Proceedings of the 34th Hawaii International Conference on System Sciences - 2001 A Framework for the Evaluation of an Electronic Marketplace Design with Evolutionary Negotiation Support Sungwon Cho University of Hawaii at Manoa 1645 Dole St. #204 Honolulu, HI 96822 sungwonc@hawaii.edu Abstract With the aid of information technology, electronic marketplaces have multiplied. Currently, however, most electronic marketplaces support only limited negotiation functions using a one-dimensional variable of price. The purpose of this study is to show how online multidimensional auction systems can be used to facilitate electronic trading in business-to-business electronic marketplaces. In this paper, we first evaluate the existing electronic marketplaces. Based on this evaluation, the functional requirements for a buyer-centric electronic marketplace are presented. Then, we propose a new multidimensional auction model with evolutionary negotiation support (MAMENS) to be used in the electronic marketplace. Finally, the evaluation framework for the MAMENS is discussed. Keywords: Electronic marketplaces; Multidimensional auctions; Multi-attribute auction; Evaluation 1. Introduction As a consequence of the Internet’s phenomenal growth, innumerable, daily online business activities are occurring, all as part of an emerging field called as Electronic Commerce (EC). EC’s potential can be compared to a volcanic eruption in its awesome power and its laying of rich and fertile groundwork for significant future business transactions. An electronic marketplace is a special kind of EC that serves as an intermediary over which multiple buyers and sellers conduct business [6]. Internet auction sites are good examples of emerging electronic marketplaces. These sites have become increasingly popular for the entertaining experience of “dynamic pricing”. The number of Internet auction sites continues to grow at a rapid pace. Although early sites focused on providing marketplaces for transactions in rare goods or second-hand goods between individuals, the true potential strength of such electronic marketplaces lies in Business-to-Business transactions. According to recent market research, consumer and business auctions will account for 29% of all EC, or $129 billion, by 2002, increased from $3.8 billion at the end of 1998 [8]. Currently, however, most electronic marketplaces support only limited negotiation functions using the onedimensional variable of price. Although this simplistic approach may help in price discovery for standardized goods, it leaves little room for negotiations for other attributes of products/services. Consequently, despite rapid automation of the other phases of transactions, negotiations are still done using face-to-face meetings or traditional communication technology such as phones, causing extra overhead costs. In this paper, we propose buyer-centric electronic marketplaces with evolutionary negotiation supports. The function requirements will be discussed along with a conceptual model for proposing electronic marketplaces. However, the most important contribution of this paper is introducing the new Multidimensional Auction Model with Evolutionary Negotiation Support (MAMENS). The paper will show how MAMENS can be used to support negotiations. In the following section, we will discuss the phase model of market transactions followed by an evaluation of current electronic marketplaces. Based on the evaluation, functional requirements for buyer-centric electronic marketplaces are presented. Then, we introduce MAMENS. Finally, the evaluation framework for the MAMENS is discussed. 0-7695-0981-9/01 $10.00 (c) 2001 IEEE 1 Proceedings of the 34th Hawaii International Conference on System Sciences - 2001 2. Phase model of electronic marketplaces Electronic marketplaces offer a place for buyers and sellers to meet and perform transactions. The narrow definition of electronic marketplace is “an interorganizational information system that allows the participating buyers and sellers in some markets to exchange information about prices and product offerings [ 1, p.1676] . ” However, a broader definition of electronic marketplace includes all the activities that support transactions. A number of studies explore the role of electronic marketplaces [2, 4, 6, 10, 15, 16]. Although each study presents a slightly different view, the following phase model of market transactions is generally used to classify the role of electronic marketplaces [2, 15, 16]. • Information phase • Negotiation phase • Settlement phase • Other service (Trust, dispute resolution, insurance, rules and regulation) Information phase The fundamental role of electronic marketplaces in this phase is to provide a matchmaking service between buyers and sellers including order matching and trading partner matching. The matchmaking service includes several subfunctions. First, buyers and sellers access and collect information concerning potential trading partners as well as goods and/or services (e.g., specification, price, etc. ). A buyer compares specification and price of the wanted goods/services. Then the buyer determines who to buy from. High transparency and low search costs for this information make electronic marketplaces particularly promising in this phase [1]. Negotiation phase Once a buyer determines what to buy and who to buy from, both trade partners need to agree on terms and conditions for the transaction. In a fixed pricing scheme, or simple auction services, this phase is often skipped. A conventional auction is a special kind of negotiation support tool that only considers price as a single factor. However, it is often the case, especially in Business-to Business trading, that we need to take into consideration multiple attributes in a transaction. payment must be transferred to the seller and the goods sold must be transferred to the buyer. Electronic marketplaces need to make sure that the goods and payment are transferred to the appropriate party based on the agreement. Other service Some functions are not directly linked to a transaction, but are highly desirable in order for an electronic marketplace to serve as a intermediary. The most important issue that may occur during the settlement phase is how to build trust. Electronic marketplaces need to maintain a high level of trust among buyers and sellers by preventing fraud. In addition, the electronic marketplaces need to support a means of dispute resolution in case one of the parties makes a claim. 3. Evaluation of current electronic marketplaces There are many electronic marketplaces and each provides a different range of functionality. Some support just auctions and the others support a much broader range of business activities. In order to compare electronic marketplaces, we identified eight evaluation criteria based on the above mentioned phase model. Table 1 shows the evaluation criteria for electronic marketplaces. To identify a broad spectrum of evaluation criteria, this study used the ABI inform online search database which is a widely used database in the business area. The study selected electronic marketplaces or Internet auction sites that were mentioned in trade magazines or academic journals during the time period of Jan.1999 to Dec. 1999. They were mainly mentioned for either their popularity, potential impact on industry, and/or unique features. Some examples of the evaluation results are shown in table 2. < Table 1. Evaluation criteria for electronic marketplaces > Phase model of market transaction Information Negotiation Settlement phase The final phase of a transaction is the settlement phase. The settlement phase comprises ensuring payment and delivery of goods. After the transaction is agreed upon, Settlement Other service 0-7695-0981-9/01 $10.00 (c) 2001 IEEE Evaluation criteria Type of goods traded Target market Specification of products Type of negotiation Type of auction mechanism Negotiation support Settlement support Trust enhancing mechanism 2 Proceedings of the 34th Hawaii International Conference on System Sciences - 2001 < Table 2. Example of evaluation of existing electronic marketplaces > Electronic marketplaces Type of goods traded Ebay (http://www.e bay.com) Books, movies, music, etc. Books, movies, music, etc. Airline tickets, etc. Yahoo (http://auctions .yahoo.com/) Priceline.com (http://www.pr iceline.com/) Targe t marke t C2C Specif icatio n Negotiation type Seller Buyer Seller 1 C2C or B2C Seller B2C Type Employed auction mechanism Negotiation support N Aucti on English, Dutch, etc. Proxy bidding 1 N Aucti on English, Dutch, etc. Buyer N 1 Aucti on Reverse auction English auction Rbuy (http://www.R buy.com/) Real estate Any Seller 1 N Aucti on FastParts (http://www.fa stparts.com/) Electronic componen ts and equipeme nt B2B Seller 1 N Aucti on ExpertsExchan ge (http://www.e xpertsexchange.com/ ) Frictionless.co m (http://www.fr ictionless.com/ ) Knowledg e C2C or B2C Buyer N 1 Aucti on Reverse auction based on rating N/A (Decision support software ) B2B Buyer N 1 Match makin g N/A 3.1 Type of goods traded One of the classifying factors for electronic marketplaces is the type of goods traded. Traditional economic theory points out that the type of goods is an important factor in the trading scenario. Therefore, many traditional auction services were established for trading specific type of goods such as perishables (e.g., produce), and rare or second-hand goods that are characterized by the limited market and difficulty in assessing an appropriate price. In fact, early Internet auction sites gained popularity by providing marketplaces for those kind of goods. However, today’s auction items are not limited to a few categories. Currently, a wide range of goods are traded through Internet auction sites. Theoretically, an auction is suitable for trading standardized items (e.g., stock), which do not require a complex ontology to describe so that the negotiation Settlement support Trust enhancing mechanism e-mail req. Rating, reputation. Payment is made by the buyer to Price.com User ID and valid credit card rating and feedback Credit card payment in advance with no setback allowed A computerized negotiation program that helps bridge the differences. Payment is made by the buyer to FastParts.com, then the payment is released to the seller. Token transfer Pre-qualified members only. Buyers have a 5 business day quarantine period Expert registration. If the buyer does not find the match form pool of products, he can turn his preferences into a reverse auction efforts can be focused on price. More recently, Internet auction sites received publicity as a potential marketplace for trading intangible goods such as expertise and intellectual property (e.g., expertexchange.com ). Such sites use social ratings or reputation mechanisms as the means of evaluating quality for these intangible goods. 3.2 Target Market This article found three types of target markets: business-to-business (B2B), business-to-consumer (B2C), and consumer-to-consumer (C2C). Although there are no typical products for different target markets, we found that electronic components, industrial parts, and surplus assets are traded in B2B; and smaller and less expensive products like books, movies, music, and art are traded through C2C or B2C. Computers, software, and travel packages are traded in B2C systems. The recent trend is that many marketplaces originally targeted for C2C are migrating 0-7695-0981-9/01 $10.00 (c) 2001 IEEE 3 Proceedings of the 34th Hawaii International Conference on System Sciences - 2001 into B2C with the involvement of small businesses which want to sell their products with little marketing effort. 3.3 Specification of products As for the specification of goods, the most important thing is the issue of ontology [3, 4]. Since different users may specify the same item in different ways, it is very difficult to create a standardized set of attributes for the same product. Product description is a problem not only in the matchmaking process but in the settlement process. For example, malicious users can intentionally avoid specifying inferior features if there is no standard set of attributes. This is often the case in classified ads in newspaper. Having a standardized set of specifications will also help buyers/sellers access multiple electronic marketplaces simultaneously, using agent technology. Product specification is also an important issue for using a multidimensional auction. Without the agreed upon set of attributes, cooperative negotiations are not feasible. There are two possibilities for solving this problem: One approach is to force the user to follow a pre-defined set of specifications according to the type of products (e.g. Personallogic.com). This way we can standardize product description. However, it is impractical to identify the necessary dimensions of all goods. The other approach is to leave product description to either the sellers or buyers who initiate the trade. In this case, we do not have standardized product descriptions, but we have more flexibility. 3.4 Negotiation type Previous research used the number of participants as a major dimension of classifying EC [3, 12]. Even before Internet auctions became popular, this kind of taxonomy was widely used in the NSS research area (e.g. bilateral vs. multilateral). Table 3 shows the taxonomy of negotiation type based on the number of participants. The majority of auction services fall into the category of 1:N whereas mediated matching services fall into N:N. < Table 3. Taxonomy of negotiation types based on the number of participants > Seller/ buyer One Many One Bargaining Reverse auction Many Auction Mediated transaction 3.5 Type of auction mechanism Since auctions provide an efficient way for price determination, many electronic marketplaces have been built based on the auction mechanism. However, there are varieties of auction mechanisms and each has its own strengths and weaknesses. Most seller-centric electronic marketplaces (i.e., B2C, or C2C) provide a variety of auction mechanisms including English, Dutch, and multiple-unit uniform price auctions [12]. On the other hand, buyer-centric electronic marketplaces (B2C, B2B) mainly use the reverse auction mechanism. The reverse auction mechanism is a familiar form to government or corporate purchasing departments. For more information on auction mechanisms, see [12]. 3.6 Negotiation support Few electronic marketplaces provide negotiation support for other than price. Some Internet auction services (e.g., Rbuy ) provide negotiation support to help both trading partners reach a consensus. However, the algorithms used in these automatic negotiations are too simple to be widely used in real transactions. On the other hand, a few of the other Internet auction services (e.g., eBay) provide a “proxy bidding” service which automatically increases bidding until the bidding price reaches users’ willing-to-pay price. Although this proxy bidding may relieve users from the burden of constantly monitoring the bidding process, it is too primitive to be considered a negotiation support. The more promising method of providing negotiation support is by using a multidimensional auction mechanism. Only a few electronic marketplaces employ multidimensional auction mechanisms (e.g., Frictionless.com). These electronic marketplaces aim to find optimal goods and partners based on the user’s preference not only on price, but also on other variables such as quantity and shipping option. 3.7 Settlement support A final and important role of electronic marketplaces is to ensure that the transaction is completed satisfactorily. To do this, they need to provide a banking service, confirm payment is settled, and resolve disputes among the trading partners. In fact, one of the major complaints from Internet auction services has been buyers’ non-payment for goods received. This paper found a number of Internet auction services attempting to solve the problem. For example, Priceline.com has a unique feature to ensure payment. When both parties have agreed to the price and terms, Priceline.com (as opposed to the buyer) pays the bill using credit card information which the buyer registered before the transaction began. In this way, an intermediary ensures the transaction is completed, as soon as agreement is reached. Non-payment is not possible, as a credit reversal would be a separate transaction. On the other hand, few electronic marketplaces provide direct shipping service. Most electronic marketplaces let trade partners use a third party carrier. This strategy, i.e. 0-7695-0981-9/01 $10.00 (c) 2001 IEEE 4 Proceedings of the 34th Hawaii International Conference on System Sciences - 2001 letting them handle the shipping process by themselves, sometimes works for smaller transactions, but in many B2B transactions, shipping is such an important issue that the electronic marketplaces need to include this feature. 3.8 Trust enhancing mechanism Maintaining trust is another important role of electronic marketplaces. The trust issues arise from the lack of opportunity for physical product inspection. The most common way of increasing trust is to require identification such as an email account from buyers and/or sellers. However, using email as an ID has a significant limitation considering the growing number of web-based free email services. Some Internet auction sites provide user profiles. As we can easily guess, brand name products sell more than those of lesser well-known companies. The other popular approach is to require credit card information. Credit cards are one of the most popular means of payment in EC because of its universal acceptance and purchasing protection mechanism. Using credit cards gives buyers more protection than any other payment options, in case the seller turns out to be a malicious trading partner. A more sophisticated solution is using a reputation or rating mechanism. With such a reputation mechanism, buyers or sellers know how previous business partners think about the potential partner. This reputation system, if properly used, can reduce the incidence of fraud. Many popular auction sites employ all or a combination of the abovementioned mechanisms. 4. Functional requirements for buyer-centric electronic marketplaces Although current electronic marketplaces support other phases of market transactions relatively well, they lack negotiation capabilities. Considering the evaluation results of current electronic marketplaces and negotiation needs, we propose a buyer-centric electronic marketplace with negotiation support. The buyer-centric electronic marketplace has the following objectives: 1) It should support all phases of market transactions. 2) It is buyer-centric. In other words, buyers specify product description and their preference and sellers make offers based on the buyers’ specifications and preference. 3) It should provide sophisticated 1:N negotiation support. (i.e., one buyer and many sellers) As we examined in the previous section, trading occurs in roughly three phases. For each phase, electronic marketplaces need to provide appropriate support for the different stakeholders. Table 4 summarizes the ideal systems requirements that this study identified for buyercentric electronic marketplaces for each stakeholder in the different phases of trading. < Table 4. Ideal systems requirements from each stakeholder’s perspective > Buyer Seller Electronic marketplaces Phase of market transaction -browsing or search function to - to increase market liquidity (attracting Information - access to rating and/or more buyers and sellers) locate needed items. phase consumer feedback on - to provide product/seller evaluation -access to information about product and sellers - to provide check points and/or guides buyers (e.g., rating) - access to check points for the product -channel for advertising.(e.g., and/or guides for the - to maintain profile of interested items advertising in the “learning product.(e.g. Circuitcity’s to sellers so the system can notify sellers product section”) “learning product section” when those items are on auction. ) - profile matchmaking service - to create a trading room -monitoring tools that notify Negotiation - utility function eliciting - to support multidimensional auction. seller with necessary info to be phase tool(e.g., automatic RFQ - to enforce negotiation(auction) rules: generating tool, or pairwise winner. (* in case when open >to make sure seller’s offer meets auction protocol is used *). comparison tool) minimum qualification - tools that evaluate their own -tools that calculate total - to act as trusted third party during offer based on the buyer’s logistics cost including negotiation. preference. delivery and tax. - tools that calculate total - tool that evaluate offers. logistics cost, including delivery and tax. - tracking capability for - to generate electronic contract with Settlement - tracking capability for shipment date, and digital certificate. phase shipment - delivery channel for digital - to generate trade summary - access to insurance 0-7695-0981-9/01 $10.00 (c) 2001 IEEE 5 Proceedings of the 34th Hawaii International Conference on System Sciences - 2001 service - access to secure payment mechanism product - secure payment mechanism - automatic auditing and certification of trade procedure - to conduct post-settlement survey - to provide legal service - trust enhancing mechanism - to provide means to enforce rules. - profit model (commissions, set up fee for profile of seller, adverting) Other/ Institutional service Information phase In an ordinary transaction process in the retail market, buyers and sellers are matched first then they start negotiating terms and prices. In the buyer-centric B2B market, however, there is no separate phase for matchmaking. The basic concept of buyer-centric B2B market is to help buyers formulate their preference and search for the product and seller that matches the preference best. If there is no perfect match, negotiation is necessary. For this purpose, we propose using a multidimensional auction mechanism in electronic marketplaces. In order to do that, we have to decide how many issues are involved and in what sequence the counter proposal is to be handled. One way of doing this is to let the electronic marketplaces fix the issues, and the buyers and the sellers conduct negotiations over the fixed issues. However, in order to reflect the buyers’ preference more correctly, it will be better for the buyers to decide on the issues, while the electronic marketplaces provide the necessary information such as check points, or guides for the products (e.g., http://www.circuitcity.com ) to help the buyers clarify their preferences. Sellers, on the other hand, want to know about the buyer: the buyer’s credit record history and previous buying habits. In addition, sellers need to monitor new postings of RFQs. Electronic marketplaces should provide means to monitor and notify the sellers of pertinent events when they occur. Furthermore, sellers/manufacturers might want to advertise their own product/service along with the electronic marketplaces’ product guides/check points services. This is revenue generation opportunity from the electronic marketplaces’ point of view. This advertising will also provide the potential buyer with more information about the products and sellers. The electronic marketplaces’ primary role is to provide the mechanisms to facilitate information flow between buyers and sellers, and to attract more buyers and sellers in order to increase market liquidity. Negotiation phase Once buyers know about the products and sellers, they need to formulate their preferences (i.e., RFQs). A pairwise comparison technique may be used, since that could help buyers articulate preferences more easily. Basically what buyers need to do is to specify their utility function with constraints. After a buyer sets his preference, the electronic marketplace needs to create a trading room for the multidimensional auction. Multidimensional auctions have different system requirements from conventional auctions. First, in the case of a closed auction protocol, both buyers and sellers should have a tool to evaluate offers according to buyer’s preference, since multidimensional auctions consider multiple issues. Second, electronic marketplaces should establish specific rules for multidimensional auctions. They may also need to provide options for different choices of alternatives from a given auction protocol. For instance, the buyer may choose between a multi-rounding auction and a one-shot auction, and may choose the degree of information feedback ( i.e. to what extent he/she is willing to reveal information to the sellers, e.g., bid ranking, score, utility). Also, bidding duration should be flexible to minimize time overhead. More specific and comprehensive rules concerning multidimensional auction mechanism will be described in the following section. Settlement phase Once negotiations are finished, payment and goods must be traded according to the contract. In order to support this, the electronic marketplaces should offer a secure payment mechanism. The buyer also might want to have an insurance option and tracking ability for shipment. For digital/information products, the delivery of goods should be done within the electronic marketplaces. From the electronic marketplaces’ perspective, they need to act as a middleman or a judge during the settlement phase. Electronic contracts will be issued by the electronic marketplaces along with a trading summary. And the electronic marketplaces need to ascertain that the trade is successfully finished. Other/institutional service The electronic marketplaces will need robust mechanisms to solve the trust issue. One possibility is to use third party certificate agencies. Those certifying agencies can be operated by either the government or credible brokers. The other approach that might be useful in B2B trading is for brokers to investigate goods on a 0-7695-0981-9/01 $10.00 (c) 2001 IEEE 6 Proceedings of the 34th Hawaii International Conference on System Sciences - 2001 transaction base. The brokers investigate the product to be sold and issue a letter of credit while taking responsibility as well as commissions. In addition, the electronic marketplaces must provide secure transaction platforms by guaranteeing network and information security [7]. Finally, the electronic marketplaces must have mechanisms to generate their own profit. The potential revenue generating sources may involve commissions from suppliers, flat fee per transaction, set up fee for profile of sellers, and selling advertising spots. 5. Multidimensional auction model with evolutionary negotiation support (MAMENS) In this section, we first describe the design criteria for the MAMENS system. Next, we provide a description of the operation of the system. 5.1 Design criteria A number of studies propose multidimensional auction models [ 5, 9, 18, 20, 22]. Based on the analysis of those models, MAMENS system was designed to foster more efficient outcomes by providing the following two improvements over previous multidimensional auction models: use of sellers’ feedback and buyers’ post utility value selection. Use of sellers’ feedback The MAMENS system was designed to incorporate seller’s feedback (i.e. cost function weight) to support evolutionary negotiation support. In the conventional auction or procurement process, the buyers research current market conditions ( i.e., product feature and price) and create RFQs to initiate the auction or procurement process. Therefore, the buyers’ aspiration level is determined by the research results. In case the buyers fail to properly assess the market conditions when they initiate auctions (e.g., buyers’ requirement is set too high for a given budget), however, the auction leads to failure, causing extra cost and time. Furthermore, the buyers do not receive any useful information to adjust ( or relax) their RFQ. Therefore, the buyers must initiate another round without knowing which requirement is set too high within a given budget. Such a situation occurs due to incomplete information inherent in the current auction process. We argue that this can be resolved by providing the buyers with information on the market’s condition. The MAMENS system is designed to foster more efficient outcomes by providing sellers’ cost structure to buyers. However, exposing detailed cost structure can be too sensitive for sellers. Therefore, revealing of sellers’ cost structure should be minimized to provide only enough information for buyers to initiate the next round of auction with a more reasonable RFQ. Suppose the following: Through a multidimensional auction, a used car buyer wants to buy a car with automatic transmission built after 1993, at less than $3000. Unfortunately, no salesman can sell a car with that feature within that price, leading to failure of the auction. In that case, the buyer has only two choices: either give up the automatic transmission or consider buying an older model. However, the buyer has no idea which of these two factors will cost less to the salesman. Therefore, the buyer should either relax the requirement which is personally less important, or not purchase the car. If the buyer could have known the sellers’ cost structure ( i.e., which feature costs more than the other), the buyer would have had a greater chance of mutually beneficial trading in the next round. Buyers’ post utility value selection The MAMENS system also allows buyers to determine their preference structure after the range of values for all the issues have been determined--in other words, after collecting offers from sellers. Most existing studies on bargaining assumed the linearity of buyers’ utility. Although this simplistic model may work for a small set of possible agreements, a real bargaining situation is much more complex. Negotiators often have non-linear utility functions over the issues. For example, a buyer who prefers a quicker delivery time may show no improvement to his utility as long as delivery time is less than three days. Therefore, we propose that the proper way to elicit a buyer’s preference structure is after the range of values for all the issues have been determined. 5.2 Operation of MAMENS mechanism < Assumptions > 1. MAMENS uses a multi-round closed auction protocol. (i.e. sealed bid ) 2. The reserve price is not shown to sellers because if it were, they would tend to set their price close to it (even if they could offer a lower price). 3. For requirements other than price; buyers reveal both the requirement itself and its weighted importance. 4. Each requirement is either negotiable or non-negotiable. Buyer’s preference A bid or RFQ by buyer i is denoted by an array that contains m possible requirements bi={b i1,b i2, .. ,b im}, which include the price and other requirements from the buyers ( We assume b i1 is the price while other requirements can be anything), and an array of 0-1 integers bc i={bc i1, bc i2, …., bc im},which indicates the conditions of each requirement; 0 for “negotiable”, and 1 for “not negotiable”, that is, even price can be negotiable. In real world situations, a requirement must have a direction as well: a positive direction in which the increase 0-7695-0981-9/01 $10.00 (c) 2001 IEEE 7 Proceedings of the 34th Hawaii International Conference on System Sciences - 2001 of value will produce more utility (e.g., quality) and a negative direction in which the increase of value will decrease utility (e.g., price, delivery time). In explaining the model, however, we will assume all the requirements have only positive direction. The buyer (or bid taker) also has a weighted-utility function that he derives from a bid. The utility function is denoted by Ui(b)=Σw j*b ij where wj is the weight to the j th requirement and Σw j=1. This utility function converts both monetary and non-monetary attributes into a utility. When a buyer initiates an auction protocol, electronic marketplaces reveal requirements bi (except bi1, i.e. price) and their relative weights (i.e. w), including that of price. However, the condition of requirements bci, is not revealed in order to maximize the buyer’s utility [22]. Seller’s offer Based on buyer i’s requirements bI (except bi1, i.e. price) and its relative weight, seller j constructs an offer Oj to maximize Ui (b) while minimizing the cost that he incurs. Oj is denoted by O j=(Oj1,O j2,…..,O jk) where k is the number of requirements and O j1 is the asking price. Also, sellers provide a cost function weight to the buyer to indicate which requirement is most expensive to fulfill in order to give a clue to the buyer, in case the buyer needs to adjust or relax his requirements. The cost function weight by the seller is denoted by C j ={C j2, C j3,…,C jk}where C jk is the relative weight of the cost-distribution to seller j, the ranking among attributes from most to least cost-causing, for the kth requirement. This can be considered as a counter-utility function showing which requirements by the buyer are more difficult to satisfy from the seller’s perspective. Evaluation of collected offers and evolutionary negotiation process Once the deadline is reached, the electronic marketplace collects all the offers,( i.e. O j with corresponding cost function weight C j.) from sellers. Then, we can expect the following scenarios. < Scenario 1: when there is at least one offer that satisfies all of the non-negotiable requirements> Find one that derives most utility to the buyer. To do that, • Define a range of values for each negotiable requirement by collecting all the value from the offers, that is [Min(Oj k), Max(Oj k)] for k th requirement where j=1...N (total number of sellers), • With the range of values, the buyer determines the weighted utility curves for the negotiable requirements. • Choose the offer that derives the highest utility to the buyer. • Terminate the auction. <Scenario 2: when no such offer exists> The buyer needs to adjust or relax his requirements based on the sellers’ feedback. • Find the least important non-negotiable requirement for the buyer that costs most to the sellers ( One will be most likely to increase utility value for both buyer and sellers.) • Then, MAMENS suggests the buyer should make this requirement negotiable. • Initiate new round of sealed bid with modified RFQ. 6. Evaluation framework In order to compare different electronic marketplaces or auction mechanisms, some evaluation framework is necessary. In this section, we will introduce an evaluation framework based on transaction cost theory. In economies, one can observe two basic mechanisms for coordinating the flow of goods and service through adjacent steps in the value-added chain: markets and hierarchies [11]. Previous research explained the shift from hierarchies toward markets based on the transaction cost theory [1, 11, 14]. According to this theory, the price of a product consists of three elements; production costs, coordination costs, profit margin [11, 17, 21]. Production costs include physical or other primary processes necessary to create and distribute the goods and services. Coordination costs include costs of all the information processing necessary to coordinate people for transferring goods and services. For example, coordination costs include costs associated with determining design, price, quantity, and delivery schedule [21]. Malone et al. [11] point out that coordination costs are higher in markets than in hierarchies. In addition, since an electronic marketplace does not create goods and services by itself, the only cost-saving source for an electronic marketplace is in reducing the coordination costs. Therefore, most of the functions of the electronic marketplaces are focused on reducing coordination costs. Sarkar et al. [14] point out in some cases the transaction costs of using electronic marketplaces can be lower than that of direct transactions between buyer and seller without intermediation. Since we are interested in evaluating performance of different market structures or auction mechanisms, we will only focus on coordination costs. Our argument is that if coordination cost is lower in multidimensional auctions such as our MAMENS than in conventional auctions, we can assume a multidimensional auction is better than a conventional auction in terms of transaction cost theory. Based on findings of previous studies [11, 17, 19], we identified the following types of coordination costs. 1.search cost 2.risk cost 3.negotiation cost 0-7695-0981-9/01 $10.00 (c) 2001 IEEE 8 Proceedings of the 34th Hawaii International Conference on System Sciences - 2001 Search costs include time, effort, and money involved in searching for a seller who has the product demanded at an acceptable price with acceptable product features and quality [17]. From the seller’s point of view, on the other hand, search costs may include marketing and advertising costs as well [17]. Risk costs represents protecting against risks of opportunistic behavior by trading partners. This situation happens through the consumers’ perception that a product or service may fail to meet expectations [11, 17]. Negotiation costs are the costs associated with determining price, quantity, delivery schedule, and other factors with trading partners [11]. For example, negotiation costs in electronic marketplaces or auctions include monitoring costs, delay, and search costs [19]. Table 5 summarizes the comparison between multidimensional auction and conventional auction based on the above cost model. Negotiation costs are much lower in multidimensional auctions than in conventional auctions. In a traditional market, all negotiations are done mainly off-line, taking considerable time and costs. Conventional auctions provide the on-line mechanism for negotiating the single factor of price. In conventional auctions, however, negotiations over other factors are conducted off-line causing extra time and costs. On the other hand, all negotiation activities can be done within the electronic marketplaces in multidimensional auctions. Furthermore, multidimensional auctions can provide the mechanism for one-to-many simultaneous negotiations based on multiattributes. Overall, the evaluation results show that buyers and sellers enjoy more costs saving in multidimensional auctions than in conventional auctions. 7. Conclusion < Table 5. Comparison based on transaction cost theory > Search cost Risk cost Negotiati on cost Traditional market Conventional auction Multidimensional auction High Medium Low Medium High High Medium High Low Search costs are lower in multidimensional auctions than in conventional auctions. Although search cost is lower in conventional auctions than in traditional markets thanks to information technology, a consumer will still have to search for a seller who has the product demanded at an acceptable price with acceptable product features and quality [17]. Sellers, on the other hand, still need to struggle to attract buyers in a conventional auction. However, In a multidimensional auction, or a buyer-centric electronic marketplace, once the RFQs are posted in the electronic marketplaces, sellers compete with each other to make an offer. Buyers do not have to search for qualified sellers. Sellers also do not have to struggle to find customers as long as they monitor RFQs. It is very difficult to compare risk costs in multidimensional auctions and in conventional auctions, since it is more related to institutional infrastructure than a functional difference between the two systems. Major risk costs stem from conducting trade with unfamiliar partners. To ease the risk costs, electronic marketplaces should provide trust mechanisms as we have explained earlier. However, it is believed that multidimensional auctions can help lower risk costs by using automatic RFQ generating tools, such as buyers’ articulating requirements for product/service features. Also automatic contracts issued by a trusted-third party (i.e. the electronic marketplaces) help resolve conflicts, in case the buyer and the seller do not agree on terms or conditions. This paper has discussed the evaluation of current electronic marketplaces and identified desirable features for buyer-centric electronic marketplaces. To make buyercentric electronic marketplaces efficient, we propose MAMENS as a new multidimensional auction model with evolutionary negotiation support, and we provide an evaluation framework for the model. To the best of our knowledge, MAMENS is the first system that supports negotiation in both directions between a buyer and sellers using cost function from sellers. However, this study did not examine the case of multi-unit auctions [12, 20] and combinatory auctions [12, 13]. In certain conditions, it might be beneficial for the buyer to select multiple sellers who jointly ( either with or without pre-arrangement among them) deliver the best value to the buyer using combinatory auctions [13]. For the future, we intend to implement a prototype of MAMENS in line with the findings of our study. Finally, we intend to conduct empirical testing to determine if MAMENS does achieve more efficiency than conventional auctions or other on-line multidimensional auctions. Acknowledgments The author wishes to thank Prof. Tung Bui for his suggestions to improve this article. The author also wishes to thank Liliane B. Bahali for help with collecting data on existing electronic marketplaces, and Sandra Laney for her editing skills. References [1] Bakos, Y. (1997). "Reducing Buyer Search Costs: Implications for Electronic Marketplaces." Management Science, Vol. 43, No. 12, pp. 1676-1692. 0-7695-0981-9/01 $10.00 (c) 2001 IEEE 9 Proceedings of the 34th Hawaii International Conference on System Sciences - 2001 [2] Bakos, Y. (1998). "The Emerging Role of Electronic Marketplaces on the Internet." Communications of the ACM. Vol. 41, No. 8, pp.35-42. [3] Beam, C.M. (1999). "Auctioning and Bidding in Electronic Commerce: The Online Auction” The Ph.D. dissertation, University of California, Berkeley, CA. [4] Beam, C.M., Bichler, M., and Segev, A. (1998). “Services of A Broker in Electronic Commerce Transactions.” EM - Electronic Markets, Vol. 8, No. 1, pp. 27-31. http://www.electronicmarkets.com/netacademy/public ations.nsf/all_pk/802 [5] Bodendorf, F., Bui, T., and Reinheimer, S. (1997). "A software-agent-based DSS for supporting an electronic air cargo market." Proc. of the International Society for Decision Support Systems(ISDSS97), Lausanne, Schweiz, pp. 181-194. [6] Choudhury, V., hartzel, K.S., and Konsynski, B.R. (1998). "Uses and Consequences of Electronic Markets: An empirical Investigation in the Aircraft Parts Industry" MIS Quarterly/ December, Vol. 22, No. 4, pp. 471-507. [7] Franklin M.K. and Reiter, M.K. (1996). "The Design and Implementation of a Secure Auction Service." IEEE Transactions on Software Engineering, Vol. 22, No. 5, pp.302-312. [8] Hof, R.D., Green, H. and Judge, P. (1999). "Online Auctions: Going, Going, Gone." Businessweek, April 12,1999. [9] Koppius, O.R., Kumar, M. and Heck, E.V. (2000). "Electronic Multidimensional Auctions and the Role of Information Feedback." Proc. of the 8th European Conference on Information Systems, Vienna. [10] Maes, P., Guttman, R.H., and Moukas, A.G. (1999). "Agents that Buy and Sell: Transforming Commerce as We Know It." Communicatins of the ACM, Vol. 42, No. 3, pp.81-91. [11] Malone, T.W., Yates, J. and Benjamin, R.I. (1987). "Electronic Markets and Electronic hierarchies." Communications of the ACM, Vol. 30, No. 6, pp. 484497. [12] Bichler, M. (2000). "A roadmap to Auction-based Negotiation Protocols for Electronic Commerce." Proceedings of the 33rd Hawaii International Conference on System Sciences. [13] Merlat, W. (1999). "An agent-based multiservice negotiation for eCommerce." BT technology journal, Vol. 17, No. 4, pp. 168-175. [14] Sarkar, M.B., Butler, B. and Steinfield, C. (1995). "Intermediaries and cybermediaries: A Continuing Role for Mediating Players in the Electronic Marketplace." Journal of Computer-Mediated Communication, Vol. 1, No. 3, http://jcmc.huji.ac.il/vol1/issue3/sarkar.html [15] Schmid, B. (1997). “Requirements for Electronic Markets Architecture.” International Journal of Electronic Markets, Vol. 7, No. 1, pp. 3-6. [16] Schmid, B.F. and Lindemann, M.A. (1998). "Elements of a Reference Model for Electronic Markets." Proceedings of the 31st Hawaii International Conference on System Sciences. [17] Strader, T.J. and Shaw, M.J. (2000). "Electronic Markets: Impact and Implications." In M. Shaw, R. Blanning, T. Strader, and A. Whinston (Eds.) Handbook of Electronic Commerce, Berlin, Germany: Springer, pp. 77-98. [18] Teich, J. , Wallenius, H. , and Wallenius, J. (1999). "Multiple-issues auction and market algorithms for the world wide web." Decision Support Systems, Vol. 26, pp. 49-66. [19] Vakrat, Y. and Seidmann, A. (1999). "Can online auction beat online catalogs?" Proc. of ICIS'99, pp. 132-143. [20] Vulkan, N. and Jennings, N.R. (2000). "Efficient mechanisms for the supply of services in multi-agent environments." Decision Support Systems, Vol. 28, pp. 5-19. [21] Wigand, R.T. and Benjamin, R.I. (1995). "Electronic Commerce: Effects on Electronic Markets." Journal of Computer-Mediated Communication, Vol. 1, No. 3, http://jcmc.huji.ac.il/vol1/issue3/wigand.html. [22] Yen, J., Lee, H.G. and Bui, T. (1996). "Intelligent Clearinghouse: Electronic Marketplace with Computer-Mediated Negotiation Supports." Proceedings of the 29th Hawaii International Conference on System Sciences, pp. 219-227. 0-7695-0981-9/01 $10.00 (c) 2001 IEEE 10