MIDDLEMEN MARGINS AND GLOBALIZATION1 Pranab Bardhan2, Dilip Mookherjee3 and Masatoshi Tsumagari4 This version: June 26, 2009 Abstract We develop a theory of trading middlemen or entrepreneurs who finance and market goods produced by workers. Brand-name reputations are necessary to overcome product quality moral hazard problems; middlemen margins represent reputational incentive rents. We develop a two sector two country model of competitive equilibrium, with endogenous sorting of agents with heterogenous entrepreneurial abilities into sectors and occupations. Trade liberalization raises inequality between workers and middlemen in the South (which has a comparative advantage in the more labor intensive good, also subject to a greater moral hazard problem). Wages remain lower in the South despite free trade, creating an incentive for Northern middlemen to offshore production to Southern workers. The distributive effects of such offshoring tend to be the opposite of trade liberalization. Keywords: middlemen, reputation, inequality, trade liberalization, NorthSouth trade; JEL Classification Nos: D33, F12, F13, F21 1 Mookherjee’s research was supported by National Science Foundation grant SES0617874. We thank Stefania Garetto, Gordon Hanson, Eric Verhoogen and seminar participants at Namur, IFPRI and Yale for useful comments. 2 Department of Economics, University of California, Berkeley, CA 94720; bardhan@econ.berkeley.edu 3 Department of Economics, Boston University, 270 Bay State Road, Boston MA 02215; dilipm@bu.edu 4 Department of Economics, Keio University, 2-15-45 Mita Minato-ku Tokyo; tsuma@econ.keio.ac.jp 1 1 Introduction Most trade theory is based on production cost differences across countries. The role of endogenous non-production costs and intermediary markups has not received comparable emphasis. This paper presents a model of middlemen in international trade. In our model, middlemen play two roles: (a) value-added managerial activities essential to organize production and transform produced goods into marketable commodities; and (b) brand-name reputations, necessary to assure customers about product quality. Management activities include financing, product design, contracting with workers and product marketing. Brand-name reputations are important in overcoming moral hazard problems in product quality, which cannot be directly observed by customers at the point of sale. Our model relies on heterogeneity among agents in the economy with regard to underlying managerial skill. The theory applies to entrepreneurs who supply skilled labor and employ unskilled workers, as well as to middlemen who operate as intermediaries between customers and producers. In what follows, we interchangeably refer to these agents as entrepreneurs, managers and middlemen. We postulate the production function for any good to depend on amounts of unskilled labor hired by entrepreneurs, and the extent of ‘skilled’ labor provided by the entrepreneurs themselves. The latter is a shorthand for the value-added management activities self-supplied by the entrepreneurs to their own businesses, as in the Lucas (1978) theory of size distribution of firms based on varying abilities of managers. An alternative interpretation is the effect of capital market imperfections which create borrowing constraints, as in theories of occupational choice of Banerjee and Newman (1993) or Galor and Zeira (1993). In this interpretation, the entrepreneur’s ‘skill’ reflects the wealth of the entrepreneur, which affects the cost of financing the firm’s operations since wealthier entrepreneurs have access to cheaper finance when capital markets are imperfect. Entrepreneurial rents or ‘middleman margins’ reflect returns to these value-added activities as well as reputational rents. We are motivated by recent empirical estimates concerning the large proportion of consumer prices accounted by middlemen margins for goods exported by developing to developed countries. Feenstra (1998) provides the following illustration: a Barbie doll sold to US customers for $10 returns 35 cents to Chinese labor, 65 cents covers the cost of materials, and $1 for transportation, profits and overhead in Hong Kong. Mattel, the US retailer earns at least $1 per doll. The remaining covers transportation, marketing, 2 wholesaling and retailing in the U.S. Feenstra and Hanson (2004) calculate Hong Kong markups on re-exports of Chinese goods at 12% of its GDP, while manufacturing accounted for only 6%. The average markup rate accruing to Hong Kong intermediaries on re-exported Chinese goods was 24%. Morisset (1998) reports that the price of coffee declined 18% on world markets but increased 240% for consumers in the US between 1975–93. The average margin between US consumer price and world price for beef, coffee, oil, rice, sugar and wheat increased by 83% between 1975–94. We construct a two sector, two occupation, two country (North-South) general equilibrium model with endogenous reputational rents earned by entrepreneurs. It departs from most existing literature on trade in two ways.5 First, entrepreneurial rents arise as a result of scarcity of managerial ability, or of wealth (combined with capital market imperfections). Each firm is identified with a single entrepreneur; the free entry condition takes the form of equality of firm profits with the rents of the entrepreneur. Only entrepreneurs with the ability (or wealth) required to manage (or finance) firms above an endogenously determined threshold actually enter. The minimum size thresholds for entry depend on the other distinguishing feature of our model: the need for firms to develop reputations for (unobservable) product quality. In contrast, most existing models of trade and product quality assume that the latter is observable by customers at the point of sale (e.g., Auer and Chaney (2009), Hallak and Sivadasan (2009), Sutton (2007)).6 Problems with unobservable quality have been prominent in recent scandals concerning quality of Chinese exports of farm products and toys. We view an essential role of trade intermediaries or entrepreneurs is to develop and maintain reputation for quality; the margins that accrue to them represent rents that provide them with the necessary incentives. We model quality moral hazard problems similar to Biglaiser and Friedman (1994): entrepreneurs have an incentive to make short-term gains from skimping on quality, which customers will not be able to recognize at the point of sale, but only afterwards when they consume the good. Reputational considerations naturally create economies of scale: high-volume sellers 5 An exception is the model of Manasse and Turrini (2001), in which entrepreneurs earn rents owing to a scarcity of skills. Our model differs from theirs by incorporating unobserved product quality and related reputational phenomena. 6 Bardhan and Kletzer (1984) present a model of choice of technology in a developing country between a local low-quality process and an imported high-quality process, but do not embed this in a open economy general equilibrium model. 3 have more at stake if their reputations are destroyed. This is the source of the minimum size threshold required for entry into the intermediary trade: we extend the Biglaiser-Friedman model to incorporate these factors. Given an underlying distribution of entrepreneurial ability or wealth in the population, agents sort into occupations (entrepreneurship and production workers, or traders and producers) and sectors. The two products differ in their requirements of labor vis-a-vis value-added activities provided by entrepreneurs, and in the intensity of the quality moral hazard problem. We refer to the inputs provided by the entrepreneur and workers as ‘skilled’ and ‘unskilled’ labor respectively. The South has a comparative advantage in the less skill intensive good (which we denote as the L-good, while the more skill intensive good is called the C-good). The main assumption on the technology is that the L-good is subject to a greater moral hazard problem. This reflects greater difficulties in quality inspection and in the difficulty of offering product warranties owing to lack of durability of the good. The C-good is more durable; it is produced in a more automated and regulated production process which is easier to inspect, and thus allows less scope for skimping on labor or other essential raw material requirements.7 Equilibria in a closed economy are shown to be either of two types, depending on underlying parameters. In one, with a relatively low price of the L-good, returns to entrepreneurial ability are equalized across the two sectors. This equilibrium is of the traditional “neoclassical” type, where incentive constraints do not restrict the movement of entrepreneurs across sectors. In the other with a relatively high price of the L-good, the returns to ability are higher in the L-sector sector. Entrepreneurs would thus strictly prefer to locate in this sector, but the incentive constraint binds, leading to a higher minimum ability threshold for entering this sector. Those with high enough ability enter the L-sector; others with intermediate ability do not meet the minimum threshold and so have no option but to enter the C-sector instead.8 Equilibria of this latter sort are “non-neoclassical” and exhibit restrictions 7 An offsetting factor would be the greater technological complexity of these goods, combining a larger number of components in the production process. This may lead to high costs of ensuring high quality, as emphasized in the O-ring theory of Kremer (1993). We are assuming that greater difficulties of production inspection and provision of warranties in farm products or garments outweigh the costs of coordinating a large number of inputs in high-tech products. 8 Those who do not meet the lower threshold of the C-sector sector become unskilled workers. 4 on movement of entrepreneurs across sectors owing to the severity of moral hazard problems associated with entrepreneurship in the lucrative L-sector. Of particular interest are the distributive effects of trade liberalization in this model. The relative abundance of unskilled labor in the South confers to it a comparative advantage in production of the L-good. Trade liberalization thus raises demand for the L-good in the South. If the economy was operating in the “non-neoclassical” type of equilibrium, the skill premium (interpreted as ratio of entrepreneurial rents to wages of workers) must rise within this sector. Since the incentive constraint associated with entrepreneurship is binding in this type of equilibrium, expanded production of the L-good requires entry thresholds to be lowered in this sector. This requires reputation rents earned by L-sector entrepreneurs to rise relative to wages of production workers (since unskilled wages form the outside option of entrepreneurs, in the event that they lose their brand-name reputation). On the other hand, rents of entrepreneurs (hence the skill premium) in the C-sector fall. The effect on the economy-wide skill premium thus depends on the relative size of the two sectors: it will rise if the economy operates in the ‘non-neoclassical regime’ and the L-sector is sufficiently large relative to the C-sector, and fall if either of these conditions are not met.9 Empirical studies have not found any systematic tendency for trade liberalization to lower or raise skill premia in LDCs, with increased skill premia found in many instances (Hanson and Harrison (1999), Winters, McCulloch and McKay (2004), Goldberg and Pavcnik (2007)). Our model provides detailed predictions concerning parameters that influence the trade effect on skill premia, which could potentially be empirically tested in future research. For instance, the model provides predictions concerning how the effects vary across sectors and countries, and how they depend on the underlying distribution of entrepreneurial skill in the economy. Efficiency effects of trade liberalization include (apart from standard allocative benefits) effects on the gap between entrepreneurial rents in different sectors and wages of unskilled workers. Agents on the margin between sectors and occupations are subject to discrete increases in incomes as they are enabled to move to their preferred options by a relaxation of incentive constraints, if the economy is operating in the “non-neoclassical” region. These constraints depend on prices; hence the model is characterized by pervasive pecuniary externalities. In the “non-neoclassical” regime, thus, trade is as9 In the “neoclassical” type of equilibrium, classical Stolper-Samuelson results obtain. 5 sociated with income effects in addition to the traditional allocative effects. If the moral hazard problem in the C-sector is negligible relative to that in the L-sector, the income effects expand the welfare gains from trade for the South country, and lower them for the North country. Starting from autarky, a small expansion of trade can thus be welfare reducing in the North. The underlying reason is that reputation rents in the L-sector exceed those in the C-sector, owing to the greater moral hazard problem in the former. These rent effects swamp the traditional allocative benefits associated with trade liberalization, since the latter are second-order starting from an autarky position. The model shows trade liberalization causes a narrowing of North-South differentials of wages of workers, but does not yield full convergence in the absence of any trade barriers. This creates an incentive for Northern entrepreneurs to shift production operations to the South. The distributive implications of such offshoring tends to be the opposite of trade liberalization: e.g., it tends to reduce skill premia in the L-sector in the South, and (under additional assumptions) raise wages. Moreover, the distributional effects of full integration (free trade-cum-costless-offshoring) relative to autarky are in general the opposite of free trade alone. Alternative theories of outsourcing and effects on inequality have been provided by Antras, Garicano and Rossi-Hansberg (2006), Feenstra and Hanson (1996) and Kremer and Maskin (2003). Of these, the most closely related to ours is Antras et.al, who develop a model in which agents of heterogenous abilities sort into hierarchical teams (which extends Kremer and Maskin’s model in a variety of directions). Inequality rises in the South in their model owing to the matching of high ability agents in the South with worker teams from the North. Our theory differs by including two goods, which allows an analysis of effects of trade liberalization as well as offshoring. Rents arise owing to moral hazard and reputational effects, rather than matching of heterogenous agents. Their theory predicts that offshoring raises inequality in the South, whereas our model shows the effect tends to go the other way. Section 2 introduces the model of the closed economy. Section 3 describes the equilibrium of the supply-side, where product prices are taken as given. Section 4 describes the economy-wide equilibrium, and comparative static properties. Section 5 then extends it to a two country context and studies effects of trade liberalization. Section 6 considers incentives and effects of offshoring. Finally Section 7 concludes. 6 2 2.1 Closed Economy Model Endowment and Technology We normalize the size of the population to unity. Each agent is characterized by a level of entrepreneurial skill a, a nonnegative real variable. A fraction 1 − µ of agents have no skill at all: a = 0: we refer to them as unskilled. The remaining fraction µ are skilled; the distribution of skill isRgiven by a ∞ cdf G(a) on (0, ∞). We shall frequently use the notation d(a) ≡ a ãdG(ã). The cdf G will be assumed to have a density g which is positive-valued. Then d is a strictly decreasing and differentiable function. There are two products L and C that are produced and consumed in the economy. We now describe the production technology. A product is produced and sold by an entrepreneur, upon hiring unskilled workers. The level of production depends on the amount of unskilled labor, and the entrepreneur’s skill. It also depends on the quality of the product, which can be either high or low. An entrepreneur with skill a employing N unskilled labor in sector C can produce and sell XC = AC FC (N, a) units of the high quality good C, and XC = AC FC (N, zC a) units of the low quality good C, where zC > 1 is a given parameter. Here FC is a CRS, smooth and concave production function, and AC is a TFP parameter. The entrepreneur may be tempted to producing the low quality good, in order to produce and sell more at the same prices. For instance, producing a higher quality product may demand more supervision or resources provided by the entrepreneur (such as ability to finance working capital requirements). The goods are experience goods, with customers unable to observe quality at the time of purchase. The parameter zC − 1 measures the proportion by which quantity can be increased by compromising quality, so it represents the severity of the moral hazard problem in sector C. Sector L has an analogous technology, described by production levels XL = AL FL (N, a) for high quality, and XL = AL FL (N, zL a) for low quality, with zL > 1. One interpretation of entrepreneurial ‘skill’ is access to finance, if capital markets are imperfect. The latter implies wealthier agents are less subject to credit rationing, so ‘skill’ can be interpreted as wealth of the entrepreneur. Production may require a combination of produced inputs and unskilled labor, and entrepreneurial wealth defines the amount of produced inputs that can be utilized in the production process. In this interpretation, the dis7 tribution of skill in the population reflects the distribution of wealth. Alternatively, entrepreneurial skill refers to management ability, as in Lucas (1978), which is relevant with regard to supervision and control of workers. It could also pertain to marketing skill of the entrepreneur. It will turn out that entrepreneurs with higher skills will in equilibrium be able to produce larger quantities, so the skill distribution will relate naturally to the size distribution of firms. An underlying assumption is that each firm is managed by exactly one entrepreneur, so the size of the firm is limited by the skill of its manager. In practice, of course, firms may employ more than one manager in order to grow, but problems of managerial moral hazard and coordination across managers eventually limit the size of firms (as emphasized by a large literature on ‘organizational diseconomies of scale’, e.g., Williamson (1967), Calvo and Wellisz (1978), Keren and Levhari (1983), Qian (1994) or van Zandt and Radner (2001)). In order to explore the industry or general equilibrium implications of limits to the size of firms created by such problems, we adopt the simplifying assumption that a firm is managed by a single entrepreneur, similar to Lucas (1978). Note that neither unskilled or skilled labor is specific to either sector. Skilled labor is equated with entrepreneurship. Given the assumption that a firm can have only one manager, there will be no market for entrepreneurs: every entrepreneur works for herself, i.e., managing her own firm. Entrepreneurial rents will correspond to imputed prices of ‘skill’ which will be equalized across all agents, and which will clear the market for skill. Consider the cost-minimizing factor combinations in each sector, when C skill is imputed a cost γ relative to unskilled labor: (θN (γ), θaC (γ)) and L (θN (γ), θaL (γ)) are defined as C C C (θN (γ), θaC (γ)) ≡ arg min{θN + γθaC | FC (θN , θaC ) = 1} and L L L (θN (γ), θaL (γ)) ≡ arg min{θN + γC θaL | FL (θN , θaL ) = 1} The following assumption states that good L is more labor intensive than good C: for any common ratio of factor costs, production of L uses a higher ratio of unskilled labor to skilled labor in the cost-minimizing factor choice. One can think of L as corresponding to agricultural products or low-end manufactured goods, while C corresponds to high-tech manufactured goods or services. 8 Assumption 1 For any γ > 0, C L θN (γ) θN (γ) > L C θa (γ) θa (γ) 2.2 Entrepreneur’s Profit Maximization and Incentive Constraint Profit maximization Consider an entrepreneur in sector L, facing a product price of pL (with the C good acting as numeraire, so pC ≡ 1). Suppose the wage rate for unskilled labor is w. If this entrepreneur were to decide to produce the high quality version of product L, she would solve the following problem: max pL AL FL (NL , a) − wNL . NL (1) The optimal employment of unskilled labor NL∗ is a function of pL /w, characterized by the first-order condition (pL /w)AL ∂FL (NL∗ , a)/∂NL = 1. (2) Let Π∗L (pL , w; a) denote the resulting level of profit earned by the entrepreneur. Define Π∗L (3) γL ≡ wa which can be interpreted as a skill premium in the L sector: the per-skill-unit return to entrepreneurs relative to the unskilled wage. This skill premium will play a key role in the analysis below. L Recall the definition of (θN (γ), θaL (γ)) as cost-minimizing factor combination in sector L corresponding to AL unit of production and γ the relative cost of skill. Given the CRS property of the production function, it follows 9 that10 NL∗ a , ) (4) ∗ FL (NL , a) FL (NL∗ , a) Using the definition (3) of γL , we can express the ratio of product price to wage as L (θN (γL ), θaL (γL )) = ( pL NL∗ + aγL = w AL FL 1 NL∗ a = [ + γL ] A L FL FL 1 L = [θ (γL ) + γL θaL (γL )] AL N (5) This equation can be interpreted as expressing equality of prices with unit costs, using γL as the imputed price of skill in sector L. It expresses a monotone increasing relation between the ratio pwL and the skill premium in sector L. A similar analysis for sector C yields an analogous price-cost relation: 1 θC (γC ) + γC θaC (γC ) = N w AC (6) where γC denotes the imputed price of skill in sector C. This equation expresses a monotone decreasing relation between the wage rate w and the skill premium in sector C. Dividing (5) by (6), we obtain the following equation which plays an important role in the equilibrium analysis in later sections: pL = 10 L AC θN (γL ) + γL θaL (γL ) . C AL θN (γC ) + γC θaC (γC ) Euler’s Theorem implies that FL (NL∗ , a) = γL = = = ∂FL ∗ ∂NL NL + ∂FL ∂a a. (7) Hence pL ∂FL ∗ ∂FL N∗ AL [ NL + a] − L wa ∂NL ∂a a pL ∂FL AL w ∂a ∗ ∂FL (NL ,a) ∂a ∗ ,a) ∂FL (NL ∂NL upon using the first order condition (2). It follows from this that (NL∗ , a) is a costminimizing factor combination, if we use γL as the (imputed) factor cost of a unit of entrepreneurial skill relative to unskilled labor. 10 It can be interpreted as equality of relative prices and unit costs of the two products. Note that the right-hand-side is increasing in the skill premium in sector L, and decreasing in the skill premium in sector C. Hence (7) expresses a relation between the skill premia in the two sectors, and the price pL of product L relative to C. This can be expressed as follows: γL = λ(γC ; pL , AC ). AL (8) For any given product price pL and set of TFP parameters, it expresses a monotone increasing relation between the skill premia in the two sectors. And for any given γC and TFP parameters, it expresses a monotone increasing relation between pL and γL . Various properties of this relationship between skill premia in the two sectors will be used subsequently. For now we note one property which plays an important role in establishing uniqueness of equilibrium. Lemma 1 dγL dγC C ≡ λ1 (γC ; pL , A ) > 1 whenever γL ≥ γC . AL Proof of Lemma 1: Implicitly differentiating (7) we obtain L γL + dγL AL θaC θN + γL θaL θaC = pL = = C L L C dγC AC θa θN + γC θa θa γC + L θN θaL C θN θaC > 1, with the second equality using (7), and the last inequality following from θL Assumption 1, γL ≥ γC and the fact that θNL is non-decreasing in γL . a This Lemma states that if the skill premium in sector L is higher than in sector C to start with, a further increase in the sector C premium (with given pL , AL , AC ) must be accompanied by a larger increase in the premium in sector L. Assumption 1 plays an important role here. Since sector L is less skill-intensive, an equal increase in the skill premium in the two sectors will cause unit cost in the L sector to increase by less than in the C sector. Hence the premium must rise by more in the L sector to ensure that the ratio of unit costs remains the same. Incentive Constraint of Entrepreneurs 11 Customers do not observe the quality of the product at the point of sale. We assume they value only the high quality version of the product, and obtain no utility from the low quality version. Entrepreneurs will be tempted to produce the low quality version which enables them to produce and sell more to unsuspecting customers. The short-run benefits of such opportunism can be held in check by possible loss of the seller’s reputation. With probability ηi , an entrepreneur selling a low-quality item in sector i will be publicly exposed (say by a product inspection agency or by investigating journalists). In this event the entrepreneur’s brand-name reputation is destroyed, and the agent in question is forever barred from entrepreneurship. In equilibrium, customers will purchase only from entrepreneurs for whom the threatened loss of reputation is sufficient to deter short-term opportunism. Hence in order for an entrepreneur with skill a to be able to operate in sector i, the following incentive constraint must be satisfied: γi wa w γi wa ≥ γi wzi a + δ[ηi + (1 − ηi ) ], 1−δ 1−δ 1−δ (9) where δ ∈ (0, 1) denotes a common discount factor for all agents. The lefthand-side of (9) is the present value of producing and selling the high quality version of good i for ever. The first term on the right-hand-side, γi wzi a represents the short-term profit that can be attained by the entrepreneur upon deviating to low quality.11 With probability ηi , this deviation results in the entrepreneur losing her reputation for ever, in which case the agent is forced to work as an unskilled agent thereafter. With the remaining probability the entrepreneur’s reputation remains intact. The incentive constraint can be equivalently expressed as a ≥ mi /γi where mi ≡ (10) δηi >1 δηi + (1 − δ)(1 − zi ) is a parameter representing the severity of the moral hazard problem in sector i. Equation (10) represents a fundamental reputational economy of scale, which also translates into a sector-specific entry barrier in terms of entrepreneurial skill required. Intuitively, higher skilled entrepreneurs produce 11 Recall that a deviation to low quality is equivalent to an increase in the entrepreneur’s effective skill from a to zi a. 12 and earn profits at a higher scale (conditional on being able to operate as an entrepreneur), while the consequences of losing one’s reputation is independent of the level of skill. The stake involved in losing reputation is thus proportional to the entrepreneurs skill, which has to be large enough for the agent to be a credible seller of a high-quality good. We assume customers can infer quality from observing the size of the corresponding firm and existing prices, by checking whether the incentive constraint is satisfied. Note that the skill threshold for entry into a particular sector is decreasing in the skill premium in that sector. The reason is simple: a higher skill premium means entrepreneurs have more to lose from losing their reputations. The skill premia depends in turn on prices and wages; hence so do the incentive constraints. This will represent the key pecuniary externality in the model. Note also that mi > 1 implies that entrepreneurs with skills above the required threshold for sector i will strictly prefer to be entrepreneurs in sector i rather than work as an unskilled agent. The per period profit from the former option is γi wa ≥ wmi > w if (10) is satisfied. We now introduce the second major assumption of the model, which states that product L is subject to a more severe moral hazard problem compared with product C. Assumption 2 mL > mC This seems descriptively accurate — agricultural products or low-end manufacturing products appear to be more prone to quality problems than high-tech products. This may owe to differences in effective inspection rates, or to greater scope for manipulating relatively less-automated production processes. It will also turn out as a consequence that the L sector will be characterized by higher margins and a more concentrated structure of trade intermediaries. 3 Industry Equilibrium In this section we take the product prices as given, and derive the resulting equilibrium of the supply-side of the economy. 13 3.1 Occupational Choice and Factor-Market Clearing First we take the skill premia in different sectors as given, and describe occupational choices of agents in the economy. This determines the demand and supply of unskilled labor. The requirement that the factor market clears serves to determine a relationship between the skill premia in the two sectors. Eventually the supply-side equilibrium will be determined by the factor market clearing condition, and the relation (7) between prices and skill premia in the two sectors. Occupational choices will depend on skill premia, as these determine both incentive constraints defining entry into the two production sectors, and their relative profitability. There are four cases to consider. mL Case 1: γL ≥ γC m C mL Since by Assumption 2, m > 1, it follows that in this case γL > γC also C holds. This implies that entrepreneurship in sector L is more profitable than in sector C. The entry threshold for this sector is also lower, as mγLL < mγCC . Hence all those with skill above mγLL will enter the L sector, and those below will become unskilled workers. Clearing of the labor market requires µ[ L θN (γL ) ]d(aL ) = µG(aL ) + (1 − µ). L θa (γL ) (11) The production levels will be XC = 0, XL = µAL d(aL )/θaL (γL ). mL Case 2: γC < γL < γC m C Here γL > γC implies that the L sector is more profitable. On the other hand, the entry threshold is higher in the L sector: aL = mL /γL > mC /γC = aC . So agents with a ≥ aL will choose to become L-sector entrepreneurs, while agents with a ∈ [aC , aL ) are unable to enter the L sector and so have to be content with becoming C-sector entrepreneurs. And agents with a < aC become workers. The labor market clears if µ[ C L mC θN (γC ) mL mC θN (γL ) mL ]d( ][d( ) + µ[ ) − d( )] = µG( ) + (1 − µ). (12) θaL (γL ) γL θaC (γC ) γC γL γC This provides a condition that relates the skill premia in the two sectors. It is easily checked that this relationship is downward-sloping, because an 14 increase in the skill premium in either sector tightens the labor market condition. To see this, note that a rise in γC lowers the entry threshold into the C sector, and raises the demand for unskilled workers for any given C sector entrepreneur. And on the other hand a rise in the L sector skill premium causes the skill threshold for the L sector to fall, motivating some entrepreneurs to switch from the C to the L sector. By Assumption 1, and the fact that γL > γC , L sector entrepreneurs demand more unskilled workers than the C sector entrepreneurs. So the switch of entrepreneurs between the two sectors tightens the labor market. This is accentuated by the rise in demand for workers by incumbent L sector entrepreneurs. In this case, production levels are: XC = µAC [d(aC ) − d(aL )]/θaC (γC ) XL = µAL d(aL )/θaL (γL ) Case 3: γC = γL γL = γC = γ, say, implies that entrepreneurs are indifferent between the two sectors. The L sector is harder to enter, as aL = mL /γ > mC /γ = aC . Hence agents with a ∈ [aC , aL ) have no option but to enter sector C, while those with a ≥ aL can enter either of the two sectors. The equilibrium in this case will involve a fraction of those with a ≥ aL who will go to sector L, the remaining going to sector C. This fraction must be such as to permit the factor market to clear. We show now that this in turn translates into an upper and lower bound for the common skill premium γ. Denoting the production levels by XL , XC respectively, the factor market clearing conditions are L C [θN (γ)/AL ]XL + [θN (γ)/AC ]XC = µG(aC ) + (1 − µ) [θaL (γ)/AL ]XL + [θaC (γ)/AC ]XC = µd(aC ) These equations are equivalent to XL = AL XC = AC C (γ)µd(aC ) θaC (γ)[µG(aC ) + (1 − µ)] − θN C L L C θN (γ)θa (γ) − θN (γ)θa (γ) L (γ)µd(aC ) −θaL (γ)[µG(aC ) + (1 − µ)] + θN . C L L C θN (γ)θa (γ) − θN (γ)θa (γ) 15 However since only agents with a ≥ aL have the option to become L-sector entrepreneurs, XL ≤ µAL d(aL )/θaL (γ) which implies µ[ L C (γ) mL θN (γ) mC θN mC mL )] ≥ µG( ]d( ) + µ[ ][d( ) − d( ) + (1 − µ). (13) L C θa (γ) γ θa (γ) γ aL γ On the other hand, XL ≥ 0 implies µ[ C θN (γ) mC mC ]d( ) ≤ µG( ) + (1 − µ). θaC (γ) γ γ (14) Inequalities (13, 14) provide lower and upper bounds on the common premium rate γ. Note that (13) is the inequality version of the factor market clearing condition (12) in Case 2. Hence the lower bound in Case 3 exactly equals the limiting premia in Case 2 as γL and γC approach each other. This will be shown in the figure below. Case 4: γC > γL γC > γL implies that sector C is more profitable. Also the entry threshold in sector C is lower. In this case no entrepreneur enters sector L. Those with skill a ≥ aC enter sector C, the rest become workers. The labor market condition is θC (γC ) µ[ N ]d(aC ) = µG(aC ) + (1 − µ). (15) θaC (γC ) The production levels are XL = 0 XC = µAC d(aC )/θaC (γC ). The relationship between skill premia in the two sectors that ensure the labor market clears is shown in Figure 1 below. The thresholds depicted γC1 , γC2 and γC3 are defined by the solutions to the following equations. µ[ µ[ L mL 1 θN ( mC γC ) 1 mL 1 ]d(mC /γC ) L θa ( mC γC ) = µG(mC /γC1 ) + (1 − µ) L C θN (γC2 ) θN (γC2 ) 2 ]d(m /γ )+µ[ ][d(mC /γC2 )−d(mL /γC2 )] = µG(mC /γC2 )+(1−µ). L C θaL (γC2 ) θaC (γC2 ) 16 µ[ C θN (γC3 ) ]d(mC /γC3 ) = µG(mC /γC3 ) + (1 − µ) 3 C θa (γC ) For future reference, we shall denote this relationship by the equation γL = ψ(γC ). (16) Note that this function depends on parameters µ, mL , mC but is independent of pL or TFP parameters AL , AC . Note also that this function is well defined for γC < γC3 , and is not a monotone relationship: it is decreasing below γC2 but increasing thereafter. The downward-sloping part corresponding to Case 2 is the ‘non-classical’ region where skill premia are not equalized across sectors. The upward-sloping part corresponding to Case 3 coincides with the line of equality, so this is the ‘classical’ region where skill premia are equalized. Note mL that the greater the relative severity m of the moral hazard problem in the C L-sector, the greater the range occupied by the non-classical region. Figures 2 and 3 subsequently display changes to this relationship resulting from an increase in mL and µ. An increase in mL raises entry barriers into the L-sector, which tends to raise the L-sector premium γL in Cases 1 and 2. A rise in µ raises the fraction of agents with entrepreneurial skills, which tighten the labor market, raise wages, and lowers skill premia in both sectors. 3.2 Supply-Side Equilibrium We are now in a position to characterize the supply-side equilibrium, by putting together the condition that the labor market clears (which incorporates reputation effects, occupational and sectoral choices by entrepreneurs), with the relation between prices and costs representing profit maximization by active entrepreneurs in each sector. The former is represented by the relation between skill premia that clears the factor markets, shown in the previous section. The latter is represented by the upward-sloping relation (7) between premia in the two sector for any given product price pL . Geometrically it is represented by the intersection of the corresponding relations between the two skill premia. This is shown in Figure 4 for different values of pL . Proposition 1 For given pL > 0, as well as other parameters µ, AL , AC , zL , zC , there is a unique supply-side equilibrium determining skill premia and outputs of the two sectors, as well as the wage rate. 17 γL = γL mL γ mC C γL = γC γC1 γC3 γC γC2 Figure 1: Relation Between Skill Premia for Factor Market Clearing We sketch the proof informally. For i = 1, 2, 3, define threshold prices piL corresponding to threshold C-sector skill premia defined previously (which mark the transition between Cases 1,2, 3 and 4): p1L = (AL /AC ) mL 1 L mL 1 γ θ ( γ ) mC C a mC C 1 C + γC θa (γC1 ) L mL 1 θN ( mC γC ) + p2L = (AL /AC ) C θN (γC1 ) L θN (γC2 ) + γC2 θaL (γC2 ) C θN (γC2 ) + γC2 θaC (γC2 ) L θN (γC3 ) + γC3 θaL (γC3 ) = (AL /AC ) C 3 θN (γC ) + γC3 θaC (γC3 ) Now consider the following price ranges. p3L Case 1: pL ≥ p1L In this case, there is an equilibrium with γC ≤ γC1 , with complete specialization in product L, and production levels XL = µd( mγLL )/θaL (γL ), XC = 0. Since the price-cost relation (7) between skill premia in the two sectors is upward-sloping, it is evident there cannot be any other equilibrium. In the interior of this range, the equilibrium outputs are locally independent of pL . 18 γL γL = mL γ mC C γL = γC γC Figure 2: Effect of a Rise in L-sector Moral Hazard Problem on FactorMarket-Clearing Skill Premia 19 γL γL = mL γ mC C γL = γC γC Figure 3: Effect of Rise in µ on Factor Market-Clearing Skill Premia 20 γL p1L Case 1 p2L Case 2 p3L Case 3 Case 4 γL = mL γ mC C γL = γC γC1 γC3 γC2 Figure 4: Supply-Side Equilibrium 21 γC Case 2: p1L > pL ≥ p2L Here there is an equilibrium corresponding to the downward sloping stretch in the relation between γC , γL expressing labor market clearing. This follows from the fact that at p1L there is an equilibrium corresponding to γC1 , and at p2L there is an equilibrium corresponding to γC2 . Moreover in this case there cannot be any other equilibrium owing to Lemma 1.12 In the interior of this range of prices, increasing pL results in an increase in XL and γL , and a decrease in XC and γC . Case 3: p2L > pL ≥ p3L Now there will be an equilibrium in which skill premia are equalized across the two sectors. The same argument as in Case 2 ensures the equilibrium is unique.13 The equilibrium skill premium in this case γL = γC = γ ∗ is determined by the condition pL = ( L AC θN (γ ∗ ) + γ ∗ θaL (γ ∗ ) ) C ∗ . AL θN (γ ) + γ ∗ θaC (γ ∗ ) (17) It is evident that an increase in pL will increase XL , reduce XC and the common skill premium γ ∗ . The latter results as the shift in production towards the L sector raises the demand for labor, inducing a rise in the wage rate. Case 4: pL < p3L In this case, there is an unique equilibrium with perfect specialization in sector C, with production level XC = µAC d(aC )/θaC (γC ). An increase in pL in this region will raise γL , while leaving XC , γC unchanged. 12 2 If there were another equilibrium, it would have to lie in the range γC > γC . But this would require the slope of the skill premium relationship expressing (7) to have a slope smaller than one somewhere above the 45 degree line, which is ruled out by Lemma 1. 13 Note in particular that Lemma 1 ensures that the slope of the relation between skill premia expressing (7) strictly exceeds unity even on the 45 degree line. Hence a tangency of this relation with the 45 degree line is ruled out. 22 γL∗ γC p2L p1L p3L Figure 5: Effect of Changes in pL on Skill-Premia 3.3 pL Comparative Static Properties of the Supply-Side Equilibrium The distributional effects of changes in parameters can now be deduced. 3.3.1 Rise in pL Recall from the price-cost relations (5, 6) that the equilibrium wage rate w moves inversely with the skill premium in the C sector, and pwL moves in the same direction as the skill premium in the L sector. And from the discussion above, we can derive the effect of changing pL on skill premia in the two sectors. This relation is depicted in Figure 5. Focusing on the region p1L > pL > p2L which corresponds to Case 2 above, a rise in pL raises the skill premium in sector L and lowers it in sector C. This implies that w rises, while pwL rises. Hence the wage rate expressed in units of the C good rises, but expressed in units of the L good falls. The effect on utility of workers thus depends on relative preferences in their consumption for the two goods: if biased in favor of the L good sufficiently, workers will be worse off. Treating entrepreneurial skill as the other factor, the return to the 23 unskilled factor relative to the skilled factor in this sector wγwL goes down: an anti-Stolper-Samuelson result. The reason is that an expansion in the output of this sector is associated with an increase in rents earned by entrepreneurs in the L sector, and a lowering of entry thresholds into this sector (i.e., a weakening of the reputational constraints that restrict entry). This requires entrepreneurial returns to rise relative to worker earnings, as the latter serves as the punishment payoff associated with a loss of reputation. Note, however, that over the price range pL ∈ (p3L , p2L ) the StolperSamuelson result does hold. Here skill premia are equalized across the two sectors, and an increase in pL is associated with a fall in the economy-wide skill premium, while the wage rate for unskilled workers rise. The behavior of the economy over this price range conforms to the Heckscher-Ohlin model. The distributional effects for the other price range (p2L , p1L ) can be shown in more detail in Figure 6. This shows the distribution of income across agents with varying skills, and how it changes as a result of an increase in pL . Agents with skill below the entry threshold aC for the C sector earn the unskilled wage w. Between the thresholds aC and aL for the two sectors, the agents are C-sector entrepreneurs, earning γC wa. By definition of the threshold aC = mγCC , it follows that the earning of a C-sector entrepreneur at this threshold equals wmC , which strictly exceeds w as mC > 1. Hence there is a discrete upward jump in earnings at the entry threshold for entrepreneurship. There is a similar discrete jump in earnings at the threshold aL for entry into the L sector, owing to the difference in skill premia between the two sectors. The highest incomes accrue to entrepreneurs in the L-sector, who manage the largest firms in the economy. They are followed by C-sector entrepreneurs, who manage smaller firms, and finally workers who work as unskilled employees in both sectors. Figure 6 shows how the distribution of income is altered following a rise in pL : the skill premium in the L-sector rises, while that in the C-sector falls, and the wage rate rises. For the economy as a whole the change in distribution of income consists of a rise in incomes at the top and the bottom, and a fall in incomes in the middle. Within the export (L) sector, however, inequality rises, and falls within the import (C) sector. Note that these inequality effects appear within firms. 24 wmL wγL a wγC a wmC w a aL aC Figure 6: Income Distribution Changes Resulting from Increase in pL ∈ (p2L , p3L ) 25 γL γC Figure 7: Effect of Increase in µ on Supply-Side Equilibrium 3.3.2 Effect of TFP Changes Now consider the effect of a change in TFP parameters AC , AL . These parameters have no effect on the factor market clearing condition. Their only AL effect is on the price-cost relation (7): a rise in A has the same effect as a C rise in pL . Hence the distributional effect of changes in relative TFP in the two sectors is qualitatively the same as the effect of a change in their relative price. 3.3.3 Effect of Changes in Skill Endowment Next consider the effect of an increase in µ, the proportion of agents in the economy with skills. As shown in Figure 3, the frontier between skill premia corresponding to the factor market-clearing condition (16) shifts inwards, owing to the resulting tightening of the market for unskilled labor. Excepting the case that γC = γL is maintained before and after the change in µ, both skill premia tend to fall, as shown in Figure 7. However, the effect on the relative production levels XL /XC is complicated, we turn to this now. Since the C good is more skill-intensive, one would intuitively expect an increase in endowment of skilled labor in the economy to raise the relative production of C, as the Rybczynski Theorem potsulates in conventional trade theory. This indeed is true in the ‘classical’ region with equal skill premia in the two sectors. From (17) which is independent of µ, it is evident that a rise 26 in µ leaves the skill premium unchanged. Hence the entry thresholds into the two sectors and the demand for unskilled labor from each active entrepreneur of the same skill is also unaffected. Since the L sector is less skill-intensive, it follows that the production of the L good must fall, in order to allow the market for unskilled labor to clear. In the ‘non-classical’ region where the skill premium in the L sector is higher, there will be an additional effect of a change in µ on skill premia in the two sectors. What turns out to matter is the change in the relative skill premia in the two sectors. An increase in µ tightens the labor market and thus tends to drive the unskilled wage higher. Since the L sector is less skill-intensive, this tends to lower the skill premium in the L sector by more than in the C sector. However, the relative skill premium γγCL may still go up, if it was high enough to start with.14 In that case, we obtain a countervailing XL effect which can raise X . C To see this concretely, we consider the following example, where the density of the skill distribution does not fall too fast, and the production functions for both sectors have constant and equal elasticity of substitution between skilled and unskilled labor. 2 g(a) Proposition 2 Assume that ad(a) is increasing in a and production function for i = L, C exhibit constant, equal elasticity of substitution κ(≥ 0): 1/κ κ−1 κ−1 κ Xi = Ai Fi (Ni , ai ) = Ai (ki ai κ + Ni κ ) κ−1 (18) with kC > kL (to ensure Assumption 1 is satisfied). Then in the supply-side equilibrium: k (i) If κ ≥ 1 − log[ kC ] L m log[ m L C for any pL ∈ , an increase in µ has the effect of decreasing XL /XC ] 3 (pL , p1L ). log[ kC ] (ii) If 0 ≤ κ < 1− log[ mkLL ] , the increase in µ has the effect of reducing XL /XC mC for any p ∈ (p3L , AC /AL ). Moreover, there exists p̄L ∈ (AC /AL , p1L ) such that XL /XC is increasing in µ for any p > p̄L . 14 Specifically, the tighter labor market tends to lower γC , and the effect on the relative d( γL ) dγL premium γγCL of a change in γC is dγγCC = γ1C [ dγ − γγCL ] which is negative if C i.e., the initial value of the relative premium is high enough. 27 dγL dγC < γL γC , pL p1L AC /AL µ↑ p2L p3L XL /XC Figure 8: Effect of Increase in µ on XL XC in Supply-Side Equilibrium The proof of this is provided in the Appendix. The Rybczynski theorem is valid if the elasticity of substitution is large (case (i)) and otherwise for C values of pL below A , but not for values of pL close enough to p1L . In the AL latter case the relative skill premium in the L sector is sufficiently high to start with that it increases as a result of the increase in endowment of skilled labor. This is strong enough to cause the relative production of the less skillXL . intensive good to rise. Figure 8 provides an illustration of the effect on X C In the context of the open economy, this will provide an instance where the Leontief paradox appears, if a North and South country differ only in their relative endowments of skilled and unskilled labor. 4 Autarky Equilibrium Now we close the model of the autarkic economy by specifying the demand side. 28 4.1 Demand-Supply Condition There is a representative consumer with a homothetic utility function U = U (DC , DL ), where DC , DL denote consumption of the two goods. The relative demand function is then given by DL /DC = φ(pL ) where φ(pL ) is continuous and strictly decreasing in pL . We assume that limpL →0 φ(pL ) = ∞ and limpL →∞ φ(pL ) = 0. The economy-wide equilibrium is then represented by equalization of relative supply and relative demand: DL /DC = φ(pL ) = XL /XC (19) XL on pL is provided by the supplywhere the dependence of relative supply X C side equilibrium described in the previous section. Proposition 3 There is a unique autarkic equilibrium, in which pL ∈ (p3L , p1L ). This follows from the fact that relative demand is continuous and strictly decreasing in pL , while relative supply is well-defined for pL ∈ (p3L , p1L ), and over this range is continuous and strictly increasing in pL . Moreover, as pL tends to p3L , relative supply of the L good tends to 0 while relative demand is bounded away from zero. And as pL tends to p1L , relative supply of L tends to ∞, while relative demand is bounded. The autarky equilibrium (pL , γL , γC , w) is characterized by conditions of profit-maximization (5), (7); the labor market clearing condition (16), and the product-market clearing condition (19). It is illustrated in Figure 9. 4.2 Comparative Static Effect of TFP Changes Consider the effect of an increase in AC /AL on the autarky equilibrium. As shown in the previous section, it causes a decrease in XL /XC in the supplyside equilibrium for any pL ∈ (p3L , p1L ). Therefore the autarky price pL will increase. However the effect on skill premia γC and γL is more complicated. From (5) and (7), these are determined by pL AL /AC . If the equilibrium level of pL AL /AC increases, the skill premia respond the same way as they do in the supply-side equilibrium when pL increases. Whether this is the case depends on the elasticity of substitution between the two goods on the demand-side. 29 pL XL /XC p∗L DL /DC Figure 9: Autarkic Equilibrium 0 Proposition 4 Let κD denote the elasticity −pL φ (pL )/φ(pL ) of relative demand at the autarkic equilibrium price p∗L . Then a small increase in AC /AL causes p∗L AL /AC to increase if and only if κD < 1. Proof of Proposition 4 Define p̃ ≡ pL AL /AC . The product market clearing condition can be written as φ(p̃AC /AL )AC /AL = (XL /XC )(AC /AL ). (20) Then note that from (7) and (16), γL and γC can be expressed as functions of p̃ alone. It is easily checked from the calculation of the supply-side equilibrium quantities that the right-hand-side of (20) can be expressed as a function of γL , γC alone. Hence this is a function of p̃, i.e., conditional on the value of p̃, it is independent of AC /AL . Moreover it is strictly increasing in p̃ over the relevant range. Since the left-hand-side of (20) is strictly decreasing in p̃ for any given value of AC /AL , it follows that the equilibrium value of p̃ is uniquely determined by this equation for any given AC /AL . The left-hand-side is locally increasing in AC /AL if and only if κD < 1, whence the equilibrium value of p̃ increases in AC /AL . 30 Hence with Cobb-Douglas utility which is associated with κD = 1, changes in TFP parameters will have no effect on equilibrium skill premia. With inelastic relative demand, a ceteris paribus rise in TFP in the C-sector will raise skill premium in the L sector and lower it in the C sector. The profit maximization conditions (5, 6) then imply that w and pwL will rise. The distributive consequences will then be similar to those for the supply-side equilibrium when pL rises, illustrated in Figure 6. 4.3 Comparative Static Effect of Changes in Skill Endowment Now consider the effect on the autarky equilibrium of increasing µ. Recall XL that the effects of this on X in the supply-side equilibrium were quite comC plicated. However it turns out that the distributional effect on the autarkic equilibrium is quite simple: income inequality tends to fall as wages rise, while skill premia in both sectors fall. Proposition 5 Consider a small increase in µ. In the autarkic equilibrium this lowers skill premia in both sectors, while w and pwL both rise. Proof of Proposition 5 First consider the case where the increase in µ locally reduces XL /XC , implying that equilibrium pL rises. Suppose that the initial price level is in (p2L , p1L ). Then as explained previously, taking pL as given, the increase in µ has the effect of decreasing γC and γL in the supply-side equilibrium. On the other hand, the increase in pL causes γC to fall and γL to rise. Therefore the total effect on γC is negative. Since the equilibrium pL rises, the equilibrium level of XL /XC becomes lower. However the right hand side of XL /XC = d(aL ) AL θaC (γC ) L AC θa (γL ) [d(aC ) − d(aL )] increases with a decrease in γC , which implies that the total effect on γL must be negative. From (5) and (6), the effect on w and w/pL must be positive. On the other hand, if the price level is in (p3L , p2L ), the increase in µ does not have a direct effect on γC and γL for given pL , and the effect on both through the increase in pL is negative. 31 Next, consider the case where the increase of µ increases XL /XC locally at the initial equilibrium. This is possible only if pL ∈ (p2L , p1L ). Then the direct effect of µ taking pL as given is negative for both γL and γC . On the other hand, the indirect effect through the decrease in pL is negative for γL and positive for γC . Hence the total effect on γL is negative. A symmetric argument to that in the previous paragraph also implies that the total effect on γC is negative. In sum, regardless of the effect of µ on pL , the increase in µ makes γL and γC go down and w and w/pL go up. 5 Free Trade Equilibrium We are now in a position to examine the effect of trade between two countries that differ in endowments or technology. Suppose there are two countries H and country F , the former corresponding to less developed country. We shall suppose they differ in either of two parameters: country F has a higher µ the proportion of skilled agents (µH < µF ), or higher TFP in the C sector F (AH C < AC ). In all other respects the two countries are identical. As discussed in the previous section, the differences in endowments or technology will create differences in the relative product price between the two countries in the absence of any trade. In the free trade equilibrium (with zero transport costs), there will be a common equilibrium price pTL in the two countries, determined by DLH + DLF XLH + XLF = H DCH + DCF XC + XCF (21) where both relative demand and supplies in each country will depend on the common price. Once pTL is determined, the respective supply-side equilibrium of each country will determine the remaining variables in each country. 5.1 Difference in Skill Endowment Suppose µH < µF , and the two countries are the same on all other dimensions. From the discussion in the previous section, the ordering of relative supplies of the two goods can go either way in autarky. We first consider the ‘regular’ case where the relative supply of the L good is lower in F , so 32 country H has a comparative advantage in production of the L good. Let pjA L denote the autarky price in country j. In most of the discussion that follows, we shall assume that the equilibrium (both under autarky and free trade) in both countries falls in the range corresponding to Case 2 where skill premia in the L sector are higher. (1) pHA < pFL A L In this case, country H has comparative advantage in the production of good L. As a result of the free trade, the equilibrium price level pTL will lie FA in (pHA L , pL ), country H will export good L and import good C. This is the same as in a standard Heckscher-Ohlin model. The distributional effects are somewhat different, however, as illustrated in Figure 10. Trade will raise pL in country H, which as discussed previously will raise the skill premium in the L sector, as well as the wage w. So trade liberalization tends to be accompanied by higher income inequality within the export sector of the developing country: increasing exports of the L good benefits entrepreneurs in the L sectors by more than it benefits unskilled workers. On the other hand, the skill premium in the C sector will decline, so the effect on income inequality in the H country as a whole is ambiguous. See Figure 6 again. Moreover, factor prices are not equalized as a result of free trade. With a common price ratio, country F has a higher skill endowment, and a tighter labor market, so the wage rate is higher in F , and the skill premium in the C sector is lower in F . Since pL is the same in the two countries, pwL is higher in H, and the L sector skill premium is also higher. Thus skill premia in both sectors are higher in H, while the wage rate is lower. (2) pHA > pFL A L In this case, country H has the comparative advantage in production of good C. As a result of free trade, the equilibrium price level pTL in the trade is in (pFL A , pHA L ), country H exports good C and imports good L. This corresponds to the Leontief Paradox in Heckscher-Ohlin theory. In this case, the distributional effects of trade are completely the opposite of the previous case. But wF T > wHT is maintained. 33 γL pFL A HT FA FT pTL pHA L HA γC w/pL wHT wF T w Figure 10: Comparing Free Trade with Autarky: the ‘Regular’ Case 34 5.2 Differences in Technology F Now consider the case of AH C < AC . Recall that in the autarky equilibrium, an increase in AC raises pL . Hence country H will have a comparative advantage in good L, and pHA < pFL A . As a result of free trade, the equilibrium L T HA F A price pL will lie in (pL , pL ). Country H exports good L and imports good C. The effect of trade is thus akin to the effect of a rise in pL in country H, 1j and a fall in country F . If pTL is in (p2j L , pL ) for j = H, F , in country H the skill premium in the L sector rises and falls in sector C, the case described in Figure 6. The opposite happens in country F . Factor prices are not equalized in the trade equilibrium: γLHT > γLF T , γCHT < γCF T and wHT < wF T . 5.3 Welfare Effects of Trade The effects of trade on the equilibrium outcomes of each country are represented by the effect of trade on relative product price pL and thereafter on the resulting supply-side equilibrium. Hence it suffices to examine the welfare effect of changes in pL , which can be shown to be equivalent to the following expression.15 Proposition 6 The aggregate welfare effect in country j of a change in pjL has the same sign as (XLj − DLj ) + wj µ[(1 − mC )g(ajC )dajC /dpjL − (γLj − γCj )ajL g(ajL )dajL /dpjL ] (22) In addition to the standard allocative effect XLj − DLj , there is an additional set of welfare effects operating through the change in entry thresholds aL and aC . This owes to the upward jumps in incomes at these thresholds, owing to the binding incentive constraints operating at these thresholds. A relaxation of these thresholds enables agents to transfer occupations (from being a worker to an entrepreneur, when aC falls) or sectors (from sector C to sector L, when aL falls) and experience a discrete income gain. This explains the second and third terms in the expression above. When aC falls, the change in income is −wj (1 − mC ) for every agent at the threshold, who is switching from being a worker to a C-sector entrepreneur. When aL falls, the change in income is proportional to the difference in skill premia between the two sectors. 15 The Proof is postponed to the Appendix. 35 In general, it is difficult to sign the sum of these income effects resulting from a change in entry thresholds following a relaxation of trade barriers. For instance, consider the cases described above where country H has a comparative advantage in the L good, and it is operating in the regime where the L sector has a higher skill premium. Trade causes an expansion in the L sector (a fall in aL ) which tends to raise aggregate entrepreneurial incomes. It also causes a contraction in the C sector (a rise in aC ) which tends to reduce aggregate income, as some C-sector entrepreneurs switch to becoming workers. The net effect is ambiguous. However, in the case where the moral hazard problem in the C sector is negligible (i.e., mC approaches one), the pecuniary externality at the aC threshold vanishes. In that case the aggregate income effect of trade is positive for country H, which adds to the standard allocative benefits of trade. Conversely, the aggregate income effect is negative for country F , which subtracts from the allocative benefits. Hence starting from autarky, a small expansion of trade can be welfare-reducing for country F ! We summarize this discussion below. Proposition 7 Suppose country H has a comparative advantage in the L good, and the moral hazard problem in the C sector is negligible (mC approaches 1), while that in the L sector is non-negligible (mL is bounded away from 1). Suppose also that both countries operate in the region where skill premia are not equalized across the two sectors. Then country H (resp. F ) experiences a welfare gain from trade in excess of (resp. less than) the standard allocative benefits. Starting from autarky, a small lowering of trade barriers will lower welfare in country F . With different parameter values, these welfare results can get reversed. For instance, suppose that the moral hazard problem in the C sector is nonnegligible, and approximately the same as in sector L (i.e., mC is bounded away from 1 and mL − mC is negligible). Then only movements in the entry threshold aC will generate non-negligible income effects. If country H has comparative advantage in the L good, trade will generate negative income effects for country H and positive income effects for country F . Starting from autarky, small trade expansion will then lower welfare in H, and raise it in F . 36 6 Offshoring The analysis in the previous section showed that free trade between H and F does not lead factor prices to be equalized. In particular, country H with either a lower endowment of skilled labor or lower TFP in the C sector, will end up with a lower wage rate for unskilled workers. Hence entrepreneurs in F will have an incentive to organize their production by hiring workers in H rather than in F . This section examines the implications of this type of offshoring. We restrict ourselves to the case where the two countries differ only in their skill endowment: µF > µH . In addition to free trade in goods, we suppose that entrepreneurs in both sectors and countries can costlessly locate their production operations in either country. The following proposition shows that the resulting equilibrium H L , is identical to that in the completely integrated economy with µG ≡ µ +µ 2 with factor prices equal across the two economies. Proposition 8 With free trade and costless offshoring, the equilibrium is equivalent to that in the completely integrated economy with µG proportion of skilled agents. In this equilibrium, wH = wF . With superscripts A and G denoting the autarky and the fully integrated equilibrium respectively, if γLiA > γCiA for i = H, F , (i)γLF A < γLG < γLHA (ii)γCF A < γCG < γCHA (iii) wF A > wG > wHA Proof of Proposition 8 Suppose that wH 6= wF with free trade and costless offshoring. If wH < wF , all entrepreneurs would hire only workers in country H. However unskilled workers in country F do not have the option to become entrepreneurs, and would thus be unemployed, implying wF = 0, a contradiction. Similarly, we cannot have wH > wF . With a common product price ratio pL and the common unskilled wage, skill premia must be equalized in each sector across the two countries. These premia must clear the market for unskilled workers in the integrated economy, i.e., satisfy (16) with µG representing the proportion of skilled agents. 37 As shown in the autarky equilibrium, in the region that γL > γC holds in the equilibrium, the autarky levels of γ C and γ L are decreasing in µ regardless of its impact on pL . Hence µH < µG < µF implies (i) and (ii). Since γC and w are inversely related, (iii) follows. In the integrated equilibrium, the absence of any trade or offshoring costs implies that entrepreneurs are indifferent which country to locate their operations. This implies that the structure of trade is indeterminate. This indeterminacy could however be resolved by the presence of small trading and offshoring costs. In either case, the difference between the total size of workers hired by country H’s entrepreneurs and the total size of H’s workers must be lower than that in country F , since µF > µH . In other words, the net size of the outsourcing must be larger for country F ’s entrepreneurs. The effects of full integration relative to autarky are shown in Figure 11. Proposition 8 indicates that the distributional effect of full integration differs considerably from that of free trade alone. The latter tends to raise the skill premium in the L sector in country H, implying L-sector entrepreneurs gain more than do unskilled workers. Integration on the other hand causes the skill premium in country H to fall (as indicated by (i)), while the unskilled wage rises (indicated by (iii)). Hence inequality between workers and entrepreneurs within the export sector falls as a result of integration, in contrast to the effects of trade liberalization alone. The comparison of full integration with free trade is somewhat more complicated. Suppose that under autarky country H has comparative advantage in the L good. Since γLHT > γLHA > γLF A > γLF T , it follows that γLHT > γLG > γLF T , i.e., offshoring causes skill premia in sector L to fall in country H, and rise in country F . This is intuitive: the higher skill premia in this sector under free trade in country H owe to the lower unskilled wage. Offshoring allows country F entrepreneurs to employ unskilled workers in country H, erasing the disadvantage they had vis-a-vis country H entrepreneurs. However the effect of offshoring on γC and w is not so clear. If relative product prices were to remain unchanged, then offshoring would raise the unskilled wage and lower the C-sector skill premium in country H. In that case, offshoring unambiguously tends to reduce income inequality between 38 γL µ G µH pFL A pG L pHA L γLHA γLG γLF A µF γC γCF A γCHA γCG Figure 11: Comparison of Autarky with Full Integration 39 unskilled and skilled agents in country H. However, offshoring could have another effect, by causing a change in pL . This effect is not easy to sign, however. If terms-of-trade effects of offshoring are insignificant we can infer that it tends to generally improve income distribution in favor of unskilled workers in both sectors in country H. 7 Concluding Comments We have constructed a theory of entrepreneurial or intermediary rents in a general equilibrium model of trade. These rents arise as return to key roles in financing and marketing they play. Of particular importance is the role of their brand-name reputations which are necessary to overcome product quality moral hazard problems vis-a-vis customers. The model helps explain why trade liberalization can increase inequality of earnings between production workers and entrepreneurs in developing countries. Reputational factors and limits to the size of firms reflecting fundamental moral hazard problems with regard to entrepreneurial functions such as management, finance and marketing prevent costless reallocation of factors across sectors, resulting in rising inequality within sectors and firms. The model explains incentives for Northern countries to offshore their production to Southern countries, and predicts the distributive implications of such offshoring to be the opposite of trade liberalization. Apart from margins earned by intermediaries, the model also generates a number of implications for size distribution of firms in different sectors, and how they are affected by relaxation in barriers to trade and offshoring. We hope these can be subject to empirical testing in future research. References Antras Pol, Luis Garicano and Esteban Rossi-Hansberg (2006), “Offshoring in a Knowledge Economy,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 121(1), 31-77. Auer Raphael and Thomas Chaney (2009), “Exchange Rate Pass-Through in a Competitive Model of Pricing-to-Market,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, 41(s1), 151-175. Banerjee V. Abhijit and Andrew Newman (1993), “Occupational Choice and the Process of Development,” Journal of Political Economy, 101(2), 274-298. 40 Bardhan Pranab and Ken Kletzer (1984), “Quality Variations and the Choice between Foreign and Indigenous Goods or Technology,” Journal of Development Economics, 14(3), 323-330. Biglaiser Gary and James Friedman (1994), “Middlemen as Guarantors of Quality,” International Journal of Industrial Organization, 12, 509-531. Calvo A. Guillermo and Stanislaw Wellisz (1978), ‘Supervision, Loss of Control and the Optimal Size of the Firm,” Journal of Political Economy, 86(5), 943-52. Feenstra Robert (1998), “Integration of Trade and Disintegration of Production in the Global Economy,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, Fall, 31-50. Feenstra Robert and Gordon Hanson (1996), “Foreign Investment Outsourcing and Relative Wages,” in Economy of Trade Policy: Essays in Honour of Jagdish Bhagwati, R.C. Feenstra, G.M. Grossman and D. Irwin, eds., Cambridge MA and London: MIT Press. —————– (2004), “Intermediaries in Entrepot Trade: Hong Kong ReExports of Chinese Goods,” Journal of Economics and Management Strategy, 13(1), 3-35. Galor Oded and Joseph Zeira (1993), “Income Distribution and Macroeconomics,” Review of Economic Studies, 60(1), 35-52 Goldberg Pinelopi and Nina Pavcnik (2007), “Distributional Effects of Globalization in Developing Countries,” Journal of Economic Literature, 65, 3982. Hallak Juan Carlos and Jagadeesh Sivadasan (2009), “Firms’ Exporting Behavior under Quality Constraints,” NBER Working Paper No. w14928. Hanson, Gordon and Ann Harrison (1999), “Who Gains from Trade Reform? Some Remaining Puzzles,” Journal of Development Economics, 59(1), 12554. Keren Michael and David Levhari (1983), “The Internal Organization of the Firm and the Shape of Average Cost,” Bell Journal of Economics, 14(2), 474-86 Kremer Michael (1993), “The O-Ring Theory of Economic Development,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 108, 551-575. Kremer Michael and Eric Maskin (2003), “Globalization and Inequality,” mimeo, Department of Economics, Harvard University. Lucas Robert. E. Jr. (1978), “On the Size Distribution of Business Firms,” The Bell Journal of Economics, 9(2), 508-523. 41 Manasse Paolo and Alessandro Turrini (2001), “Trade, Wages and Superstars,” Journal of International Economics, 54(1), 97-117. Morisset Jacques (1998), “Unfair Trade? The Increasing Gap Between World and Domestic Prices in Commodity Markets during the Past 25 Years,” World Bank Research Observer, 12 (3), 503-526. Qian Yingyi (1994), “Incentives and Loss of Control in an Optimal Hierarchy,” Review of Economic Studies, 61(3), 527-44. Sutton John (2007), “Quality, Trade and the Moving Window,” Economic Journal, 117(524), F469-498. Van Zandt Timothy and Roy Radner (2001), “Real-Time Decentralized Information Processing and Returns to Scale,” Economic Theory, 17(3), 545-75. Williamson E. Oliver (1967), “Hierarchical Control and Optimal Firm Size,’ Journal of Political Economy, 75, 123-138. Winters L. Alan, Nel McCulloch and Andrew McKay (2004), “Trade Liberalization and Poverty: The Evidence So Far,” Journal of Economic Literature, 42(1), 72-115. 42 Appendix Proof of Proposition 2 Step 1 C (i)If κ ≥ 1, d[γL /γC ]/dγC = d[λ(γC ; pL , A )/γC ]/dγC > 0 for any γC so that AL AC λ(γC ; pL , AL )/γC ≥ 1 C )/γC ]/dγC > 0 if and only if (ii)If κ < 1, d[γL /γC ]/dγC = d[λ(γC ; pL , A AL 1 pL < AC /AL (and equivalently γL /γC < ( kkCL ) 1−κ ). Proof of Step 1 From (7), d[γL /γC ]/dγC = (1/γC )[ γL + L θN θaL γC + C θN θaC − γL ], γC which means that d[γL /γC ]/dγC > 0 if and only if γL θaL (γL ) γC θaC (γC ) < . L C θN (γL ) θN (γC ) Under this production function in the proposition, θai (γi ) = (γi )−κ ki i θN (γi ) and pL = L 1 AC θN (γL ) + γL θaL (γL ) AC kL γL1−κ + 1 1−κ = [ ] . 1−κ C C AL θN (γC ) + γC θa (γC ) A L k C γC + 1 In the case of κ ≥ 1 and γL ≥ γC , γL θaL (γL ) γC θaC (γC ) 1−κ 1−κ = (γ ) k < (γ ) k = L L C C L C θN (γL ) θN (γC ) implying d[γL /γC ]/dγC > 0. In the case of κ < 1, γC θaC (γC ) γL θaL (γL ) < , L C θN (γL ) θN (γC ) 1 if and only if γL /γC < ( kkCL ) 1−κ which is equivalent to pL < AC /AL . 43 Step 2 k (i) If κ ≥ 1 − log[ kC ] L m log[ m L C ] , d[λ(γC ; pL , AC )/γC ]/dγC > 0 AL holds for pL ∈ [p2L , p1L ). k (ii) If 0 ≤ κ < 1 − log[ kC ] L m log[ m L ] , for any pL < AC /AL , C d[λ(γC ; pL , AC )/γC ]/dγC > 0 AL and for any pL > AC /AL , d[λ(γC ; pL , AC )/γC ]/dγC < 0. AL Proof of Step 2 First suppose that k 1>κ≥1− log[ kC ] L m log[ m L C ] mL mC ≤ [ kkCL ]1/(1−κ) and κ < 1, which are equivalent to . If pL ∈ (p2L , p1L ), since mL /mC > γL /γC ≥ 1 is satisfied in an equilibrium of supply-side, it implies γL /γC < ( kkCL )1/(1−κ) (or pL < From (ii) of Step 1, this means that d[λ(γC ; pL , AC ). AL AC )/γC ]/dγC > 0 AL holds for pL ∈ [p2L , p1L ). From (i) of Step 1, this inequality also holds for κ ≥ 1. This completes the proof of (i). k Next take 0 ≤ κ < 1 − log[ kC ] L m log[ m L C ] . From (ii) in Step 1, for any pL < AC /AL , d[λ(γC ; pL , AC )/γC ]/dγC > 0 AL and for any pL > AC /AL , d[λ(γC ; pL , AC )/γC ]/dγC < 0 AL This completes the proof of (ii). 44 Step 3 Taking pL ∈ (p1L , p2L ) as given, let’s consider the effect of µ on XL /XC = AL θaC (γC ) d(aL ) L AC θa (γL ) [d(aC ) − d(aL )] We can use the following relationship. θaC (γC ) ]/dµ θaL (γL ) 0 0 θaC (γC ) θaC (γC ) θaL (γL ) AC = L )]dγC /dµ [ C − L λ1 (γC ; pL , θa (γL ) θa (γC ) θa (γL ) AL d[ 0 0 θC (γC ) θaL (γL ) γL = aL [ θa (γL ) θaL (γL ) γC γC θaC (γC ) θaC (γC ) γL θaL0 (γL ) θaL (γL ) − λ1 (γC ; pL , 0 A θaC (γC ) θaL (γL ) λ(γC ; pL , ACL ) = L [ θa (γL ) θaL (γL ) γC γL θaL (γL ) L (γ ) θN L +1 γC θaC (γC ) C (γ ) θN C +1 − λ1 (γC ; pL , AC )]dγC /dµ AL A 0 < AC )]dγC /dµ AL AC θaC (γC ) θaL (γL ) λ(γC ; pL , ACL ) − λ (γ ; p , )]dγC /dµ < 0 [ 1 C L θaL (γL ) θaL (γL ) γC AL C if d[λ(γC ; pL , A )/γC ]/dγC > 0. This relationship is using the fact that AL 0 γi θai γi θai = −κ/( + 1) i θai θN C and d[λ(γC ; pL , A )/γC ]/dγC > 0 if and only if AL we obtain γL θaL (γL ) L (γ ) θN L < γC θaC (γC ) C (γ ) . θN C Similarly, d(aC ) )/dµ d(aL ) d(aC ) (aC )2 g(aC )/γC (aL )2 g(aL )/γL = [ − λ1 (γC , pL )]dγC /dµ d(aL ) d(aC ) d(aL ) A AC d(aC ) (aL )2 g(aL )/γL λ(γC ; pL , ACL ) [ − λ1 (γC ; pL , )]dγC /dµ > 0 > d(aL ) d(aL ) γC AL d( 45 C if d[λ(γC ; pL , A )/γC ]/dγC > 0. This is using the assumption that AL increasing in a. This implies that a2 g(a) d(a) is d(XL /XC )/dµ < 0. k for pL ∈ [p2L , p1L ) if κ ≥ 1 − L m log[ m L ] and for pL ∈ [p2L , AC /AL ) if 0 ≤ κ < C k 1− log[ kC ] log[ kC ] L m log[ m L ] . C Step 4 Next suppose pL ∈ (p2L , p3L ). γL = γC = γ ∗ is determined by pL = ( L AC θN (γ ∗ ) + γ ∗ θaL (γ ∗ ) ) C ∗ . AL θN (γ ) + γ ∗ θaC (γ ∗ ) γ ∗ is independent of µ. This means that dγ ∗ /dµ = 0. We have only the direct effect of µ on XL /XC , which is negative. From step 3 and this step, this completes the proof of (i) and the first half of (ii) in the proposition. Step 5 Finally let us show the last part of (ii). Suppose that there does not exist p̄L ∈ (AC /AL , p1L ) so that XL /XC is increasing in µ for any p ∈ (p̄L , p1L ). Then p1L has to be non-decreasing in µ. However dp1L /dµ = mL 1 L mL 1 γ θ ( γ ) γC1 θaC (γC1 ) mC C a mC C 1 1 − ]dγC1 /dµ (pL /γC )[ L mL 1 mL 1 L mL 1 C 1 1 C 1 θN ( mC γC ) + m γ θ ( γ ) θ (γ ) + γ θ (γ ) N C C a C C C a mC C is negative from step 2(ii). This is the contradiction. Proof of Proposition 6 Let the indirect utility function for country j be V (pjL , I j ) where national income I j = pjL XLj + XCj . 46 V (pj ,I j ) By Roy’s identity DLj = − Vp (pjL ,I j ) , I L dV (pjL , I j )/dpjL = ∂V (pjL , I j ) ∂V (pjL , I j ) dI j + ∂I j ∂pjL dpjL = dI j ∂V (pjL , I j ) j [−D + ] L ∂I j dpjL = ∂V (pjL , I j ) [(XLj − DLj ) + pjL dXLj /dpjL + dXCj /dpjL ] ∂I j ∂V (pj ,I j ) L Since > 0, the sign of the welfare effect of the change in pjL is the ∂I j same as the sign of (XLj − DLj ) + pjL dXLj /dpjL + dXCj /dpjL Owing to linear homogeneity of the production function and the common NL /a chosen by all entrepreneurs in a given sector, XLj = AL FL (NLj , HLj ) where NLj (resp. HLj ) is the total amount of unskilled (resp. skilled) labor used in the L sector of country j. Since pjL dXLj /dNLj = wj and γLj = j j j ∂FL (NL ,HL )/∂HL j j j ∂FL (NL ,HL )/∂NL , pjL dXLj /dpjL = pjL AL [∂FL (NLj , HLj )/∂NLj [dNLj /dpjL ] + ∂FL (NLj , HLj )/∂HLj [dHLj /dpjL ]] = wj [dNLj /dpjL + γLj dHLj /dpjL ] Similarly dXCj /dpjL = AC [∂FC (NCj , HCj )/∂NCj [dNCj /dpjL ] + ∂FC (NCj , HCj )/∂HCj [dHCj /dpjL ]] = wj [dNCj /dpjL + γCj dHCj /dpjL ] Therefore pjL dXLj /dpjL +dXCj /dpjL = wj [d(NLj +NCj )/dpjL +γCj d(HLj +HCj )/dpjL +(γLj −γCj )dHLj /dpjL ]. j j j3 j2 j j1 Since HLj = µd(ajL ) for pjL ∈ (pj2 L , pL ) and γL = γC for pL ∈ (pL , pL ), (γLj − γCj )dHLj /dpjL = µ(γLj − γCj )d(d(ajL ))/dpjL j1 j j j j j holds for pjL ∈ (pj3 L , pL ). With NL + NC = µG(aC ) + (1 − µ) and HL + HC = j j j3 j1 µd(aC ) for pL ∈ (pL , pL ), (XLj − DLj ) + pjL dXLj /dpjL + dXCj /dpjL = (XLj − DLj ) + wj µ[dG(ajC )/dpjL + γCj d(d(ajC ))/dpjL + (γLj − γCj )d(d(ajL ))/dpjL ] = (XLj − DLj ) + wj µ[(1 − mC )g(ajC )dajC /dpjL − (γLj − γCj )ajL g(ajL )dajL /dpjL ] 47