DISTRIBUTION THE NEWSLETTER OF THE DISTRIBUTION AND FRANCHISING COMMITTEE Antitrust Section — American Bar Association Vol. 20, No. 1 — March 2016 In this Issue Message from the Chair.................................................................................... 1 Franchise Law Developments in Germany: Appellate Court Recognizes Claim for Damages Based on Pre-Contract Information Provided by Franchisor................................................................. 3 California Assembly Bill 525: A Resounding Win for Franchisees or a Source for Further Dispute.............................................................. 5 Resale Price Maintenance and Dual Distribution............................................. 8 The 2016 Auto Distribution Workshop: An Insider’s Take..............................14 Summary of FTC Workshop: Auto Distribution: Current Issues and Future Trends.................................................................................16 Distribution and Franchising Committee: ABA Section of Antitrust Law THE HIGHLIGHT ZONE: MESSAGE FROM THE CHAIR Submitted for your consideration … the first issue of DISTRIBUTION in the 2015-2016 ABA year. On behalf of the Distribution & Franchising Committee, I hope you’ll find its contents thought-provoking and educational. This issue will be of special interest to practitioners with clients involved in franchise relationships. We are grateful to authors Marcus Schriefers and Michaela Schwuchow for their update entitled, Franchise Law Developments in Germany: Appellate Court Recognizes Claim for Damages Based on Pre-Contract Information Provided by Franchisor. Several times zones to the west of Germany, Anthony Marks and Kazim Naqvi comment on California Assembly Bill 525: A Resounding Win for Franchisees or a Source for Further Dispute? Reuben Arnold, Neill Norman, and Daniel Schmierer take a look at Resale Price Maintenance and Dual Distribution. And in the aftermath of the FTC’s day-long workshop on the state of motor vehicle distribution in the U.S., the intrepid Anna Aryankalayil provides a useful Summary of the FTC Workshop: Auto Distribution: Current Issues and Future Trends, while industry veteran Steven Cernak offers valuable insights in his piece, The 2016 Auto Distribution Workshop: An Insider’s Take. As we develop the contents of our next issue of this newsletter, we invite you to contact the editors about contributing an article, book review, commentary, practice tips, case note, or interview. Good articles come in all shapes and sizes! We hope to see many readers at the Section of Antitrust Law Spring Meeting in early April. Our Committee is the sponsor of a Spring Meeting panel discussion entitled, Spinning Our Wheels: Clarifying Liability in Huband-Spoke Conspiracies, and co-sponsor of no fewer than three other programs with a focus on distribution issues: Price War: Reconciling Conflicting National Pricing Restraints, International Perspectives on Online Vertical Restraints and Marijuana, Twenty-Three States and Counting…. If you are looking for excellent speakers and fascinating topics, look no further. Later this year, the Committee looks forward to the publication of the second edition of The Law and Economics of Product Distribution, a compilation of legal and economic approaches to antitrust issues arising in the context of distribution relationships. We invite you to join the Distribution & Franchising Committee if you have not already done so. Membership is free to all Section members. All you have to do is enter the Section website, go to the Committees page, click on “JOIN A COMMITTEE” and follow the instructions. Enjoy this newsletter and join us soon for another episode of … The Highlight Zone. Warmest regards, Alicia L. Downey Chair, Distribution and Franchising Committee Copyright Notice ©Copyright 2016 American Bar Association. All rights reserved. The contents of this publication may not be reproduced, in whole or in part, without written permission of the ABA. All requests for reprints should be sent to www.americanbar.org/utility/reprint. March 2016 1 Distribution and Franchising Committee: ABA Section of Antitrust Law DISTRIBUTION is published by the Distribution and Franchising Committee of the American Bar Association Section of Antitrust Law. The views expressed in Distribution are the authors’ only and not necessarily those of the American Bar Association, the Section of Antitrust Law, or the Distribution and Franchising Committee. If you wish to comment on the contents of DISTRIBUTION, please write to the American Bar Association, Section of Antitrust Law, 321 North Clark, Chicago, IL 60610. Submission of Materials: DISTRIBUTION welcomes submissions of articles, and case summaries involving significant or interesting decisions, trials, or developments in antitrust law affecting all types of distribution arrangements. Please send all submissions to: Craig G. Falls, Vice Chair Dechert LLP 1900 K Street, NW Washington DC 20006-1110 202.261.3373 craig.falls@dechert.com Celeste C. Saravia, Vice Chair Cornerstone Research Two Embarcadero Center, 20th Floor San Francisco, CA 94111-3922 415.339.8116 csaravia@cornerstone.com Jeff L. White, Vice Chair Weil Gotshal & Manges LLP 1300 I Street, NW, Suite 900E Washington, DC 20005-3348 202.682.7059 Jeff.white@weil.com THE DISTRIBUTION AND FRANCHISING COMMITTEE LEADERSHIP Alicia L. Downey, Chair Downey Law LLC 155 Federal Street, Suite 300 Boston, MA 02110 617.444.9811 alicia@downeylawllc.com Katrina M. Robson, Vice Chair O’Melveny & Myers LLP 1625 Eye Street, NW Washington DC 20005 202.220.5052 krobson@omm.com Craig G. Falls, Vice Chair Dechert LLP 1900 K Street, NW Washington DC 20006-1110 202.261.3373 craig.falls@dechert.com Joy K. Fuyuno, Vice Chair Microsoft One Marina Boulevard #22-01 Singapore 018989 SGP 65.6568887475 joyf@microsoft.com Celeste C. Saravia, Vice Chair Cornerstone Research Two Embarcadero Center, 20th Floor San Francisco, CA 94111-3922 415.339.8116 csaravia@cornerstone.com Jeff L. White, Vice Chair Weil Gotshal & Manges LLP 1300 I Street, NW, Suite 900E Washington, DC 20005-3348 202.682.7059 Jeff.white@weil.com Melanie A. Hallas, Young Lawyer Representative Sidley Austin LLP 1501 K Street, NW Washington, DC 20005 202.736.8029 mhallas@sidley.com March 2016 2 Distribution and Franchising Committee: ABA Section of Antitrust Law Franchise Law Developments in Germany: Appellate Court Recognizes Claim for Damages Based on Pre-Contract Information Provided by Franchisor by Marcus Schriefers and Michaela Schwuchow In a September 5, 2015 judgment, the Higher Regional Court of Hamburg, Germany ruled that a franchisee of the Tom Tailor apparel franchise system was entitled to recover damages based on unreliable and inaccurate data in documents Tom Tailor provided to the franchisee prior to the parties’ entering into their franchise agreement. Based on this ruling, any franchisor that provides incorrect information to a franchisee in the pre-contract/negotiation phase is potentially liable for damages where the franchisee bases their decision to join the franchise system on the incorrect information. This decision is in line with the recent approach of German courts to the franchisorfranchisee relationship. German courts have a tendency to protect the “smaller” business, and particularly so in distribution relationships like franchises. Franchising in Germany has developed steadily since first appearing in the 1960s. Germany is now one of the fastest growing markets for franchises in the EU. In Germany today, franchises are present in a wide variety of business markets, from food and other service providers, to do-it-yourself retailers, to fashion apparel stores like Tom Tailor. As the number of German franchise systems and franchisees has grown, the application of German law to franchise relationships has become increasingly important. Despite the rapid growth and current prominence of franchise businesses in Germany, there is only limited statutory German law specifically addressing franchising. Rather, German franchise law has developed in the courts through the application of general legal principles. Although the European Union (“EU”) published a group exemptions regulation in 1999 dealing specifically with franchises, that regulation was focused specifically on antitrust considerations. In 2010, the EU’s 1999 regulation was overruled by a new, more general group exemption regulation addressing vertical restraints— March 2016 again with an antitrust focus. The 2010 regulation is the only current statutory provision specifically directed at franchise contracts under German law. All other aspects of franchise law are governed by general German legal principles. German case law addressing franchise relationships provides for an enhanced protection of franchisees and, in particular, provides that a franchisor is obliged to correctly and fully inform the potential franchisee about the profitability of the franchise system during contract negotiations prior to the execution of a franchise contract (cf. Higher Regional Court of Düsseldorf, judgment of 25 October 2013). The judgment of the Higher Regional Court of Hamburg of September 5, 2014 regarding the Tom Tailor fashion group is in line with this established case law but further substantiates the concept of franchisor liability for faulty information provided in the precontract phase of the parties’ relationship. Tom Tailor, a franchise chain established in Germany in 1962 that has seen its popularity grow significantly in the past decade, sells medium-priced fashion apparel to teens and young adults. In the recently decided case, a Tom Tailor franchise sued for damages, contending that prior to entering into the franchise agreement, Tom Tailor had supplied the franchisee with unsubstantiated and false information regarding the performance of other Tom Tailor stores. In the judgment of the court of first instance dated January 17, 2014, the Regional Court of Hamburg ordered Tom Tailor to pay damages in the amount of € 156,450.17 (approx. $ 175,742) based on its finding that the franchisor had provided the franchisee with an inventory turnover forecast in investment proposals during contract negotiations that did not correspond to the average inventory turnover of all other existing 3 Distribution and Franchising Committee: ABA Section of Antitrust Law Tom Tailor Stores or to the actual inventory turnover in existing Tom Tailor Stores that were comparable to the size and location of the store the franchisee intended to establish. The court of the first instance also found that the target figure regarding the expected increase in inventory turnover in the investment proposals supplied by the franchisor was based only on assumptions and hopes about how the inventory turnover would develop in the future. The investment proposal provided by the franchisor stated, inter alia, that an inventory turnover of € 3,000 (approx. $ 3,370) per square meter of sales area and an increase in turnover of 5% within the first five years of business was to be expected. The franchisee claimed to have relied on those figures in deciding to sign the franchise agreement. However, from the outset the franchisee’s store experienced inventory turnover far behind the turnover forecast supplied by the franchisor and the franchisee’s inventory turnover was not even sufficient to cover the operations costs of the store. The court of first instance offered some other noteworthy pronouncements and observations in its ruling. For example, the court declared that a franchisor is not allowed to create false impressions about profitability by – without explicitly informing the franchisee about this – using incorrect data or using data that is not based on a thorough investigation of the market and therefore only has the nature of an estimate. The court further determined that a forecast lacks a realistic factual basis if the forecast is based on figures that are in fact only reached by few franchisees, as such a forecast can create the false impression that the forecast figures can be reached “normally” or by an “average franchisee” or “during the normal course of business.” As the Higher Regional Court of Hamburg pointed out in its Judgment, the burden of proof to demonstrate that the pre-contractual information provided by the franchisor is correct lies with the franchisor. The Tom Tailor case is in line with the general tendency of German courts to protect the “smaller” partner in any kind of distribution system. This general principle is March 2016 akin to German law governing sales agency relationships, where the sales agent has for a long time enjoyed special legal rights and protections against the principal. These protections were initially extended to distributors in distribution relationships and, subsequently, franchisees in franchise systems. The Tom Tailor case offers some important lessons and cautions for franchisors who are looking to do business in Germany. For example, during contract negotiations with a potential German franchisee a franchisor should: • Only provide inventory turnover forecasts, profitability calculations, or other similar data that are determined using a comprehensible and realistic factual basis or experience based on the size and type of location under consideration; and • Affirmatively advise the franchisee where the franchisor lacks the factual basis to deliver such a forecast due to the fact that there are no stores established that are comparable to the size and/ or location of the store the franchisee intends to establish or due to the fact that the franchise system does not have sufficiently comparable figures. • If a franchisor does provide the franchisee with data that is not from comparable locations, the franchisor should specifically indicate in writing on the face of the data that such data is from locations that are not comparable to the prospective franchisee’s location and is not meant to be a forecast or projection of the future performance of the prospective franchisee’s location. Marcus Schriefers is a partner with Heussen Rechtsanwaltsgesellschaft mbH in Stuttgart, Germany and serves as head of the firm’s distribution and logistics practice group, Michaela Schwuchow an associate with Heussen Rechtsanwaltsgesellschaft mbH in Stuttgart. 4 Distribution and Franchising Committee: ABA Section of Antitrust Law California Assembly Bill 525: A Resounding Win for Franchisees or a Source for Further Dispute? by Anthony Marks1 and Kazim Naqvi2 On October 11, 2015, California Governor Jerry Brown approved Assembly Bill Number 525 (“AB 525”), since dubbed the “Franchise Bill of Rights.” AB 525 proposes three notable changes that shift the dynamics within the franchisor/franchisee relationship. First, franchisors previously were prohibited from terminating a franchise prior to the expiration of its term except for good cause, which was defined as “the failure of the franchisee to comply with any lawful requirement of the franchise agreement after being given notice and a reasonable opportunity to cure the failure within 30 days.”3 Now, the definition of good cause has been changed to “the failure of the franchisee to substantially comply with any lawful requirement of the franchise agreement,”4 and the time to cure has been extended to 60 days. Second, AB 525 states that franchisees cannot be restricted from transferring assets or interest in a franchise, provided that the transferee is qualified under the operative franchise agreement and the franchisor’s then-existing and reasonable standards for approving new or renewing franchisees.5 Lastly, AB 525 requires a franchisor, upon a lawful termination or nonrenewal of a franchisee, to purchase certain of franchisee’s resalable equipment, inventory, and supplies at “the value of price paid, minus depreciation.”6 Although these three changes seek to provide further clarity and limitation on franchisor control and discretion, they also present several unanswered questions. This article seeks to provide possible interpretations, answers, and best practice tips to franchisors and franchisees alike when complying with AB 525’s new requirements. A Different Standard for Termination The new provisions of AB 525 have undoubtedly caused both franchisors and franchisees alike to seek guidance as to what “substantially comply” actually means. Before, franchisors could technically pursue termination if franchisees violated any provision of the franchise agreement, no matter how minor. Now, the required level of non-compliance by franchisees has been changed. Is “failure to substantially comply” a brand new standard introduced by AB 525 or have similar standards been employed by tribunals when governing contract disputes? Although not directly applicable to contract interpretation, several California courts have tried to specify the meaning of “substantial compliance” in the context of statutes. Again, in the context of statutory compliance, courts have stated that “substantial compliance means actual compliance with respect to the substance essential to every reasonable objective of the statute, as distinguished from simple technical 1 Tony Marks [https://www.bryancave.com/en/people/anthony-j-marks.html] is the Co-leader of the Franchise and Distribution Law Team of Bryan Cave LLP. He is located in Los Angeles, California where he counsels clients in all industry areas in the full spectrum of franchise and distribution law matters. 2 Kazim Naqvi [https://www.bryancave.com/en/people/kazim-a-naqvi.html] is an associate in the Los Angeles office of Bryan Cave LLP. He practices in the commercial litigation and franchise and distribution areas where he represents franchisors in various industries, including transportation, education, and food and beverage services. 3 http://leginfo.legislature.ca.gov/faces/billNavClient.xhtml?bill_id=201520160AB525. 4 Id. 5Id. 6 Id. 7 Hoffmaster v. City of San Diego, 55 Cal. App. 4th 1098, 1103 (1997). March 2016 5 Distribution and Franchising Committee: ABA Section of Antitrust Law imperfections of form.”7 “Substance prevails over form. When the plaintiff embarks on a course of substantial compliance, every reasonable objective of the statute at issue has been satisfied. The court’s primary concern is the objective of the statute.”8 This may or may not be the result when a California court considers substantial compliance of a franchise agreement. Other courts have invoked a doctrine of substantial compliance in contract law. “The doctrine of substantial compliance or substantial performance is well-established in contract law, dating back to Justice Cardozo’s holding that a deficiency in performance may not be considered a breach as long as it is not ‘so dominant or pervasive as in any real or substantial measure to frustrate the purpose of the contract.’”9 “To determine questions of substantial compliance, a court generally considers the promised performance, the purpose of the contract, and the extent to which any defects in performance have frustrated the purpose of the contract.”10 Under the above authorities, Courts generally employ a broad, holistic analysis of to determine whether a party has substantially complied with the contract’s purpose. On the contrary, the determination of what constitutes a “material breach,” which many are familiar with, tends to focus on an isolated key term of the contract, such as payment of royalties. “Normally the question of whether a breach of an obligation is a material breach, so as to excuse performance by the other party, is a question of fact. Whether a partial breach of a contract is material depends on the importance or seriousness thereof and the probability of the injured party getting substantial performance.”11 When determining whether a breach is “material” or “immaterial,” courts may look at whether the isolated breach impacts the core nature of a particular product or service, or if it is merely ancillary to the franchisee’s brand and business. For example, the Ninth Circuit held that “hours of operation are material to the franchise agreement” and a “franchisee’s willful noncompliance with a court order to be significant to the determination of whether termination was proper.”12 Similarly, the Seventh Circuit held that where the franchisee was found to have actually cheated the franchisor out of money due to the franchisor, termination was proper under the franchise agreement.13 Other courts have held that failure to pay required fees and royalties constitutes a material breach of a franchise agreement.14 Conversely, where a franchisor sought termination based on a franchisee’s failure to report and pay its state sales tax, the Ninth Circuit held that “[t]his is not a term that is fundamental to the franchise relationship, nor does the term have real importance or great consequence to the relationship.”15 AB 525 inserts a new uncertainty into terminations of franchise agreements. The judiciary will have to tell us if and how a failure to substantially comply is different from the statutory requirements before AB 525. The amendments by AB 525 invite more subjectivity and likely more disputes over franchise terminations. Transfers Must Meet “Then-Existing” Standards Many franchise agreements reserve the franchisor’s right to approve a proposed transfer of the franchise agreement, either by providing the franchisor with 8 Malek v. Blue Cross of California, 121 Cal. App. 4th 44, 45 (2004). 9 Wapato Heritage, LLC v. United States, 2008 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 117185, at *16 (E.D. Wash. Nov. 21, 2008). 10 J.K. v. Humble, 2013 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 95454, at *5 (D. Ariz. May 17, 2013) (“the first task in resolving questions of substantial compliance is to define the nature of the promised performance. When a party’s promised performance relates to a qualitative term of a contract that affords the party discretion in performance, the analysis of whether the party has breached that contractual term typically turns on whether the party has breached the covenant of good faith and fair dealing.”). 11 Brown v. Grimes, 192 Cal. App. 4th 265, 266 (2011). 12 Chevron, U.S.A., Inc. v. Mebtahi, 148 F. Supp. 2d 1019, 1025 (C.D. Cal. 2000) (discussing Texaco Refining and Marketing, Inc. v. Davis, 835 F. Supp. 1223 (9th Cir. 1994)). 13 Baker v. Amoco Oil Co., 956 F.2d 639 (7th Cir. 1992). 14 See Tolle Furniture Group, LLC v. La-Z-Boy, Inc., 2009 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 64965, at *7-8 (W.D. Wash. July 17, 2009); Era Franchise Sys. v. Brager & Assocs., 2007 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 56418, at *24 (E.D. Cal. Aug. 1, 2007). 15 Chevron, U.S.A., Inc., 148 F. Supp. 2d at 1025. March 2016 6 Distribution and Franchising Committee: ABA Section of Antitrust Law the sole discretion to do so, or that the franchisor’s approval will not be unreasonably withheld. As revised, a franchisor may no longer withhold its approval unless the proposed transferee does not meet its “thenexisting standards for the approval of new or renewing franchisees.” This requirement does not preclude a franchisor from exercising its contractual right of first refusal, but the franchisor’s offer must be equal to the franchisee’s bona fide offer. Now, franchised owners cannot prevent the transfer of a franchise if the transferee otherwise meets the then existing standards and the criteria set forth in the franchise agreement. Franchisors must also apply its transfer discretion consistently across its franchise brand. Further, the franchisor must make available to the franchisee its standards and requirements for transfer. Required Repurchase of Franchisee’s Business Previously, upon a lawful termination or nonrenewal of a franchise, many franchisors had discretion as to whether it wanted to purchase back the inventory, equipment, supplies, and furnishings of the franchisee. And, the valuation of those assets would have been established by the applicable contract. Now, in the context of a lawful termination or nonrenewal, the franchisor is obligated to repurchase the franchisee’s resalable current inventory, supplies, equipment, fixtures and furnishings at the price paid less depreciation. The required repurchase is limited to those items that are purchased or paid for under the terms of the franchise agreement by the franchisee to the franchisor or its approved suppliers and sources. Naturally, there will be dispute as to the depreciated value of the items repurchased. Another point of dispute is to determine which of the many methods of depreciation to employ. Although there are several methods of calculating depreciation, and AB 525 is silent as to how depreciation is determined, a simple procedure would be to use a method permitted for federal income tax purposes. There are four different methods generally employed by California and 9th Circuit courts. The simplest method is straightline depreciation, which charges an equal amount of depreciation to each accounting period.16 The unit-ofproduction method assigns an equal amount of expense to each unit produced or service rendered by the asset.17 The sum-of-the-years digits method determines annual depreciation by multiplying the asset’s depreciable cost by a series of fractions based on the sum of the asset’s useful life digits.18 Lastly, the double-declining balance is a type of accelerated depreciation method that calculates a higher depreciation charge in the first year of an asset’s life and gradually decreases depreciation expense in subsequent years.19 To avoid dispute and ensure clarity, the parties may be best serviced to identify a depreciation method in the franchise agreement. Franchisor/Franchisee Relationships Moving Forward Many of the new issues raised by AB 525 will undoubtedly be the subject of litigation between franchisors and franchisees. Specific examples of what constitutes a “failure to substantially comply” will help both franchisors and franchisees understand where the threshold for termination lies. Further, examples of how to quantify depreciated value of saleable assets will help franchisors and franchisees understand the best way to conduct the buy-back procedure. Until such issues are raised in an appropriate forum, one can only take an educated guess as to how to appropriately comply with AB 525. However, until the interpretive authority is further fleshed out, franchisors and franchisees are advised to be proactive, as opposed to reactive, in thinking through these issues before entering into a franchise agreement. 16 San Francisco v. Public Utilities Com., 6 Cal. 3d 119, 123 (1971) (“Straight line depreciation provides for essentially uniform annual write-offs of a depreciable asset over the life of the asset.”). 17 Mohawk Petroleum Co. v. Commissioner, 148 F. 2d 957, 958 (9th Cir. 1945). 18 Portland General Electric Co. v. United States, 1964 U.S. Dist. LEXIS 9939, at *9 (D. Or. Mar. 16, 1964). 19 Pacific Power & Light Co. v. United States, 644 F. 2d 1358, 1361 (9th Cir. 1981). March 2016 7 Distribution and Franchising Committee: ABA Section of Antitrust Law Resale Price Maintenance and Dual Distribution by Reuben Arnold, Neill Norman, and Daniel Schmierer 1 Several recent antitrust cases brought by both direct and indirect purchasers have challenged minimum resale price maintenance (“RPM”) policies imposed by manufacturers engaged in dual distribution or multi-channel distribution.2 These cases are frequently dismissed because plaintiffs fail to establish a relevant market or fail to demonstrate that the defendant has market power in that market.3 While these are appropriate threshold tests, dismissal on these grounds means that the court does not reach the central economic issue in the case, namely whether the procompetitive benefits of an RPM policy that supports dual distribution outweigh any harm to competition. In this article, we discuss the positive impact of dual distribution and multi-channel distribution on interbrand competition, review the economic analysis of RPM, and demonstrate that RPM plays a key role in facilitating the competitive benefits that can arise from dual distribution and multi-channel distribution. “Dual distribution” describes the distribution strategy of a manufacturer that sells to customers both directly and through third-party distributors or retailers. “Multichannel distribution” describes a distribution strategy in which a manufacturer sells through multiple types of retailers, such as online vs. bricks-and-mortar stores, or big box stores vs. specialist stores, etc. In this article we focus on RPM as it applies dual distribution although the analysis applies to multi-channel distribution as well, except where noted. Dual distribution and multi-channel distribution are common practices across many industries, including information technology, consumer electronics, cosmetics, apparel, and home furnishings, among many others. As one Harvard Business School case study puts it, “[i] practice, most producers and resellers are usually members of multiple—often, competing—channels systems. Producers often sell through a number of intermediaries, while resellers often carry the products of competing manufacturers as well as the lines of many other suppliers in different product categories.”4 For example, Levi Strauss, a manufacturer of blue jeans and other clothing, sells a variety of product lines through different channels targeting different segments of the market, including its own retail stores, high-end stores like Neiman Marcus, department stores like Macy’s and Sears, and discount retailers like Wal-Mart.5 Coach, a manufacturer of luxury handbags and accessories, markets products to its consumers through a variety of channels, such as retail stores, factory outlets, concession counters within larger stores (shop-in-shops), online channels, and specialty stores.6 1 Reuben Arnold is a senior analyst, Neill Norman is a principal, and Daniel Schmierer is a manager at Cornerstone Research. The opinions expressed are those of the authors, who are responsible for the content, and do not necessarily reflect the views of the Cornerstone Research. 2 See, e.g., Complaint, Costco Wholesale Corp. v. Johnson & Johnson Vision Care, Inc., 3:15-cv-00941 (N.D. Cal. Mar. 2, 2015); Corrected Consolidated Class Complaint, In re: Disposable Contact Lens Antitrust Litig. 1:15-md-2626-HES (M.D. Fla. Nov. 23, 2015); People of the State of New York v. Tempur-Pedic Int’l, Inc., 916 N.Y.S.2d 900 (N.Y. Sup. Ct. 2011); Jacobs v. Tempur-Pedic Int’l, Inc.,No. 4:07-cv-02-RLV (N.D. Ga. Dec. 11, 2007); and House of Brides, Inc. v. Alfred Angelo, Inc., No. 11 C 07834 (N.D. Ill. Dec. 4, 2014). 3In House of Brides, Inc. v. Alfred Angelo, Inc., the plaintiff failed to allege facts that plausibly suggested that a single wedding dress brand constituted a cognizable product market. In People of the State of New York v. Tempur-Pedic Int’l Inc; the state court ruled that RPM provisions are unenforceable but not unlawful under New York state law. In Jacobs v. TempurPedic International, Inc., the federal court concluded that plaintiffs had not identified a relevant market as required under the rule of reason standard that had to be applied after Leegin Creative Leather Prods., Inc. v. PSKS, 551 U.S. 877 (2007). Costco Wholesale Corporation v. Johnson & Johnson Vision Care Inc., and In Re: Disposable Contact Lens Antitrust Litigation are ongoing. 4 Frank V. Cespedes, Channel Management, Harvard Business School Case Study No. 9-590-045, 3–6, 8 (rev. Nov. 2006). 5 S. C. Jain and G. T. Haley, Marketing Planning and Strategy 339 (8th ed. 2009). 6 P. Kotler and K. L. Keller, Marketing Management 495 (15th ed. 2016). March 2016 8 Distribution and Franchising Committee: ABA Section of Antitrust Law I. Competitive Benefits from Dual and MultiChannel Distribution Dual distribution and multi-channel distribution can expand a manufacturer’s output, reduce distribution costs, and thereby yield pro-competitive benefits that would not be realized under single-channel distribution. First, multi-channel and dual-channel distribution may allow suppliers to reach a wider array of demand segments within a broad market. In markets for many differentiated consumer goods, preferences for pointof-sale service vary.7 By providing a product through a variety of channels that offer differing levels of service at the point of sale, a manufacturer can cater to a wider range of consumer preferences and penetrate different market segments.8 This expands output, and increases competition between brands. For example, a consumer purchasing a computer may value the ability to use the product on a trial basis buying it and or the transfer of their data and settings from an old computer to the new computer; a small business purchasing the same computer may value the availability of local repair services and procurement advice; and a large corporation with dedicated IT staff purchasing the computer may need none of these services. Different distribution channels tailored to different demand segments allow a manufacturer to efficiently satisfy these varied needs and desires. In many cases, this segmentation would not be possible were a manufacturer to sell entirely through distributors or entirely directly to consumers, or entirely through a single type of reseller.9 Aside from product and service specifications, dual and multi-channel distribution also allow manufacturers to optimize across location and delivery method while minimizing costs.10 For example, it may be most efficient for a company to sell directly to consumers in a dense urban area and to sell through a distributor in a more thinly-populated rural area.11 Again, this distribution strategy has a pro-competitive impact: a supplier reaches certain market segments at a lower cost than it can attain on its own, and thereby increases the degree of competition between brands in the marketplace. Additionally, the nature of a given product or market segment may require a company to take direct control of a particular channel, while other channels are more efficiently shared with intermediaries.12 For example, if a manufacturer of auto parts sells some proportion of its product to an auto manufacturer that uses the product as an intermediate input, the auto parts manufacturer may wish to control distribution directly to minimize the possibility of supply interruption. In contrast, the parts manufacturer may find it simpler to allow an intermediary to distribute that same part to its auto parts store and auto mechanic customers. Second, and relatedly, multi-channel distribution allows different channels to focus on marketing and selling efforts in which they have a comparative advantage. In many cases, local retailers have an informational advantage that allows them to more effectively engage in local advertising and selling efforts than a national manufacturer. However, a national brand may be able to run large advertising campaigns and target market segments that are difficult for a local retailer to reach. For example, a local HVAC retailer that sells Trane products likely has a better strategy for targeting and selling to local small businesses than Trane does. However, Trane itself can produce and run large advertising campaigns more effectively, and can compete for large corporate procurements. This sort of dynamic exists in many areas; distributors provide many services such as order processing, customer support, and 7 See Frank Mathewson and Ralph Winter, The Law and Economics of Resale7 Price Maintenance,” 13 Rev. Indus. Org. 67 (1998) (“Additional demand factors include: the number of outlets or availability of the product, the convenience of the outlet’s location, the information provided to customers at the point of sale, the sales effort and talent of dealers, the reputation of the product for quality, the prominence of the display of the product and so on.”). 8 Jain, supra note 5 at 338. 9Id. 10 Kotler, supra note 6 at 494. 11 Jain, supra note 5 at 340. 12 “Channel Management,” Cespedes, supra note 4 at Harvard Business School, Case Study No. 9-590-045, pp. 3–6, 8. March 2016 9 Distribution and Franchising Committee: ABA Section of Antitrust Law customer education that a manufacturer may be wellpositioned to deliver to some segments of the market but poorly-positioned to deliver to other segments.13 Indeed, in many cases, manufacturers add channels when they realize there are customers or market segments that they cannot effectively satisfy with existing channels.14 While product distribution through third-party retailers may be the most efficient solution for many manufacturers, others choose to integrate forward into direct sales to consumers for a number of reasons. First, a manufacturer-operated retail store allows the manufacturer to shape its brand image by controlling the shopping experience more closely and providing a broader selection of its goods. Nike and Apple are notable examples of this approach.15 Many large firms and brands have also decided to manage Internet sales of their products for the same reason. Estee Lauder, for example, decided to launch an Internet channel for its Clinique products as an alternative distribution method to traditional sales via department store cosmetics counters.16 Similarly, Apple manages its own online storefront and prohibits its bricks-and-mortar resellers from selling over the Internet.17 Second, a manufacturer that integrates forward into retail may be able to generate higher profit margins and expand output by eliminating double marginalization.18 Finally, direct selling provides closer contact with customers and customer information, improving supply chain efficiency by giving the manufacturer a better picture of market demand.19 Manufacturers that choose a dual distribution strategy are able to realize these benefits while simultaneously enjoying the benefits of third-party distribution in other market segments. This efficient 13 combination of distribution methods increases the manufacturer’s competitiveness in the market which, in turn, promotes inter-brand competition and improves consumer welfare. II. Resale Price Maintenance Can Facilitate Dual - and Multi-Channel Distribution and Enhance Interbrand Competition As part of a dual or multi-channel distribution strategy, manufacturers frequently impose vertical restraints, i.e., policies that limit the conduct of both the manufacturer and its downstream trading partners. These include policies such as resale price maintenance, minimum advertised prices, exclusive territories, and exclusive dealing. Minimum resale price maintenance (RPM)20 in particular can play a key role in facilitating successful dual and multi-channel distribution, as it provides the manufacturer with an instrument with which it can elicit the level of retail promotion services consistent with its objectives for its brand. First, manufacturers may use RPM to correct a wellknown market failure — the free rider problem — that can otherwise frustrate attempts to elicit competition in retail services to promote its products. A free rider is an economic agent who appropriates the benefits of another agent’s (costly) economic endeavors. The classic example involves a complex consumer durable good whose sale requires a knowledgeable salesperson to inform and persuade a consumer of the product’s merits. Suppose that, upon receiving the requisite information from the full-service retailer, the shopper leaves the store without making a purchase, travels to a discount operation that stocks the product the consumer now knows she wants, A. A. Tsay and N. Agrawal, Modeling Conflict and Coordination in Multi-Channel Distribution Systems: A Review, in Handbook of Quantitative Supply Chain Analysis: Modeling in the E-Business Era 558 (2004). 14 Jain, supra note 5 at 340. 15 Kevin Lane Keller, Brand equity management in a multichannel, multimedia retail environment. 24:2 J. Interactive Marketing 58-70 (2010). 16 Tsay, supra note 13 at 559. 17 Steve Tobak, How to Sell Like Apple, CBS News Moneywatch (May 13, 2010), available at http://www.cbsnews.com/news/how-to-sell-like-apple/. 18 Jean Tirole, The Theory of Industrial Organization, MIT Press (1988), pp. 174-175. 19 Tsay, supra note 13 at 558. 20 A minimum resale price maintenance agreement between a manufacturer and a retailer sets a minimum price that a retailer may charge for the manufacturer’s products. See Dennis W. Carlton and Jeffrey M. Perloff, Modern Industrial Oorganization 423 (4th ed 2004). March 2016 10 Distribution and Franchising Committee: ABA Section of Antitrust Law and buys it for a lower price. The lower price is possible because the buyer and ultimate seller can free-ride on (i.e., appropriate the benefits of) the full-service retailer’s costly investment in pre-sale service. In markets in which free-riding is common, sellers may reduce the level of services they provide because they do not receive adequate compensation in the form of a sufficient retail margin. Consumers in turn may reduce their participation in such markets because they do not receive adequate pre- or post-sale services. The upshot is a reduction of output, consumer welfare, and interbrand competition. In the extreme, the market for a desirable good (i.e., a good whose value exceeds its opportunity cost) can simply dissolve because of free-riding. RPM corrects the free-rider problem by requiring retailers of a manufacturer’s products to charge a minimum price that provides a profit margin sufficient to justify investment in pre-sale service, thereby thwarting discounters that seek to free-ride on other retailers.21 The effect of the policy is to enhance intrabrand service competition, limit intrabrand price competition, and increase interbrand competition. The use of RPM is not confined to markets for information-intensive consumer goods vulnerable to free-riding. Manufacturers also implement RPM pricing policies for goods that do not require detailed information or extensive product demonstration at the point of sale, or significant post-sale service commitments. Economics offers two theories to explain this phenomenon. Under the “quality certification” view of RPM, retailers may use protected margins to invest in greater services (e.g., longer hours of operation, nicer store furnishings, additional sales force training) that signal or certify the quality of their merchandise and increase demand for the manufacturer’s product.22 A second view explains RPM as a contract enforcement mechanism that a manufacturer adopts to assure that retailers supply non-contractible retail service that increases the demand for the manufacturer’s product. Where incomplete information and monitoring costs make writing and enforcing a complete and explicit performance contract with a retailer impractical, manufacturers may instead use RPM to elicit performance by retailers who are eager to retain the protected retail margin it affords.23 The problem of free-riding can be a particular concern in cases where there is dual distribution. The fact that the retailer and the manufacturer have different incentives, business models, and cost structures can increase the likelihood of conflict between the retailer and manufacturer and increase the incentives to free-ride. Therefore, to have an effective dual distribution system, a manufacturer can use RPM to reduce conflicts and eliminate free-riding. A. Manufacturers Selling Directly to Consumers Have Incentives Consistent with Interbrand Competition Manufacturers who sell directly to consumers do not have the same incentive to free-ride as non-affiliated retailers. This is because the manufacturer internalizes the impact of its actions on the brand as a whole. While any individual third-party retailer has an incentive to reduce its provision of service and reduce its price to undercut other retailers of the manufacturer’s products, the manufacturer will not engage in such behavior itself because it recognizes that this behavior is inconsistent with the long-term competitiveness of its brand. This is one reason why some manufacturers, particularly those who are concerned with the provision of service or the consistency of their brand image, may choose to control the online sales of their products: whereas thirdparty Internet retailers have an incentive to free ride on the services provided by bricks-and-mortar stores, the manufacturer does not. 21 Lester G. Tesler, Why should manufacturers want fair trade? 3 J. Law and Econ. 86-105 (1960). 22 See Howard P.Marvel and Stephen McCafferty, Resale price maintenance and quality certification, 15 RAND J. Econ. 346-359 (1984). 23 See Benjamin Klein and Kevin M. Murphy, Vertical restraints as contract enforcement mechanisms, 31 J. Law and Econ. 265-297 (1988); Benjamin Klein, Competitive Resale Price Maintenance in the Absence of Free Riding, 76 Antitrust L.J. 431-481 (2009). March 2016 11 Distribution and Franchising Committee: ABA Section of Antitrust Law This distinction between the incentives of the manufacturer (in its role as a direct-to-consumer seller) and third-party retailers is perhaps best illustrated through examples. As the following examples show, RPM policies can be useful to manufacturers with different retail strategies. However, in both examples, an RPM policy allows the manufacturer to implement a dual distribution strategy that increases interbrand competition. and education. Since the manufacturer is concerned with the long-term profitability and strength of its brand, it prices its online sales at a level that internalizes the impact of online sales on service. In doing so, it may, for example, choose to sell online only at MSRP. By supporting the provision of service and education, this arrangement may strengthen the competitiveness of the cosmetic manufacturer’s brand and thereby enhance inter-brand competition. B. Example: Dual Distribution Online and Through Specialty Stores C. Example: Multi-Channel Distribution through Online and Retail Direct Channels and Multiple Third-Party Retail Channels As a first example, consider a manufacturer of high-end cosmetics that sells products both through beauticians (specialty bricks-and-mortar stores) and through its own website. This manufacturer sells (offline) only through beauticians because it wants to make sure that customers are provided with the service and education needed to properly use the manufacturer’s products. Suppose the manufacturer sells its products to beautician retailers at prices substantially below the manufacturer’s suggested retail price (MSRP). The gap between the wholesale price and MSRP is meant to cover the costs that retailers will incur in providing service related to the manufacturer’s products. However, in this situation, each individual retailer has an incentive to set up an online storefront and sell the manufacturer’s products at discounted prices below MSRP, because the retailer does not incur the costs of service and education in sales to online customers. To protect against this type of free riding, the manufacturer may put in place an RPM policy to keep retailers from selling online at deep discounts. At first blush, the need to prohibit retailers from selling at deep discounts online (and therefore not providing in-store service) may seem inconsistent with the manufacturer itself selling its products online. But the key difference is that the manufacturer, when it sells online, does not have the same incentive to free ride on the service and education provided by the bricks-andmortar retailers. When pricing its own online sales, the manufacturer weighs the direct profits from online sales against the broader impact of those sales on the ability of the bricks-and-mortar beauticians to provide service March 2016 As a second example, consider a manufacturer of computers and electronics that sells its products to consumers directly both online and in manufactureroperated retail stores, and indirectly through a variety of third-party retailers, including big-box electronics stores and small businesses that focus on repair and sales of the manufacturer’s products. Much like the cosmetics manufacturer described above, this manufacturer chooses to sell through vendors that it believes will adequately convey its brand and educate consumers about its products. As part of its retail strategy, this manufacturer also introduces an RPM policy to eliminate the possibility of discounted online sales by third parties. This policy is meant to prevent third parties from free-riding on the brand-building activity conducted by the manufacturer. Since the manufacturer has a strong incentive to ensure a positive customer experience that will generate repeat purchases, and since it benefits from customer purchases regardless of channel, the manufacturer has chosen to invest substantial capital in the development of its website, with professionally-produced videos explaining its products and beautifully-designed interfaces that generate a premium shopping experience. A third-party online seller does not share the manufacturer’s incentive to create a premium online shopping experience, because it cannot completely internalize the return from that investment. Instead, it has an incentive to minimize its costs associated with the online sale of the manufacturer’s brand and free-ride on the positive 12 Distribution and Franchising Committee: ABA Section of Antitrust Law brand image and national marketing conducted by the manufacturer. By setting a minimum resale price, the manufacturer removes the ability of third party online retailers to free ride on the manufacturer’s brand building activities by undercutting the manufacturer on price. The RPM policy also incentivizes third party online sellers to compete, both with each other and with the manufacturer, on the quality of the online shopping experience, which benefits consumer welfare. The RPM policy therefore helps the manufacturer eliminate online customer experiences that would damage its brand, thus improving its ability to compete in the long term against other consumer electronics manufacturers. III. Conclusion differentiated goods and services to different customer segments efficiently and permit them to delegate tasks such as order processing and customer support that may be difficult for them to complete in a cost effective manner. However, retailer free-riding and difficulty in obtaining non-contractible retail services can compromise these benefits and undermine dual and multi-channel distribution. RPM policies can support dual and multi-channel distribution and increase interbrand competition. Thus, when analyzing RPM under the rule of reason, the presence of dual and multi-channel distribution — and its attendant benefits to consumers and competition — should be taken into account. Dual and multi-channel distribution strategies, when working as intended, allow manufacturers to deliver March 2016 13 Distribution and Franchising Committee: ABA Section of Antitrust Law The 2016 FTC Auto Distribution Workshop: An Insider’s Take by Steven Cernak On January 19, 2016, the FTC held a workshop on how auto distribution trends might impact current or potential regulation. While some of the issues covered were unique to this industry, many apply to all industries. Here, I offer a few comments based on my years dealing with these laws. These comments do not necessarily represent the views of any past, present, or future client, employer, or colleague. Background – These laws and other government involvement date back decades FTC Chairwoman Edith Ramirez kicked off the workshop by describing the FTC’s long history of review of the auto industry, pointing to the FTC’s 1939 report on the industry (the report is now available on the workshop’s website—the section on distribution begins on p. 106).1 While it is correct that the FTC been involved in the industry for decades, I think the government review of the industry that had a more direct influence on regulation of car distribution is the 1955 Senate Judiciary Committee investigation into the antitrust laws that ended up focusing on General Motors.2 Many GM business practices were reviewed, including alleged mistreatment of its car dealers. During the hearings, GM announced that it would change the length of its standard dealer sales and service agreement from 1 year to 5 years, a move that soon became an industry standard. That change was in response to complaints that GM and others used the threat of non-renewal to drive dealer behavior. In 1956, the federal Dealer Day in Court Act (15 U.S.C. § 1222) was passed. The Act imposed a good faith requirement on manufacturers when performing or terminating their agreements with dealers. As dealers determined that the federal law did not provide enough protection, they turned to the states. While some state laws governing the manufacturer/ dealer relationship date back to the 1930s, many more and stronger laws were passed beginning in the 1960s and 1970s. It is those laws that the FTC workshop covered. Those laws vary, but they all impose limitations on when and how a manufacturer can decide to terminate, move, or fail to renew an existing dealer. In some cases, they also allow the dealer to appoint a successor. The laws also regulate other aspects of the manufacturer’s relationship with a dealer, including how the dealer is compensated for performing warranty repairs. As has been publicized recently, some of these laws also prevent an end run around the regulation by forbidding any sales of cars to consumers except through dealers. “Dealers: Good or Bad?” is not the right question to ask Before the event, I feared the debates would devolve into “dealers are good and so the state laws protecting them are good” and its opposite. Unfortunately, I think most of the dealer and state law defenders did just that. Fortunately, the others (especially the economists) focused on the more relevant question: Whether or not 1 https://www.ftc.gov/news-events/events-calendar/2016/01/auto-distribution-current-issues-future-trends. 2 http://www.autonews.com/article/20060925/SUB/60919020/government-tips-scales-for-dealers-automakers. March 2016 14 Distribution and Franchising Committee: ABA Section of Antitrust Law auto dealers are good or bad, what is unique about them to justify state laws that override their agreements with manufacturers and require manufacturers to only sell through them? Future technology—and its implications for regulations—are still in the, uh, future If you read press releases from the recent Consumer Electronics Show or Detroit Auto Show, then you might think that it is only a matter of months before we will all be pushing a button on a smartphone and calling up some Jetsons-like car. Thankfully, the panel on future trends in the industry was much more realistic about the pace of technological change. (For my own part, I’ll point out that the research joint venture on advanced batteries for electric vehicles that I helped negotiate is nearly twenty-five years old.)3 Yes, change is coming, and maybe more quickly than in the past, but there still are technical and, especially, customer acceptance hurdles to leap. have been tried in the past and abandoned as too complex for mass market vehicles. That does not mean that state laws should prevent such efforts or that they are doomed to fail again—but hopefully others have learned from those who went before them (or are at least aware of their efforts). You could have held this conference ten (or more) years ago Very few of the topics—warranty reimbursement, add points, dealer terminations, even direct distribution — have anything to do with electric vehicles, autonomous vehicles, or ride-sharing. Heck, I debated warranty reimbursement in New Jersey with one of the panelists before either one of us had grey hair. Many industry lawyers, now long-retired, spent entire careers working on these issues. I’m glad newcomers to the industry have sparked interest in the issues by the FTC, academics and even mainstream media,4 but I can’t help wondering: What took you so long? More relevant to the workshop, the implications of those technological changes are not certain, and so the proper policies and regulations are not clear either. For instance, one speaker pointed out that autonomous vehicles will reduce the cost (at least in terms of time) of driving, and so those vehicles probably will be driven more miles— but whether those vehicles will be owned and operated by individuals, fleets, the government, or some peerto-peer company isn’t clear. These panelists just urged regulators to understand what they know—and don’t know—about new technology before regulating. Great job by the FTC The automotive industry didn’t start in 2003 Steve Cernak was on the General Motors Legal Staff from 19892012. Since then, he has been Of Counsel in the Ann Arbor Office of Schiff Hardin. He is a Council Member of the ABA Antitrust Section. It was helpful to hear industry veterans like Maryann Keller and Jim Anderson remind the audience that building vehicles to order and distributing them directly The FTC does a fine job of advocating on behalf of competition and consumers in front of state legislatures and international enforcers. Sometimes, the methods5 chosen lead to unintended consequences.6 But efforts like this workshop to bring together industry participants and experts to “prompt meaningful dialogue” (as Chairwoman Ramirez said) go a long way to “protect consumers and promote competition” without any new regulation.7 3 http://uscar.org/guest/teams/12/U-S-Advanced-Battery-Consortium-LLC. 4 http://www.usnews.com/opinion/economic-intelligence/2015/01/19/laws-protecting-auto-franchises-are-bad-for-consumers-and-innovation. 5 http://antitrustconnect.com/2015/04/13/phoebe-putney-nc-board-winning-legal-battles-not-hearts-and-minds/. 6 http://antitrustconnect.com/2015/08/19/slower-crony-capitalism-the-immediate-aftermath-of-nc-board/. 7 https://www.ftc.gov/about-ftc/what-we-do. March 2016 15 Distribution and Franchising Committee: ABA Section of Antitrust Law Summary of FTC Workshop Auto–Distribution: Current Issues and Future Trends by Anna Aryankalayil 1 On January 19, 2016, the Federal Trade Commission (“FTC”) hosted an all day workshop to discuss issues related to the regulation of motor vehicle distribution in the United States. The workshop was organized around four panels that presented the perspectives of attorneys, economists, and representatives of auto manufacturers and dealers. The panels addressed the rationale for state regulation of the manufacturer/dealer relationship, the impact of that regulation on competition and consumers, and how emerging technologies and distribution practices may affect the current regulatory regime. FTC Chairwoman Edith Ramirez and former FTC Bureau of Economics director Francine Lafontaine opened the workshop by providing a historical perspective on the FTC’s role in auto distribution dating back to 1939. And, Professor Dennis Carlton delivered the Keynote Address, in which he provided an economic perspective on the “state action doctrine.” This article summarizes the key issues and the opposing viewpoints expressed in each of the four panels and briefly summarizes the respective remarks by Chairwoman Ramirez, Dr. Lafontaine, and Dr. Carlton. The workshop demonstrated that there continues to be substantial disagreement on the need for regulation of the manufacturer/dealer relationship, with battle lines clearly drawn between dealers and manufacturers. Panelists advocating for the dealers expressed concern about an imbalance of power in a relationship in which dealers are locked in to certain manufacturers as a result of relationship-specific investments. Those advocating for the manufacturers expressed concern with the effect of regulation on manufacturers’ ability to address dealer performance and to customize their distribution practices in a dynamic industry where potentially revolutionary 1 developments like autonomous cars are already on the horizon. Economists recognized merit in both sides’ positions, but tended to be skeptical overall that the problems presented in auto distribution were unique or unsolvable by contract. Ultimately, the workshop was a productive forum for interested parties to express their views, to challenge their adversaries’ arguments, and to sharpen their own, but little consensus was reached, and FTC signaled no clear change in policy. I. Opening Remarks In her opening remarks, FTC Chairwoman Edith Ramirez explained that the current system of auto distribution has remained essentially unchanged for the past 80 years. The current state regulatory regime is a result of dealers turning to their state legislatures for protection against what they believed were abusive and coercive practices by manufacturers. Dealers who had made large, manufacturer-specific investments became concerned that they would be at the mercy of their affiliated manufacturers-- especially with few manufactures available as alternatives prior to entry of foreign competitors. Chairwoman Ramirez noted that while some regulation may be beneficial and necessary, regulation can also have detrimental consequences for consumers if it harms competition or stifles innovation. She called on the FTC to continue to consider whether the state laws are necessary to protect dealers against abuses by manufacturers. Former FTC Bureau of Economics director Francine Lafontaine noted that there are today about half as many automobile dealerships as thirty years ago, which she Anna Aryankalayil is an Antitrust Associate in Dechert LLP’s Washington, D.C. office. The statements in this article do not necessarily represent the views of the author, Dechert LLP, or its clients. March 2016 16 Distribution and Franchising Committee: ABA Section of Antitrust Law attributed primarily to the loss of smaller dealerships that may have sold gasoline and other things in addition to vehicles. Dr. Lafontaine further noted that most laws concerning dealer termination and non-renewal/ continuation were not in place until about 1979, and that even at that time, only about half of the states had laws that provided dealers with ability to object to establishment of a new nearby dealership. By 2009, however, all 50 states had laws governing termination and non-renewal, and all but three states had laws regulating establishment of new dealerships. Dr. Lafontaine discussed a study she conducted with Fiona Scott-Morton in 2009, in which she compared GM’s dealer network, which was put in place before state regulation, and the network of newer entrant Toyota, which was put in place after such laws were already on the books. Her study found that GM dealerships were located closer to each other, were not necessarily located near to areas of population growth, and were selling on average about a half to a third as many cars as the Toyota dealerships. Dr. Lafontaine suggests that these results could support the view that state regulation may make dynamic adjustments in the franchise system too difficult. She queried whether there is a way that dealer investments can be protected while also providing for dynamic adjustments to the dealer network. Teeing up issues for later panels, Dr. Lafontaine expressed interest in empirical results of recent changes in regulation on warranty reimbursement, and asked why manufacturers would find it beneficial to outsource distribution, why they would choose to do so under a franchise system, and why any law should prevent a manufacturer from dealing direct if the manufacturer found that model beneficial. II. Panel 1: State Regulation of Dealer Networks Moderated by James Frost and Patrick Roach of the FTC, the first panel featured Jim Anderson of Urban Science, Carl Chiappa of Hogan Lovells, Aaron Jacoby of Arent Fox, Joseph Roesner or Fontana Group, and 2 Professor Henry Schneider of Cornell.2 The panelists debated why state regulation of dealer networks is necessary and what effects such regulation has on competition and consumers. The panel noted that all 50 states regulate the manufacturer/dealer relationship, with the three most litigated issues being: dealer terminations, establishing a new dealership, and re-locating an existing dealer. These laws override private contracting, permit dealers to obtain stays without a showing otherwise required of plaintiffs seeking a preliminary injunction, and permit government oversight over manufacturer actions under a “good cause” standard that also includes considerations of consumer convenience and public welfare. In this contentious debate, Carl Chiappa, representing the dealer perspective, argued that existing “one-size-fitsall” regulations are too blunt an instrument for a dynamic industry in which manufacturers are often growing at different rates and in which they have differentiated competitive strategies (e.g., luxury vs. high-volume). Mr. Chiappa also noted that the laws have not changed over the years to reflect changing circumstances such as the effect of dealer consolidation or the impact of the internet on retail. Mr. Chiappa further argued that, instead of serving to promote dealer investments, the state laws can have the opposite effect as manufacturers lack the means to reward dealers that invest in better service or facilities, or deter poor performance by dealers. He further noted that the process to resolve disputes is so lengthy that it ends in settlements in which the manufacturer effectively has to pay a tax to incumbent dealers in order to take the steps necessary to be competitive with other manufacturers. On the other side of the debate, Aaron Jacoby noted that the auto industry is an important economic sector similar to health care, telecom, shipping, and transportation, all of which are regulated. He noted that the auto industry can act as a substantial drag on the economy, as it did James Frost, Office of Policy & Coordination, FTC; Patrick Roach, Office of Policy Planning, FTC; Jim Anderson, Founder, President & CEO, Urban Science; Carl Chiappa, Partner, Hogan Lovells; Aaron Jacoby, Partner, Arent Fox; Joseph Roesner, President, Fontana Group; Professor Henry Schneider, Cornell University. March 2016 17 Distribution and Franchising Committee: ABA Section of Antitrust Law during the Great Recession, or substantially bolster the economy in better times. Reading the legislative intent from the California laws, Mr. Jacoby further noted that regulation ensures a well-organized distribution system in which warranty, recall, and repair facilities are available to maintain vehicles. Mr. Jacoby also argued that regulation was necessary to curb abuses by manufacturers and to deal with unequal bargaining power because dealers are small and are prohibited by antitrust from collective bargaining. He rejected the idea that consolidation had changed this imbalance of bargaining power because even consolidators negotiate each dealership agreement separately. Mr. Jacoby further emphasized that state regulation merely provides objective third party oversight by experienced state boards and does not give any dealer absolute veto rights. And Mr. Roesner added that state franchise laws merely create a process to analyze manufacturer decisions on termination, add-points and relocation, but do not prohibit such actions. Manufacturers need only show “good cause,” and oversight prevents arbitrary behavior by manufacturers. Jim Anderson of Urban Science noted that the franchise system works relatively well for dealers, manufacturers and consumers, and that a dispute resolution system is necessary, but expressed concern that the current process is too slow and expensive. Professor Schneider acknowledged that dealers have some legitimate concerns, but opined that long term contracts could address them. From an economic perspective, state regulations impose serious costs and make it harder to for manufacturers to adjust to a change in demand (i.e., relocating a dealership in response to demographic shifts) and it becomes harder to reach economies of scale (i.e., consolidating dealerships). 3 III. Panel 2: Warranty Reimbursement Regulation The second panel discussed the merits of state laws governing the rates by which dealers are reimbursed for services the dealers provide to consumers pursuant to manufacturer warranties. These state laws can require manufacturers to pay the same retail prices for parts and labor that individual consumers pay for non-warranty work. The panel discussed whether such regulation was necessary and how it impacted prices that consumers pay for cars. The session was moderated by Nathan Wilson and James Frost of the FTC and the panelists were James Appleton of the New Jersey Coalition of Automotive Retailers; attorneys Daniel L. Goldberg of Morgan, Lewis & Bockius, and Richard Sox of Bass Sox Mercer, and Professor David Sappington of the University of Florida.3 Panelists reflecting the dealer perspective took the position that state regulation is necessary because of the imbalance in bargaining power between manufacturers and dealers and that state regulation merely assures that the dealer is paid the market rate. Mr. Appleton argued that regulation encourages investments necessary to ensure that dealers provide adequate warranty services that consumers need. He further noted that manufacturers view warranty work as only an expense while dealers see it as a revenue opportunity that encourages them to compete for that work. If manufacturers were permitted to pay less than retail for warranty work, it would result in increased consumer costs of non-warranty work or decrease the quality of dealer’s service. Mr. Appleton further noted that, in states where reimbursement rates are regulated, manufacturers already impose surcharges on dealers that Nathan Wilson, Bureau of Economics, FTC; James Frost, Office of Policy & Coordination, FTC; James Appleton, President, New Jersey Coalition of Automotive Retailers; Daniel L. Goldberg, Partner, Morgan, Lewis & Bockius LLP; Professor David Sappington, University of Florida; Richard Sox, Partner, Bass Sox Mercer. March 2016 18 Distribution and Franchising Committee: ABA Section of Antitrust Law more than cover their costs of reimbursing dealers for warranty work. Mr. Sox added that manufacturers had capped reimbursement on warranty repairs during a period of time in which manufacturers were increasing dealer overhead costs through certain demands for facilities upgrades and requirements to keep fleets of loaner vehicles, and that repair costs had also increased due to the need to obtain specialized technician training and specialized diagnostic equipment to repair more sophisticated vehicles. Mr. Sox noted that dealers cannot refuse warranty work, and thus must incur these overhead costs without knowing how much warranty work they will actually get. Because a dealer must cover all of this overhead, it is incorrect to think of a dealer markup on warranty services as profit. Dan Goldberg, representing the manufacturers’ perspective argued that it is unusual for states to set minimum pricing for any good or service. He queried why a manufacturer should have to pay any markup, much less retail, on a part that the manufacturer was itself providing to the dealer for the warranty repair. The natural solution should be that the manufacturer would just provide the part for free so that neither side is paying any markup on the part. Mr. Goldberg further argued that manufacturers would not offer warranties unless it provided them an advantage in competing for car buyers, and so they have a competitive incentive to ensure that dealers are properly incented to do the warranty work. Mr. Golberg pushed back on the imbalance of power argument, noting that dealers, on average, net $1 million in profit a year and there are very large dealer entities making billions of dollars a year. Although there are some small dealers, because manufacturers adopt nationwide policies, he argued that small dealers are being protected by the large dealers. He was troubled by the notion that dealers are victims of warranty obligations when it is a profit center for them and helps to drive repeat business that could translate into new 4 car sales. Regarding balance of power, he suggested that the dealers have influence with local legislatures due to their local presence and local employment whereas manufacturers have facilities only in distant states. He even suggested that perhaps the real reason for warranty reimbursement regulation was to maintain the revenue stream to dealers that had otherwise been declining due to better performing cars that needed fewer repairs. Professor Sappington, offering an economic perspective, was skeptical of the argument that an imbalance of power created a market failure necessitating regulation. He saw manufacturers and dealers working more cooperatively as a team in competition with other manufacturers and dealers. He saw this team-based competition as providing sufficient incentives for manufacturers and dealers to agree on mutually beneficial warranty reimbursement terms that serve their joint competitive efforts. He further noted that regulation could create perverse incentives such as encouraging dealers to raise non-warranty rates so that their reimbursements are higher on warranty rates. IV. Panel 3: Direct Distribution The third panel debated why state regulation should prohibit direct distribution or direct service by manufacturers. Patrick Roach and Paolo Ramezzana of the FTC moderated the panel, which featured Professor Dan Crane, consultant Maryann Keller, Todd Maron of Tesla Motors, Joel Sheltrown of Elio Motors, and private attorneys Steven McKelvey of Nelson Mullins and Paul Norman of Boardman & Clark.4 Mr. Maron explained that Tesla prefers direct distribution because its stores are located in urban, high foot traffic areas, while traditional dealers are located in out-ofthe way suburban locations, and Tesla does not need inventory because each vehicle is built to the buyer’s specifications. While dealers tend to make high-volume, fast-paced deals, buying a Tesla is a more time-intensive process that requires Tesla to educate the customer about Patrick Roach, Office of Policy Planning, FTC; Paolo Ramezzana, Bureau of Economics, FTC; Professor Dan Crane, University of Michigan; Maryann Keller, Managing Partner, Maryann Keller & Associates; Todd Maron, General Counsel, Tesla Motors; Steven McKelvey, Partner, Nelson Mullins; Paul Norman, Partner, Boardman & Clark; Joel Sheltrown, Vice President of Government Affairs, Elio Motors. March 2016 19 Distribution and Franchising Committee: ABA Section of Antitrust Law the unique circumstance of owning an electronic vehicle. Tesla vehicles have fewer parts than gas-powered vehicles and Tesla does not finance the purchase, so the typical profit centers for dealers are not available. Tesla also does not advertise and would not be able to co-fund dealer advertising. Thus, there is little for Tesla to offer a franchised dealer, and little for Tesla to gain from the relationship. Mr. Maron noted that very few states prohibit direct distribution, but remarked that these prohibitions only exist in the United States. He saw opposition to direct distribution coming from dealer groups and from traditional manufacturers and saw both as protectionist. Joel Sheltrown of Elio Motors described how his company’s autocycles are different from other vehicles due to their low $6,800 target price, and next-day delivery model. Elio found that 25% of retail price is in advertising and dealer network, and Elio wants to cut those costs through by using 60 retail centers with servicing provided by Pep Boys. Maryan Keller provided her perspective as an industry participant for over 30 years, and noted that there is nothing new about direct distribution. Manufacturers like Ford previously tried the model and found that a franchise system provided better value. She disputed the argument that direct distribution necessarily is lower cost, noting that Ford increased costs through its retail network, and that respective specialization on manufacturing and sales can be efficient. She also expressed skepticism that made-to-order assembly could compete with the engineering involved in traditional manufacturing, and noted the benefits of dealers competing in intra-brand competition in which they have more flexibility to meet consumer needs than a one-sizefits-all manufacturer model. Paul Norman also spoke in support of such state laws based on the principles of federalism. He noted that state franchise laws should be given much deference 5 by federal agencies such as the FTC. He also credited the state franchise laws for promoting intra-brand competition. Professor Crane explained that there is no need for public policy to favor a certain method of distribution over another. The method of distribution itself is a component of competition. Laws that entrench incumbents chill innovation because new technologies may require new methods of distribution. Professor Crane called existing laws “dealer protection” and not consumer protection. In fact, vertical integration means lower prices for consumers because, at the very least, it avoids double marginalization. V. Panel 4: Future Trends The final panel was moderated by Ellen Connelly and Patrick Roach of the FTC, and the panelists were Avery Ash, Ashwini Chhabra, Robbie Diamond, Professor Fiona Scott-Morton, Professor Bryant Walker Smith, and Peter Welch.5 The panelists considered whether existing regulatory regimes need to change to accommodate new technologies such as autonomous vehicles and car sharing services like Uber and Lyft that have become more prevalent. Panelists opined that accelerated trends may shift purchasing of automobiles from individuals to fleet purchasers. This may negate some of the historical reasons for state regulations as fleet purchasers may choose to deal with manufacturers directly. On-air repairs directly from the manufacturer could minimize the need for warranty reimbursement regulation. Panelists generally agreed that given the uncertainty of the scope of new technologies, a regulatory regime built for the future must be flexible enough to both accommodate new technology and not chill yet further innovation. Dr. Scott-Morton noted that we already are having trouble permitting direct distribution, which does not bode well for the flexibility that will be required for new technologies. Panelists expressed concerns about interest group capture of regulations to deter innovation, Ellen Connelly, Office of Policy Planning, FTC; Patrick Roach, Office of Policy Planning, FTC; Avery Ash, Director of Federal Relations, American Automobile Association; Ashwini Chhabra, Head of Policy Development, Uber Technologies; Robbie Diamond, Founder, President and CEO, Securing America’s Future Energy; Professor Fiona Scott Morton, Yale University; Professor Bryant Walker Smith, University of South Carolina; Peter Welch, President, National Automobile Dealers Association. March 2016 20 Distribution and Franchising Committee: ABA Section of Antitrust Law but Mr. Welch expressed his faith in state regulators to develop good public policy. VI. Keynote Address Professor Dennis Carlton6 presented the keynote address on the broader topic of “state action” immunity, which he described as a doctrine that allows states to take actions that would violate the antitrust laws if conducted by individuals. Dr. Carlton suggested certain economic justifications for the doctrine: such as the rationale that, if everyone is participating in the political process, the state’s action must be the right result, or that if a state makes a mistake, citizens can move to a different state that offers better policy. He characterized this rationale as “flimsy” because there are significant costs to moving, legislation often reflects influence of special interests, and because the policy of one state may have externalities on citizens in another state who have no ability to participate in the first state’s legislative process. Dr. Carlton warned that the real danger of state action is that it may be an invitation for special interest legislation. Special interest legislation distorts the competitive process by favoring one group over others, leading to inefficiency. Dr. Carlton suggested that, if legally possible, the state action should be modified such that it 6 does not apply to state action that harms a person in a different state nor to state action that has no cognizable benefits. He observed that the FTC is on the right track by restricting the application of state action doctrine to circumstances where there is clear articulation by the state and close state supervision. He also invited the FTC to study the incidence of how special interest legislation is affected by corruption and campaign contributions. He observed that it would be useful to explicitly evaluate the effect of special interest legislation on consumers’ prices and the quality of their goods. Although he had not planned on addressing auto distribution specifically, Dr. Carlton responded to the first two panels by disputing the argument that regulation is required because an industry is important or that regulation is rendered harmless because there will be a neutral fact-finder reviewing disputes. He also rejected the argument that regulation is necessary to make things fair between manufacturers and dealers since the concept of fairness has no guiding principle. Moreover, he did not see any market failure or other special circumstance that would require regulation of auto distribution as opposed to any other industry. David McDaniel Keller Professor of Economics, Booth School of Business, University of Chicago. March 2016 21