NEGATIVE FEEDBACK, POLICY COALITIONS, AND POLICY CHANGE Alan M. Jacobs Department of Political Science University of British Columbia C425-1866 Main Mall Vancouver, B.C. V6T 1Z1, Canada jacobs@politics.ubc.ca R. Kent Weaver Georgetown University and The Brookings Institution 1775 Massachusetts Ave, NW Washington, DC 20036 KWEAVER@brookings.edu Abstract The concept of policy feedback has become central to the study of policymaking. This paper seeks to advance the analysis of policy feedback in three principal ways. First, it argues that the current literature on policy feedback overemphasizes positive feedback at the expense of negative feedback. Negative feedback effects, we contend, are common and have important implications for policy development over time. Second, we theorize a set of mechanisms through which the adverse consequences of policy can feed back into politics to generate pressure for policy change. The paper focuses on mechanisms that affect the formation of mass- and elite-level coalitions for and against policy change. Third, we suggest important ways in which negative feedback mechanisms and their effects depend upon specific features of the political and social context. A systematic account of policy development over time must be informed by claims about to the conditions under which negative, in combination with or in lieu of positive, feedback effects are most likely to operate. A short account of the recent evolution of the U.S. health care policy is employed to illustrate these analytical arguments. By illuminating the causal logic and importance of self-undermining policy dynamics, the paper seeks to contribute to a burgeoning literature on the endogenous sources of policy and institutional change. 2 Over the past two decades, the related concepts of policy feedback and path dependence have become central to the study of policymaking in democracies (see, e.g., Skocpol 1992; Pierson 1993, 1994; Hacker 1998, 2002). The key insight of this approach is that past policy choices shape, and in particular limit, later policy choices and outputs. The analysis of feedback effects has generated a large number of persuasive explanations of current policy arrangements and of policy development over time. This paper shares the perspective that policy feedback is an important influence on public policy, but seeks to advance the analysis of policy development by illuminating the importance of negative policy feedback and the mechanisms through which it operates. It is widely recognized that public policies almost universally impose costs on citizens as well as delivering valued benefits. What is far less widely acknowledged is that degree to which those costs can generate political processes that undermine the status quo and raise the likelihood of policy change. In this paper, we argue that there are strong reasons, inherent in the logic of policymaking in a democracy, to expect such negative policy effects to be common. At the same time, there is nothing automatic about the translation of policy losses or policy “failure” into political incentives or opportunities to enact policy change. We thus seek to analytically unpack a set of mechanisms through which negative feedback is likely to operate and influence governments’ policy choices. Our focus here is on the ways in which policy losses can alter the coalitional politics of policy change: the processes through which mounting policy burdens can both expand the group and mass-level coalitions for policy change and diminish those opposed to it. The processes that we identify operate through three principal channels: via the mobilization of social interests; via mass-level political cognition; and via changes in the menu of available policy alternatives. Throughout the paper, we employ case examples to illustrate the broad relevance of these feedback logics and their potential to generate policy change. We further demonstrate the fruitfulness of analytical attention to negative feedback through a more extended case study of a domain commonly associated with strong path dependence: health care policy in the United States. As other analysts have demonstrated, the repeated failure of attempts to introduce universal health insurance in the United States can be substantially attributed to positive feedback effects of fateful choices (and non-choices) made at points earlier in the 20th century (see, especially,Hacker 1998). At the same time, we argue that the dramatic policy change represented by the passage of the Affordable Care Act of 2010 can be substantially explained by the types of negative feedback mechanisms that we identify. Through their effects on the alignment of organized interests, on citizens’ assessments of the alternatives, and on the policy menu, the mounting adverse consequences of the pre-reform system of medical insurance, we contend, expanded the coalition of actors willing to support reform and diminished the array of forces opposed to it – enabling enactment even in a system riddled with institutional veto points. The aim of this paper is not to emphasize the importance of negative feedback at the expense of positive feedback. It is, rather, to expand our understanding of the ways in which public policies can produce their own politics: of the ways in which policy choices at t1 can generate consequences at t2 that can reshape the political prospects of policy alternatives at t3. In short, we seek to highlight and unpack the ways in which such 2 endogenous processes can be self-undermining as well as self-reinforcing.1 An understanding of policy development over time that integrates and analyzes both negative and positive policy feedback can help to address one of the most important limitations of a feedback approach focused solely on self-reinforcing dynamics: that it has difficulty explaining major change without ad hoc reliance on exogenous shocks. In this sense, our approach is in line with recent historical-institutionalist work concerned with identifying endogenous sources of institutional change (e.g., Streeck and Thelen 2005; Mahoney and Thelen 2009b). In making the case for serious consideration of negative as well as positive feedback effects, we seek to push analysts to do more than acknowledge that both types of effects can occur. Any systematic account of endogenous policy development over time must rest on an understanding of the conditions under which particular kinds of feedback effects are most likely to operate. The literature on positive feedback has gone a considerable distance toward identifying (or, at least, hypothesizing) those circumstances most conducive to path dependence: policies, for instance, that encourage societal actors to make investments with high fixed costs are understood to be more prone to selfreinforcement over time than those that do not (Pierson 2000; Patashnik 2008; Patashnik and Zelizer 2009). Similarly, for each negative-feedback mechanism outlined, this paper advances tentative propositions about the conditions under which it is likely to operate most strongly. The first section of the paper focuses on clarifying the concepts of positive and negative feedback and their potential relationships to policy stability and policy change. 1 While our approach is different, our concern is similar to Greif and Laitin’s in exploring the endogenous sources of institutional stability and change (2004) 3 The four sections that follow then theorize specific negative feedback mechanisms and suggest the kinds of conditions most conducive to their operation. The sixth section shows how this analysis can explain the evolution of U.S. health care reform policy over the past two decades. The conclusion reviews the major implications of our arguments and suggests directions for future research. DEFINING NEGATIVE FEEDBACK As we will use the term, policy feedback describes the following causal process: a policy chosen at t1 has effects at t2 that influences the relative likelihood of policy alternatives (including maintenance of the status quo) being chosen at t3. Following Pierson (2004), we define positive policy feedback as a processes in which the policy effects at t2 increase the relative benefits (or reduce the relative costs) of the policy arrangements to influential political actors as compared to the conceivable policy alternatives. The historical-institutionalist literature commonly depicts mechanisms of positive feedback as conducive to the outcome of stability – a process that, over time, “makes it more difficult to reverse course” (Pierson 2004). As Thelen (2004) writes, “…[I]ncreasing returns and positive feedback arguments…have been more helpful in understanding the sources of institutional resiliency than in yielding insights into institutional change” (27-28). In parallel with the above definition of positive feedback, we then define negative feedback effects as policy effects at t2 that raise the relative costs (or reduce the relative benefits) of the status quo for politically influential actors. Consistent with the existing literature, we understand these costs and benefits in broad terms: involving not just fiscal 4 impacts and economic costs and benefits imposed on particular groups in society, but also the political risks and rewards faced by officeholders and the administrative ease or difficulty with which policy options can be implemented. Indeed, we understand policy change in a democracy as arising ultimately from processes that raise the benefits (e.g., in terms of career or sincere policy preferences) or reduce the costs of policy change for officeholders. Those relative benefits, however, will be substantially determined by the relative costs and benefits of policy change (real or perceived) to coalitions of those organized and unorganized constituencies on whose support officeholders depend or whose welfare they seek to advance. We thus focus the analysis to come on the ways in which negative feedback alters the alignment of coalitions favoring and opposing policy change. Prominent arguments in the discipline imply that feedback effects are largely positive. In his seminal work on the logic of historical analysis, Pierson (1993, 2000, 2004) begins by noting a set of economic insights into the sources of increasing returns and path-dependent development in market interactions (David 1985; North 1990; Arthur 1992). He then argues that political interactions display qualities that should make positive feedback especially common in this domain. Such qualities include the institutional density of political life, the prevalence of coordination problems, and the opacity of outcomes. Moreover, Pierson contends, self-corrective mechanisms – such as processes of competitive selection and effective learning, which may pertain in many economic domains – are frequently weak or absent in politics. Foreshortened time horizons and the status quo bias of political institutions, moreover, make reversal unlikely even when actors recognize undesirable consequences of past choices. Taken 5 together, these observations – which lie at the center of much historical-institutionalist analysis – suggest that positive feedback effects should be far more common in public policy than negative ones. At the same time, the public policy literature also supplies a range of examples of self-undermining policy effects. Although Pierson’s (1994) early application of policyfeedback logic to retrenchment politics focused heavily on self-reinforcing dynamics – especially the tendency of social programs to generate their own bases of political support – his study also pointed to program features that facilitate the efforts who those that seek to undermine the welfare state, such as service delivery based on state ownership of a stock of physical assets (e.g., housing). Theda Skocpol (1992) has argued that the patronage politics associated with Civil War pensions led both to the demise of that program and to a truncation of options for later programs. Esping-Andersen’s analysis of class development in the three worlds of welfare capitalism notes negative effects associated with each type of regime: very high budget costs for the Scandinavian social democratic model, social exclusion and high unemployment among younger workers in continental welfare states, and high income inequality in liberal welfare states (EspingAndersen 1990, 1999). And, although he did not employ the concept of policy feedback, Kingdon’s (1984) pathbreaking work on agenda-setting demonstrates that the “problem stream”—the set of issues that policymakers feel pressured to respond to—is importantly affected by negative outcomes associated with current policies. Patashnik (2008) has demonstrated how major policy changes in the United States – from the 1986 Tax Reform Act to the reform of agricultural subsidies – have become subject to erosion or outright reversal by actors who bear their costs. 6 A number of analysts have also begun, on a more general level, to highlight the centrality of self-undermining processes in politics. Mahoney and Thelen (2009a), for instance, point out that institutions are arrangements with distributional implications: the very existence of groups that perceive themselves to be losers under the status quo implies that policies and institutions will routinely provoke their own political opposition – a powerful negative feedback effect. An emerging historical literature seeks to explain institutional change as arising from such endogenous processes of conflict and challenge (Thelen 2004; Streeck and Thelen 2005; Clemens and Schneiberg 2006). A parallel literature on institutional change from a game-theoretic perspective suggests that, even where political institutions are “self-enforcing” (that is, providing incentives to act in ways that are encouraged by the existing policy regime), they may be “self-undermining” rather than “self-reinforcing”— weakening, rather than perpetuating, themselves over time (Greif and Laitin 2004). Soroka and Wlezien’s (2010) cross-national study of “thermostatic” effects in the relationship between public policy and public opinion, moreover, suggests a broadly operating negative feedback process in democratic accountability, in which policy moves in one direction can generate electoral pressure to pull policy back in the other direction.2 In the following sections of this paper, we build on these general insights by elaborating a set of reasons why negative feedback is likely to be a common feature of policymaking in democracies, the causal channels through which it is likely to affect policy, and the conditions under which those mechanisms are most likely to operate. 2 Distinct from arguments about self-undermining effects of policy are arguments about the limits to self-reinforcing effects. See, e.g., Patashnik (2008) and Patashnik and Zelizer (2009). 7 THE OBJECTIVE PROFILE OF POLICY GAINS AND LOSSES In this and the next three sections, we present a set of reasons to expect negative policy feedback processes to be prevalent and to frequently exert strong pressures on politicians to enact policy change. Throughout these sections, we focus on how negative policy consequences can shape the coalitional politics of policy change and stability: on how and when increasing policy losses can both expand political coalitions favoring policy change and diminish the ranks of those seeking to defend the status quo. We begin, in the present section, by examining the objective profile of losses and gains that public policies are likely to generate. The members of any coalition for policy change must, in the first instance, face substantial costs under the status quo (as compared to imaginable policy alternatives). We argue that, for reasons intrinsic to the logic of policymaking, public policies will frequently generate high costs and, often, diminishing returns for large segments of society. Policymaking coalitions, however, do not form mechanically as a response to the profile of objective policy consequences. In the next two sections, we turn to the pathways through which policy losses are likely to affect policymaking coalitions operating at two levels: the electoral support base for policy change at the mass level and the strength of pro- and anti-change coalitions of organized interests. Finally, we consider negative feedback effects operating through the menu of policy alternatives. As we argue, the menu of alternatives is itself partly endogenous to the consequences of the status quo: political actors are more strongly motivated to search for new policy alternatives where current policy imposes high societal costs. In expanding the menu, policy entrepreneurs do not just go looking for “good” ideas: they 8 particularly seek out solutions with distributions of costs and benefits that are likely maximize their appeal to winning group and electoral coalitions. Prevalence of policy costs We begin by considering the first step in a policy feedback loop: the set of material costs and benefits that the policy produces for members of society. Claims about positive feedback are typically premised on a particular understanding of the profile of those costs and benefits, especially about their distribution over time. In particular, arguments about path dependence frequently point to the tendency of some public policies to generate increasing social or political returns over time (Pierson 2000). Indeed, the expectation of political opposition to policy change – and the increasing force of that opposition over time – is premised on the presence of high and increasing (or more widely shared) policy gains. Network and coordination effects, learning effects, and adaptation by actors may often make the policy status quo increasingly and more broadly beneficial as time passes. Yet there are also important reasons why policies will frequently yield a profile of high, objective social losses that bear the potential to generate pressures for policy change. The tendency of public policies to generate large social costs derive from at least four fundamental features of policymaking as a social activity. First, state action often embodies a distributive tradeoff. As Thelen (2003) and Mahoney and Thelen (see also Knight 1992; 2009a) have noted, institutional and policy arrangements create both winners and losers. Policy may impose “losses” in multiple senses. Most narrowly and straightforwardly, a new policy that makes one group better off frequently does so at the 9 expense of leaving another group worse off – whether through the imposition of taxes, the enforcement of constraints, or the withdrawal of public largesse. The distributive character of policy choice means that losses may also be relative, rather than absolute: a policy may deliver rewards to Group A but even greater rewards to Group B, leaving members of Group A at a relative disadvantage vis-à-vis an arrangement that spread its gains more evenly. And losses may be counterfactual, rather than actual: even Group B may “lose” under the status quo as compared to the greater spoils that it might reap under a readily imaginable policy alternative. Second, policy choice is typically a collective activity, requiring policymakers to win the assent of multiple actors representing diverse constituencies. Thus, as Pierson (2004) himself points out, policies frequently represent compromise among competing goals and policy logics. The program architectures that result from collective political decision-making will frequently contain substantial complexity and incoherence rather than a single policy logic. Unforeseen interactions among policy mechanisms may yield outcomes that are both unexpected and unwanted by members of the policy’s enacting coalition. In fact, the path-dependent nature of policy can itself be a source of unintended incoherence: where past policy decisions are deeply entrenched, today’s policymakers will frequently be forced to “layer” new structures over old (Schickler 2001; Thelen 2003; Hacker 2004), expanding the opportunities for institutional friction and for outcomes that are undesired by either yesterday’s winning coalition or today’s. A third problem is uncertainty. Even where a policy regime can be lent a coherent design, the causal relationships connecting policy structures to social consequences are often poorly understood (Blyth 2002; Pierson 2004; Jacobs 2011). While the immediate 10 effects of, say, tax rates on citizens’ income may be readily forecast, longer-term and second-order outcomes – e.g., for economic growth – are much more difficult to forecast. Governments’ capacity to deliver intended benefits and avoid costly errors is, for many policy ventures, inherently limited by causal complexity combined with weak causal knowledge.3 Fourth, even where future consequences are knowable, policymakers will often place much greater weight on short- over longer-term social outcomes. A common reason, intrinsic to policymaking in a democracy, will be short-run electoral pressure (Nordhaus 1975; see also Geddes 1994; Jacobs 2011). Thus, policymakers will sometimes seek to maximize near-term social benefits but pay little heed to the longerterm costs. Our point here is not simply that policymaking is messy, or that policy ventures can go awry. We wish to emphasize two more specific implications. First, these dynamics imply that the returns to policy will often be diminishing, rather than increasing, over time: as the layered complexity of a policy regime increases and as outcomes recede beyond policymakers’ original time horizons and capacities for prediction, the likelihood of adverse social outcomes mounts. Second, public policies will sometimes work out badly for politically advantaged actors. It may not be a problem for path-dependence arguments if increasing policy losses fall on the few, the poorly resourced, or the 3 We note that each of these last three characteristics of policymaking – collective choice, uncertainty, and foreshortened time horizons – appears in Pierson’s (2004) arguments about the path-dependent nature of politics. Pierson refers to these features as inhibiting “self-corrective” mechanisms in politics and as undermining the case for an “actorcentered functionalist” account of institutions. Yet, as we argue, they also imply that policymaking will sometimes be subject to diminishing rather than increasing returns over time. 11 unorganized – those unable to exert political pressure for change. But our arguments imply that public policies may work out poorly for those groups sufficiently privileged to have shaped those policies’ original design. Compromise-driven and historically generated complexity, causal uncertainty, and foreshortened time horizons create scope for policy to generate consequences that are unacceptable to the influential actors that fashioned it in the first place. Thus, well-resourced members of yesterday’s winning policy coalition may become well-resourced members of tomorrow’s coalition for policy change. The limits of adaptation Arguments about positive feedback, however, do not depend on policy costs being low. A key mechanism of increasing returns, in many positive-feedback arguments, is the adaptation of social actors to public policies over time. Where policy imposes costs on actors, those actors may adjust their behavior and invest in patterns of activity in ways that minimize the burdens that they face (see also Pierson and Trowbridge 2002; Pierson 2004). Manufacturers, for instance, may adapt to onerous pollution rules by installing new equipment that allows production processes to comply with those legal standards at lower cost. Thus, to say that policies impose costs is not necessarily to say that they will expand the coalition for policy change and undermine the support base for the status quo: via adaptation, even loss-imposing policy choices can reshape the political battlefield in self-reinforcing ways. This logic of loss-reducing adapation hinges, however, on a very specific set of conditions. It depends on adaptation being both feasible and relatively cheap – in 12 particular, cheaper for loss-bearing actors than just paying the policy’s current costs (e.g., fines for non-compliance). In some domains, an expectation of cheap adaptation may be reasonable. It was relatively inexpensive for American employers developing occupational benefit systems during and after World War II to layer those systems atop Social Security, a decision that would later make them dependent on the continued payment of Social Security benefits (Hacker 2002). By contrast, for manufacturers and energy producers facing environmental regulation, adaptation may mean very costly investment in physical capital – or may in fact be infeasible given existing technology, short of divestment from the sector. For these firms, it may be cheaper to live with highly visible current policy burdens, while seeking the repeal of those burdens, than to reorganize their activities and physical plants to make the policy less burdensome. Where adaptation is either impossible or relatively costly, the losers from (and potential opponents of) the policy status quo at today will remain losers and potential change agents tomorrow. The above logics do not merely suggest that factors conducive to negative feedback exist. They also point to specific conditions under which policy is more likely to generate high social costs. The general qualities of policymaking processes that we have identified are in fact variables, not constants. Policy should be more likely to generate high and rising negative outcomes for powerful groups to the extent that (a) policy enactment depends on the agreement of a large number of actors (i.e., where veto power is more widely dispersed); (b) policy has been designed by actors facing near-term electoral pressures rather than those insulated from such pressures (e.g., elected officials in a competitive context rather than career bureaucrats or parties in a dominant electoral 13 position); (c) the policy endeavor involves an ambitious task of social engineering characterized by vast causal complexity; and (d) social actors affected by the policy are relatively “locked in” to current patterns of behavior or production, making adaptation to policy losses costly or impossible. GROUP MOBILIZATION AND POSITIONING If influential coalitions for policy change are to form, then actors must do more than bear losses: they must mobilize to reduce those losses. We conceive of mobilization and coalition-formation in a democracy as operating at two levels: among organized groups and within the electorate. We address group-level dynamics in this section and the mass public in the next. Our focus in the present section is on (a) the tendency of policy losses to reshape the organization of policy stakeholders and (b) the mounting pressures on organized groups to join coalitions for policy change as the probability of change rises. The mobilization of opposition The positive-feedback literature has articulated a number of ways in which public policies may mobilize their own beneficiaries, enlarging the political-support basis of the status quo. For instance, the creation of a new social program may encourage beneficiaries of that program to organize in order to protect or expand it (Pierson 1993). Public programs may also lend a group’s members resources, capacities, and political orientations that allow and encourage them to become more politically engaged (Campbell 2003; Mettler 2005). 14 While it is not hard to point to examples of this positive feedback dynamic, there are important conditions under which it will fail to operate – and under which policy losses may generate strong mobilization against past policy choices. First, the beneficiaries of the status quo may not be the only well-organized stakeholders in the policy domain. Many policy sectors set well-organized pairs of interests against one another (Wilson 1980). Welfare-state reform politics in continental Europe, for instance, frequently pits the interests of well-organized labor groups against those of wellorganized capital. If trade unionists represent a set of highly mobilized beneficiaries of the status quo, organized business has been a powerful advocate for reforms that would reduce the losses that it faces under current arrangements. Explanations of far-reaching pension, unemployment-insurance, and welfare cutbacks in the 2000s in Germany, for instance, attribute a central role to the demands and political influence of organized business for measures to stabilize social contribution burdens (Schludi 2005; Jacobs 2011). Second, as Thelen (2003; see alsoMahoney and Thelen 2009a) has emphasized, the “losers [of political battles] do not necessarily disappear” (231): to the contrary, they will often undertake enhanced collective efforts to reverse their losses. The post-1970 rise of organized business in the United States represents a striking example of countermobilization in the wake of major policy defeats. While employers had long constituted an important organized political force in American politics, they faced major unexpected policy setbacks in the late 1960s and early 1970s, including a raft of new environmental, consumer, and worker-safety rules that dramatically increased the regulatory burdens on firms. The response to these adverse policy shocks was a massive expansion of corporate 15 collective action. The next decade witnessed a doubling in membership of the U.S. Chamber of Commerce and the National Federation of Independent Business, a quadrupling of the number of corporate PACs, and a proliferation of new foundations and think tanks dedicated to the promotion of free-market principles (Vogel 1989; Hacker and Pierson 2010). As Hacker and Pierson document, this “organizational counter-offensive” paid handsome dividends for American capitalists across a broad range of policy domains, from taxation to financial regulation and corporate governance. Nor do business groups appear unique in their capacity to generate “counteroffensives” in response to loss. A wave of liberalizing and secularizing developments, in the 1960s and 1970s, in the domains of cultural and reproductive policy in the United States triggered a massive and enduring mobilization by American evangelicals (Liebman and Wuthnow 1983). And environmental organizations across the developed democracies have frequently enjoyed sharp expansions in membership and increased political clout and policy success as the negative consequences of lax regulation become publicly visible (Vogel 1993, 2003). In sum, the distribution of collective action capacities in polities is neither fixed nor uniformly reinforced by past policy trajectories. We should expect those who suffer policy defeat at t1 to frequently redouble their collective efforts to win at later times, reshaping the organizational landscape in ways that undermine the political foundations of current policy. At the same time, the examples provided above suggest that the prospects for counter-mobilization are not unlimited: it is more likely under some conditions than others. Mobilization by U.S. business and evangelical groups was greatly aided by pre-existing political advantages held by these groups: vast financial resources 16 in the former case, and a pre-existing array well-networked non-political organizations in the latter. While environmental groups enjoy some growth in the wake of environmental policy failure, their mobilizational successes have generally paled by comparison to those of employer and religious groups – likely, because they enjoy smaller financial or organizational advantages. We should expect negative feedback via counter-mobilization to be most common, then, when the “losers” under the status quo possess a wealth of latent political resources than can be converted to political purposes. Adaptive Expectations and Group Positioning As Pierson (2004) points out, one common source of positive feedback in politics are adaptive expectations: the frequent importance, in politics, of “picking the right horse.” Political expectations can thus have a self-fulfilling quality to them, often yielding compounded advantages for those actors already perceived as powerful and reinforcing current arrangements. Yet adaptive expectations, like a number of feedback mechanisms, are distinctly double-edged. Particularly in the later stages of coalitionbuilding process, adaptive expectations can amplify negative feedback dynamics bringing status-quo-winners into the coalition for policy change. Adaptive expectations can never, by themselves, generate policy change; but they can accelerate processes of negative feedback and dampen opposition from groups with high stakes in the status quo. As public and elite demands for policy change gather force, organized stakeholders and their allies in office will often face pressures to join what they expect to be the winning side. One reason – identified by Kingdon (1984) as a “bandwagon effect” – is that those on the winning side of a policy battle get to write the rules. Once the likelihood 17 of policy change reaches a certain threshold, groups and officeholders with a stake in the status quo may join the coalition for change in order to ensure themselves a seat at the table as the new policy regime is crafted. A bandwagon effect appears to have pushed a number of powerful groups – particularly, hospitals and drug companies – to support the Obama health-reform initiative, in exchange for influence over key elements of the deal (Hacker 2010). A second motive for joining forces with advocates for policy change is the reduction of policy uncertainty. Where economic actors must make long-range investment plans, they may prefer a certain but less-preferred policy change over the uncertain prospect of maintaining a more profitable status quo. As Belfry (2010) demonstrates in her study of Canadian environmental policy, intensified public concern about the threat of climate change during the 2000s generated enormous uncertainty about the future price of carbon and, in turn, about the returns to long-range energyintensive investments. In order to lock in a degree of certainty for long-range planning, the Canadian energy sector – followed by the business community as a whole – shifted over the decade from firm opposition to strong backing for a modest level of carbon pricing, resulting in the adoption of carbon-taxation or cap-and-trade schemes by the largest Canadian provinces. As this illustration suggests, decisive support for policy change may come from precisely those actors from whom, in a world of purely positive policy feedbacks, we would expect entrenched resistance: actors making inflexible investments the value of which depends on policy. The rigidity of social actors’ choices, however, is distinctly double-edged: if the legacy of actors’ past investments may generate vested interests in 18 the status quo, the need to make future fixed investments and an aversion to downside risk will sometimes generate coalitional bandwagons that amplify pressures for policy change. Along with enhanced influence over the new rules, the management of uncertainty can be a compelling reason for threatened winners to acquiesce in seemingly adverse policy change. POLICY FEEDBACK AND ELECTORAL COALITIONS: LOSSES IN MASS COGNITION Even where strong organized coalitions for policy change have been formed, elected officials may still hesitate to enact reform if they fear punishment from voters who value the status quo. We might expect the electoral risks to be especially great when citizens have developed high material stakes in current arrangements that would be manifestly threatened by policy change. This is precisely the electoral conundrum that Pierson (1994) describes in his seminal study of welfare-state reform politics in Britain and the United States. Thus, the likelihood of policy change in response to a costly statusquo depends not only on the formation of group coalitions, but also on the presence of change-permitting electoral coalitions: a sufficiently large or pivotal segment of the electorate that demands or is willing to accept reform. Pierson (1994) identifies one set of mechanisms through which change-permitting electoral coalitions can arise: through strategies of elite policy design that render the costs of change difficult for voters to perceive or to trace back to the politicians responsible. Here, we focus instead on mechanisms through which voters can be persuaded of the need for policy change. Our discussion centers on the implications for negative feedback of two cognitive dynamics 19 commonly identified in the literatures on mass policy attitudes: a negativity bias in perception and judgment and the effects of elite framing. Negativity Bias Numerous studies in psychology and political behavior have documented a negativity bias in information-processing: people’s tendency to attend more closely to, recall more readily, and weigh more heavily negative or threatening information than positive information (Lau 1985; Klein 1991; Vonk 1993; Weyland 1998; Soroka 2006). Related to this bias is a well-known human aversion to losses relative to the status quo as compared to the prospect of equivalent gains (Tversky and Kahneman 1991). As political analysts have pointed out, these twin biases have important implications for citizens’ policy attitudes: in particular, citizens are often thought to be more sensitive to policy losses than to policy gains (Weaver 1986; Pierson 1994). Arguments about positive feedback often draw strength from an application of these cognitive mechanisms. In his seminal study of welfare-state reform, Pierson (1994) argues that the negativity bias makes social-program retrenchment more difficult: even if program cutbacks promise gains for taxpayers, it also imposes losses on beneficiaries – and the latter will weigh more heavily in constituents’ minds than the former. In a more general form of this logic, a loss-averse electorate should generally be biased against any policy change that will generate a combination of sizeable gains and sizeable losses. This logic, however, offers too narrow an understanding of the potential effects of these cognitive biases on policy development. The negativity bias and loss-aversion can operate to generate public opposition to a costly status quo as readily as it can yield hostility toward loss-imposing policy change. The central reason is that stability in policy 20 does not imply stability in social outcomes: where policies yield diminishing returns (for reasons discussed above), they will commonly impose mounting costs on constituents. Maintaining pension benefits, in the context of aging populations, has required most OECD countries to increase payroll tax burdens over the last 30 years. Where current policy makes citizens and businesses progressively worse off over time, they are likely to attend to and react against those losses relative to prior circumstances – and the electoral incentives to enact policy change will rise. Elite framing At the same time, voters are known to be largely inattentive to matters of public policy and are unlikely to arrive at clear verdicts on current policy on their own (Converse 1964; Zaller 1992; Kuklinski and Quirk 2001). Rather, as findings in political psychology make clear, citizens’ policy attitudes are frequently given shape by elites’ rhetorical strategies: by the framing efforts of politicians and other political elites (Nelson et al. 1997; Chong and Druckman 2007). The importance of framing effects means that voters need not take automatic notice of the costliness of the status quo; elites may make the case for policy change for them. Elites opposed to the status quo will commonly introduce frames that try to achieve three things. First, elite frames will commonly make the costs of current policy salient to the broad public, thus depicting the status quo as a loss-imposing arrangement. Second, frames will typically connect outcomes to policy, indicating which programs are responsible for those losses. Third, elite rhetoric will introduce a policy alternative and paint it as the loss-avoiding option. 21 Framing, of course, can cut two ways: while group leaders and politicians who favor the status quo will have an incentive to frame it as a success and to frame change as a serious risk, those opposed to current policy will have an incentive to frame it as a disaster. Yet the existing literatures on policy accountability and agenda-setting suggest a set of conditions under which anti-status-quo frames are likely to be most effective. First, frames depicting the status quo as loss-imposing will be more persuasive to relatively inattentive voters when policy costs are distributed in particular ways: especially, when they are highly concentrated on easily identifiable groups (Arnold 1990; Pierson 1994). Politicians seeking to portray the status quo as a state of diminishing returns are likely to have greater success when the losses are made perceptible by their heavy per capita burden or incidence on well-defined and tightly networked groups. Second, Kingdon (1984) points out, negative focusing events – such as plane crashes, industrial accidents, or company bankruptcies – can turn the public’s attention to adverse social outcomes that would otherwise persist unnoticed (see also Birkland 1998). By increasing the visibility of a policy’s costs, focusing events can be a key informational resource for those seeking to depict the status quo as a loss-imposing arrangement. Third, elites’ capacities to frame policies per se as sources of loss-imposition depends on how easily adverse consequences can be connected to state action. As Deborah Stone (1989) argues, causal stories are often contested: whether a negative social outcome, such as rising inequality, is the result of inexorable market forces or of a remediable inadequacy in public policy is often a matter of fierce of debate. Which causal story is most plausible, however, depends in part on the structure of existing policy. As Pierson (1994) demonstrates in his analysis of British and American retrenchment 22 politics, the structure of public programs can affect the clarity of the causal linkages between a policy and its consequences, making it easier or harder for constituents to trace social outcomes back to the policy choices responsible for them (see also Arnold 1990). In sum, the negativity bias cuts two ways: it can make citizens fiercely defensive of what they have, or it can make them all-the-more eager to abandon the “sinking ship” of the status quo. The key question is whether and when change-seeking politicians can persuade voters that the policy ship is sinking. Elites will be far better equipped to craft electoral coalitions for policy change where policy losses are made perceptually salient by their distribution or by dramatic events and where the link between state action and adverse outcomes can be simply depicted. COALITIONS AND THE EXPANDING MENU OF ALTERNATIVES Broadly speaking, positive feedback has been conceived of as a process that progressively narrows the range of options available to decision-makers. As Pierson (2004) puts it, “once actors have ventured far down a particular path, they may find it very difficult to reverse course. Political alternatives that were once quite plausible become irretrievably lost” (10-11). Once-conceivable alternatives become less technically, financially and administratively feasible and even cognitively available over time. However, the set of imaginable alternatives – the set of available policy ideas that could plausibly work – is subject to change. Over time, new policy instruments are conceived of, technological change makes new tools available, and ideas from other jurisdictions enter the debate. Crucially, moreover, a key driver of policy-intellectual 23 development is the set of perceived social consequences of existing policy. Where status quo policy is perceived to generate adverse social outcomes, politicians, bureaucrats, and policy experts become more likely to undertake a search for new alternatives to address those problems. In other words, the policy menu is not forever narrowing: negative policy effects often provoke efforts to expand the range of available and workable alternatives. This search for additional options may involve drawing on theoretical and policy models developed within academia, borrowing and lesson-drawing from other jurisdictions – often importing ideas from other countries – or efforts by policymakers themselves to invent new alternatives. In the environmental sphere, for example, U.S. regulators in the 1970s seeking to improve air quality without choking off growth plucked proposals from the economics literature for tradable permit schemes that promised, via market mechanisms, to reap pollution abatement at the lowest possible cost (Baumol and Oates 1971). These searches for new alternatives, motivated by some actors’ dissatisfaction with the status quo, often do more than simply add options to the menu. They can also expand the political coalitions for policy change (and shrink those opposing it) by altering the social and political net costs of change. They can do so in at least three ways. First, an expansion of the policy menu can make change less costly to potential opponents by enhancing the social efficiency with which new policy benefits can be produced. Leveraging market mechanisms, for instance, the U.S. sulfur-dioxide trading scheme was able to generate large improvements in air and water quality in the Great Lakes region at considerably lower economic cost than would have been associated with options 24 previously on the policy menu. As a result, opposition to SO2 controls considerably weakened (Ellerman 2003). Second, new policy options can change the distribution of costs and benefits across groups in ways that minimize the size of the opposing coalition. We discuss a clear instance of this effect – the use in the United States of an individual health-insurance mandate to create gains for potential reform opponents – in our case study in the next section. Third, new policy options can help reduce elected officials’ accountability for the costs of change by expanding blame-avoidance opportunities. Often, the search for new policy options turns up policy mechanisms that will make the costs of policy change either less visible to citizens or harder for citizens to trace back to the politicians responsible. Notional defined contribution (NDC) pension reforms are a classic case in point. Although current and future pension beneficiaries are often considered vested interests par excellence in accounts of positive policy feedback, NDC reforms render the size of future benefit cuts uncertain and delay them in time by tying them to an automatic formula based on economic and demographic trends, insulated from the discretionary judgments of particular officeholders. They thus make it harder for citizens to punish politicians for cutting future benefits (Brooks and Weaver 2005) – and, in doing so, enlarge the effective change-permitting electoral coalition. Under what conditions are policy losses likely to generate such expansions of the policy menu? Existing theories of politics do not offer tremendous leverage on the questions. One plausible hypothesis, however, is that political systems are likely to vary in their capacity to generate new alternatives, depending on (a) the overall level of policy expertise and (b) whether it is concentrated in the hands of government or more broadly 25 diffused in the society. In the United States, for instance, where “losing” groups have ready access to a wealth of academic and other policy expertise, and to institutions that set broad societal discussion (e.g., the media) and governmental action agendas (e.g., government expert commissions, legislative committees), the generation of a broadened set of alternatives in response to policy losses is more likely. CASE ILLUSTRATION: VARIABLE FEEDBACKS AND HEALTH CARE REFORM The evolution of the postwar U.S. health insurance system illustrates many of the analytical points made in this paper. Most importantly, a focus on negative feedback and variable returns to the policy status quo over time can help to explain both the persistence of health care reform on the broad national “discussion agenda” and its cyclical appearance on governmental action agendas, generally during Democratic administrations. The current public-private patchwork of health financing in the United States was never “chosen” by any single actor (Hacker 1998), but “layered” on by shifting policymaking coalitions across multiple points in time. Most historical analyses of U.S. health policymaking have focused on feedbacks that have reinforced the status quo. These include fears of Americans with health insurance that an increased state role might make them worse off (Skocpol 1996; Hacker 2002), and the high profitability of the status quo for well-organized and well-resourced health care payors and providers (Hacker 1998). Further, gaps in Medicare coverage helped to stimulate membership in AARP, by allowing the organization to provide discounted “Medigap” insurance as a 26 selective benefit, and the huge AARP membership has helped, in turn, to make real or perceived Medicare cutbacks politically toxic (Pierson 1993). In addition, “[p]rogram design …sends messages — positive or negative — to recipients about their standing as citizens, influencing beneficiaries’ sense of political efficacy and entitlement” (Campbell 2003)—messages that have deepened U.S. seniors’ sense of deservingness regarding their current Medicare benefits. All of these effects are real and powerful and have helped hold the post-1965 health care arrangements in place, against multiple high-level national efforts at reform. But these path-dependent processes have co-existed with powerful negative feedback mechanisms that have gradually expanded the coalition for policy change over the last three decades. First, layered policy complexity has generated massive and moundting objective losses. The multiplicity of payers and complex institutional relationships in the system have hobbled many cost control efforts, leading to total health care expenditures in the United States that are far higher as a share of GDP than those of any other country. Importantly, this fragmented system of financing – especially, through its tendency to drive costs upward and price patients out of the market for services – has generated growing adverse consequences for highly mobilized stakeholders -- for instance, by squeezing the profits of premium-paying employers. Growing cost pressures on both public and private payors have, in turn, led them to try to reduce their costs by reducing or eliminating coverage and cutting payments to providers. The costs of the status quo have also increasingly fallen on large segments of the electorate. As employment-based coverage declined, the proportion of Americans who lack health care coverage, are underinsured, or face the risk of losing their insurance has 27 grown (DeNavas-Walt et al. 2011). Many workers who retain coverage have faced sharply increased out-of-pocket costs through higher premiums, deductibles and coinsurance. Employers have also increasingly driven their employees into managed care, which is widely perceived to reduce choice and result in denial of care (Thorpe 1999). In this densely interconnected system, moreover, losses imposed on the average individual quickly translate into losses for other, better-organized actors: governments and hospitals, for example, have been increasingly saddled with the burden of providing services to those lacking insurance (Hacker 2010). To a substantial extent, the enactment of major reform in 2010 was made possible by the willingness of well-organized groups -- winners of prior policy battles but now absorbing major unforeseen losses -- to join coalitions for policy change or withdraw from those opposing it (Hacker 2010). Adaptive expectations also appear to have been at work: in the 2009-10 round of reform, groups such as health insurers and pharmaceutical manufacturers, facing an evidently high probability that health care reform would pass, chose to negotiate favorable treatment for their industry in exchange for neutrality or support for reform (Oberlander 2010). High objective losses also expanded the electoral coalition permissive of reform. In both the Clinton and Obama rounds of health care reform, politicians and interest groups offered conflicting framings about the nature of the policy problem, as well as who was to blame for policy failures, and the likely consequences of policy alternatives vis-à-vis the status quo. Among reform opponents, these efforts were aimed not just at changing public opinion but also in creating among media and political elites the perception that there was a groundswell of public opposition to reform proposals (West et al. 1996). But 28 the increasing losses and risks of the status quo, combined with the hard economic times, substantially buttressed the framing efforts of reform advocates in the late 2000s. As worker premiums and copayments rose, employers withdrew coverage, and job losses mounted, even those who liked their current health coverage were at increasing risk of losing it. Thus, in framing pro-reform messages, Democratic leaders were able to leverage voters’ loss aversion for their own purposes, depicting reform as protection against losses that were likely to emerge under the status quo. While the Affordable Care Act was never widely popular, these pro-reform framing opportunities likely helped make it less unpopular than it would otherwise have been, creating electoral conditions just hospitable enough for Democratic leaders to hold their caucuses together in Congress on key votes. Ultimately, even most conservative congressional Democrats signed on, providing a powerful boost to reform. Negative feedback processes also had a powerful impact in expanding the menu of policy alternatives. Rather than truncating policy menus, the extremely high costs and incomplete coverage of the mixed health care system in the United States led to a decades-long search for reform alternatives that could address coverage gaps and skyrocketing costs while overcoming strong opposition from entrenched interests, notably employers (especially small business), providers and insurers. These new policy options have included an employer mandate and managed competition under the Clinton administration (Skocpol 1996), and an “individual mandate” proposed by Republicans and enacted in Massachusetts in 2006 under Governor Romney. Ultimately the development of the individual mandate to purchase health care, and its adoption in Massachusetts, was a critical step toward legislative enactment of the Obama health care 29 package. Perhaps most importantly, this option changed the potential distribution of costs and benefits for key health reform actors. Although private insurers in the U.S. were natural opponents of a greater government role in health-care financing, an individual mandate to purchase insurance helped to dramatically soften their opposition to reform by guaranteeing them millions of new customers, helping to offset the costs associated with tighter regulation of underwriting practices (Hamburger and Geiger 2009; Quadagno 2011). The health care policy example also points to the critical importance of institutional structures in conditioning the prospects for policy change in response to adverse social consequences. The U.S. system of multiple veto points within Congress and between branches of government, and the need for a legislative super-majority in the Senate to avoid a filibuster, makes it much easier for strong interests to block change – even when the status quo is imposing broad losses on society. This is thus an institutional context in which we would least expect negative feedbacks to result in institutional change. Institutional obstacles were evident in 1993, when the Clinton administration was unable to even get a health care bill to the floor of either chamber of Congress (Steinmo and Watts 1995). Even in 2010, the Obama administration’s success depended on a fleeting filibuster-proof Democratic supermajority in the Senate in late 2009 (Jacobs and Skocpol 2010).4 Of course, separation of powers in the United States also means that the health reform Act remains, at the time of writing, vulnerable to a challenge in the courts. 4 With the loss of that super-majority in January 2010, following the election of Scott Brown in Massachusetts’ special Senate election, House Democrats were forced to approve the already-passed Senate version and then use the budget reconciliation procedure to (which circumvented the possibility of a Republican filibuster) to enact changes agreed upon by the majority leadership in both chambers. 30 It is nonetheless striking that -- even in a political system riddled with veto points, and in a policy field densely packed with well-organized stakeholders – the adverse social consequences or prior policy choices generated sufficient pressure to bring about major legislative change. CONCLUSION The literature on feedback effects and path dependence has had a powerful impact on political science over the past two decades. This article has attempted to build on these previous insights while adding important complements and qualifications to three common features of arguments about policy feedback. The first of these is a tendency, when studying the endogenous influences on policy development over time, to pay almost exclusive attention to positive rather than negative feedback. There are good reasons to expect self-reinforcing dynamics to emerge with some frequency in political life. But there are also strong reasons to expect public policies to generate negative feedback, including their tendency to create losers and to produce undesirable effects unforeseen by their creators. Second, we have argued that additional attention should be paid to the nature of the processes through which both positive and negative feedbacks are framed and political coalitions mobilized. These processes are often heavily contested, and alliances among the bargaining leverage of contestants may shift over time. Third, we have called for better specified – particularly, more conditional – arguments linking policy choices at t1 to policy choices at a later time. The dependence of feedback effects on other factors is implicit in many accounts, but it is rarely theorized 31 explicitly. Yet the emergence of feedback effects as well as their impact on policy stability or change often hinge on the social, economic, political, and institutional conditions under which they occur, in ways that we can readily theorize. Indeed, even the direction of feedback effects can turn on such interactions. One analytical advantage of conditional arguments is that they allow for a well-structured integration of both sets of influences. Conditional arguments can also provide crucial analytical leverage in explaining the balance between positive and negative feedbacks and, thus, accounting for major change. We see a more detailed formulation and testing of conditional relationships to be a productive next step in the study of policy feedbacks. The case of health care in the United States over the past twenty years suggests the utility of the analytical framework developed in this paper and the importance of politically-constructed negative feedbacks in leading to policy change. Rising costs and coverage gaps played a key role in giving health reform a recurrent place on the U.S. agenda. Interest groups and politicians competed over how those feedbacks were framed and the priority given to them, and politicians and interest groups attempted to mobilize perceived losers from the status quo as well as winners. Visible negative feedbacks stimulated a search for new policy alternatives by experts, politicians and interest groups. In a complex political environment featuring high institutional hurdles to change, the ability of the Obama administration to buy off potential opponents, adaptive expectations by key groups, and a temporary Senate super-majority all played critical roles in giving turning negative feedbacks into legislative success for the Obama administration where the Clinton administration had failed. 32 We close by pointing to two potential elaborations of the theoretical framework presented here, suggested by the health-care case. First, the case suggests that substantial attention should be paid to feedback effects on the state and its capacities, as well as on social actors. Most importantly, these would include the fiscal strain that past policy choices may place on current governments – a major driver of governmental interest in health reform, at federal and state levels, in the United States (see also Campbell and Morgan 2005). In general, negative feedback effects on state capacities should be especially important in the field of social welfare policy, where governments are saddled with fiscal commitments that are massive relative to the size of public budgets. Second, the health care case suggests important interactions between social consequences and the policy predispositions of governments – an important role, that is, for politicians’ own policy preferences and for the character of their particular support bases. While the objective effects of current health policies have not varied substantially across Democratic and Republican administrations, the priority given to reform certainly has. Whether officeholders advance proposals for policy change in response to objective problem pressure will often depend, in part, on what counts as a “problem” in their normative worldview or for the constellation of organized interests upon which they depend for political support. 33 REFERENCES Arnold, R. Douglas. 1990. The Logic of Congressional Action. New Haven: Yale University Press. Arthur, W. Brian. 1992. "On Learning and Adaptation in the Economy." Santa Fe: Santa Fe Institute. Working Paper 92-07-038. Baumol, William J., and Wallace E. Oates. 1971. "The Use of Standards and Prices for Protection of the Environment." Swedish Journal of Economics 73:42-54. Belfry, Kaija. 2010. "The Third Man: Investor Influence on Business Preferences for Climate Change Policy Instruments in Canada." In Annual Meeting of the Canadian Political Science Association. Montreal, Quebec. Birkland, Thomas A. 1998. "Focusing Events, Mobilization, and Agenda Setting." Journal of Public Policy 18 (1):53-74. Blyth, Mark. 2002. Great Transformations: Economic Ideas and Institutional Change in the Twentieth Century. New York: Cambridge University Press. Brooks, Sarah M., and R. Kent Weaver. 2005. "Lashed to the Mast? The Politics of Ndc Pension Reform." In Pension Reform: Issues and Prospects for Non-Financial Defined Contribution (Ndc) Schemes, ed. Robert Holzmann and Edward E. Palmer. Washington, D.C.: The World Bank. Campbell, Andrea Louise. 2003. How Policies Make Citizens : Senior Political Activism and the American Welfare State. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press. Campbell, Andrea Louise, and Kimberly J. Morgan. 2005. "Federalism and the Politics of Old-Age Care in Germany and the United States." Comparative Political Studies 38 (8):887-914. Chong, Dennis, and James N. Druckman. 2007. "Framing Theory." Annual Review of Political Science 10:103-26. Clemens, Elizabeth, and Marc Schneiberg. 2006. "The Typical Tools for the Job: Research Strategies in Institutional Analysis." Sociological Theory 24 (3):195227. Converse, Philip E. 1964. "The Nature of Belief Systems in Mass Publics." In Ideology and Discontent, ed. David E. Apter. New York: Free Press. David, Paul A. 1985. "Clio and the Economics of Qwerty." Economic History 75 (2):3327. 34 DeNavas-Walt, Carmen, Bernadette D. Proctor, and Jessica C. Smith. 2011. "Income, Poverty, and Health Insurance Coverage in the United States: 2010." Washington, D.C.: U.S. Census Bureau. Current Population Reports, P60-239. Ellerman, A. Denny. 2003. "Ex Post Evaluation of Tradable Permits: The U.S. So2 CapAndtrade Program." Center for Energy and Environmental Policy Research. 03003 WP. Esping-Andersen, Gøsta. 1990. The Three Worlds of Welfare Capitalism. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press. ———. 1999. Social Foundations of Postindustrial Economies. New York: Oxford University Press. Geddes, Barbara. 1994. Politician's Dilemma: Building State Capacity in Latin America. Berkeley, California: University of California Press. Greif, Avner, and David D. Laitin. 2004. "A Theory of Endogenous Institutional Change." American Political Science Review 98 (4):633-52. Hacker, Jacob S. 1998. "The Historical Logic of National Health Insurance: Structure and Sequence in the Development of British, Canadian, and U.S. Medical Policy." Studies in American Political Development 12 (1):57-130. ———. 2002. The Divided Welfare State: The Battle over Public and Private Social Benefits in the United States. New York: Cambridge University Press. ———. 2004. "Privatizing Risk without Privatizing the Welfare State: The Hidden Politics of Social Policy Retrenchment in the United States." American Political Science Review 98 (2):243-60. ———. 2010. "The Road to Somewhere: Why Health Reform Happened." Perspectives on Politics 8 (3):861-76. Hacker, Jacob S., and Paul Pierson. 2010. "Winner-Take-All Politics: Public Policy, Political Organization, and the Precipitous Rise of Top Incomes in the United States." Politics and Society 38 (2):152-204. Hamburger, Tom , and Kim Geiger. 2009. "Healthcare Insurers Get Upper Hand." Los Angeles Times, August 24. Jacobs, Alan M. 2011. Governing for the Long Term: Democracy and the Politics of Investment. New York: Cambridge University Press. Jacobs, Lawrence R., and Theda Skocpol. 2010. Health Care Reform and American Politics: What Everyone Needs to Know. New York: Oxford University Press. 35 Kingdon, John W. 1984. Agendas, Alternatives, and Public Policies. New York: Harper/Collins. Klein, Jill G. 1991. "Negativity Effects in Impression Formation: A Test in the Political Arena." Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin 17 (4):412-8. Knight, Jack. 1992. Institutions and Social Conflict. Cambridge [England] ; New York, N.Y.: Cambridge University Press. Kuklinski, James H., and Paul D. Quirk. 2001. "Conceptual Foundations of Citizen Competence." Political Behavior 23 (3):285-311. Lau, Richard R. 1985. "Two Explanations for Negativity Effects in Political Behavior." American Journal of Political Science 29 (1):119-38. Liebman, Robert C., and Robert Wuthnow, eds. 1983. The New Christian Right. Hawthorne, N.Y.: Aldine Pub. Co. Mahoney, James, and Kathleen Thelen. 2009a. "A Theory of Gradual Institutional Change." In Explaining Institutional Change: Ambiguity, Agency, and Power, ed. James Mahoney and Kathleen Thelen. New York: Cambridge University Press. ———, eds. 2009b. Explaining Institutional Change: Ambiguity, Agency, and Power. Edited by James Mahoney and Kathleen Thelen. New York: Cambridge University Press. Mettler, Suzanne. 2005. Soliders to Citizens: The G.I. Bill and the Making of the Greatest Generation. New York: Oxford University Press. Nelson, Thomas, Rosalee Clawson, and Zoe Oxley. 1997. "Media Framing of a Civil Liberties Conflict and Its Effect on Tolerance." American Political Science Review 91:567-83. Nordhaus, William D. 1975. "The Political Business Cycle." The Review of Economic Studies 42 (2):169-90. North, Douglass C. 1990. Institutions, Institutional Change, and Economic Performance. New York: Cambridge University Press. Oberlander, Jonathan. 2010. "Long Time Coming: Why Health Reform Finally Passed." Health Affairs 29 (6):112-6. Patashnik, Eric M. 2008. Reforms at Risk: What Happens after Major Policy Changes Are Enacted. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Patashnik, Eric M., and Julian Zelizer. 2009. "When Policy Does Not Remake Politics: The Limits of Policy Feedback." Paper presented at Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association, September 3-6, at Toronto, ON. 36 Pierson, Paul. 1993. "When Effect Becomes Cause: Policy Feedback and Political Change." World Politics 45 (4):595-628. ———. 1994. Dismantling the Welfare State? Reagan, Thatcher, and the Politics of Retrenchment. New York: Cambridge University Press. ———. 2000. "Increasing Returns, Path Dependence, and the Study of Politics." American Political Science Review 94 (2):251-67. ———. 2004. Politics in Time: History, Institutions, and Social Analysis. Princeton, N.J.: Princeton University Press. Pierson, Paul, and Trowbridge. 2002. "Asset Specificity and Institutional Development." In Paper presented at the Annual Meeting of the American Political Science Association. Boston, MA. Quadagno, Jill. 2011. "Interest-Group Influence on the Patient Protection and Affordability Act of 2010: Winners and Losers in the Health Care Reform Debate." Journal of Health Politics, Policy and Law 36 (3):449-53. Schickler, Eric. 2001. Disjointed Pluralism: Institutional Innovation and the Development of the U.S. Congress. Princeton: Princeton University Press. Schludi, Martin. 2005. The Reform of Bismarckian Pension Systems : A Comparison of Pension Politics in Austria, France, Germany, Italy and Sweden. Amsterdam: Amsterdam University Press. Skocpol, Theda. 1992. Protecting Soldiers and Mothers: The Political Origins of Social Policy in the United States. Cambridge, MA: Belknap Press of Harvard University Press. ———. 1996. Boomerang: Clinton’s Health Security Effort and the Turn against Government in U.S. Politics. New York: W.W. Norton. Soroka, Stuart N. 2006. "Good News and Bad News: Asymmetric Responses to Economic Information." Journal of Politics 68 (2):372–85. Soroka, Stuart N., and Christopher Wlezien. 2010. Degrees of Democracy: Politics, Public Opinion, and Policy. New York: Cambridge University Press. Steinmo, Sven, and Jon Watts. 1995. "It's the Institutions, Stupid! Why Comprehensive National Health Insurance Always Fails in America." Journal of Health Politics, Policy and Law 20 (2):329-72. Stone, Deborah. 1989. "Causal Stories and the Formation of Policy Agendas." Political Science Quarterly 104 (2):281-300. 37 Streeck, Wolfgang, and Kathleen Ann Thelen, eds. 2005. Beyond Continuity: Institutional Change in Advanced Political Economies. New York: Oxford University Press. Thelen, Kathleen. 2003. "How Institutions Evolve: Insights from Comparative Historical Analysis." In Comparative Historical Analysis in the Social Sciences, ed. James Mahoney and Dietrich Rueschemeyer. New York: Cambridge University Press. ———. 2004. How Institutions Evolve: The Political Economy of Skills in Germany, Britain, the United States, and Japan. New York: Cambridge University Press. Thorpe, Kenneth. 1999. "Managed Care as Victim or Villain?" Journal of Health Politics, Policy and Law 24 (5):949-56. Tversky, Amos, and Daniel Kahneman. 1991. "Loss Aversion in Riskless Choice: A Reference-Dependent Model." Quarterly Journal of Economics 106 (4):1039-61. Vogel, David. 1989. Fluctuating Fortunes : The Political Power of Business in America. New York: Basic Books. ———. 1993. "Representing Diffuse Interests in Environmental Policymaking." In Do Institutions Matter? Government Capabilities in the United States and Abroad, ed. R. Kent Weaver and Bert A. Rockman. Washington, D.C.: The Brookings Institution. ———. 2003. "The Hare and the Tortoise Revisited: The New Politics of Consumer and Environmental Regulation in Europe." British Journal of Political Science 33 (4):557-80. Vonk, Roos. 1993. "The Negativity Effect in Trait Ratings and in Open-Ended Descriptions of Persons." Personality and Social Psychology Bulletin 19 (3):26978. Weaver, R. Kent. 1986. "The Politics of Blame Avoidance." Journal of Public Policy 6 (4):371-98. West, Darrell M., Diane Heith, and Chris Goodwin. 1996. "Harry and Louise Go to Washington: Political Advertising and Health Care Reform." Journal of Health Politics, Policy and Law 2 (1):35-68. Weyland, Kurt. 1998. "Swallowing the Bitter Pill: Sources of Popular Support for Neoliberal Reform in Latin America." Comparative Political Studies 31 (5):53968. Wilson, James Q. 1980. "The Politics of Regulation." In The Politics of Regulation, ed. James Q. Wilson. New York: Basic Books. 38 Zaller, John. 1992. The Nature and Origins of Mass Opinion. New York: Cambridge University Press. 39