Management controls on agent’s risk-taking incentive: The organizational architecture of Public-Private-Partnerships Demi Chung* demi.chung@unsw.edu.au School of Accounting The Australian School of Business University of New South Wales Australia 2052 David A. Hensher david.hensher@sydney.edu.au The Institute of Transport and Logistics Studies The Business School University of Sydney Australia 2006 John M. Rose john.rose@sydney.edu.au The Institute of Transport and Logistics Studies The Business School University of Sydney Australia 2006 January 2013 [Please do not quote.] * Corresponding author 1 of 43 Management controls on agent’s risk-taking incentive: The organizational architecture of Public-Private-Partnerships Abstract This paper investigates the extent to which the three pillars of management controls, namely allocation of decision rights, performance measures, and rewards and punishments, affect an agent’s risk-taking incentive. This is identified by analysing the organizational architecture of public-private-partnerships (PPPs) in a framework that draws on ideas embodied in transaction cost economics, agency theory and social contract theory. Using a sample of partners in PPP roads and a computer-assisted-personal-instrument survey that includes a stated choice experiment and a record of prior PPP experience, we test the direct effects of management controls on the agent’s risk preferences. The paper provides new evidence that the incentive effect of right to pricing decision must be supported by social expectations. Performance evaluation based on noisy measures and the fixed-price reward weaken the agent’s risk-taking incentive. The double moral hazard has resulted in the strengthening effect of financial penalty. Surplus-sharing to curtail the management control problem of decision right misuse weakens the risk-taking incentive, whilst long contract duration to mitigate effort aversion strengthens the effect. Key words: management controls, incentive contract, risk preference, transaction cost economics, agency theory, social contract, public-private-partnerships, decision right, fixedprice compensation, performance measures, penalties, contract duration, surplus-sharing, media coverage 2 of 43 1. Introduction This paper examines the extent of management controls on an agent’s risk-taking incentive. We define management controls as allocation of decision rights, performance measurement, and rewards and punishments (Jensen and Meckling, 1992). We follow the sentiment of March and Shapira (1987) in which a risk-taking incentive is dictated by the perceived ability to control risks to measure risk-taking incentives using varying degrees of risk aversion. Accounting, management and economics literatures have long recognized the importance of the three pillars of management controls in organizational architecture design. Many of these studies assume managerial moral hazard, only reporting the design and implementation of management controls from the principal’s perspective (Bajari and Tadelis, 2001; Nagar, 2002; Anderson and Dekker, 2005; Widener et al., 2008; Campbell et al., 2009). Other studies that take into account the agent’s perspective consider each control in isolation (Joskow, 1985; Polinsky, 1987; Luft, 1994; Fehr and Schmidt, 2007; Christ et al., 2012), none of these studies have examined all three issues jointly. Most recently, a growing body of empirical research integrates agency theory and transaction cost economics (TCE) to examine the association between management controls and transaction characteristics (Anderson and Dekker, 2005; Sedatole et al., 2012). This literature is redefining a new era in the study of organizational architecture design. Building on the prior literature, we develop a framework integrating three strands of theories: the TCE, agency theory, and social contract theory, to investigate the three pillars of management controls on the agent’s risk-taking incentive. TCE makes provision for management controls through the impact they have on the adaptive capacity to transaction characteristics (Tadelis and williamson, 2012). Agency theory explicitly recognises the riskbearing implication in control strategies (Eisenhardt, 1985). We extend these two streams of literature to examine whether management controls designed in a transaction costs economising way motivates the agent to bear risks. Social contract takes into consideration the social context in which the transaction occurs. Under this notion, a firm is expected to perform certain socially desirable functions and its pursuit of private benefits should not compromise social benefits, or sanctions will be imposed by the society (Ramanathan, 1976). While the power of social legitimacy influencing corporate disclosure has been afforded much attention in the accounting literature (O'Dwyer, 2002; Aerts and Cormier, 2009), their role in strengthening (or weakening) the power of management controls has not received the same attention. 3 of 43 The empirical examination of this integrated framework is studied in the context of publicprivate-partnership (PPP) transactions of road infrastructure. The multiple dimensions of PPPs make them a suitable setting to test our integrated framework of control involving TCE transaction characteristics, agency-theoretical personal attributes and risk-bearing provisions, and the social contract implicit in the transacting environment. The main thrust of PPPs is to allocate risks to the party who is best able to manage those risks; therefore risk-sharing plays an important role in the choice of management controls. The management control outcomes are concerned with the service delivery (road availability) generated from an asset-specific investment (road infrastructure), although the PPP scheme typically bundles the finance and construction of the asset with operations and maintenance of the asset. Our results show that decision right to pricing control matters to the agent’s risk aversion only when approval by social contract is taken into account, highlighting the social contract dimension in strengthening the effects of formal control. Consistent with prior empirical results, we find that noisy performance measures (Krishnan et al., 2011) and fixed-price reward (Evans III et al., 2006) impose risks on agents, and hence weaken their risk-taking incentive. However, contrary to previous results reporting the lower agent effort under financial penalty punishment (Christ et al., 2012), we demonstrate that the propensity to rely on legal recourse of court ordering under double moral hazard explains the opposite effect of penalty on the agent’s incentive. We show how the double moral hazard makes the case for long contract duration an incentive. We offer evidence to show that the mechanism to the control problem of misuse of a decision right over which the principal can expropriate agent’s surplus above predetermined earning threshold, is positively associated with agent’s risk aversion. Social approval through media coverage explains the effects of these management controls on agent’s risk-taking incentive over and above TCE and agency theory. This study contributes to the literature in several ways. First, we supplement the literature concerning risk aversion as the determinant of the design of management controls, to show that risk aversion is also the outcome of these designs. The extant literature generally focuses on the role that risk aversion plays in the design of incentive contracts (Lafontaine and Bhattacharyya, 1995; Evans III et al., 2006), and therefore is mainly concerned with testing the implication of risk aversion from the principal’s perspective. Our research is one of the first studies to investigate from the agent’s perspective, how management controls in incentive contracts jointly affect their risk aversion. 4 of 43 Second, it adds to the emerging literature that jointly tests TCE and agency theory. This literature provides analytical as well as empirical evidence to show that transaction characteristics and transactors’ attributes jointly determine management control structures. We further show the extent to which management controls in response to transaction hazards and agency problems affect agent’s risk-taking incentives. Unlike prior research, which examines how agency theory can strengthen TCE’s explanatory power in determining the association between transaction characteristics and investment choice (Sedatole et al., 2012), we examine the effectiveness of management controls resulting from the joint consideration of TCE and agency theory on agent’s incentive to take risk. The empirical models in this discipline are generally lacking in that they typically rely on indirect proxies for measurements of controls and risk preferences. We are able to obtain direct measures using a computer-assisted-personal-instrument (CAPI) survey to capture these variables. Our results demonstrate that the choices of management controls affect risk preferences, providing empirical support for the (de)motivating effects associated with management controls. Third, we contribute to the growing accounting literature in interorganizational relationships, where the problem of double moral hazard is paramount. This problem has long been acknowledged in franchising (Luft, 1994; Lafontaine and Bhattacharyya, 1995)1. Our investigation, from the agent’s perspective, will enhance the understanding of the extent to which management controls induce risk-taking behaviour. Following Sedatole et al. (2012), we measure risk-taking behaviour using the likelihood of an agent investing in risky projects. Our additional analyses on the varying degrees of risk aversion on contract choice involving investment decisions in PPP infrastructure, shows that management controls through their effects on agent’s risk aversion can affect agent’s risk-taking behaviour. Finally, the most significant contribution lies with the contribution to the theory of management controls. Our inclusion of elements of TCE, agency theory and social contract offers an explanation for why the management controls formalised by contract must be supplemented by informal controls endogenized in the social context in order to achieve management control outcomes. The empirical analysis is the first study to test the potential role of social legitimacy in impacting the effectiveness of management controls. 1 A franchise is a two-way contract where the franchisor and the franchisee share risk by giving each party property rights in those aspects of the transaction that they can efficiently control (Rubin, 1978). 5 of 43 The paper is organised as follows. In the next section we develop a framework integrating three strands of theories: the TCE, agency theory and social contract, to show how management controls are established in response to transaction characteristics, transaction parties’ attributes and the characteristics of the transaction environment. We formulate our hypotheses based on analyses of management controls deployed in PPPs and their intended outcomes. Section 3 describes our approach to measure risk aversion. Section 4 outlines our research method and presents descriptive data. Section 5 reports the empirical results. Additional analyses between risk aversion and investment choice are included to demonstrate the extent to which management control choices, through their affects on decision maker’s risk-taking incentives, as determinants of investment decisions. The last section offers a number of conclusions and a summary of the major contributions of the paper. 2. Theory and hypothesis development In this section, we develop an integrated framework involving TCE, agency theory and social contract of control, in order to study the organization architecture of PPPs. We then formulate hypotheses to test the management controls deployed in PPPs on agent’s risk aversion within the outcome bounds of the PPP scheme. 2.1 Triangulation of management controls: Transaction cost economics, agency theory and social contract Management controls are central to theories of contract although their functions differ within TCE, agency theory and social contract theory, as illustrated in Figure 1. [Insert Figure 1 here] Management controls in TCE are in response to transaction characteristics, and adaptations are taken into account as the central purpose of management controls. Organizing transactions with different characteristics becomes the structure of control mechanisms that create the governance dimensionalities with parallel adaptive ability. The critical dimensions of alternative modes of TCE governance are incentive intensity (strong under fixed-price reward schemes and weak under cost-plus reward schemes), administrative command and control (strong under ownership of decision rights), and a contract laws regime (strong under legal recourse by court ordering and weak under private ordering) (Williamson, 2010). TCE maintains the transactors’ behavioural assumption of risk neutrality to bring out the 6 of 43 imperative of an efficient alignment between governance structures and transaction characteristics (Williamson, 1985, pp. 388-390). Agency theory assumes that economic actors have different preferences toward risk (Arrow, 1971) and display the propensity of shirking opportunism (Alchian and Demsetz, 1972). The theory embraces the risk-bearing perspective to explain the effects of management controls in inducing agent’s incentive and in mitigating moral hazard (Jensen and Meckling, 1976; Eisenhardt, 1989). The force of implicit and explicit societal expectations is applied through an unwritten social contract underscoring society’s approval of organizational behaviour. A social contract relies on the notion that there is a contract between an organization and the society in which it operates. It is assumed that society allows the organization to continue operations as long as it generally meets society expectations. If an organization cannot justify its continued operation, the community may revoke the organization’s ‘contract’ to continue its operations. This might occur through consumers reducing or eliminating the demand for the products of the business, factor suppliers eliminating the supply of labour and financial capital to the business, or constituents lobbying government for increased taxes, fines or laws to prohibit the actions that do not conform to acceptable social norms (Deegan and Rankin, 1996). When faced with threats of sanction by the society, organizations will adapt their methods of operation to conform to prevailing norms of the transaction environment (Dowling and Pfeffer, 1975). Studies of managerial behaviour therefore must look beyond formal controls by a contract mechanism as a way to understand behaviour ‘regulated’ by the social contract. 2.2 The organization architecture of PPPs In PPP transactions, government sells a private consortium an ownership concession. This is a right to generate income from ownership (Buitelaar et al., 2007) through designing, building, financing and operating an infrastructure asset as well as profit from the sale of ancillary services like road availability generated from the asset. Using the insights from van der MeerKooistra and Vosselman (2000), the characteristics of PPPs can be separated into three elements (see Table 1): the transaction, the transaction environment, and the transaction parties. [Insert Table 1 here] 7 of 43 The transaction characteristics feature in a bundling product in which the contracted assetbased service (road availability) is derived from the road infrastructure built and financed by the agent. The primary rationale of the contract to the principal is the purchase of the service and not the asset itself. The payment of service is linked to requirements set out in the output specification (Akbiyikli et al., 2006) and is payable only when the service meets required performance measures (Debande, 2002). The characteristics of site specificity of the road infrastructure (Williamson, 1991), and the intensity of capital investment2, mean that the period it takes for the agent to recoup the cost of capital and earn a required rate of return on equity can be lengthy. The above characteristics of the transaction are associated with a number of uncertainties in the transaction environment such as future contingencies and market demand in the long-run. These uncertainties highlight the relevance of the institutional environment, its specified legal rules, systems and social norms in minimising the impact of adverse uncertain events, and opportunistic behaviour of transactors. Transaction parties display, as assumed in agency theory, heterogeneity in objectives and risk preferences (Jensen and Meckling, 1976). de Palma et al. (2012) argue that transaction parties in PPPs are characterised by two-way information asymmetry and double moral hazard. Twoway information asymmetry exists because there is a very real possibility that the principal could hold more information than the agent, and thus the agent may equally face risks associated with the behaviour of the principal. When both the principal and the agent make non-contractible actions to the transaction, the relationship is characterised by double moral hazard (Lutz, 1995). Double moral hazard is substantiated by the experience that private sector operators involved in PPPs have been subject to abusive behaviour by the state (for example, nationalization or the sudden cancellation of a contract) with little recourse if any (de Palma et al., 2012), which underlines the relevance of the characteristics of the institutional environment. The institutional environment extends protection to the agent through public regulatory bodies including the courts and the justice system. Although such bodies are part of the public sector, they usually enjoy a level of independence that, in good circumstances, makes them able to discipline the government (i.e., principal) if it behaves improperly. This, however, only applies in countries where regulatory bodies are strong, and the rule of law is binding. Finally, the social nature of contracts looks beyond the bilateral 2 The capital cost of road infrastructure in Australia is in the gamut of A$246 million to A$2.3 billion (Chung, 2009, Appendix B). 8 of 43 relationship of the principal and the agent to recognize any organizational architecture as a nexus of obligations within the social context (Cuevas-Rodríguez et al., 2012). Transaction parties to PPPs often face risks originating from perception biases from the transaction environment (Chung et al., 2010) which underscore the social embededness in explaining their risk behaviour. In light of the elements in Table 1, the organizational architecture of PPPs consists of two main components: incentives to align the agent’s behaviour to management control outcomes; and devices to mitigate management control problems. The incentive components are made up of the delegation of decision rights that offers flexibility in managing performance risk, and compensation schemes designed for inducing performance effort. Incentives are subject to various inefficiencies including distorted performance effort (Lyons, 1996; Fehr and Schmidt, 2007). The mitigating elements involve the use of contract duration to guard against poor quality in ex ante investment and ex post shirking, performance measures to evaluate service outcome, financial penalties to punish shirking behaviour, and the sharing of surplus to prevent service quality being compromised by the profit maximisation motive. In the following subsections, we will develop a number of hypotheses to test the effectiveness of management controls implemented in PPPs. The relationships between these controls and their intended outcome to motivate agent’s risk-taking incentives (measure by agent’s risk aversion) are summarised in Figure 2. [Insert Figure 2 here] Decision rights to pricing control TCE’s adaptations argue that delegating an agent a decision right to control an asset’s use under uncontracted contingencies gives them a high power of incentive which enhances adaptability (Hart and Moore, 1990). Agency theory adds an additional view that decision rights should be delegated to the agents who are familiar with the circumstances in which changes occur and who possess the specific knowledge relevant to the decision (Jensen and Meckling, 1992). In an outcome contract concerning road availability, the agent who has the first-hand real-time knowledge about the traffic conditions on the road facility under their management should be delegated the decision to control pricing, varying the price levels to adjust traffic demand has the effect of easing congestion which is in line with the principal’s preference for ensuring road availability to motorists. From the agent’s perspective, this 9 of 43 control mechanism can facilitate their fulfilment of contractual obligations to deliver road availability, and comes with the motivating incentive for them to bear the risk of managing traffic congestion. We predict that: H1a: The decision right to pricing control is negatively associated with the agent’s risk aversion. Fixed-price compensation TCE maintains that the high power of coordinated adaptation must be complemented with weak cost-control incentives in order to enhance adaptive ability. Empirical studies of agency theory are in support of TCE. For example, the incentive structures prevailing in the managed care services in the US demonstrate how the decision autonomy involving the exercise of specialised knowledge and the associated weak cost-control compensation incentives rolled out in practice (Evans III et al., 2006). Similarly, evidence from franchising supports the positive association between authority delegation to agents with superior local knowledge and the use of high-powered incentive pay with the agent retaining residual profits from their units (Campbell et al., 2009). Both theories suggest that characteristics of PPP transactions and transactors will need the support of a reward scheme with weak cost-control incentives. However, compensation schemes in PPPs were designed to help in realising the principal’s project objectives (Aziz, 2007) rather than aligning transaction characteristics. Prima facie, the purpose of the fixed-price contract3 in PPPs is to remove revenue uncertainty for the agent so that they will exert greater effort in managing performance risks. Polinsky (1987) has shown analytically that when the agent is risk averse, a fixed-price contract will insure the agent against demand uncertainty. An implicit but overpowering purpose of the fixed-price scheme is its budget certainty to the principal. From an incentive viewpoint, the fixed-price scheme has the agent bearing all the cost of operations and maintenance (Bajari and Tadelis, 2001) leaving all of the risk of cost uncertainty to the agent. As argued by Joskow (1985), in circumstances where the agent’s actual costs rise significantly above the fixed price, a fixed price contract creates breach incentives such as reduced quantities provided, cessation of 3 There are a variety of compensation schemes used in PPPs: toll payments directly by motorists, shadow payments from the principal based on the number of vehicles travelling on the road, availability payments that are equivalent to a fixed-price contract involving a series of periodic payments of fixed sum agreed in the contract, government subsidies, or a combination of these methods (Chung, 2009). Here we focus on the effect of the fixed-price contract. The effect of surplus-sharing which we will discuss is related to the compensation involving toll payments collected directly from motorists at the point of travel. 10 of 43 investments in order to maintain production capacity, and the running down of the value of equipment. We hypothesise that: H1b: A fixed-price contract is positively associated with the agent’s risk aversion. Performance measures TCE takes the efficient alignment between transactions with different characteristics, and organizational forms with different cost and competences, as the solution to adaptive problems (Williamson, 2010). There is thus little mention of the roles of performance measures and the resultant rewards and punishments required to control moral hazards arising from delegation. Agency theory argues that the inevitable agency costs resulting from the delegation of decision rights, necessitates the principal to devise a set of performance measures primarily because the agent’s behaviour is often unobservable (Jensen and Meckling, 1992). Reliable performance measures can reduce the risks imposed by delegation and compensation schemes on the agents (Widener et al., 2008). However, in a risky operating environment with high task uncertainty and demand uncertainty, performance measures become difficult to specify with precision ex ante, therefore have limited or little use for contracting (Krishnan et al., 2011). Performance of road service providers is measured against the extent that the road is available to motorists; therefore any vehicle breakdowns, accidents, or overflow of traffic with the consequence of failing to clear road congestion in time are indications of poor performance, even in situations where the causes of accidents (e.g., poor weather condition) are well beyond the agent’s control, resulting in high task uncertainty. Demand uncertainty is exacerbated in contracts of long duration – it makes traffic demand forecast problematic; hence difficulties in budgeting for repair and maintenance. Measures that suffer from task and demand uncertainties become counter-effective in reducing risks that have been imposed on the agent by delegation and fixed-price compensation. On this basis, we expect that the agent’s risk aversion increases with the use of such noisy measures. H1c: The performance measures specified ex ante in PPP contracts are positively associated with the agent’s risk aversion. Penalties A fixed-price compensation with penalty clauses linked to performance measures can be optimal for the principal to incentivise the agent to perform tasks in an uncertain environment 11 of 43 (Hannan et al., 2005; Zhao, 2008). Many experimental studies on contract framing have, however, challenged this proposition and concluded that control-averse behaviour actually increased with the use of penalties. Luft (1994) noted that the use of a “penalty label” generated persistent aversion in the parties being evaluated, arguing that contracts framed as financial sanctions magnified the loss effect. Further evidence showed that when penalty and fines were interpreted as an explicit threat of sanction, they could be seen as a hostile act (Fehr and Schmidt, 2007). Contract incompleteness was found to exacerbate this adverse effect. Incomplete contracts present greater opportunities for the principal’s discretionary behaviour, representing higher risk of opportunism on the part of the principal. The presence of a double moral hazard has the agent perceived penalties as a sense of distrust from the principal leading to higher risk and effort aversions (Christ et al., 2012). Conclusions drawn from these studies of agency theory are contextualised in governance by hierarchy, with the implicit assumption of a weak contract regime. Recourse to the court-orderings to delimit threat positions has little role to play in governance by hierarchy (Williamson, 2010), so when double moral hazard presents, the hierarchy is its own court of ultimate appeal for agent’s disputes over principal’s discretionary compensation. In contrast, TCE’s concept of contract laws asserts that court-ordering plays a significant role in a hybrid mode of contracting (Williamson, 1991). The study of hybrid governance based on a large sample of survey data has led Anderson and Dekker (2005) to conclude that bilateral dependence between parties to contracts involving asset specificity has made the reliance on legal recourse more pronounced. Other empirical work has confirmed that explicit penalty clauses make the legal process less costly and more certain, and are used to protect specific investments against opportunistic breach (Lyons, 1996, p. 44). On the basis of this literature and the double moral hazard prevailing in PPPs, we predict that the penalties specified in the contract will reduce the agent’s risk aversion. H1d: Penalty clauses are negatively associated with the agent’s risk aversion. Contract duration A number of empirical studies give strong support to TCE finding that long contract durations were structured to promote durable asset-specific investments in heavily regulated industries with high publicity like gas (Masten and Crocker, 1985) and coal (Joskow, 1987). The incentive effect of long duration becomes more pronounced in contracts involving bundling tasks. Bundling is optimal if it can create “countervailing incentives”. That is, if the costs of accomplishing the two tasks are negatively correlated, allocating the second task to the same 12 of 43 agent may make eliciting the first task’s cost realization less costly, with the benefit of reducing an agent’s total information rent (Baiman and Rajan, 2002, p. 216). Bundling, however, can distort optimal level of investments. For instance, if an agent is given a difficultto-measure task (such as the design quality of the asset) and an easy-to-measure task (such as the maintenance of the asset), they will have a tendency to overinvest in the maintenance task and to under-invest in the quality of the asset (Holmstrom and Milgrom, 1991). Long contract duration serves to monitor these two aspects of the bundling product: the longer the contract duration, the more difficult it is for the agent to cover up any design defects and maintenance problems arising from shirking. From the agent’s view, a lengthy duration is a protection against moral hazard of the principal. Infrastructure assets often require substantial capital investment upfront, and many contracts have a duration ranging between 30 and 99 years (Chung, 2009) outliving governments. A long contract duration protects the agent against opportunistic hold-up by generations of governments. This safeguarding property of contract duration under a double moral hazard acts to minimise the agent’s risk aversion. H1e: The contract duration is negatively associated with the agent’s risk aversion. Control device to mitigate authority misuse Agency theory recognises that the delegation of decision rights like pricing control is subject to the moral hazard problem of authority misuse (Nagar, 2002). This hazard is particularly concerning to a principal who is also a regulatory body, especially when the problem can potentially generate social welfare loss. Surplus-sharing arrangements are often applied to regulated industries, under which the regulated firm shares any earnings above a specified level with the regulatory authority (Sappington and Weisman, 1996). PPP road contracts generally impose surplus-sharing conditions to curtail the agent’s private objective of profit maximisation at the cost of road congestion to motorists. This ability of the principal to expropriate some of the ex post surplus created by the agent’s investment weakens the agent’s incentive (Baiman and Rajan, 2002, p. 220). We argue that surplus-sharing contributes to the agent’s increasing degree of risk aversion. H1f: Provision of surplus-sharing is positively associated with the agent’s risk aversion. 13 of 43 Control by social contract The implicit expectation that organizational behaviour should be commensurate with the norms embodied within the social contract, is a powerful influence on an organization’s continuous operations (Mathews, 1997; Deegan, 2002). Transactions involving public utilities in particular tend to attract high public visibility and are prone to threats voiced through negative media coverage (van der Meer-Kooistra and Vosselman, 2000). Consistent with prior research showing that the media can be particularly effective in shaping community perceptions concerning an organisation’s legitimate behaviour (Brown and Deegan, 1998), our in-depth interview study has confirmed that media risk is a undermanaged social variable in PPPs (Chung et al., 2010). The power of media in influencing organization behaviour has been documented in a number of accounting studies (Deegan et al., 2000; Deegan et al., 2002; Islam and Deegan, 2010; Mäkelä and Näsi, 2010), and organization behaviour was reportedly highly sensitive to the intensity and negativity of media attention (Brown and Deegan, 1998; Aerts and Cormier, 2009). We argue, in the absence of negative media attention, i.e., if media attention toward these PPP projects is neutral, the effects of formal control mechanisms on the agent’s risk-taking incentives can be strengthened. H2: Neutral media attention within the transaction environment strengthens the effects of formal management controls on the agent’s risk aversion. 3. Measure of risk aversion We draw on the Hensher Service Quality Index (HSQI) empirical framework (Hensher and Prioni, 2002; Hensher et al., 2003) as a way to establish a set of risk indices relevant to PPP roads as measures of the agent’s risk aversion. The HSQI represents a set of quantitative performance indicators to measure service delivery quality and effectiveness in the context of bus services. Under this framework, the overall level of satisfaction is measured by how an individual evaluates the total package of services offered. The evaluation process involves the search for appropriate weights attached to each service dimension to identify the strength of positive and negative source of overall satisfaction. To fulfil this objective, stated choice (SC) methods were used in the original study (Hensher and Prioni, 2002), whereby a sample of passengers were asked to choose their most preferred package from a number of alternative packages of service levels based on these attributes. Logit models were estimated to establish the relative weights attached to the statistically significant attributes, representing the contribution of each service attribute to the calculation of an overall service quality index. In 14 of 43 addition, a set of attribute reference levels were obtained in order to apply the weights. For this purpose, revealed preference (RP) data of the perceptions of passengers relative to the levels of each attribute as experienced in a current trip were obtained; they were then multiplied by the relevant weight; summing these calculations across all attributes to produce the service quality index for each sampled passenger. To implement the HSQI framework, we need to define a set of quantitative risk attributes pertinent to PPP roads. Based on prior literature (Monteiro, 2010, p. 263), risk is defined as: An event that may or may not occur and can lead to failure to satisfy project requirements…and is being considered as having an upside and a downside: a party facing risk suffers from negative events, but may also benefit from positive events. In this way, the party will have higher incentives for putting effort into preventing negative outcomes. Risk comprises the expected value of a trade-off outcome associated with downside risk (the likelihood of an outcome reaching a disaster level), upside gain (the likelihood of an outcome reaching an optimistic level), and risk neutrality (the likelihood of an outcome reaching the expected level) (Lafontaine and Bhattacharyya, 1995). In the seminal paper by March and Shapira (1987), risk preference is subject to a decision maker’s ability to control the odds, is conditional upon their experience in the underlying investment, their knowledge and skills in pooling resources to mitigate downside outcomes and in trading off one risk with another, and their informational advantage. The considerations of trade-off are framed by attention factors that considerably affect action. Risk-averse individuals tend to pay greater attention to the dangers of downside risk, hence displaying a propensity for risk-avoiding; risk-seeking individuals have a predilection for opportunities for upside gain and thus exhibit risk prone behaviour; and risk-neutral individuals favour certainty over variability, with a strong reaction to risk neutrality. Based on the sentiment of HSQI, in our CAPI survey (discussed in research method section) we included a series of SC experiments designed to obtain SC data on respondents’ perception of risk associated with alternative packages of attributes that define the dimensions 15 of 43 of PPP risk4 (see Table 2). The SC experiments contain five hypothetical scenarios that are well-defined within the transaction context of PPP road contracts; which overcomes real-life constraints confronted by the decision maker while maintaining the realism in the choice scenarios (Hensher et al., 2005). [Insert Table 2 here] Construction of the empirical risk index entails using parameter estimates obtained from a choice model, using data gathered by way of a SC experiment to condition the role of reference levels representing the attribute risk levels perceived by stakeholder experience in real PPP settings. We used the latent class (LCM) model to obtain estimates of the parameters. The LCM model is preferred over the standard multinomial logit model because of the increased behavioural richness of the model in accommodating, through discrete distributions of the estimates of each attributes parameters, heterogeneity of stakeholder preferences for specific levels of risk (given the likely outcome associated with the full attribute package). LCM models also avoid the controversial implications of arbitrarily selecting specific continuous distribution for each parameter that is required in mixed (or random parameter) logit models, and are also starting to accumulate evidence of improved goodness-of-fit over all alternative discrete choice model forms (Greene and Hensher, 2003). The risk index of interest is given in equation (1). · (1) (RI=risk index; n=decision maker, j=investment alternative, k=attribute weight) Given the reported reference levels from respondents’ prior experience in terms of risk borne in PPP road projects, i.e., in Equation (1), we multiply the by the betas (parameter estimates) and sum them across all risk attributes to produce the risk index as the measure of each respondent’s risk preference. A respondent is risk-averse if the outcome of Equation (1) is negative; a respondent is risk-seeking if the outcome is positive; and a respondent is riskneutral if the outcome is zero. 4 We adopted the nine key risk attributes pertaining to PPP roads identified in Chung et al. (2010); these are: traffic risk, financial risk, network risk, force majeure, sovereign risk, risk of unclear project objectives, political and reputation risk, media risk and risk of public perceptions. 16 of 43 4. Research method and data description Following the empirical testing structure developed in Section 2, we designed a CAPI which contains a SC experiment and a series of non-stated-choice questions that seek out information on the respondent’s experience with PPPs as well as their subjective views on the key factors influencing their choice of contract. There are several distinct parts to the survey: (1) general questions capturing the socio-demographic attributes of respondents and other contextual effects; (2) stated-choice menus corresponding to a PPP-road-concession setting; (3) RP questions surveying respondents’ “prior experience” to determine the reference levels for the derivation of the risk index; (4) questions intended to assess the extent to which management controls and other factors impact on respondents’ evaluations of the riskiness of PPPs; and (5) attitudinal questions designed to obtain respondents’ preferences for PPPs. Before the commencement of each survey, a semi-structured interview was conducted with each respondent in order to understand their current or past role in the field. All interviews were transcribed. These qualitative data serve as the reference point to make sense of each participant’s risk preference and their willingness to take on risks. Data collection was completed in 2010. Demographic attributes of respondents We solicited participants from the mailing list of the Institute of Transport and Logistics Studies at the University of Sydney based on the criteria that they must have had direct input in the decision-making process of entering into a PPP road contract. Additional subjects were recruited through referrals by respondents. One hundred and one people participated in the survey of which 41 represent the public sector principal (PRINCIPAL) and 60 represent the private sector agent (AGENT). All have had direct input into the decision-making associated with entering into a PPP road contract. The respondents’ experience in PPP years (contracts) runs the gamut of one to 46 years (one to 120 contracts). They bring to this study their contract experience in 32 countries covering six regions. The distributions in Table 3 show that the AGENT5 cohort represents a good spread in roles and organisations, suggesting that our results are not biased toward any category. [Insert Table 3 here] 5 Since this study focuses on the agent’s perspective, we only report data description concerning the AGENT cohort mainly. 17 of 43 Respondents were asked to list the three most recent projects that they have been involved in. As presented in Table 4, the locations of projects are diverse, showing that PPPs are an important and popular procurement method of road infrastructure across the world. [Insert Table 4 here] Stated-choice data of incentive contracts as a source of attribute weights During the interview, each respondent was briefed that they were about to make an investment choice related to PPP road out of two alternatives. Each alternative has a unique risk profile and the respondent was specifically instructed to exercise their judgement based upon their prior experience and their ability to manage the risks associated with the alternatives. Stated differently, the project risks are presented as the level of downside, upside and neutrality in the experiment; whether they are acceptable to the decision maker is dependent on the attitude the decision maker formed from their prior experience with respect to their ability to manage and (or) trade-off these project risks, taking into account cooperative efforts of all contracting. The AGENT’s choice in the “1st row” in Figure 3 and the PRINCIPAL’s choice in the “2nd row” in Figure 3 are used to obtain parameter estimates under the LCM model form for each attribute for the AGENT and PRINCIPAL respectively. Five choice scenarios were shown to each respondent, allocated from D-efficient design that ensures that each choice scenario is equally represented (i.e., balanced) throughout the entire sample. Full details of how the stated choice experiment was designed are given in Chung (2012). [Insert Figure 3 here] Revealed preference data of “prior experience” as a source of reference levels After completing the SC experiments, respondents were presented with the opportunity describe their real experience in terms of risk borne (Figure 4). These RP data determine the reference levels referred to in a previous section as input into the risk indices. [Insert Figure 4 here] Table 5 contrasts the mean value for each risk attribute associated with the PRINCIPAL and the AGENT6. The last column shows AGENT’s share of each downside risk (upside gain) 6 The three risk attributes of each risk category, i.e., downside, upside and neutrality (omitted from the table) sum to 100 percent. 18 of 43 relative to PRINCIPAL, while the third (second) column shows AGENT’s (PRINCIPAL’s) upside-downside trade-off in each risk category. The contrast shows that the AGENT has suffered mainly from market risks. The last column in Table 5 suggests that the downside risk associated with the traffic volume (financial return) has been borne by the AGENT is almost four (three) times more than by the PRINCIPAL, while the AGENT’s shares of the related upside gains (1.5 times more relative to the PRINCIPAL in both risk attributes) are far less than the losses they have suffered. For the remaining contractible risk categories, i.e., network risk, force majeure, and sovereign risk; in comparison with the PRINCIPAL, the mean shares for the AGENT in upside gain differ notably from the downside risks they have borne, with the gains relative to losses being much greater for network risk and much smaller for force majeure, and sovereign risk. Compared with the PRINCIPAL, the AGENT’s shares in the upside gains related to noncontractible risks (risk of unclear project objectives and political and reputational risk) trade off the downside risk fairly well (third column of Table 5). But the downside loss associated with political and reputational risk to the PRINCIPAL (39.20) far outweighs the upside gain (13.41), with the ratio close to three, suggesting that the PRINCIPAL has suffered badly from the loss of reputation. In terms of media risk, both the AGENT and the PRINCIPAL have suffered greatly from negative media coverage, but the PRINCIPAL is the greatest loser, experiencing three times more in downside risk (41.17 percent) compared with upside gain (13.10 percent). This evidence highlights the importance of media attention in impacting contracting parties’ perceptions regarding the social contract of control. Finally, similar to media risk, both the AGENT and the PRINCIPAL have suffered greatly from risk of public perception while the magnitude associated with the PRINCIPAL is more severe, being almost four times more in downside risk (45.37 percent) compared with upside gain (12.68 percent). This experience illustrates not only how the design of management controls needs to consider the incentive effects on the agent but also must take into account the resultant agent’s behaviour, given the legitimacy of the principal in the eyes of the public community. In testing H2, we will use “media-risk neutral” (omitted from the table) to measure neutral media attention. [Insert Table 5 here] 19 of 43 Measures of management controls A number of survey questions were included to understand respondents’ views on the importance of the management controls specified in a contract and the factors prevailing in the external environment that impact on their assessment of the riskiness of PPP road infrastructure investments (Figure 5). These variables are measured using a one to seven likert scale, where “one” indicates very unimportant and “seven” indicates very important. Table 6 lists the explanatory variables to be investigated (as described in H1) as potential sources of systematic influence on the risk index obtained for each AGENT. [Insert Figure 5 here] [Insert Table 6 here] Preferred contract choice as a measure of risk-taking behaviour Respondents’ decisions to invest in PPPs are captured in the survey through their preferred choice of contract, which are presented in an ordered outcome scale of seven levels (see Figure 6). Table 7 shows that there is a much higher proportion of AGENT that prefer PPPs (71.67 percent in scales 1 and 2 combined) than their PRINCIPAL counterparts (24.39 percent in scales 1 and 2 combined). The scale is related to any PPP project and has not incorporated risk-bearing. We show below that AGENT’s contract preference will shift dramatically once actual experience of risk-bearing enters into decision making. [Insert Figure 6 here] [Insert Table 7 here] 5. Empirical results Risk-transfer and risk aversion We estimated a LCM by pooling both segments of data, i.e., PRINCIPAL and AGENT.7 After the weights are identified, we multiply each attribute level associated with the RP data in “prior experience” by the relevant weight and sum these calculations across all attributes for each of the 101 respondents to produce the sector-specific risk index as specified in Equation (1). All but one PRINCIPAL, who displays risk neutrality, are risk averse. The values of risk indices associated with the PRINCIPAL are in the range of -18.53 percent and zero percent with a mean value of -7.26 percent; the range of risk indices associated with the 7 We specified two latent classes, but changes in classes did not improve model fit nor did it increase the number of significant parameters. Results are available on request from the first author. 20 of 43 AGENT lies between -56.98 percent and -3.47 percent with a mean value of -23.15 percent; these risk indices (RIA) measure the agents’ risk aversion. For easy interpretation, we convert all indices into the positive range by normalising the index of the RIA with the highest relative value to a base of zero (see Figure 7).8 [Insert Figure 7 here] Management control mechanisms and agent’s risk aversion We estimated the following model specifications to test H1 and H2. H1: RIA = f ( PRIXCNL, FXPRIX, PERIDC, PENALTY, DURATION, SURSHARE) - H2: + + - - + RIA = f ((PRIXCNL, FXPRIX, PERIDC, PENALTY, DURATION, SURSHARE),MEDIANEU) -/- +/+ +/+ -/- -/- +/+ PRIXCNL = decision rights to pricing control, FXPRIX = fixed-price compensation scheme, PERIDC = performance measures specified in contract ex ante, PENALTY = financial penalties to punish not meeting specified performance measures, DURATION = contract duration, SURSHARE = surplus-sharing between the principal and the agent, and MEDIANEU denotes neutrality of media attention within the transaction environment as measured by a ratio data of “prior experience” provided by respondents in the media risk (risk-neutrality) category. A descriptive summary and the correlation matrix of these independent variables are presented in Table 8. -/- (+/+) = strengthening effects by the inclusion of MEDIANEU. [Insert Table 8 here] The results of a multivariate regression reported in Table 9 show the association between RIA and the identified management controls by contract. All parameter estimates are significant at the one percent level except PRIXCNL. The significant parameter estimates are all of expected sign. [Insert Table 9 here] 8 From this point onward, all analysis will be based on normalised indices, i.e., risk aversion indices are presented in positive values; higher value means greater risk aversion. 21 of 43 These results shed important light on the organizational architecture of PPPs. Fixed-price compensation schemes will not motivate agent’s incentive to take risk. The message to the principal is that the trade-off between loss of incentive intensity and budget certainty needs to be weighed ethically because PPP roads are not just projects of the procuring authority; they have long-lasting implications for generations of the public. Performance measures specified ex ante in a risky environment characterised with high task and demand uncertainties worsen agent’s risk-taking incentive. The expected negative sign of PENALTY confirms that in the presence of double moral hazard, recourse to court-ordering can reduce an agent’s risk aversion. The negative PENALTY also highlights the substitute nature of control and trust (Vosselman and van der Meer-Kooistra, 2009); the potential lack of trust between the agent and the principal has led to the agent’s greater reliance on formal control through the legal system. The expected negative sign of DURATION suggests that long contract duration protects the agent from opportunistic breach by the principal and hence enhances agent’s risktaking incentive. The positive sign of SURSHARE suggests that conditions on the agent’s earning cap by way of surplus expropriation weaken incentive intensity. We analysed the correlation matrix (Table 8) and interview transcripts to investigate the possible cause for the insignificant PRIXCNL. The correlation between PRIXCNL and RIA is trivial compared with PRIXCNL’s correlations with other variables, while its correlation with MEDIANEU is the strongest. Reference to interview data confirms our predication that strong public adversity to organisation behaviour can make a decision right to pricing control counter-effective. In our case, agents were reluctant to exercise this right as they did not wish to be seen as using their right for private gain at the expense of motorists, which may have been seen as violating the social contract. Both observations underscore our proposition that if media attention can be neutralised, the agent would be more willing to exercise their decision right. Based upon the correlations in Table 8, we use the interaction term PRIXCNL*MEDIANEU in the following empirical model to test H2. RIA = · · · · · ! · " # · $$% The results reported in the second column of Table 9 support H2. After interacting PRIXCNL with MEDIANEU, the effect of PRIXCNL becomes highly significant at the one percent 22 of 43 level. The negative sign indicates that as long as media attention is neutralised, delegating the agent the decision right to pricing control has a strong effect on reducing their risk aversion. Furthermore, the adjusted R2 in the second column of Table 9 (0.387) is much higher than the adjusted R2 (0.243) in the first column of Table 9, suggesting that incorporating MEDIANEU in the model strengthens the explanatory power of the independent variables in explaining RIA. The evidence that social approval through media attention explains the effects of these management controls on agent’s risk-taking incentive over and above TCE and agency theory, emphasises the complementary power of informal management controls. The organizational architecture of PPPs not only needs to consider the choice of control mechanisms based upon an understanding of each party’s risk preferences, but all parties need be wise to the opportunity to use the media as a way of fulfilling obligations under the implicit social contract within the transaction environment. Additional analysis: management controls and investment decisions We undertook additional analyses to investigate the extent to which management control choices, through their effects on decision maker’s risk-taking incentives, are determinants of risk-taking behaviour. Following Sedatole et al. (2012), we measure risk-taking behaviour using the likelihood of agent’s decisions to invest in risky projects. We apply the following ordered logit form using the derived risk index to test: Ci_AGENT = &' &( · )*+ where Ci_AGENT denotes the agent’s contract preference and data are as reported in Table 7; with model results presented in Table 10. Testing a model that has an ordered scale as the dependent variable requires an ordered response model that recognises the nonlinearity of a ranking scale and defines points on the observed rating scale as thresholds (Jones and Hensher, 2004). The ordered logit model has a constant term, one, as the first right hand side variable, therefore one of the threshold parameters (µs) is not identified, so µ0 is normalised to zero. A direct interpretation of the parameter estimates in Table 10 is not possible given the logit transformation of the outcome dependent variable required for model estimation. We therefore provide the marginal effects of the two end scales, i.e., Y=1 (PPP is the most preferred choice) and Y=7 (PPP is the least preferred choice), defined as the derivatives of the probabilities, to explain the influence a one 23 of 43 unit change in an independent variable, i.e., risk aversion, has on the probability of selecting a particular outcome, i.e., choice of investment, ceteris paribus. [Insert Table 10 here] The results suggest that RIA has a strong statistical impact, i.e., both parameter estimates are significant at the one percent level, on the probability of choosing PPP as the most preferred investment. The negative parameter estimate for Prob(Y=1) indicates that a one unit change in the mean of PRVRI leads to a -0.56 change in the probability of Y=1, i.e., one unit increase in AGENT’s risk aversion reduces the probability of PPP being favoured by them with a magnitude of 56 percent, ceteris paribus; the positive parameter estimate for Prob(Y=7) suggests the otherwise although at a much less scale, i.e., increase in one unit of the risk aversion increase the odds of non-PPPs being chosen by four percent, ceteris paribus. Overall, the results suggest that the greater the risk aversion of the AGENT the less they prefer PPP investments. Stated differently, degree of the AGENT’s risk aversion is negatively associated with their decision to invest in PPPs. These findings are consistent with Sitkin and Weingart (1995) which provided clear support for the importance of risk perception as a crucial influence on individual risk-taking behaviour. We have shown choices of management controls can affect agent’s risk aversion measured by SC data on the perceived riskiness of two contracts on offer. If the objective of the principal is to encourage agent’s risk-taking behaviour (investment choice), then the design of management controls should consider the way in which control choices can modify agent’s risk-taking incentives (risk aversion). 6. Conclusions This paper has empirically tested a framework of management controls integrating TCE, agency theory and social contract in order to incentivise agent’s risk-taking incentives within a choice experiment setting. Within the context of the PPP procurement contract, we examine the effects of agency theory on management controls formalised in the contract on enhancing the agent’s incentive to take risks. We have provided evidence on how fixed-price compensation, performance measures, financial penalties, contract duration, and surplussharing can affect agent’s risk-taking incentive. Our results confirm that social approval through neutral media attention strengthens the effects of these management controls on 24 of 43 agent’s risk-taking incentive over and above TCE and agency theory, and decision rights to pricing control only matters when social approval is taken into account. From a practical standpoint, consideration of double moral hazard raises an important question for both sides of the contractual relationship to rethink how the organizational architecture of PPPs can achieve the intended risk-sharing outcomes. A number of strong messages emerge: i) organizational design must go beyond formal management controls to consider the effects of informal controls on non-contractible effort; ii) there is lack of trust between the agent and the principal as reflected in agent’s greater reliance on penalty clauses for court-ordering for conflict resolution; if the trust issue remains unresolved it is unlikely the long-term cooperative effort can be sustainable; and iii) risk behaviour can be modified by the design of management controls. Supported by the coverage and diversity of the experience and knowledge of the respondents who took part in this study, the findings are of significant international relevance. The study, however, is not without limitations. First, we acknowledge that trust plays a significant role in sustaining long-term cooperative effort in the PPP environment, but we have not undertaken an empirical examination of its effects. Second, empirical studies on the role of management controls on ex post outcomes are scarce; Anderson and Dekker (2005) and Susarla (2012) are two exceptions. Although our test of this relationship from the agent’s perspective has made a small contribution to the void, the respondents who participated are mainly involved in the decision-making phase of contract entering, with the exceptions of 24 primary decision makers and six tollroad operators who also have been actively engaging in operating PPP projects. The limitation is that some respondents may not have experienced the incentive effects associated with the management controls over the operational phase. A further limitation is associated with the inherent nature of PPPs. Their long contract duration means that there is little opportunity to collect data on ex post outcomes before these contracts have run their course. These limitations justify our reliance on behavioural data reflecting respondents’ perceptions of accumulated experiences to date. In spite of these drawbacks, the results are consistent with Sitkin and Weingart (1995) who find that risk perceptions are important determinants of risk-taking behaviour. These findings support the validity of our approach, relying on respondents’ perceptions to draw conclusions on the extent to which management controls motivate their risk-taking incentives and hence their risk-taking behaviour. 25 of 43 In closing, two emerging opportunities – the recently concluded M4 motorway in Australia and the Dartford Bridge in the UK, can provide critically needed evidence on ex post outcomes in order to attest the predicted role of management controls in risk and effort aversions. We leave the investigation of trust and the ex post outcomes of management controls for future research. 26 of 43 References: Aerts, W. and Cormier, D. (2009) "Media legitimacy and corporate environmental communication", Accounting, Organizations & Society, vol. 34, no.1, pp. 1-27. Akbiyikli, R., Eaton, D. and Turner, A. (2006) "Project Finance and the Private Finance Initiative (PFI)", Journal of Structured Finance, vol. 12, no.2, pp. 67-75. Alchian, A. A. and Demsetz, H. (1972) "Production, Information Costs, and Economic Organization", The American Economic Review, vol. 62, no.5, pp. 777-795. Anderson, S. W. and Dekker, H. C. (2005) "Management control for market transactions: the relation between transaction characteristics, incomplete contract design, and subsequent performance", Management Science, vol. 51, no.12, pp. 1734-1752. Arrow, K. J. (1971) Essays in the Theory of Risk-bearing, Markham Pub. Co., Chicago. Aziz, A. M. A. (2007) "A survey of the payment mechanisms for transportation DBFO projects in British Columbia", Construction Management and Economics, vol. 25, no.5, pp. 529 - 543. Baiman, S. and Rajan, M. V. (2002) "Incentive issues in inter-firm relationships", Accounting, Organizations and Society, vol. 27, no.3, pp. 213-238. Bajari, P. and Tadelis, S. (2001) "Incentives versus transaction costs: a theory of procurement contracts", The RAND Journal of Economics, vol. 32, no.3, pp. 387-407. Brown, N. and Deegan, C. (1998) "The public disclosure of environmental performance information -- a dual test of media agenda setting theory and legitimacy theory", Accounting & Business Research (Wolters Kluwer UK), vol. 29, no.1, pp. 21-41. Buitelaar, E., Van der Heijden, R. and Argiolu, R. (2007) "Managing Traffic by Privatization of Road Capacity: A Property Rights Approach", Transport Reviews, vol. 27, no.6, pp. 699 - 713. Campbell, D., Datar, S. M. and Sandino, T. (2009) "Organizational design and control across multiple markets: the case of franchising in the convenience store industry", Accounting Review, vol. 84, no.6, pp. 1749-1779. Christ, M. H., Sedatole, K. L. and Towry, K. L. (2012) "Sticks and Carrots: The Effect of Contract Frame on Effort in Incomplete Contracts", Accounting Review, vol. 87, no.6, pp. 1913-1938. Chung, D. (2009) "Private provision of road infrastructure: unveiling the inconvenient truth in New South Wales, Australia", Road and Transport Research, vol. 18, no.1, pp. 68-85. --- (2012) Contractual approach to optimising risk sharing: a quantitative study of the multidimensional nature of risk in private provision of road infrastructure, PhD thesis, The University of Sydney, Australia. Chung, D., Hensher, D. A. and Rose, J. M. (2010) "Toward the betterment of risk allocation: Investigating risk perceptions of Australian stakeholder groups to public-privatepartnership tollroad projects", Research in Transportation Economics, vol. 30, no.1, pp. 43-58. Cuevas-Rodríguez, G., Gomez-Mejia, L. R. and Wiseman, R. M. (2012) "Has agency theory run its course?: Making the theory more flexible to inform the management of reward systems", Corporate Governance: An International Review, vol. 20, no.6, pp. 526546. de Palma, A., Leruth, L. and Prunier, G. (2012) "Towards a Principal-Agent based typology of risks in Public-Private Partnerships", Reflets et perspectives de la vie économique, vol. 51, no.2, pp. 57-73. Debande, O. (2002) "Private Financing of Transport Infrastructure", Journal of Transport Economics & Policy, vol. 36, no.3, pp. 355-387. Deegan, C. and Rankin, M. (1996) "Do Australian companies report environmental news objectively? An analysis of environmental disclosures by firms prosecuted successfully by the Environmental Protection Authority", Accounting, Auditing & Accountability Journal, vol. 9, no.2, pp. 50-67. 27 of 43 Deegan, C., Rankin, M. and Tobin, J. (2002) "An examination of the corporate social and environmental disclosures of BHP from 1983-1997: A test of legitimacy theory", Accounting, Auditing & Accountability Journal, vol. 15, no.3, pp. 312-343. Deegan, C., Rankin, M. and Voght, P. (2000) "Firms' disclosure reactions to major social incidents: Australian evidence", Accounting Forum, vol. 24, no.1, pp. 101-130. Deegan, C. M. (2002) "Introduction: the legitimising effect of social and environmental disclosures - a theoretical foundation", Accounting, auditing and accountability journal, vol. 15, no.3, pp. 282-311. Dowling, J. and Pfeffer, J. (1975) "Organizational legitimacy: social values and organizational behavior", The Pacific Sociological Review, vol. 18, no.1, pp. 122-136. Eisenhardt, K. M. (1985) "Control: Organizational and Economic Approaches", Management Science, vol. 31, no.2, pp. 134-149. --- (1989) "Agency Theory: An Assessment and Review", The Academy of Management Review, vol. 14, no.1, pp. 57-74. Evans III, J. H., Kim, K. and Nagarajan, N. J. (2006) "Uncertainty, legal liability, and incentive contracts", Accounting Review, vol. 81, no.5, pp. 1045-1071. Fehr, E. and Schmidt, K. M. (2007) "Adding a stick to the carrot? the interaction of bonuses and fines", The American Economic Review, vol. 97, no.2, pp. 177-181. Greene, W. H. and Hensher, D. A. (2003) "A latent class model for discrete choice analysis: contrasts with mixed logit", Transportation Research Part B: Methodological, vol. 37, no.8, pp. 681-698. Hannan, R. L., Hoffman, V. and Moser, D. (2005) 'Bonus versus penalty: does contract frame affect employee effort?', In (Eds, Rapoport, A. and Zwick, R.), Experimental Business Research,ed., Springer US, pp. 151-169. Hart, O. and Moore, J. (1990) "Property rights and the nature of the firm", Journal of Political Economy, vol. 98, no.6, pp. 1119-1158. Hensher, D. A. and Prioni, P. (2002) "A Service Quality Index for Area-Wide Contract Performance Assessment", Journal of Transport Economics and Policy, vol. 36, no.1, pp. 93-113. Hensher, D. A., Rose, J. and Greene, W. H. (2005) Applied Choice Analysis : A Primer, Cambridge University Press. Hensher, D. A., Stopher, P. and Bullock, P. (2003) "Service quality--developing a service quality index in the provision of commercial bus contracts", Transportation Research Part A: Policy and Practice, vol. 37, no.6, pp. 499-517. Holmstrom, B. and Milgrom, P. (1991) "Multitask principal-agent analyses: incentive contracts, asset ownership, and job design", Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization, vol. 7, Special Issue, pp. 24-52. Islam, M. A. and Deegan, C. (2010) "Media pressures and corporate disclosure of social responsibility performance information: a study of two global clothing and sports retail companies", Accounting & Business Research (Wolters Kluwer UK), vol. 40, no.2, pp. 131-148. Jensen, M. C. and Meckling, W. H. (1976) "Theory of the firm: managerial behavior, agency costs and ownership structure", Journal of Financial Economics, vol. 3, no.4, pp. 305360. Jensen, M. C. and Meckling, W. H. (1992) 'Specific and general knowledge and organizational structure', In (Eds, Werin, L. and Wijkander, H.), Contract Economics,ed., Blackwell Ltd, Oxford, U.K.: Basil, pp. 251-274. Jones, S. and Hensher, D. A. (2004) "Predicting Firm Financial Distress: A Mixed Logit Model", The Accounting Review, vol. 79, no.4, pp. 1011-1038. Joskow, P. L. (1985) "Vertical integration and long-term contracts: the case of coal-burning electric generating plants", Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization, vol. 1, no.1, pp. 33-80. 28 of 43 --- (1987) "Contract duration and relationship-specific investments: empirical evidence from coal markets", The American Economic Review, vol. 77, no.1, pp. 168-185. Krishnan, R., Miller, F. and Sedatole, K. (2011) "The use of collaborative interfirm contracts in the presence of task and demand uncertainty", Contemporary Accounting Research, vol. 28, no.4, pp. 1397-1422. Lafontaine, F. and Bhattacharyya, S. (1995) "The role of risk in franchising", Journal of Corporate Finance, vol. 2, no.1–2, pp. 39-74. Luft, J. (1994) "Bonus and penalty incentives contract choice by employees", Journal of Accounting and Economics, vol. 18, no.2, pp. 181-206. Lutz, N. A. (1995) "Ownership rights and incentives in franchising", Journal of Corporate Finance, vol. 2, no.1–2, pp. 103-131. Lyons, B. (1996) "Empirical relevance of efficient contract theory: inter-firm contracts", Oxford Review of Economic Policy, vol. 12, no.4, pp. 27-52. Mäkelä, H. and Näsi, S. (2010) "Social responsibilities of MNCs in downsizing operations", Accounting, Auditing & Accountability Journal, vol. 23, no.2, pp. 149-174. March, J. G. and Shapira, Z. (1987) "Managerial perspectives on risk and risk taking", Management Science, vol. 33, no.11, pp. 1404-1418. Masten, S. E. and Crocker, K. J. (1985) "Efficient adaptation in long-term contracts: take-orpay provisions for natural gas", The American Economic Review, vol. 75, no.5, pp. 1083-1093. Mathews, M. R. (1997) "Twenty-five years of social and environmental accounting research Is there a silver jubilee to celebrate?", Accounting, Auditing & Accountability Journal, vol. 10, no.4, pp. 481-531. Monteiro, R. S. (2010) 'Risk management', In (Eds, Hodge, G. A., Greve, C. and Boardman, A. E.), International Handbook on Public-Private-Partnerships,ed., Edward Elgar, Cheltenham, UK, pp. 262-291. Nagar, V. (2002) "Delegation and innovative compensation", Accounting Review, vol. 77, no.2, pp. 379-395. O'Dwyer, B. (2002) "Managerial perceptions of corporate social disclosure: An Irish story", Accounting, Auditing & Accountability Journal, vol. 15, no.3, pp. 406-436. Polinsky, A. M. (1987) "Fixed Price versus Spot Price Contracts: a study in risk allocation", Journal of Law, Economics, & Organization, vol. 3, no.1, pp. 27-46. Ramanathan, K. V. (1976) "Toward a theory of corporate social accounting", The Accounting Review, vol. 51, no.3, pp. 516-528. Rubin, P. H. (1978) "Theory of the firm and the structure of the franchise contract", Journal of Law and Economics, vol. 21, no.April, pp. 223-233. Sappington, D. E. M. and Weisman, D. L. (1996) "Revenue sharing in incentive regulation plans", Information Economics and Policy, vol. 8, no.3, pp. 229-248. Sedatole, K. L., Vrettos, D. and Widener, S. K. (2012) "The use of management control mechanisms to mitigate moral hazard in the decision to outsource", Journal of Accounting Research, vol. 50, no.2, pp. 553-592. Sitkin, S. B. and Weingart, L. R. (1995) "Determinants of risky decision-making behavior: a test of the mediating role of risk perceptions and propensity", The Academy of Management Journal, vol. 38, no.6, pp. 1573-1592. Tadelis, S. and williamson, O. (2012) "Transaction cost economics", in R. Gibbons, and J. Rooberts (eds), Handbook of organizational economics, Princeton University Press, Princeton, USA. van der Meer-Kooistra, J. and Vosselman, E. G. J. (2000) "Management control of interfirm transactional relationships: the case of industrial renovation and maintenance", Accounting, Organizations and Society, vol. 25, no.1, pp. 51-77. 29 of 43 Vosselman, E. and van der Meer-Kooistra, J. (2009) "Accounting for control and trust building in interfirm transactional relationships", Accounting, Organizations and Society, vol. 34, no.2, pp. 267-283. Widener, S. K., Shackell, M. B. and Demers, E. D. (2008) "The juxtaposition of social surveillance controls with traditional organizational design components", Contemporary Accounting Research, vol. 25, no.2, pp. 605-638. Williamson, O. E. (1985) The Economic Institutions of Capitalism: Firms, Markets, Relational Contracting, Collier Macmillan, London. --- (1991) "Comparative Economic Organization: The Analysis of Discrete Structural Alternatives", Administrative Science Quarterly, vol. 36, no.2, pp. 269-296. --- (2010) "Transaction Cost Economics: the natural progression", American Economic Review, vol. 100, no.3, pp. 673-690. Zhao, R. R. (2008) "All-or-nothing monitoring", The American Economic Review, vol. 98, no.4, pp. 1619-1628. 30 of 43 Table 1: Characteristics of PPPs in the road sector Characteristics of the transaction Asset-based service Outcome-based performance and payment Site specific road asset built and financed by the agent Intense capital investment Lengthy period to recoup capital investment Characteristics of the transaction environment Uncertainty about future contingencies Degree of market risks cannot be estimated reliably Institutional environment (rules, systems and social norms) Characteristics of the transaction parties Heterogeneity in objectives Heterogeneity in risk preference Two-way information asymmetry Double moral hazard 31 of 43 Table 2: Definitions of Risk Attributes Traffic risk Financial risk Network risk force majeure Downside risk of X% indicates that there is a X% probability that the actual traffic volume will be below forecast changes in economic conditions will adversely affect the financial returns the tollroad is expected to earn future transport network developments by government may reduce traffic flows to the tollroad the occurrence of uninsured events may worsen the tollroad’s performance Sovereign risk future changes in government policies may worsen policy fragmentation across different levels of government Risk of unclear project objectives project objectives are unspecified or are unclear to contracting parties and the community Political and reputation risk contracting parties will not deliver the project in the public interest, the public sector is seen as offloading public accountability, thus causing public resentment to the PPP scheme and the project the media is critical of the PPP scheme/project, thus exposing the tollroad to poor publicity Media risk Risk of public perception public acceptance of private ownership of tollroad, public expectations of benefits derived from the tollroad, and of both sectors’ commitment to the community are poor Risk neutral of Y% indicates that there is a Y% probability that the actual traffic volume will be meeting the forecast changes in economic conditions will make no difference to the financial returns the tollroad is expected to earn future transport network developments by government may have no major impact on traffic flows to the tollroad in the event that uninsured events occur, the other party will agree to a transparent approach to redress the aggrieved party future changes in government policies may not have an effect on the existing overall PPP policy framework project objectives are clearly specified and there are clear communications amongst contracting parties and the community political and reputational risk is not of significant concern the media is neutral to the PPP scheme/project, thus resulting in low publicity for the tollroad public perceptions of private ownership of tollroad, public expectations of benefits derived from the tollroad, and of both sectors’ commitment to the community are of insignificant concern Upside gain of Z% indicates that there is a Z% probability that the traffic volume will be above the forecast changes in economic conditions will increase the financial returns the tollroad is expected to earn future transport network developments by government may increase traffic flows to the tollroad all events are well insured, or if not both parties are willing to negotiate in good faith to redress the aggrieved party future changes in government policies may result in a more consistent and coherent PPP policy framework across all political jurisdictions project objectives are made clear to the market and project deliveries will adhere to stated objectives throughout all project phases all parties understand this risk and are willing to internalise this risk within its own sector as well as to collaborate with the other party to resolve public resentment the media is supportive to the PPP scheme/project, it conveys to the community the public benefits of the tollroad, resulting in welcome publicity the public welcomes private ownership of tollroad and public expectations of benefits derived from the tollroad, and of both sectors’ commitment to the community are high 32 of 43 Table 3: Demographic attributes of AGENT# Role Primary decision maker Tollroad operator Debt financier Equity investor Consultant# TOTAL No 24 6 5 12 13 60 Experience in years (no. of projects) 15 (25) 12 (10) 14 (21) 14 (10) 12 (27) Organization No Tollroad company Construction company Commercial bank Investment bank Consultancy # 15 17 9 11 8 60 Multiple roles exist in an organization. For instance, a primary decision maker may come from a construction company while the company may also contribute significant equity finance to the project and hire consultants for advice. Table 4: Project Experience in PPP roads (Regions and Countries) REGION Africa (2 countries) Asia-Pacific (9 countries) Caribbean (2 countries) Europe (13 countries) COUNTRY South Africa Mozambique Australia Bangladesh India Indonesia Korea New Zealand Russia Thailand Vietnam Jamaica Puerto Rico Austria Belgium Croatia REGION Europe (continued) North America (3 countries) South America (3 countries) Total COUNTRY France Greece Hungry Ireland Italy Netherlands Poland Portugal Spain UK Canada Mexico USA Chile Brazil Colombia 32 33 of 43 Table 5: Prior Experience of Risk Borne (Contrast of Mean) Traffic_downside risk (TRAD) Traffic_upside gain (TRAU) Financial_downside risk (FIND) Financial_upside gain (FINU) Network_downside risk (NETD) Network_upside gain (NETU) Force majeure_downside risk (FORD) Force majeure_upside gain (FORU) Sovereign_downside risk (SOVD) Sovereign_upside gain (SOVU) Unclear project objectives_downside risk (UNCD) Unclear project objectives_upside gain (UNCU) Political and reputational_downside risk (POLD) Political and reputational_upside gain (POLU) Media_downside risk (MEDD) Media_upside gain (MEDU) Public perception_downside risk (PUBD) Public perception_upside gain (PUBU) PRINCIPAL Mean (%) 14.15 11.37 13.41 15.20 19.32 21.15 21.88 5.98 23.90 7.93 33.24 12.20 39.20 13.41 41.17 13.10 45.37 12.68 AGENT Mean (%) 54.07 17.38 45.47 22.30 22.78 31.50 14.57 8.12 17.40 9.63 18.60 16.43 21.87 21.03 25.13 18.05 27.63 20.57 Ratio AGENT/PRINCIPAL 3.82 1.53 3.39 1.47 1.18 1.49 0.67 1.36 0.73 1.21 0.56 1.35 0.56 1.57 0.61 1.38 0.61 1.62 Table 6: Survey Questions and Measures of Management Controls Question Measure (1= very unimportant; 7=very important) PRIXCNL c 7 indicates that the ability to exercise this decision right is a very important consideration in evaluating the riskiness of PPPs. FIXPRIX k 7 indicates that the fixed-price compensation scheme is a very important consideration in evaluating the riskiness of PPPs. PERIDC e 7 indicates that the performance measures prescribed in contract are a very important consideration in evaluating the riskiness of PPPs. PENALTY f 7 indicates that the penalty clauses are a very important consideration in evaluating the riskiness of PPPs. DURATION d 7 indicates that the long contract duration is a very important consideration in evaluating the riskiness of PPPs. SURSHARE j 7 indicates that the revenue-sharing between the principal and the agent is a very important consideration in evaluating the riskiness of PPPs. 34 of 43 Table 7: Preferred Investment Choice – PRINCIPAL versus AGENT Scale# Freq. 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Mean # 3 7 7 18 3 3 0 5.86 PRINCIPAL Accumulative Accumulative Freq. % 3 7 10 24 17 41 35 85 38 93 41 100 41 100 Freq. 22 21 4 6 1 5 1 8.57 AGENT Accumulative Accumulative Freq. % 22 36.67 43 71.67 47 78.33 53 88.33 54 90.00 59 98.33 60 100.00 1=PPP is the most preferred; 7=PPP is the least preferred choice 35 of 43 Table 8: Correlations between risk aversion and management controls by incentive and social contracts (N=550) 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 RIA PRIXCNL FIXPRIX PERIDC PENALTY DURATION SURSHARE MEDIANEU PRIXCNL*MEDIANEU Mean Mode Min Max 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 0.238 0.855 0.873 0.291 0.182 0.982 0.091 56.89% 50.82% -4 7 7 4 5 4 60% 240.00% 0.035 1 1 1 1 1 1 0% 0% 0.570 7 7 7 7 7 7 100% 100% 1 0.007 0.165 0.133 -0.142 -0.235 0.197 -0.507 -0.405 1 0.152 -0.190 -0.207 -0.056 -0.228 0.231 0.645 1 0.124 0.039 0.356 -0.069 -0.002 0.068 1 0.632 0.087 0.354 -0.141 -0.182 1 0.179 0.039 0.028 -0.077 1 0.043 0.035 0.003 1 -0.104 -0.164 1 0.850 1 36 of 43 Table 9: The relationship between risk aversion and management controls by incentive and social contracts H1 Expected sign Constant Parameter t-value 0.456 (12.81) *** H2 Parameter 0.517 t-value (17.03) *** PRIXCNL - -0.011 FIXPRIX + 0.103 (6.98) *** 0.113 (8.62) *** PERIDC + 0.071 (5.27) *** 0.052 (4.20) *** PENALTY - -0.106 (-7.06) *** -0.097 (-7.23) *** DURATION - -0.313 (-8.71) *** -0.314 (-9.74) *** SURSHARE + 0.079 (4.68) *** 0.066 (4.33) *** PRIXCNL*MEDIANEU - Adjusted R2 (-0.80) -0.001 (-11.31) *** 0.243 0.387# # Adjusted R2 is higher than that in that in H1 (0.24305), supports H2. N = 550 (50 pilot observations to which FIXPRIX was not surveyed are excluded). ***, **, * indicate a p value of =< 1%, 5%, 10%. 37 of 43 Table 10: Risk Aversion and Choice of Incentive Contract Dependent Variable Ci_AGENT Independent Variable Constant RIA Threshold parameters MU (1) µ (1 to 2) MU (2) µ (2 to 3) MU (3) µ (3 to 4) MU (4) µ (4 to 5) MU (5) µ (5 to 6) MU (6) µ (6 to 7) Marginal effects Independent variable RIA (at mean) AIC LL function N Parameter t-value Hypothesis Support Model -0.001 2.419 (-0.01) (3.77) 1b NO Ordered logit 0 1.505 1.870 2.614 2.787 4.675 (18.22) (20.15) (21.14) (20.98) (14.69) Prob (Y=1) -0.560 t-value (-3.75) Prob (Y=7) 0.038 t-value (3.30) 1787.61 -886.80 600 (N= 60PRVP×5experiments×2contracts) 38 of 43 TCE: management controls to enhance adaptations Management controls Agency theory: management controls embedded with riskbearing implications to foster incentive alignment Social contract: informal control implicit in social contracts to ensure behaviour is consistent with social norms Figure 1: Framework of Triangulation on Management Controls 39 of 43 Agent’s risk aversion H1a: (-) Delegation of decision right to pricing control H1b: (+) H1c: (+) Fixed-price compensation H1d: (-) Performance measures Penalties H1e: (-) Contract duration H1f: (+) Surplus-sharing Mitigate authority misuse H2: strengthens effects of management controls on agent’s risk aversion Neutral media attention from transaction environment Figure 2: Effects of management controls on agent’s risk aversion 40 of 43 1st row 2nd row Figure 3: The Stated Choice Experiment – Contract Choice Figure 4: The Reference Levels – Prior Experience 41 of 43 Figure 5: Other Factors Influencing the Assessment of Riskiness of PPPs Figure 6: Prefer Contract Choice as the Measure of Risk-taking Behaviour 42 of 43 Figure 7: Risk Indices: PRINCIPAL vs. AGENT 43 of 43