenous and redundant instruments are dropped as a result of further tests. It is remarkable that the CS coefficients remain largely unchanged and retain statistical significance. However, one should bear in mind that the exogeneity of repartnership and total net income is only true in a statistical sense, i.e. one can not reject the null that the covariance between the regressor and the error term is equal to zero. Given the likelihood of measurement errors in these two variables, and the fact that CS is a component of total net income, we would prefer the current main specification which is less likely than the one in the appendix to be biased by measurement error or endogeneity. 3) The “Two-parent” model: CS for Intact Children So far we have only used the intact families in the descriptive analysis. Following Knox (1996), we carry out an “natural experiment” by testing whether predicted CS for children in intact families using the first-stage coefficients from the IV model above help to explain the variations in educational achievements. If predicted CS turns out to affect educational outcomes for intact children, then the causal explanation found for non-intact children is called into question, as it might be due to any remaining unobserved heterogeneity among families. Table 4 presents the model estimates for the two-parent model. In contrast to the results for non-intact families, the predicted CS has no effect at all on either educational outcome. On the other hand, predicted total net income is statistically significant for both outcomes12. This finding lends strong support to the causal interpretation based on the non-intact family sample. Table 4 Two-Parent Model Estimates (bootstrapped robust s.e.’s in brackets, 1000 repetitions), N=1126 Outcomes Predicted Mother Repartnered Predicted CS Receipt (£100/week) Predicted Total Net Income (£100/week) Adj. R-squared Leaving School at 16 0.141 (0.166) -0.123 (0.086) -0.129 (0.045) 0.107 5+ GCSEs -0.391 (0.206) 0.108 (0.136) 0.235 (0.063) 0.382 Note: Other regressors include child and mother characteristics as outlined in Table 2. Bold figures indicate statistical significance at the 5% level. 12 It is also worth noting that the coefficient of the instrumented income is still smaller than the CS effect for non-intact families, a result that would be consistent with a credit constraint explanation. 12 4) Sensitivity Analysis One might be concerned with the use of an average measure of repartnership and CS, which are averaged over the non-intact years in the sample period. Table 5 presents the second-stage IV estimates13 with binary measures for mother ever repartnered and ever received CS during the sample period. Table 5 IV Estimates Second Stages (robust s.e.’s in brackets), N=414 Outcomes Mother Ever Repartnered Mother Ever Received CS Total Net Income (£100/week) Anderson canon corr statistic Chi-sq (df) P-value Hansen J stat Chi-sq (df) P-value Leaving School at 16 -0.208 (0.332) -0.853 (0.387) 0.119 (0.121) 5+ GCSEs -0.040 (0.319) 0.824 (0.378) -0.046 (0.116) 5.188 (5) 0.393 LR 3.497 (4) 0.478 4.257 (4) 0.373 Note: Other regressors include child and mother characteristics as outlined in Table 2. Bold figures indicate statistical significance at the 5% level. It is striking that the CS effect remains positive for both outcomes, despite the loss of efficiency through using dichotomous measures of repartnership and CS receipt as indicated by the increases in standard errors and worse test statistic for the Anderson IV relevance test14. The results support the hypothesis that improved family dynamics associated with the receipts of CS (i.e. change at the extensive margin) are more important than CS-induced changes in spending patterns (i.e. change at the intensive margin) as far as children’s educational outcomes are concerned. Table 6A and 6B present the second-stage IV estimates for non-intact families with below- and above median family net incomes. For the poorest half of non-intact families which is overrepresented by single parents and benefit recipients, the CS effect is no longer statistically significant, although it still has the right sign and similar magnitude. One possible explanation for this finding is that income has to be above a critical threshold for CS to have a significant effect. The complex interaction 13 To save space, first stage IV estimates for the sensitivity analyses are not shown but will be available from the authors upon request. 14 However, the test of joint significance of the excluded instruments can still be rejected at the level of 5% for all three endogenous variables. 13 between CS and social security benefits which withdraws out-of-work benefits pound for pound might also be responsible. Besides, the measurement error problem might also be more acute for benefit recipients. In contrast, Table 6B clearly shows that our CS findings hold true for nonintact families with above median incomes, with very little change in the magnitude of the effects. Table 6A IV Estimates Second Stages (robust s.e.’s in brackets), Below Median Income, N=207 Outcomes Mother Repartnered CS Receipt (£100/week) Total Net Income (£100/week) Anderson canon corr statistic Chi-sq (df) P-value Hansen J stat Chi-sq (df) P-value Leaving School at 16 -0.195 (0.500) -0.380 (0.444) -0.198 (0.406) 5+ GCSEs -0.155 (0.526) 0.418 (0.407) 0.564 (0.385) 7.756 (5) 0.170 LR 5.662 (4) 0.226 3.579 (4) 0.466 Note: Other regressors include child and mother characteristics as outlined in Table 2. Bold figures indicate statistical significance at the 5% level. Table 6B IV Estimates Second Stages (robust s.e.’s in brackets), Above Median Income, N=207 Outcomes Mother Repartnered CS Receipt (£100/week) Total Net Income (£100/week) Anderson canon corr statistic Chi-sq (df) P-value Hansen J stat Chi-sq (df) P-value Leaving School at 16 -0.195 (0.232) -0.527 (0.254) -0.004 (0.090) 5+ GCSEs 0.087 (0.234) 0.731 (0.271) -0.018 (0.088) 11.276 (5) 0.046 LR 3.412 (4) 0.491 4.628 (4) 0.328 Note: Other regressors include child and mother characteristics as outlined in Table 2. Bold figures indicate statistical significance at the 5% level. 14 Table 7 IV Estimates Second Stages (robust s.e.’s in brackets), Separated Mothers Only, N=327 Outcomes Mother Repartnered CS Receipt (£100/week) Total Net Income (£100/week) Anderson canon corr statistic Chi-sq (df) P-value Hansen J stat Chi-sq (df) P-value Leaving School at 16 0.099 (0.255) -0.296 (0.202) -0.061 (0.064) 5+ GCSEs -0.127 (0.283) 0.515 (0.264) 0.039 (0.077) 14.516 (5) 0.006 LR 6.417 (4) 0.093 4.164 (4) 0.244 Note: Other regressors include child and mother characteristics as outlined in Table 2. Bold figures indicate statistical significance at the 5% level. Finally, Table 7 presents evidence for separated couples only. Although the CS coefficient for school leaving at 16 dips below the 10% significance level, it remains significant at just above the 5% significance level for attaining 5+ GCSEs. This suggests that the causal effect we find earlier is not completely driven by the inclusion of children born out-of-wedlock. IV. Conclusion Our findings suggest that CS payments have a beneficial effect on educational outcomes that is well over and above income from other sources for children living in non-intact families in the UK. This result is very robust with respect to the successive addition of controls for child and mother characteristics, hence offers little support to the selection explanation of the CS effect. Moreover, our instrumental variable coefficients of CS based on retrospective information on fertility, relationship and employment of the mother remain highly significant. On the other hand, predicted CS using the first-stage coefficients from IV model for non-intact children does not affect the educational outcomes for children living in intact families. This natural experiment lends further support to the causal explanation based on the instrumental variable model. We also carry out sensitivity analysis to show that our results are robust with respect to a number of potential pitfalls. 15 References Aizer, A. and S. McLanahan (2006), “The Impact of Child Support Enforcement on Fertility, Parental Investments, and Child Well-Being.” Journal of Human Resources 41(1): 28–45. Argys, L. M., Peters, H. E., Brooks-Gunn, J. and J. R. Smith (1998), “The Impact of Child Support on Cognitive Outcomes of Young Children”, Demography, 153, pp. 159-173. Amato, P.R. and B. Keith (1991), “Parental divorce and the well-being of children: A meta-analysis”, Psychological Bulletin, 110, 26-47 Amato, P.R. (2001), “Children of divorce in the 1990s: an update of the Amato and Keith (1991) meta-analysis”, Journal of Family Psychology, 153, 355-70. Aughinbaugh, A. (2001), “Signals of Child Achievements as Determinants of Child Support”, American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, Vol 91, 2, 140-144. Bjorklund, A. and M. Sundstrom (2007), “Parental separation and children’s educational attainment: A siblings analysis on Swedish register data”, Economica, forthcoming. Booth, A.L. and H.J. Kee, 2005, “Birth Order Matters: The Effect of Family Size and Birth Order on Educational Attainment”, IZA Discussion Paper 1713. Cancian, M., D.R. Meyer, and H-O. Park (2003), “The Importance of Child Support for Low-Income Families”, IRP Wisconsin mimeo. Chevalier, A., C. Harmon, V. O’Sullivan and I. Walker (2005), “The Impact of Parental Income and Education on the Schooling of their Children” IZA Discussion Paper 1496. Dahl, G. and L. Lochner (2005), “The Impact of Family Income on Child Achievement”, NBER Working Paper 11279. Del Boca, D. and C. Flinn (1994), "Expenditure Decisions of Divorced Mothers and Income Composition," Journal of Human Resources Vol.29 pp. 742-761. Del Boca, D. and R. Ribero (2001), “The Effect of Child-Support Policies on Visitations and Transfers”, American Economic Review Papers and Proceedings, Vol 91, 2, 130-134. Ermisch, J. (2005), “New Families, Child Support and Divorced Fathers’ Contact with their Children”, University of Essex, mimeo. Francesconi, M., S.P.Jenkins and T. Siedler (2005), The Impact of Family Structure during Childhood on Later Life, Anglo-German Foundation report. González, L. (2005), “The Determinants of the Prevalence of Single Mothers: A Cross-Country Analysis”, IZA DP 1667. Gregg, P, Propper C., Washbrook E. and S. Burgess (2005), “The Effects of Early Maternal Employment on Child Development in the UK”, Economic Journal, Vol. 115, F48-80. Greene, W., 2000, Econometric Analysis, 4th edition, Prentice Hall. 16 Haveman, R. and B. Wolfe (1995), “The determinants of children’s attainments: A review of methods and findings”, Journal of Economic Literature, 33, 18291878. Knox, V. W. 1996. "The Effects of Child Support Payments on Developmental Outcomes for Children in Single-Mother Families." Journal of Human Resources 31(4):816-840. Kooreman, P. (2000), “The Labelling Effect of a Child Benefit System”, American Economic Review, 90, 371-383. Lundberg, S. (2005), “Men and islands: Dealing with the family in empirical labour economics”, Labour Economics, 12, 591-612. Meyer, D. R. and M-C. Hu (1999), “A Note on the Antipoverty Effectiveness of Child Support among Mother-Only Families”, Journal of Human Resources, 34, 225-34. Plug, E. and W. Vijverberg (2003), “Schooling, family background, and adoption: is it nature or nurture?”, Journal of Political Economy, 111, 611-641. Plug, E. and W. Vijverberg (2005), “Does family income matter for schooling outcomes? Using adoptees as a natural experiment”, Economic Journal, 115, 879-906. Rhum, C.J. (2004), “Parental employment and child cognitive development”, Journal of Human Resources, 39, 155 92. Walker, I. and Y. Zhu (2006), “Child Support and Partnership Dissolution”, Economic Journal, 116, C93-C109. 17 Appendix: Table A3A IV Estimates Second Stages (robust s.e.’s in brackets), N=414 Outcomes Mother Repartnered CS Receipt (£100/week) Total Net Income (£100/week) R-squared Anderson canon corr statistic Chi-sq (df) P-value Hansen J stat Chi-sq (df) P-value Leaving School at 16 -0.183 (0.092) -0.620 (0.229) 0.046 (0.027) 0.307 5+ GCSEs 0.140 (0.111) 0.801 (0.275) -0.036 (0.034) 0.353 31.725 (5) 0.000 LR 6.092 (4) 0.192 2.893 (4) 0.576 Note: Other regressors include child and mother characteristics as outlined in Table 2. Bold figures indicate statistical significance at the 5% level. Table A3B First Stage IV Results (robust s.e.’s in brackets), N=414 Endogenous variable Mother Repartnered Total Net Income (£100/week) Log mother’s age at 1st birth Square of log mother’s age at 1st birth In-wedlock birth Log mother’s age at 1st relationship Square of log mother’s age at 1st relationship Shea’s Partial R2 P-value (joint significance of IVs) Repartnership -0.253 (0.080) 0.089 (0.029) -5.694 (4.724) 0.947 (0.750) 0.106 (0.057) -0.406 (0.221) 0.141 (0.070) 0.074 0.0026 Note: Bold figures indicate statistical significance at the 5% level. All reported variables are excluded instruments except for mother repartner and total net income 18