Trademarks as an Indicator of Innovation and Industrial Change Sandro Mendonça ISCTE University and Dinâmia Dept. of Economics Av. das Forças Armadas, 1649-026 Lisbon, Portugal Tiago Santos Pereira CES - Centro de Estudos Sociais Universidade de Coimbra Colégio de S. Jerónimo Apartado 3087, 3001-401 Coimbra, Portugal tsp@ces.uc.pt Manuel Mira Godinho ISEG/UTL and CISEP Rua Miguel Lupi 20, 1200 - 725 Lisboa, Portugal A conference in honour of Keith Pavitt 'What Do We Know About Innovation?' SPRU/University of Sussex, 13-15th November 2003 Abstract: As innovation becomes an ever more central issue for the development of human societies and private firms so the need for improved assessments of innovative performance grows more urgent. In order to reflect the innovation endeavour of countries and companies several internationally comparable indicators have been imagined and developed since the 1950s. This paper suggests that trademarks can yield reliable results and proposes methodological steps to make this a useful indicator for capturing and monitoring relevant aspects of innovation phenomena. We argue that trademarks emerge as complementary resource in the portfolio of empirical tools of innovation studies, which is still centred on inputs rather outputs. Our empirical exploration of the indicator is based on a study of Community Trade Marks and national trademarks of Portuguese firms. Quantitative as well as quantitative data, including survey information from a representative sample of Portuguese manufacturing and service firms, are used to identify the advantages and the problems this research tool. Keywords: trademarks; IPRs; innovation; industrial dynamics NOTE: Unrevised first draft. Please do not quote without permission. This is a preliminary long version of the paper. The conceptual framework and the data analysis will be consolidated soon as we are expecting to complete our database. Trademarks as an Indicator of Innovation and Industrial Change1 1. Introduction The business of branding products and services has been part of ordinary economic life for a long time. Trademarks are the outcome of establishing recognizable designations and symbols for material goods, services as well as firms. They are a crucial part of the innovation and commercial process, helping to differentiate the quality and content of products and services in the market place. These characteristics make trademarks a potential new indicator of product innovation and sectoral change. Recent advances in the institutions of international filing and registration of marks and the increasing availability of digital databases have increased the potential use of trademark statistics as a new source of information for industrial and innovation studies. Trademarks are of interest for social sciences for at least three reasons: they confer an exclusive right of using a brand helping companies to appropriate the returns of investing in new products or improve existing ones; they are an important aspect of contemporary culture world-wide; and they are a source of qualitative and quantitative information on socio-economic activity. This paper focuses on the third of these characteristics. It assesses the possibilities and problems of using trademark data when analysing the introduction of new or improved goods and services in competitive markets. Along with a methodological reflection, the paper offers a concrete empirical application of the indicator to EU-15 data and provides an in-depth study of a intermediate European economy, Portugal, for which we have national trademark data for the period after 1980, survey data from 724 firms collected during 2003 and information obtained from thematic workshops held with entrepreneurs, managers and consultants. We argue that trademark-based indicators provide a partial measure of the innovative output of profit-oriented organisations. In its most simple formulation innovation can be understood as the commercialisation of new idea, product or a production process. As an Intellectual Property Right (IPR) that is designed to identify certain goods or services as those provided by a person or a firm helping customers to purchase something if they recognise its nature and quality meets their needs. The filling of new trademarks by economic actors reveals the introduction of new offerings aimed at persuading potential buyers that the range of their problems were not solved by the supply of solutions available in the market. In this way, given that companies have to pay fees to register and renew national and international offices, the compromise to 1 No order of seniority implied. The authors are involved in a long-term process of collaboration that keeps theirs names rotating. This research started in 2001 in the context of a project commissioned by Instituto Nacional de Propriedade Industrial (INPI) on the use of industrial property rights by Portuguese individuals, firms and other organizations. Research is now being completed. The authors acknowledge INPI for permission to use the data generated and organized in the project. One way or another the three of us were influenced by Keith Pavitt’s sharp and provocative views as a Professor, a colleague and friend. It is clear in our mind that the current work would not have been the same without the experience of having known him. Any faults in this paper are entirely our responsibility. 2 register a new brand or logo reveals an economic decision and an entrepreneurial initiative that are worth investigating. Given the growing demand from governments, firms and universities for more reliable information on innovation there is a case to test trademarks has a complementary indicator to the more traditional measures of technological activity such as R&D and patents. Furthermore, trademarks have the additional advantage in relation to patents that they can capture changes in service activities. Trademarks show promise in analysing (1) rates and directions of product innovations in different industrial sectors, (2) international patterns of sectoral specialisation, (3) links between technological activity and marketing advantages; (4) evolution of economic organisations and structures, not only in terms of entry and exit of firms, but also in terms of firm growth, differentiation, and diversification. Evidence from the Portuguese case suggests that the trademark filling largely behaves has expected in tracking the innovative performance of firms, industries and countries over time. However, simple counts of trademarks at an intellectual property office are affected by various sources of bias, such as difficulties in data consolidation (e.g. one brand can be protected simultaneously by a combination of words, symbols and 3D design) and weaknesses in international comparability (given different target markets for local firms). All of these issues cannot be explored or solved in this contribution. The full assessment of trademarks as indicators of innovative activity and industrial competitiveness requires further classificatory, survey and econometric research, as well as in-depth case studies. The paper is organised as follows: the first section discusses what is trademark in an IPR and managerial perspectives; the second approaches the conceptual and analytical issues that arise when we consider trademark statistics as an innovation indicator; the this is followed by a presentation of the key patterns found on Community Trade Marks for 15 countries of the EU and a detailed studied of the Portuguese case; the fifth critically reviews the findings and points out avenues for further research; the final section concludes. 2. Brands and logos in business life People show a tendency to label other beings and things surrounding them. It is thought that the first marks served to indicate the legitimate proprietor of livestock in Neolithic times 7,000 years ago.2 Later on marks evolved to point the author of one object and setting down her obligation in assuring the quality of the product. The first documented example of the economic use of trademarks is found in Roman Empire. Roman bricks had the stamp of the manufacturer, the date and the place of production. During the Middle Ages corporations of craftsmen started to identify their workmanship with a mark. In the absence of a modern means of advertising the reputation of trade guilds was carried through marks. By the dawn of the industrial era explicit trademark laws were enacted in France (1857), UK (1862) and the US (1870). In this field, as well as in others, framing institutions co-evolved with the actors’ 2 This information is drawn a website maintained by the Library of the University of Texas at Austin which compiled and synthesizing information on trademark history from impressively wide and diverse collection of previous works on the topic: http://www.lib.utexas.edu/engin/trademark/timeline/tmindex.html 3 behaviours and goals. This section brings in the key institutional features of trademarks as a part of IPR system and examines the economic rationale and the historical practise of its use by business firms.3 The IPR institution According to the World Intellectual Property Organization (WIPO) a trademark is defined as “distinctive sign used to distinguish the goods or services of an enterprise from those of another” (WIPO, 2003). The double objectives of protection and dissemination built into this definition are practically indistinguishable. Like patents a trademark provides legal protection to the owner by granting the exclusive right to use it to identify goods or services, or to lice its use to another it in return for payment. Rights are obtained at the national level but, unlike patents and copyrights, once registered can be renewed indefinitely in time on payment of additional fees. The common expectation in trademark regimes is that a registered mark is used; an unused trademark is implicitly regarded as a barrier to economic initiative and can be requested for by other company after a grace period. As stated by Doern (1998, p. 72), who carried out over 70 interviews with officials of seven agencies, trademarks constitute the second highest volume of revenue after that generated by patents. As a creation of the mind, a trademark does not reveal technological inventiveness but rather marketing inventiveness. Patents are granted to inventions on the basis of nonobviousness, inventiveness in the face of prior art and that deemed capable of industrial application. Commercial signs may also be denied registration but only if judged deceptive to consumers (a misleading description of the character or quality of the goods or services), contrary to public morality or reserved for use by the state or other public organisations. A trademark might also be refused if another company opposes it on the grounds of confusability. Today, trademarks may consist of one or a combination of words, slogans, letters, and numerals, they may also be drawings, symbols, three-dimensional signs such as the shape and packaging of goods, audible signs such as musical or vocal sounds, or fragrances distinguishing and colours. Therefore, they might seem like a lower order of intellectual creation. Notwithstanding, trademarks constitute a crucial part of innovation and commercial processes helping to differentiate the nature and quality of products (Doern, 1998, p. 69). Trademarks are an IPR issued by an authorised national government agency following an examination process that is dependent on instituted criteria and a mix of given human and technical resources. Once an application has been filled, examiners search available databases to detect any other marks in use that can come into conflict with the applicant’s. A successfully registered trademark is recognisable by having one of these two symbols attached: “‚” or “‰”. The lag between the filling and formal registration is much shorter than for patents. For instance, while it takes up to a year to register a Community Trade Mark (CTM) for mark for which there is no grounds of refusal, it can take over five years to obtain a patent from the European Patent Office. 3 For a history accounts of trademark history see Diamond (1983) and Wilkins (1992). 4 The first international trademark agreements was reached at the Paris Convention of 1883 whereby countries involved in this convention agreed to provide the same protections regarding marks to foreign applicants as those provides to nationals. In this context, WIPO emerged as a coordinating institution promoting the development of IPR laws and allowing the international registration of trademarks. This role flows from the 1891 Madrid Agreement Concerning the International Registration of Trademarks that opened up the scope for protection of marks beyond their market of origin. Another important international development was the establishment of the Community Trade Mark (CTM) in Europe, which came into being with the establishment of the Office for Harmonisation in the Internal Market (OHIM) in 1994, a EU institution. The sources for trademark information have to be found elsewhere than OECD and the Offices of Science & Technology. Amongst the national sources, the Patent and Trademark Offices are the public agencies traditionally entrusted with registering and keeping the records of trademarks although not in a shape of databases easily usable for statistical treatment. The major public international agencies responsible for trademarks are WIPO and OHIM, which publishes monthly and annual surveys of trademark activity, broken down by country of applicant, year of filling and registration, trademark class of goods and services and trademark type (word mark, figurative mark, three-dimensional mark, etc) since 1996. Finally, amongst private sources there are an increasing variety of firms compiling and selling databases on trademarks. Brands and business strategy Brands are commercial signatures that firms create, maintain, protect and reinforce for a number of different marketing objectives. Brand names have multiple origins. Some are linked to the names of the company founders (Ford, Nestlé), others show a connection to a particular line of business (Microsoft, Airbus), other still are pure inventions (Kodak, Xerox), etc. It is especially since the late XIX century that with the rise of consumer product industries oriented toward mass markets in western societies that brands become genuine cultural references. Brands such as Coca-cola, Campbell’s Soup or McDonalds are like (or disliked) by many (or few) but surely they mean something to people. Many brands became synonym in many languages of iconic innovations of the XXI century (Hoover, Gillette, Black & Decker). Many others established themselves as true national symbols (GM, Ferrari, Nokia) or even a representation of transitional partnerships (Airbus). For better or worse brands make us company, and their influence on our lives is not bound to diminish in the near future. Judging from newspaper interviews to CEO’s and popular business literature, branding is becoming a central concern in product strategy. Evidence from everyday life tells us that hardly anything goes unbranded. Even fruits are branded – Chiquita bananas. So, where does all that interest in brands come from? Sure that brands are obviously of interest to buyers, but in the what ways such awareness and loyalty commanded by brands translate into a competitive asset are completely clear. The rationale and actual influence of trademarks is a relatively neglect aspect in the development of modern corporations (Wilkins, 1992). For one, economics has 5 notoriously little to say about the activity of branding. From the point of view of economists prices and quantities are still the most important economic variables. Products and the complex set of decisions concerning their attributes, such as quality, features, reputation, support services, and so forth, are still rather scarce in economic theory no to mention applied research (Trajtenberg, 1990, p. 8). Standard industrial organisation textbooks tend to cluster issues such as product differentiation and advertising in the same chapter and focus on the relationship between market structure and the advertising to sales ratio. Brand decisions are implicitly considered part of advertisement expenditures. Luís Cabral, who is editor of the Journal of Industrial Economics and author of a popular textbook on the field (Cabral, 2000), goes on to make an interesting mea culpa on this subject. Under the heading “Price and non price strategies” of a teaching note available in the companion site his book, he states that: “(a)dvertising is not one of the core topics of IO ... this chapter may therefore be omitted from a course directed primarily at economics majors”, and he goes on to admit that “(n)ot much economics research has been done on this topic. As a consequence, most of the points presented are rather tentative: more questions are raised than answered.” The only explicit paper on the “economics of trademarks” we were able to detect (an interesting but rather under-cited paper published in a non-technical journal) gives us the usual cost and benefit perspective (Economides, 1987). The author points out that the key reason why brands are indispensable for the efficient provision of products is that they are a device which facilitates consumer’s choice in the wide rage of variety and quality combinations available in a modern economy. Nevertheless, the monopoly power embedded in that IPR is bound to cause inefficiencies and allocative distortions. Part of such anticompetitive effects consists of barriers to entry to new competitors which are noted to be very hard to grasp using the traditional analytical framework of mainstream economics. In economic terms, a brand should be protected by a trademark when its expected value (probability of being accepted times the revenue associated with the brand) exceeds the cost of applying for it. In the management literature the question “to brand or not to brand” is treated by marketing research. In terms of the classic marketing framework, brands are working on the Product variable of their marketing mix. This the conventional view of the set of tools that a firm blends to influence the demand for its product, which is composed of four key ingredients known as the “four Ps”: Product, Pricing, Promotion and Placement (Kottler et all, 1999). Contrary to what one would expect, brands are not seen as a tactical tool for promotion management, which refers to communications activities including advertisement, sales-people approach to customers, special promotions, public relations, etc. This is evidence that marketers regard brands as a key characteristic that helps delivering the core benefits to the consumers. The implication of this understanding is that brands do more that just transmitting persuasive signals (horizontal differentiation), they also a deeper role in transforming customers’ experience of using the product (vertical differentiation). Such customer benefits such as trust and satisfaction have a translation into the strategic motivations that underlie trademark management. The issue of whether or not to go ahead with branding a product depends on a complex list of potential motivations that have to be balanced with the cost of the branding strategy – see Box 1. In deciding to create a brand, and whether or not 6 protecting it legally through a registered trademark, a company must define its overall brand strategy. According the marketing literature there is a proliferation of strategic intents behind involving situations when companies a company introduces additional items in existing products under the same brand, such as new flavours, ingredients, colours, packages, which eventually evolve to become sub-brands (e.g. Diet Coke, Pepsi Blue). Another common strategy, called brand-stretching or brand extension, consists of using a successful brand image to launch new or modified products into new categories (a classic cases being the way Honda penetrated the US car market having achieved a great reputation for motorcycle engineering). Since there are no established taxonomies we give our own, incomplete, list of motives and strategies behind the uses of brands. Box 1. Strategic motivations behind the creation of a brand • • • • • • • • Building inelasticity around the product and achieving a premium pricing (differentiation, line extensions) Opening up opportunities to enter new product segments or entirely new lines of business (brandstretching) Penetrating new geographical markets (geographical market diversification) Entering the market for trademarks (licensing) Saving on promotion expenditures (building loyalty) Achieving greater bargaining power against suppliers (supply chain coordination) Signalling changes in strategy or changes in corporate identity (internal and external marketing) Prolonging the protection conferred by other IPRs after their expiration date (namely patents) Naturally, as in the case of patents, trademarks are not identical in their value. The value of patents is equated to the net money equivalent stemming from the exploration of the rights associated to a particular idea or innovation (Grilliches, 1990, p. 1690). The value of patent is generally understood to the magnitude of the innovation protected (Trajtenberg, 1990, pg. 5). As for trademarks, what counts to determine trademark equity is a set of characteristics such as name awareness, customer loyalty, perceived quality and associations to the brand that add value to the product being offered (Aaker, 1991). Trademark or brand equity influences the market value of a firm, namely those large corporations acting on the global market. Interbrand, a specialised consultancy firm, regularly releases reports where it estimates which are the world’s most important brands – see Figure 1. In seeking and maintaining trademark rights, companies making important economic decisions. Companies are deciding to create or enhance a protected brand intended to distinguishing themselves from other suppliers and rise above the competition. Therefore, something deeper than horizontal differentiation might be at stake. By monitoring what happens to trademarks we can learn a great deal about the entrepreneurial dynamics of given firms or aggregates of firms as well as gain a lever for making inferences about their marketing capabilities. This is the reason why trademark statistics are interesting in spite of all the difficulties involved in their use and interpretation. 7 Table 1. The world’s most valuable brands 1990 1992 1996 1997 1999 2000 1 Coca-cola Marlboro McDonald’s Coca-cola Coca-cola Coca-cola 2 Kellogg’s Coca-Cola Coca-cola Marlboro Microsoft Microsoft 3 McDonald’s Intel Disney IBM IBM IBM 4 Kodak Kellog Kodak McDonald’s GE GE 5 Marlboro Nescafé Sony Disney Ford Nokia 6 IBM Budweiser Gillette Sony Disney Intel 7 Amex Pepsi-Cola Mercedes Kodak Intel Diney 8 Sony Gillete Levi’s Intel McDonald’s Ford Sources: www.interbrand.com, Kotler et al (1999), Grandstrand (1998) 3. Towards a trademark indicator This section tries to make the case that trademarks constitute an unique and underutilised source for the analysis of the process of innovation and industrial evolution. Trademarks rivals with patents in terms of accessibility and quantity of available data. True, they do not exhibit the detail of information as patents show in the description of a technological invention, the individual inventors that contributed to it and the citations made of prior art. It is also not immediately clear what are trademarks really indicating. However, the promise of adding a new indicator of innovative economic activity to the rather scarce portfolio of output S&T indicators is a strong motivation for research in this area. If that is true, the potential applications to fields such as innovation studies, industrial evolution, business history and international trade can be very rewarding. Of course, implications for public policy and management strategy would follow. Indicators in innovation studies Indicators are means to obtain quantitative information about certain aspects of a phenomenon. There are, of course, no perfect and complete indicators of innovation as there are no perfect indicators of other socio-economic phenomena. The problem with the innovation is because it is a multidimensional phenomenon related with qualitative change involving economic, strategic, organisational and institutional factors. Thus, in order to proceed and operationalise a trademark indicator it is important to get to terms with the ontological properties of this tool for achieving reliable knowledge. Indicators consist in indirect observations of phenomena. Galileu used a telescope to directly observe the planets. But obtaining evidence is not always so unintermediated. but electrons were infinitely small, impossible to be seen or weighted or measured, so that sophisticated instruments had to be invited to provided a notion of the dimension of the phenomenon and its changes. In the same, social sciences cannot always rely on 8 interviews or case studies, especially, if the goal is to achieve generalisable conclusions. As far as innovation indicators are concerned, they convey behavioural information on social entities. They detect and register “movement” of individuals, companies, institutions and countries. The source of knowledge is not so much “people telling” but “people doing”. The imperfect nature of the assessments is always present. Indicators capture, but only partially so, some dimensions of the object at stake. One needs, therefore, to be aware of the intrinsic limitations of an indicator, it is not an objective, complete measurement. Indicators are institutionally created and maintained. They are socially constructed, growing more out of practise e rather than out of theory. There is nothing sacred about them. For instance, there are no a-priori reasons to think that registered trademarks do not involved as judgemental and non-technical process than patents on inventions. They often turn out to be given other uses from those originally intended. In fact, something that makes trademarks close to other S&T indicators such as R&D and patents, is that academics were also not involved the invention neither in control of improvements in measurement (Patel and Pavitt, 1994, p. 15). Numbers can be misleading as much as words. As Smith (2003) stresses, indicators are not simple numbers. They tend to come with strings attached to some theory that models they way quantitative information is produced and/or interpreted. Even though we abide by the view of innovation as an evolving process of interactions and feedbacks, we are well aware that labelling trademarks as a “output indicator of innovation” might be misleading. It is uncomfortably compatible with the linear model of innovation. This invites us to follow the recommendation made by Martin and Irvine (1983) to take the trademarks as a partial indicator of performance that should be combined with other information in order to produce reliable results. The study of the sources and patterns of technological change has progressed enormously since the mid 1960s when the first internationally comparable statistics on R&D activities were published by the OECE on the basis of work by C. Freeman and A. Young. Despite having such a long history S&T indicators remain contested even today, one paramount reason is because of the emphasis on inputs rather than on outputs and impacts (Godin, 2003). In order to realised the potential of trademarks we need to identify the basic procedures that should be involved in counting and comparing. Only with scepticism and care can trademarks be used as indirect measure of innovation and a tool to assess structural changes in the economy. From trademark data to information on innovation and industrial phenomena Given the experience with using patents as proxy measures of technological activities (Pavitt, 1985; Griliches, 1990) it is natural to take advantage of this accumulated knowledge and techniques to begin the search for prudent practices in manipulating trademark data. 9 As with patents, trademark statistics have the advantage of having a reasonably unambiguous legal definition and being collected and classified by (the same) specialized institutions for a long time. From our point of view, the most important classification is based on the 1957 Nice Agreement Concerning the International Classification of Goods and Services for the Purposes of the Registration of Marks. The Nice classification system consists of a categorisation of goods and services for the purposes of registering trademarks and service marks. It is regularly revised and it is on its 8th edition, which is in force January 1, 2002, has 34 classes of manufactured goods and 11 classes of services (three new service classes were added in the last edition). Perhaps the most problematic issue with trademark classes is that are much too aggregate to allow us to be bold in our inferences. Take Class 5 for instance. In this class trademarks covering the product categories of pharmaceutical, medical and veterinary preparations are mixed with dental wax, disinfectants, fungicides, herbicides, and even food for babies. This advises us to be extremely cautions in out interpretations. Another characteristic of trademark data is that a given trademark for a word or symbol can be asked for one or all classes at the cost of a rising fee. That means that the number of counts in the total classes will be much larger than the total number of trademarks filled. This is a feature absent from patent data and might be as revealing as well as confusing. A given product or supplier can also be protected by a number of trademarks. For instance, the Coca-cola beverage is protected by the word mark “Coca-Cola”, by its distinguish logo (the stylised letters composing the word underlined by a ribbon) and by a three-dimensional mark protecting the distinctive shape of the bottle. Intel Corporation not only is protected its Intel name with word mark and a corresponding, it filed sound mark as well. These considerations mean that there is no clear-cut correspondence between a new product and a new trademark. Raw data can lead us to over evaluate the patterns observed. However, the multiplication of trademarks in certain product categories surely constitutes evidence of increased competition. Box 2. Examples of overlapping protection using trademarks an other IPRs According to Coca-Cola corporation its flagship brand is the most recognised trademark in the world, recognised by 94% of the world’s population and is the most widely recognised word after "OK". The trademark of the word “Coca-Cola” is obtained in 1887. The type of print used for the logo is called "Spencerian Script". In an effort to safeguard the bottle contour, on 1977 it was registered as a three dimensional mark. The argument was that the packaging distinguished the beverage from others. The musical notation of the describing the registered Intel’s jingle is: It is clear that the relationships beween the trademarks and other IPRs, namelly industrial design and copyright, are not very clear. Another source of ambiguity is the relationship between trademarks and domain names on the Internet. Sources: www.coca-cola.pt, www.dww.com/articles/protect.htm 10 Another limitation of trademark data is that is not common for government agencies to classify trademark applications according the main product line of the applicant company. There are many other hidden biases that escape our attention in the unknown territory of trademark indicators. One lesson taken from patent analysis is that decisions to file an IPR vary among different companies, technologies, industries and countries. Likewise, there is no reason that decisions to trademark do not vary as well. One further, complication is the anecdotal observation is there are many unregistered brands in use in the marketplace. This is similar to the problems found in patents: not all inventions can be patented and not all patentable inventions are patented. In the case of trademarks, brands take the place of inventions. Unlike inventions, however, a given brand might be protected by many trademarks (words, logos, 3D mark, sound) whereas an invention is supposed be protected by just one patent. The effect of these factors on different companies, product categories, industries and countries is not yet fully clear. On the positive side the large and increasing numbers of trademarks allow us to be confident that many aspects of corporate commercial activities will be revealed. Because they are cheaper and do not require a technological breakthrough, a much wider range of small and medium firms are likely to be involved in applying for trademark rights compared to patent rights. Moreover, give the know limitations of patents this indicator has a comparative advantage in covering service and software development activities. This allows us to cover a wider spectrum of the industrial tissue. In this paper is use CTMs as source of internationally comparable trademark statistics. Why use OHIM data? This EU trademark systems is naturally biased towards members states commercial activities, having, therefore, an overrepresentation of European trademarks. However, the EU is the world’s largest market, thus is probably the most important space for protect brands from theft and counterfeiting. Applications from all countries are on a equal footing as international law administered by WIPO guaranties equal opportunities. Furthermore, trademark applications are judged against precisely the same criteria using the same database. From an instrumental perspective, OHIM presents the researcher with a wealth of trademark data and reports accessible online for free. To our knowledge the first explicit reference to trademarks as an indicator of innovation is a report on the 2001 Germany’s Technological Performance written Report written on behalf of the Federal Ministry of Education and Research byby a group of 8 German research centres (Velling, 2002). Here the team of authors that trademarks can no longer be considered a subordinate industrial right. The fact that the number of trademark registrations filed in Germany tripled during the 1990s area a “clear indication that trademarks are being assigned considerably more importance than in the past” (Velling, 2002, p. 20). Although, novelty is not a requirement for registering a trademark, the authors say one can safely assume that trademarks are filed primarily for new products and services. They also point out that commercial enterprises constitute a large number of applicants. Another positive aspect emphasised in this pioneering contribution is related to the degree the indicator is updated and keeping pace with the market, since in Germany it takes just six months for a trademark to be entered into databases after application. This section of the report is 11 rather short (4 consolidated pages in a total content of 174 pages) and lets many questions unasqued and unanswered. Of course, as a policy report its natural not to go deeper into methodological issues. But, why, for example, authors prefer to count trademarks applications and not registration? Our prime answer would be that due to the lack of technical content in trademarks, applications reflect much better the trademarking intentions (and the revealing underlying motives of protecting innovation and marketing capabilities of companies). We follow this route and try to provide a new map of the territory. 4. Empirical exploration The study we report is of relevance to two questions: (1) can innovation and industrial changed be assessed trademarks-based?, (2) more precisely, can significant differences and evolution in performance be identified? We would maintain a positive answer for both questions. Although the methodological understanding for using trademarks is far from matured, our results show that this indicator can generate useful insights for researchers, policy-makers and managers. In addressing these research questions we hope not only to demonstrate the power of this type of data for studying innovation and industrial change but also to shed light on the case of Portugal in the European context. Trends in Community Trade Marks (CTM) applications In this sub-section we present the moving picture of the rate and direction of CTM applications. We start by the basic observation of aggregate trademark fillings. Figure 2 shows the number of total CTM filled since the point in when this IPR was instituted. In 7 years 294 625 CTMs were filled by companies from the EU and around the world. Of this total 65% were word marks and 34% were figurative marks (logos). Figure 1. Total CTMs filled, 1996-2002 70,000 60,000 50,000 40,000 30,000 20,000 10,000 0 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 Source: IHMI (2003), Annual Report 2002 Note: 2000 data point is based on estimation by interpolation. 12 The graph shows an initial bubble. This very high level of trademark applications is probably due to the start of new registration system. Many marks already existing and decisions of economic agents who already were prepared were accumulating up the start of the new system. So, if we compute the average rate of growth using the extreme years of 1996 and 2002 we have a 0,6% change. But the wrong message is conveyed: something is going on, the demand for CTM is developing. In fact, ignoring the value of the year, we get a 8,7% growth of applications per annum. Latter years reveal a downward trend in the number of applications which is, probably, caused by the general macroeconomic downturn and a the readjustment of business investment expectations. What about the territorial origin of those applications? As expected, table 2 shows applications are dominated by the 15 EU states, that the proportion of EU trademarks does not seem to be loosing ground. Trademarks appears to be (increasingly) important for EU companies. Table 2. – Origin of CTM applications, 1996-2002 Annual average 1996-2001 Year 2002 Number of applications % Number of applications % EU-15 Rest of the world 25 679 15 908 62 38 29 435 15 669 65 35 Total 41 587 100 45 104 100 Source: OHMI (2003), Annual Report 2002; Own calculations Within EU member-countries exhibit different performances, table 3 compares them. Trademark applications are strongly concentrated. Germany, UK and Italy have 60% of the total CTM filled in the period from 1996 to 2001.4 These first five countries in trademark applications correspond to the largest European economies, are responsible for 80% of all the fillings. The “rest of the world” is dominated by the US, which represents 78% of the CTM filled between 1996 and 2001. Actually, the US is that biggest single user of the CTM system, it applied for more CTMs than any other European on its own. As such, this suggests that “trademarking” in the EU large and sophisticated market is a comprehensive reflection of the trends and patterns in the development of marketing activities of firms. In order to refine the analysis, we chose to normalise the number of CTMs by the population and the size of the economy. This are usual procedures to deal with patents and they are a good technique to gain a sense of scale. And, in fact, the ranking changes considerably. If we discount the abnormal performance of Luxembourg, we see a number of small countries the ladder, including all the Nordic countries, Ireland and Austria. Their pattern of business activity appears to be very trademark intensive in the European context. Of the large countries the UK and Germany come out best, and Italy and France the worse.5 4 Detailed 2002 data not available. Conclusions must be prudent. As trademarks we are counting my types of distinctive signs such word marks, logos, 3D, etc. Moreover, specific goods and services can protected by many trademarks at the same time. Strategies to protect products may vary from country to country. 5 13 The specific case of Portugal does not surprise to the light of other known pointers such as the standard S&T indicators R&D and patents. A time that the UE is the main destination of our exportations, these data show how important is to have a deeper understanding of the Portuguese external competitiveness. Portugal lags both in technological capabilities but also in marketing capabilities. However, an interesting observation in terms of CTMs, is that Portugal is behaving against the cycle, that is Portuguese CTM applications start very low but grows faster than the EU average. Table 3. Trademark performance among the EU, 1996-2001 1996 - 2001 MC/Pop MC/PIB DE 41554 LU 2852 LU 61 GB 32664 DK 734 SE 25 IT 17713 SE 623 DK 25 ES 15679 IE 619 GB 22 FR 14944 GB 547 IE 21 NL 6586 DE 506 ES 20 SE 5530 AT 456 DE 20 DK 3915 FI 453 FI 18 AT 3700 NL 415 AT 17 BE 3655 ES 397 NL 15 FI 2347 BE 356 BE 14 IE 2344 IT 310 IT 12 PT 1543 FR 254 FR 10 LU 1252 PT 154 PT 9 648 GR 61 GR 4 154074 EU 410 UE 17 GR EU Sources: IHMI (2003), Statistics of community trade marks, Situation at the end of 2002; OCDE, Labour Force Statistics; Own calculations Note: BE – Belgium ; DK – Denmark; DE – Germany; GR – Greece; ES – Spain; FR – France; IE – Ireland; IT – Italy; LU – Luxembourg; NL – Netherlands; AT – Austria; PT – Portugal; FI – Finland; SE – Sweden; GB – United Kingdom On dynamic terms EU’s “trademarking” performance as been ahead of the “rest of the world”. Between 1996 and 2001 the CTM applications for the EU-15 taken together grew annually 2.4%, excluding 1996 we have average annual growth of 9.8%. Within the EU, the best performers were Spain and Greece, followed by Luxembourg and Portugal. Sweden and Netherlands are on the other end of the spectrum. For reasons of sensitivity control, we calculate the annual rate of growth including and excluding 1996 and 2002 as reference years. 14 Table 4. Detailed annual data for the EU-15, 1996-2002 1996 BE DK DE GR ES FR IE IT LU NL AT PT FI SE GB UE 643 706 7 714 85 2 794 1 610 282 2 211 137 1 069 678 161 358 855 5 705 1997 418 473 3 911 65 1 468 1 891 217 2 070 112 908 393 183 282 713 3 659 1998 1999 562 526 4 811 78 1 965 2 131 289 2 378 148 877 537 232 330 787 4 234 2000 574 621 7 040 111 2 609 2 735 436 3 263 227 994 615 274 387 870 5 303 2001 771 822 9 793 161 3 417 3 406 636 4 221 349 1 632 766 396 507 1 346 7 622 687 767 8 285 148 3 426 3 171 484 3 570 279 1 106 711 297 483 959 6 141 Growth rate Growth rate Growth rate Growth rate 2002 96-01 97-01 96-02 97-02 598 727 7 113 197 3 759 3 411 429 3 719 233 1 055 717 378 438 801 5 860 1.1% 1.4% 1.2% 9.7% 3.5% 12.0% 9.4% 8.3% 12.6% 0.6% 0.8% 10.7% 5.1% 1.9% 1.2% 10.4% 10.2% 16.2% 17.9% 18.5% 10.9% 17.4% 11.5% 20.0% 4.0% 12.6% 10.2% 11.4% 6.1% 10.9% -1.0% 0.4% -1.2% 12.8% 4.3% 11.3% 6.2% 7.7% 7.9% -0.2% 0.8% 13.0% 2.9% -0.9% 0.4% 6.2% 7.4% 10.5% 20.3% 17.0% 10.3% 12.0% 10.3% 13.0% 2.5% 10.5% 12.9% 7.6% 2.0% 8.2% 25 008 16 763 19 885 26 059 35 845 30 514 29 435 3.4% 12.7% 2.4% 9.8% Sources: IHMI (2002), Detailed Applications Statistics. Situation at the end of June 2002; IHMI (2003), Annual Report 2002; Own calculations Note: Data for 2000 are estimations. Heterogeneity is also evident in terms of the distribution of applications by NICE classes. Table 5 shows the ten most “trademarked” product classes between 1996 and 2002. These absorbed 53.2% of the total applications. In 2002 the most demanded product categories were: Instruments (Class 9), Research (Class 42), Business Consultancy (Class 35), Paper Products (Class 16) and Education (Class 16).6 Table 5. Most “trademarked” NICE product classes, 1996 to 2002 Top 10 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 Total NICE Class 9 42 16 35 41 25 38 5 36 3 Applications 1996-2001 79.374 64.171 44.927 41.535 32.935 29.659 29.292 21.276 20.618 17.864 % 12.1 9.8 6.9 6.3 5.0 4.5 4.5 3.3 3.2 2.7 58.3 Top 10 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 NICE Class 9 42 35 16 41 25 5 38 3 36 Applications 2002 12.961 8.490 8.029 6.941 6.237 5.681 4.797 4.362 3.797 3.407 % 10.7 6.9 6.6 5.7 5.1 4.7 3.9 3.6 3.1 2.8 53.2 Source: IHMI (2003). Statistics of community trade marks. Situation at the end of 2002; Own calculations 6 It is still not clear is this is due to a great dynamism of innovative activities in this product classes or rather a manifestation of toughness of competition. 15 How do, on the whole, intangible products measure up to intangible ones? Table 6 shows that while goods classes still count as the major segment, services are rising fast in importance. This might be interpreted as evidence of structural change in the EU economies. The latest OECD figures point out that the service sectors acounts of 70% of OECD’s GDP (OECD, 2003). The study by Velling and his colleagues (2002) find the same pattern for German home trademark applications. They also suggest that behind the spectacular increase of service marks in the 1990s one of the possible contributing factors is an increase of trademark applications by manufacturing companies. Table 6. Structure and sectoral dynamics of CTM “trademarking” 1996 1997 1998 1999 2001 2002 Goods Services 74 26 72 28 69 31 65 35 58 42 Growth rate 96-02 Growth rate 97-02 66 34 0.4% 6% 9% 14% Fonte: IHMI (2002), Detailed Applications Statistics, Situation at the end of June 2002; IHMI (2003), Statistics of community trade marks. Situation at the end of 2002; Own calculations Note: Desagregated data for 2000 nor available If services are a dynamic category, how have services themselves changed in terms of structure? Looking for the individual service classes can give another insight of what was the direction of development in services, what specific services drove the overall increase in services. Table 7 shows the composition of the service trademarks by different service classes, while table 8 presents the rates of growth7 of the different classes. The services having more trademark applications are Research (Class 42), Business Consultancy (Class 35), Education (Class 41) and Telecoms (Class 38). These services are usually regarded as Knowledge-based services. Table 7. Composition of CTM service applications NICE Class 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 43 44 45 Total Descriptor 1996-2002 % Business Consultancy Finance Construction Telecommunications Transportation Processes Education Research Restaurants and Hotels Medical Care Personal Services 49564 24025 17814 33654 17346 6607 39172 72661 1883 1501 506 19 9 7 13 7 2 15 27 1 1 0.2 Services 264733 100 Source: IHMI (2003), Detailed Applications Statistics, Situation at the end of June 2002 7 Classes 43, 44 and 45 were added latter in the period, therefore growth rates were not included. 16 The following table presents trademark application evolution by type of service for the available years. NICE Class growing above of the average of the service sector were again of knowledge-based services based on knowledge: Business Consultancy (Class 35) and Telecoms (Class 38). Table 8. CTM growth within service product categories NICE Class 35 36 37 38 39 40 41 42 Total Descriptor Business Consultancy Finance Construction Telecommunications Transportation Processes Education Research Services Growth rate 1996-2002 Growth rate 1997-2002 12.5 5.3 2.2 9.1 6.0 6.5 6.3 1.7 20.0% 14.4% 14.4% 16.5% 15.3% 15.2% 15.2% 8.6% 7.4 16.2% Source: IHMI (2002), Detailed Applications Statistics. Situation at the end of June 2002; IHMI (2003), Statistics of community trade marks. Situation at the end of 2002; Own calculations Two difficulties limit, however, our capacity to produce more precise conclusions. On the one hand, NICE classes are very aggregate, containing many different kinds of products under same heading. On the other hand, the initial bubble of applications and of the fact to make use of few years make us unable to produce safe conclusions on the comparative dynamics of product classes. Patterns of use of national trademark by Portuguese firms The oldest trademark in Portugal that is still standing today was registered February 20, 1890. The trademark Real Companhia Vinícola do Norte de Portugal given to the company with the same name for the specific uses of stamping in Port wine casks.8 Among the ten oldest registered trademarks the majority of them correspond to the wine and olive oil business. which gives an impression of the productive profile of the Portuguese economy. This section reports evidence from the period from 1980 to 2001. Trademark filled by the Portuguese industrial property office (INPI) to resident company surpassed annual GDP growth. The growth was 10% a year. Portuguese trademarkers are mostly business firms (80%), the rest are private individuals (most of whom are likely to be owners of small firms). Concession rates (trademarks registered on the base of trademarks applied) are 86% for residents and 96% for non-residents. Non residents tend to have trademarks that last longer, they keep paying their fees to support the trademarks: total drop-out in the period was 11% where as residents dropped 19% of the trademarks registered in the period. Non-residents have a lower growth rate of applications, these companies’ applications peaked just after Portugal became a member of the European Economic Community. Among non-residents USA (39% of all non-resident applications) is the largest filler, followed by the UK (15%), Spain 8 This mark was registered as an international trademark in 1925 17 (12%), Japan (6%), France (4%), Germany (3%) and Brazil (3%). On the EU fillings account for 42% of the total non-resident trademarking. From the mid-1990s Spanish and Brazilian companies became the most dynamic foreign trademarkers. National marks are also classified on the basis of the of NICE Agreement. The most demanded classes by residents consist of Pharmaceutical and Hygiene Products (Class 5), Instruments(Class 5), followed by Detergents and Cosmetics (Class 3), Paper Products and Clothing and Footwear (Class 25). This pattern discloses some differentiation by applications of residents and, above all, a predominance of products face to the services. However, the last years of the period the panorama suffered some alterations, with classes typically of services be more demanded, namely Class 41 (Education), Class 42 (Research) and Class 35 (Business Consultancy). Trends for both residents and non-residents follow the standard of sectoral change in line with processes of economic development. These transformations essentially are characterised by a gradual fall of the proportional importance of the tangible goods and by increases in the service products. Table 9 presents this pattern. As expected, non-residents do not trademark as much services as the residents give the fact that services are basically non-transactional goods. Also, the weigh of the national wine industry comes out in the detailed data, Class 33 (Beverages) is much more “trademarked” by residents than by non-residents. In the service categories, the resident entities apply for a relatively larger number of trademarks in services that are dependent on proximity: Restaurants and Hotels (Class 43), Medical Care (Class 44) and Personal Services (Class 45). Table 9. - Distribution of national trademark applications by goods and services Residents Non-residents Goods Services Total Goods Services Total 80-84 89.7% 10.3% 4665 87.8% 12.2% 4435 85-89 87.1% 12.9% 9285 87.4% 12.6% 9971 90-94 80.5% 19.5% 22669 84.6% 15.4% 22563 95-99 66.3% 33.7% 31279 78.9% 21.1% 17700 2000-02 51.0% 49.0% 27751 72.4% 27.6% 7575 Total 68.4% 31.6% 95649 82.2% 17.8% 62244 9 Source: INPI; Own calculations The information obtained from our IPR survey shows that the interest for and actual use of IPRs is still very limited. Only 39% of business firms state having acquaintance with INPI activities, while a smaller proportion (19%) acknowledges actual use of IPRs or intention of their use in the near future. These values have a statistically significant variance across sectors and display a positive association with firm size. 9 June 2002. 18 In terms of attitude, more than half of firms state having a “low interest” in IP issues. with responses varying between 54.0% and 86.7% for different IPR types. Trademarks are the IPR modality showing higher attraction, with 17.8% of the firms showing “high” interest for it and an additional 28.2% “medium” interest. In terms of actual use 4.2% of the surveyed firms state that they have applied for Patents or Utility Models while 17.7% applied for Trademarks and 2.6% for protection related to Technical Designs and Industrial Models. These results are not surprising or particularly different from what has been observed elsewhere. They stem from a variety of reasons. the most important ones being: (1) economic structure (relative low weight of both high tech industries and information intensive services. and absence of large firms acting on global markets); (2) low supply of critical competencies (required to explore commercially IPRs and manage complementarities within IPR portfolios); (3) low accessibility both to demanding users and to technology markets (this inhibits the capacity to explore commercially any IPR undertaken by firms. inventors or RTOs). In relation to trademarks we found a number of variables that reveal a statistically significant degree of association if we cross tab them against the importance attributed to trademarks and their use in the past. These factors included the existence of an autonomous marketing department in the company. the relationship with specialised consultancies, the size of marketing budgets and the knowledge of the about the national IPR agency’s services and role. A variable such as size is always strongly significant in the analysis. However, whether a firm is geared to intermediary products or final consumer products does not discriminate firm in terms of importance attributed to trademarks but only in their actual use: consumer goods firms tend to use more trademarks. Since we found a great correlation between the uses of different IPR rights, it’s perhaps not strange that there are clear distinctions between manufacturing industries aggregated by OCDE classification of technological intensity. High and medium high-technology industries tend to use more trademarks. So, the OECD Technological intensity taxonomy seems to discriminate well industries in relation to their use of trademarks. Services, that we divided between high and low intensity of operations involving information, exhibit a clear divide: high information intensive service sectors. such as consultancies, telecoms and banks employ much more trademarks in their business strategies than sectors real-estate, restaurants, transportation and personal service industries. These survey observations are in line with what the trademark databases shown. 6. Avenues for further research There is a variety of ways in which trademark data can be further testes and used to produce more complex indicators. One suggestion is to follow the path already taken by patent analysis and construct a Relative Marketing Advantage (RMA) indicator. The RMA calculates a country’s industry share in each of the trademark classes divided by the share of total trademarking in the same class. It can be though of indicating the relative trademarking activity of an country (j) in a specific product 19 category (i), normalised to the total trademarking of the relevant population in that class. Preliminary analysis using CTM data has shown that Portugal comparative marketing advantages in Metal Goods (Class 6), Textiles (Class 24), Business Consultancy (Class 35) and Personal Services (Class 45). While the first to results are unproblematic give the weight of automotive components and clothing products in the international trade profile of the Portuguese economy, the observation of the service strenghts are more difficult to interpret give their non-transactional nature. TM ij RMA ij =  TM kj k  TM il l   TM kl k l Another avenue for further research, is to estimate the Propensities to Trademark among different industries. This can be defined as the number of trademarks registered per unit of marketing expenditure. Other aspects can be further analysed such as the life cycle of brands, the factors and trends in trademark licensing, etc. The relationship between trademarks and other IPRs in the context of integrated IPR management could be a research topic worth pursuing. Moreover, the ways different trademarks (word marks, logos, 3D, sound, etc.) are combined to protect given products are not well understood. In fact, NICE classes demanded are larger than the number of trademark applications, which we expect to be also larger than the number of brands created. 7. Concluding remarks This paper tried to tackle the question “what can we learn from trademarks?”. The objective was to test trademarks as an output indicator of innovative activity as well as an indicator of marketing capabilities of profit-oriented firms. Brands are a very important s part of firms’ marketing plans and strategies, their used to protect their products and business identity but also to for other purposes like business diversification. Firms make a huge (and increasing) use of brands as a (dynamic) competition tool. Applications for service trademarks have boomed in the 1990s, and this trend was led by knowledge-based services: Business Consultancy, Telecoms and Education. Within the EU-15, a number of small countries seem to exhibit very strong marketing capabilities, namely the Nordic countries, Ireland and Austria. Portugal is lagging behind. However, Portugal shows signs of structural change. It accompanies the general trend towards service trademarking. Moreover the composition of this trend is biased towards Education, Research and Business Consultancy categories. Evidence from the Portuguese case suggests that companies that tend to use one kind of IPR tends to use other IPRs. That implies that highly technological intensive sectors, which use more patents, also are found to make a more intensive use of trademarks. In the case of services, those usually considered as intensive users of information are those that tend to use more patents, an observation that is compatible 20 with the evidence from EU trademarks on the dynamism of knowledge services in the transition to the XXI century. Combined with the increasing availability of electronic data, there is an opportunity to use trademarks as indicators of innovation and industrial change. Constructing and analysing indicators of science, technology and innovation is an increasingly important task in carrying out research and policy actions in this whole area. We argue that trademark data can serve the purpose of being a partial output indicator of new products introduced in the market and, therefore, can be used as an empirical yardstick for measuring change in economic activity. This can prove to be especially useful for advancing research in innovation studies, industrial dynamics, international economics, economic and business history, innovation policy, competition intelligence, etc. However, in order to properly use numbers, and not be unconsciously used by them. we need a set of methodological guidelines. This paper tried also to contribute to the reflection around methodological issues. Much remains to be done. References Aaker, D.A. e E. Joachimsthaler (2000), Brand Leadership, The Free press: New York. Aaker, D.A. (1991), Managing Brand Equity: Capitalizing on the Value of a Brand, The Free press: New York. Cabral, L. (2000), Introduction Industrial Organization, The MIT Press: Cambridge, Massachusetts. Christopher. M. and M. Mcdonald (1991), Marketing: An Introdutcion, Pan... Cohen, W.. R. Nelson and J. Walsh (2000), “Protecting their intellectual assets: Appropriability conditions and why U.S. manufacturing firms patent (or not)”, NBER Working Paper Series 7552. Dearlove. D. e S. Crainer (1999), As 50 Maiores Marcas. Biblioteca Executive Digest, Abril/Controljornal Editora: Linda-a-velha. Diamon. S.A. (1983), “The historical development of trademarks”. trademark Reporter. vol. 73. no. 3. pp. 222-47. Doern. G. B. (1999), Global Change and Intellectual Property Agencies. Pinter. Londres. Economides. Nicholas (1987), ‘The Economics of Trademarks’. TradeMark Register, vol. 78, pp. 523539. Godin. B. (2003), “The emergence of S&T indicators: Why did governments supplement statistics with indicators?”, Research Policy, vol. 32, pp. 679-691. Granstrand, Ö. (1999), The Economics and Management of Intellectual Property – Towards Intellectual Property, Edward Elgar: Cheltenham, Northampton. Griliches, Z.. (1990), “Patent statistics as economic indicators: A survey”. Journal of Economic Literature, vol. 27, pp. 1661-707. Kotler, P.. G. Armstrong. J. Saunders e V. Wong (1999), Principles of Marketing, Second European Edition, Prentice Hall Europe. 21 Martin. B. and J. Irvine (1983). “Assessing basic research: Some partial indicators of scientific progress in radioastronomy”. Research Policy. vol. 12. pp. 61-90. Narin, F. and D. Olivastro (1988), “Technology indicators based on patents and patent citations”, in van Raam. A. (ed.), Handbook of Quantitative Studies of Science and Technology. North Holland. Amsterdam. p. 465-5. OECD (2003), STI Scoreboard 2003, OECD: Paris. Patel, P. (1998), “Indicators for systems of innovation and system interactions”, IDEA Paper series 11. STEP Group. Patel, P. and K. Pavitt (1994), “Patterns of economic activity: Their measurement and interpretation”, in Stoneman. P. (ed.), Handbook of Economics of Innovation and Technical Change. Blackwell: Oxford. Pavitt. K. (1985), “Patent statistics as indicators of innovative activities: Possibilities and Problems”. Scientometrics, Vol. 7, Nos 1-2, pp. 77-99. Scherer. F.M. (1983), “The propensity to patent”, International Journal of Industrial Organisation, vol. 1, pp. 107-28. Smith, K. (2003), “Measuring innovation”, forthcoming in J. Fagerberg, D. Mowery and R. Nelson (eds), Understanding Innovation - Oxford Handbook of Innovation, Oxford University Press. Trajtenberg, M. (1990), Economic Analysis of Product Innovation: The Case of CT Scanners, Harvard University Press: Cambridge. Massachusetts. Trajtenberg, M. (2001), “Innovation in Israel 1968-1997: A comparative analysis using patent data”, Research Policy, vol. 30, pp. 363-89. Velling, J. (ed.) (2002), 2001 Germany’s Technological Performance, Bundesministerium für Bildung und Forschung. Wilkins. M. (1992), “The negleted intangible asset: The influence of the Trade Mark on the rise of the modern corporation”, in Harvey and Jones (eds). ... . pp. 691-707. Appendix NICE CLASSIFICATION SYSTEM 1. 2. 3. 4. 5. 6. Chemicals used in industry. science and photography. as well as in agriculture. horticulture and forestry; unprocessed artificial resins. unprocessed plastics; manures; fire extinguishing compositions; tempering and soldering preparations; chemical substances for preserving foodstuffs; tanning substances; adhesives used in industry. Paints. varnishes. lacquers; preservatives against rust and against deterioration of wood; colorants; mordants; raw natural resins; metals in foil and powder form for painters. decorators. printers and artists. Bleaching preparations and other substances for laundry use; cleaning. polishing. scouring and abrasive preparations; soaps; perfumery. essential oils. cosmetics. hair lotions; dentifrices. Industrial oils and greases; lubricants; dust absorbing. wetting and binding compositions; fuels (including motor spirit) and illuminants; candles and wicks for lighting. Pharmaceutical and veterinary preparations; sanitary preparations for medical purposes; dietetic substances adapted for medical use. food for babies; plasters. materials for dressings; material for stopping teeth. dental wax; disinfectants; preparations for destroying vermin; fungicides. Herbicides. Common metals and their alloys; metal building materials; transportable buildings of metal; materials of metal for railway tracks; non-electric cables and wires of common metal; ironmongery. small items 22 of metal hardware; pipes and tubes of metal; safes; goods of common metal not included in other classes; ores. 7. Machines and machine tools; motors and engines (except for land vehicles); machine coupling and transmission components (except for land vehicles); agricultural implements other than handoperated; incubators for eggs. 8. Hand tools and implements (hand operated); cutlery; side arms; razors. 9. Scientific. nautical. surveying. photographic. cinematographic. optical. weighing. measuring. signalling. checking (supervision). life-saving and teaching apparatus and instruments; apparatus and instruments for conducting. switching. transforming. accumulating. regulating or controlling electricity; apparatus for recording. transmission or reproduction of sound or images; magnetic data carriers. recording discs; automatic vending machines and mechanisms for coin-operated apparatus; cash registers. calculating machines. data processing equipment and computers; fire-extinguishing apparatus. 10. Surgical. medical. dental and veterinary apparatus and instruments. artificial limbs. eyes and teeth; orthopedic articles; suture materials. 11. Apparatus for lighting. heating. steam generating. cooking. refrigerating. drying. ventilating. water supply and sanitary purposes. 12. Vehicles; apparatus for locomotion by land. air or water. 13. Firearms; ammunition and projectiles; explosives; fireworks. 14. Precious metals and their alloys and goods in precious metals or coated therewith. not included in other classes; jewellery. precious stones; horological and chronometric instruments. 15. Musical instruments. 16. Paper. cardboard and goods made from these materials. not included in other classes; printed matter; bookbinding material; photographs; stationery; adhesives for stationery or household purposes; artists' materials; paint brushes; typewriters and office requisites (except furniture); instructional and teaching material (except apparatus); plastic materials for packaging (not included in other classes); printers' type; printing blocks. 17. Rubber. gutta-percha. gum. asbestos. mica and goods made from these materials and not included in other classes; plastics in extruded form for use in manufacture; packing. stopping and insulating materials; flexible pipes. not of metal. 18. Leather and imitations of leather. and goods made of these materials and not included in other classes; animal skins. hides; trunks and travelling bags; umbrellas. parasols and walking sticks; whips. harness and saddlery. 19. Building materials (non-metallic); non-metallic rigid pipes for building; asphalt. pitch and bitumen; non-metallic transportable buildings; monuments. not of metal. 20. Furniture. mirrors. picture frames; goods (not included in other classes) of wood. cork. reed. cane. wicker. horn. bone. ivory. whalebone. shell. amber. mother-of-pearl. meerschaum and substitutes for all these materials. or of plastics. 21. Household or kitchen utensils and containers (not of precious metal or coated therewith); combs and sponges; brushes (except paint brushes); brush-making materials; articles for cleaning purposes; steelwool; unworked or semi-worked glass (except glass used in building); glassware. porcelain and earthenware not included in other classes. 22. Ropes. string. nets. tents. awnings. tarpaulins. sails. sacks and bags (not included in other classes); padding and stuffing materials (except of rubber or plastics); raw fibrous textile materials. 23. Yarns and threads. for textile use. 24. Textiles and textile goods. not included in other classes; bed and table covers. 25. Clothing. footwear. headgear. 26. Lace and embroidery. ribbons and braid; buttons. hooks and eyes. pins and needles; artificial flowers. 27. Carpets. rugs. mats and matting. linoleum and other materials for covering existing floors; wall hangings (non-textile). 28. Games and playthings; gymnastic and sporting articles not included in other classes; decorations for Christmas trees. 29. Meat. fish. poultry and game; meat extracts; preserved. dried and cooked fruits and vegetables; jellies. jams. fruit sauces; eggs. milk and milk products; edible oils and fats. 30. Coffee. tea. cocoa. sugar. rice. tapioca. sago. artificial coffee; flour and preparations made from cereals. bread. pastry and confectionery. ices; honey. treacle; yeast. baking-powder; salt. mustard; vinegar. sauces (condiments); spices; ice. 31. Agricultural. horticultural and forestry products and grains not included in other classes; live animals; fresh fruits and vegetables; seeds. natural plants and flowers; foodstuffs for animals. malt. 23 32. Beers; mineral and aerated waters and other non-alcoholic drinks; fruit drinks and fruit juices; syrups and other preparations for making beverages. 33. Alcoholic beverages (except beers). 34. Tobacco; smokers' articles; matches 35. Advertising; business management; business administration; office functions. 36. Insurance; financial affairs; monetary affairs; real estate affairs. 37. Building construction; repair; installation services. 38. Telecommunications. 39. Transport; packaging and storage of goods; travel arrangement. 40. Treatment of materials. 41. Education; providing of training; entertainment; sporting and cultural activities. 42. Scientific and technological services and research and design relating thereto; industrial analysis and research services; design and development of computer hardware and software; legal services. 43. Services for providing food and drink; temporary accommodation. 44. Medical services; veterinary services; hygienic and beauty care for human beings or animals; agriculture. horticulture and forestry services. 45. Personal and social services rendered by others to meet the needs of individuals; security services for the protection of property and individuals. 24