Lessons in public sector reform from China Abstract China is a good case study for adoption of “best fit” options for progressive transition to State functioning on “good governance” principles. It‟s spectacular record in sustained economic growth, social and human development and poverty reduction are the outcomes of (a) Nation building around a core commitment to inclusive, pro poor development with a progressive shift towards citizen centric development; (b) providing fiscal and managerial space for strategic decision making to local governments, while simultaneously enhancing fiscal leverage for central oversight over policies and goals; (c) graduated change in the behavior, mind set and skills of its Party and government cadres aligned with the human capital needs of its policies and (d) a comprehensive merit based performance management system for government structures and cadres. Without replicating the institutional structures commonly associated with “good governance” China has embedded aspects of the core principles of accountability and participation within its institutional envelop of single party domination, inner Party democratization, state led, but Nation and increasingly citizen centric, market oriented development and fiscal and administrative decentralization. Keywords Accountability, capacity development, decentralization, nation building, participation, performance management. Authors Xiaoyun Li, China Agricultural University; Sanjeev Ahluwalia, World Bank; Dong Qiang, China Agricultural University 1 Introduction 1. The emergence of China, as a dominant economic power, with concurrent improvements in access to and the quality of basic public services and sharp reductions in the level and scale of poverty, pose the question, whether there are any lessons in public sector management, which can be drawn, from its experience. Reforms commenced in China in 1978 but 1992 was an inflection point. Early in that year, chief reform architect Deng Xiaoping delivered his Southern Tour Speeches, proposing to accelerate the reform process. Later that year, the Fourteenth National Congress of the Communist Party of China confirmed the establishment of a socialist market economy as the country‟s economic system reform objective setting China on the path of a becoming a transitioning market economy. 2. China has had thirty years of continuous, rapid economic growth, unprecedented in world history, at an average annual rate of approximately 10% 1 . In 2010, China‟s GDP accounted for 9.3% of total global output, surpassing Japan to become the world‟s second largest economy. At the same time, China transformed from an agriculture-based, centrallyplanned economy to an industrialized, market-oriented one. In 2011, the country‟s level of urbanization exceeded 50%, with the urban population overtaking its rural counterpart for the first time. Rapid economic growth enabled large-scale poverty reduction. The proportion of the poor population (those earning less than $1.00 a day) declined from 73.5% in 1981 to 8.1% in 2005. The population of the poor reduced by 624 million people during this period. Over the same period, the global incidence of poverty fell from 41.7 to 16.1% or from 1.53 billion to 879 million (Shaohua Chen and Martin Ravallion, 2008). China accounted for 96% of the 1 World Bank data. 2 651 million lifted out of poverty globally during this period. The Government of China reset the national poverty line from 865 to 1,274 RMB, at the end of 2010. Even by this revised classification there were only 26.88 million poor in rural areas. (PRC State Council News Office, 2011). This sets an enviable record of poverty reduction and provides important lessons for the developing world. 3. China has similar significant achievements in public service delivery. In 1978, the central government began to transfer the responsibility of public service delivery to local government. By 1990 public service delivery was positioned as a key component of national development, reflecting the collaborative roles of government, market and civil society. According to assessments by the Ministry of Foreign Affairs and UN China (2008), the country has fully met the second millennium development goal (MDG) of primary education provision and is already moving forward to formulate a national development plan calling for universal nine-year compulsory education. By the end of 2007, the rate of primary school attendance for males and females reached 99.5%. From 2000 to 2006, the completion rate of primary school (five years) rose from 95% to 99%, while the rate of middle school attendance increased to 98% and universal nine-year compulsory education coverage, to 99.3%. During the period 1991 to 2007, the infant mortality rate dropped from 50.2% to 15.3%, and the under-five mortality rate, from 61% to 18.1%, accomplishing another MDG ahead of schedule. The maternal mortality rate is likely to be 75% lower by 2015. In 1990, the number of maternal deaths was 94.7 per 100,000 people. By 2007, this rate had already fallen to 36.6 per 100,000 people, representing a 61.4% decrease. Throughout this period, China endeavoured to restructure its public service system. In 2003, it piloted nationwide the New 3 Rural Cooperative Medical Scheme. By the end of 2009, the number of participating counties (cities and districts) reached 2,716, while the program‟s coverage included 833 million people, or a participation rate of 94.19%2. In 1999, the government established the Minimum Living Standards Guarantee Scheme, eventually extending this program into rural areas in 2007. By 2010, the scheme covered 23,105,000 urban residents and 52,140,000 rural residents3 3. This remarkable story of social and economic transformation with striking results in poverty reduction begs the question; Are there lessons in economic growth and poverty reduction for the rest of the developing world? The prevailing view is that China‟s success is due to circumstances which are not replicable elsewhere, as evidenced by the following: the extended political stability, due to the Communist Party of China (Party) being continuously in power since 1949 and enabling thereby, long term strategic planning and uninterrupted implementation; the relative cultural homogeneity of China, diluting the political imperative for multiparty politics, so important in more fractured societies; and the strategic convenience of Hong Kong and Taiwan, as off shore conduits for foreign investment and the harmonious assimilation of private sector led, market oriented policies, into the socialist political fabric of the country. Barry Naughton, identifies three features of China‟s experience which are unique: the scale of China and the possibilities offered by a large internal market; the emergence of new industry based on labor intensive development after a period of state socialism based on capital intensive development; and the maintenance and restructuring of China‟s hierarchical authoritarian system (Minglu Chen and David S. G. Goodman, 2012). 4. 2 3 It is striking, however, that many developing countries have enjoyed similar Ministry of Health, PRC, 2010 Ministry of Civil Affairs, PRC, 2011 4 advantages but without comparable results from episodic attempts at public sector reform, most often funded by foreign aid. Tanzania has had the same political party in power since independence in1962. It has an abundance of natural resources and direct access to the sea. It enjoys tribal and religious harmony unlike much of Africa. It also went through thirty years of socialist political rule before starting to liberalize its economy in 1992. However, the results in poverty reduction, social and human development do not elicit widespread acclaim. India is another continental sized country with a comparable population, a large domestic market, the potential for export led growth, an extended period of state investments in industrial and infrastructure development since the early 1950‟s and significant social transformation through democratization, including political plurality at all levels of government over the last twenty five years. Yet results in poverty reduction, social and human development remain unexceptional. The hypothesis 5. This paper hypothesizes that the key difference between China and other developing countries, is the selective but committed embedding of core good governance principles, as the norm for government functioning. It is important here to distinguish between the core good governance principles of “transparency, accountability and participation” and the institutional forms of good governance which have become commonplace but rigid symbols of good governance. The principle of transparency, which is intended to enable informed over sight, has come to mean formal access to public information for citizens and an expansion in the scope and range of public information preferably through a Right to Information law. What is stressed in assessments of transparency is the legal right to information or the 5 existence of formal mechanisms for getting access to public information rather than measuring the availability of information demanded by an average citizen. The principle of horizontal accountability is measured on the basis of the existence and functioning of an elected and capable legislature; an independent and capable judiciary and other oversight entities, like an Audit Agency and Anti Corruption Agency, as essential institutions for horizontal accountability. However attribution of a specific form of institutional development to results with respect to services for citizens is uncertain. Vertical accountability is equated to functional rules of service for public servants, clear identification of roles, responsibilities and delegated powers with sanctions and rewards based on measurable criteria of individual performance. Similarly the benchmarks for downward accountability to citizens are the use of direct citizen feedback systems on the performance of government like service delivery surveys and citizen score cards including, more recently, the use of social media for this purpose. Increasing levels of participation of citizens from managing schools to street lighting to local level planning and monitoring of budget execution are viewed under the “demand for good governance framework” as positive outcomes of open government. 6. China clearly does not fit into this model of “good governance”. It does not score high on transparency indicators. Its leaders are not “democratically” elected by the people but are selected through an inner party process which is not “transparent” in that a leader is chosen by the Party. The line between what is permitted in the media and what is not is unclear and needs to be negotiated with care and access to public information is not legally enforceable by citizens. Citizens cannot march into a government engineer‟s office and demand to see his accounts as they can in India. In China the Communist Party of China (The 6 Party) rules and is supreme. There is no concept of an independent judiciary or legislature so horizontal accountability, beyond and outside of what the Party considers appropriate, does not exist. Citizens were not invited, till recently, to participate in service delivery surveys or to review the budget of their city or village or monitor government expenditure. However, vertical accountability within the Party/government is rigidly enforced. Vertical accountability is based on clearly developed work programs and responsibilities with quantified targets, which feed into national programs. Performance is monitored and less than adequate performance is sanctioned, sometimes harshly. While China does not fit into the conventional model of good governance, this paper hypothesizes that it enforces the core good governance principles of accountability and participation. It enforces downward accountability by making the Party responsible for ensuring the well being of citizens. Participation is similarly ensured through inner party democratization. Consensual adherence to these principles explains its exemplary performance in poverty reduction, social development and economic growth. More significantly in the thirty years since 1992 when the reform commenced China has shown its capacity for adaptive behavior to align the Party with the aspirations of the people without losing its dominance. This strategy has given it the political space for sustained reforms. Building a Nation 7. If “good governance” is equated with “development effectiveness” China is a star performer based on sustained economic growth, social and human development and poverty reduction. It does this by ensuring that all levels of the Party and the government, commit to and work towards, implementing the shared objective of national development, but with considerable freedom, for lower levels, to develop localized operational strategies. This sense 7 of personal commitment to a national goal is weak elsewhere and “nation-building” is no longer considered necessary in a globalised world, except in the context of fragile states where it is seen as“glue” which could bind fractured societies. However, as the recent Euro zone crisis illustrates, even in the developed world, building and maintaining a citizen‟s sense of belonging to a nation is based on a functional, credible and legitimate state. This is the approach that China has taken since 1947. State building in China The Party and the State 8. China does not distinguish between the State and the Party. This is not unique. There are any number of countries where this distinction does not exist de facto, though the façade of “democratic” elections is played out. China views democratization as a progressive goal which must be preceded by developing a capable State and Party. It has consequently worked to build the State over the last sixty years. The centrality of the Party provides the ground for national consensus. China‟s political system has always been one of centralized state power. In 1949, following the establishment of the Communist Party of China, the Party and the State became indistinguishable. The relationship between Party and the State is principally reflected in the notion of “Party represents and is indistinguishable from government” (以党代政,党 政不分) (Ding Xueliang 2011: 44). While this relationship has undergone changes post 1978, the Party continues to lead the government through direct or indirect means. 9. Beginning in 1982, and then again in 1988, 1993, 1998, 2003, and 2008, the Chinese government implemented six institutional reforms, attempting to simplify and restructure its structures and systems. In the early years the government studied and implemented the 8 Soviet model of a planned economy, with planning administration as its primary means of economic regulation. Prior to the reform and opening up, the Party designed national development plans according to the guiding principle of continuous revolution, committing, what would later be considered, a number of errors. In 1978, the Third Plenary Session of the Eleventh Central Committee of the CPC decided to shift the focus of the Party and the State toward the modernization of socialism. Since then, the Party not only produces a long-term plan for socio-economic development, it also details specific objectives, focal points and measures which the government and its various departments implement (Zhou Tianyong, 2008: 92). Nation building 10. Nation-building began at the turn of the 20th century, during the late Qing, early Republican era, when Sun Yat-sen proposed the “Three Principles of the People,” attempting to resolve the crisis in state authority and establish a modern State. In Sun Yat-sen‟s view, following the expulsion of the Manchus from power, the Chinese people had been able to recover their own nation and its political system (Sun Yat-sen 1956: 68-70). With the support of nationalist sentiment, Sun Yat-sen achieved national integration and produced a cohesive State. The Kuomintang, or Nationalist government, however, could not complete Sun Yatsen‟s nation-building project. Subsequent to the Party gaining power, China transformed into a totalist state system, exercising absolute control over society. National development became the common objective of the Party, government and the people and the interest of the State superseded all other considerations. In 1953, the Party initiated the expropriation of all private business rights. In 1958, the central Party-State called on the masses to construct backyard 9 furnaces as part of a large-scale, all-encompassing steel-smelting campaign. That same year, it began the construction of the people‟s communes, collectivizing ownership of the means of production and allocating labour based on work-points. The people‟s commune directly eliminated the private ownership of land and squeezed out peasant household industries. In 1955, urban youth began to arrive in rural areas to engage in the reclamation of land. In December 1968, Mao Zedong transmitted his instructions for “young intellectuals to be sentdown to countryside to receive the indispensible re-education of Chinese rural poverty,” launching the “go up the mountain and go down to the village” (上山下乡) movement. In those years, all middle and high school students (i.e., students who would have been attending school between 1966 and 1968) were sent-down. An exceptionally high proportion of these students were forced to participate as a result of political pressure. 11. From 1949 to 1978, China‟s development plans failed to focus on citizens as partners in the process of national building. Citizens were viewed as a source for labour for centrally planned development. In 1978, the Eleventh Plenary Session of the Third Central Committee of the CPC recognized that given the lagging economy, disordered political system, Socialism faced a crisis of legitimacy. The Party resolved to initiate reform with the objective of implementing citizen centric development, which was expected to reinforce the political legitimacy of the Party. This trend was reinforced in the 1990s, following the momentous changes in Eastern Europe. Decentralisation 12. Decentralisation, a key component of “good governance”, has been a key feature of China‟s strategy for inclusive development. However, decentralisation has not followed the 10 traditional model of synergistic and parallel devolution of political, administrative and financial powers and functions. China‟s model of decentralisation is a hybrid of centralised revenue raising powers, policy development and government cadre management coupled with high levels of fiscal and administrative decentralisation enabling tactical decision making at the local level for implementing national policies. Political power remains tightly vested in the Party. The Party in turn intervenes closely in the appointment of all government functionaries. Fiscal powers for raising revenues have been centralised over the period 1978 to 2009. The share of local revenue in national revenue fell from a level of 84.5% in 1978 to 47.6% in 2009. However expenditure at the local level increased from 52.6% to 80% over the same period4. This was aligned to the strategy to increasingly decentralizing power. With the freedom to innovate on how to implement centrally planned development, local governments have continuously expanded the scale of local economic activity, enhancing their local economic potential. While the 1994 tax sharing reform, weakened local government‟s ability to raise fiscal resources, it did not constrain the availability of fiscal resources for locally led development, although all development is within the broad parameters of central policy. The key innovation in China has been the centralisation of revenue raising powers, with the objective of acquiring leverage to enforce central goals and policies and yet encourage decentralized decision-making and strategies for achieving these goals, including the decentralization of expenditure powers. Annex 1 gives a more detailed account of the evolution of fiscal management in China. Capacity development of Party and government cadres 4 China Statistical Yearbook-2010 11 13. China gives great importance to shaping the mind set and skills of its cadres, to align with the requirements of its development strategy. Elsewhere, capacity development is primarily funded by foreign aid, loosely regulated, inadequately “owned” by governments and usually delivered by international consultancy organizations, which thrive on “cookie cutter” approaches. It is no wonder then, that it is often unrelated to the underlying incentives, organizational structure and development strategy, leading to uncertain results in learning, behavioral change or effectiveness in work. To construct a system conducive to economic development, the objectives, priorities, sense of responsibility and expectation of shared benefit of the process‟s core participants must be reshaped, thereby fundamentally cultivating a common rationality (Dietrich Rueschemeyer, 1977). China adopted a three pronged strategy for capacity development. The first component of this strategy was to disseminate the national vision of the government. The second was to reinforce training. The third was to strengthen the review and approval process of cadre appointments and promotions at all levels of the party organization (Shen Dawei, 2011: 201). In 1995, the Party initiated the “Three Stresses Campaign” announcing that cadre education would focus on three areas, namely, learning, politics and righteousness. In 2004, it initiated an advanced education program and in 2008, it developed a study program for development practioners. The Party attaches great importance to cadre education and training. Since the beginning of the new century, the central government has formulated two five-year plans for cadre education and training, the “20012005 National Cadre Education and Training Plan” and “2006-2010 National Cadre Education and Training Plan,” in addition to the “2010-2020 Cadre Education and Training Work Reform Outline.” In 2006, it also drew up a preliminary version of “Cadre Education 12 and Training Work Regulations.” Under the leadership of the central party committee, the Central Organization Department oversees the division of work and responsibility within the state apparatus and the management of cadre education and training at each level of government. It is responsible for the overall regulation of nationwide cadre education as well as for the education and training of centrally-supervised cadres of specialists and technical experts of key state-owned enterprises and financial institutions. Each region must follow the requirements of the cadre education and training management system, delegating responsibility for relevant tasks. 14. The content of cadre education and training is designed according to responsibilities and administrative levels and primarily encompasses political theory, policy legislation, professional knowledge, cultural education and skills training. While political theory education remains the principal focus, the training also offers elective study, full and part-time programs and learning opportunities both at home and abroad, promoting the all-around enhancement of cadres‟ quality and capacity. In addition, the training targets particular partystate officials (i.e., leading cadres, reserve cadres, grassroots cadres, female cadres, ethnic minority cadres, non-party cadres and other public functionaries) and, according to their level and classification, provides party-state officials, enterprise managers and technical experts with educational training. The cadre education and training mechanism primarily consists of party schools and institutes / academies of governance, socialism and cadre management as well as the Central Organization Department‟s directly-controlled Yan‟an Cadre Academy, Jinggangshan Cadre Academy, Pudong Cadre Academy and China Business Executives Academy (Dalian). There are about 2,700 party schools, more than 2,000 local academies of 13 governance and over 1,000 institutes of socialism nationwide. The party schools focus more on politics and ideology, the academies of governance emphasize economic and practical skills, and the institutes of socialism primarily train ethnic minority cadres and other United Front representatives (David Shambaugh, 2008). In addition, members from business training organizations, institutions of higher education and scientific research institutes also participate in cadre education and training. 15. By September 2000, the Central Party School had trained four million cadres of which 2.3 million were from mid-to-high level ranks, 4,500 “young reserve cadres,” 3,000 ethnic minority cadres and 7,300 Propaganda Department cadres and Central Party School instructors (Wan Fuyi, 2001: 292). By the end of 2001, half of the country‟s 6,932,000 cadres had been trained; 989,000 at a party school; 195,000 at an academy of governance; 225,000 at a cadre management college and 1,669,000 through other forms of professional training programs (General Office of the Central Organization Department, 2002). Performance management 16. China has an effective system for performance management, which focuses on results and not process. Even the Party subjects itself to performance review, with derived performance measures for lower cadres and levels of government. Following the 1978 decision to concentrate on economic reform, China established an effective system for evaluating the performance of local government officials based on economic growth rates. The lack of “clutter”, or inclusion of multiple objectives for performance evaluation, enabled quantitative evaluation though attribution of results to effort may have become uncertain. Performance assessment is the determining factor in career progression of local officials. The 14 Chinese government uses a top-down approach to the formulation and articulation of objectives, requiring lower levels of government to handle implementation. Performance evaluation is based on quantitative measures derived from the “list of duties” of each employee. At the beginning of each year, the State Council draws up a government work report, summarising the past year‟s work and putting forth the current year‟s objectives. All ministries and commissions use the relevant content of the government work report to craft more specific departmental targets, subsequently transmitting them down the ranks. Every level of local government must summarize and report on those targets passed down to them from their superiors before transmitting them once again to even lower-level ranks. National medium-to-long term strategic plans, likewise, follow the aforementioned process of target formulation, dissemination and assessment. 20. In China‟s model of collaborative leadership of party and government, the Party is responsible for the evaluation and promotion of local officials while the central government articulates development objectives. (Zhou Li‟an, 2007). Party-State officials of equal rank from across all the Regions of China compete on the basis of economic growth rates as the measure of their relative performance. This mechanism ensures that officials both articulate and disseminate these growth objectives among their subordinates. In practice, the performance evaluation system results in healthy but intense competition among local officials of equal rank since it is closely linked to rewards and sanctions. This system aligns individual incentives with national objectives. On the basis of panel data from 28 provinces and directly controlled municipalities, between 1979 and 2002, Zhou Li‟an, Li Hong bin and Chen Ye (2005) established that economic performance significantly influenced the 15 promotions of provincial officials. Secondly, they found that performance trends over several years had a higher impact on career prospects than single year‟s performance signalling appropriate attribution of results to effort. 21. The shift in 1992 from single minded pursuit of economic growth to comprehensive development presented a major challenge for performance evaluation since the performance matrix has expanded. Due to information asymmetries and unquantifiable objectives the previously “closed” system of performance evaluation has become insufficient. The Party and government has responded to this new challenge by beginning to associate citizens with performance assessments of government using surveys of the level of citizen satisfaction with public services. The 2006 “Scientific Outlook on Development‟s Pilot Methods for the Comprehensive Evaluation of Local Party and State Leading Groups and Cadres” lists the use of statistical data to rate performance. Some of the principal performance indicators included: local per capita GDP and its rate of increase, per capita fiscal revenue and its rate of increase, urban and rural incomes and their rates of increase, resource consumption and production safety, elementary education, urban employment, social security, urban and rural cultural life, population and family planning, arable land conservation, environmental protection and investment and innovation in science and technology. More specific targets are formulated related to local conditions. Meritocratic based career progression 22. While adherence to Party principles is a primary requirement, recruitment and promotion in China, is meritocratic and performance counts towards personal progress at all levels. This is in sharp contrast to other developing countries where no more than lip service 16 is paid to performance management and results orientation and recruitment is often non meritocratic and personal progress is often unrelated to performance. The Party manages the entire process of cadre recruitment, evaluation, promotion and supervision. At the time of cadre selection, it pays close attention to both political and professional criteria along the lines of being “both red and expert” (又红又专). After 1978, with economic growth as the primary development objective, while being “red” continued to be a fundamental criterion increasing emphasis is placed on professional ability. When politics itself demands specialization, cadres must become experts if they want to be considered “red” (James R. Townsend and Brantly Womack 2003), In August 1980, Deng Xiaoping5 stated that “In accordance with enterprise development, it is necessary to formulate new requirements and new means for upgrading each industry‟s cadres and talented employees. In the future, many professions and positions will hire only on the basis of tested qualifications.” 23. Beginning in 1990, the Party laid out a series of new regulations to enhance the overall quality of party-state cadres by consistently improving selection methods. In 1995, the central government issued the “Provisional Regulations for the Selection and Appointment of Party and State Leading Cadres.” Seven years later, in 2002, it again drew up the “Regulations for the Selection and Appointment of Party and State Leading Cadres.” These regulations stipulated that leading party-state cadres must possess the following basic prerequisites: 1) They must possess knowledge about Marxism-Leninism, Maoist Thought and Deng Xiaoping Theory necessary to fulfil their position‟s obligations and earnestly practice the Three Represents‟ main ideas; 2) They must have a long term goal of communism 5 “Reform of the Party and State Leadership System,” 17 and a firm belief in Socialism with Chinese Characteristics, resolutely implementing the Party‟s guidelines and policies and be committed to the reform, opening up and modernization, during which they must endure hardship to achieve significant change; 3) By maintaining liberation ideals, seeking evidence based options, remaining professionally competent, being innovative in solving real problems and conducting investigations and research, they are to integrate Party policy with practical conditions at the local level to make performance more effective; 4) They must be committed to the revolutionary cause, be politically responsible and have the practical experience; organizational ability, educational qualifications and specialized knowledge to be a competent leader. In 2004, the Central Committee of the CPC formulated its “Provisional Regulations for the Public Selection of Party and State Leading Cadres” and it‟s “Provisional Regulations for Competitive Posting in Party and State Organizations.” These two provisions institutionalised the government‟s inclusion of merit and qualifications. In April 2005, the Fifteenth Session of the Tenth National People‟s Congress Standing Committee approved the “People‟s Republic of China Civil Servant Law,” stipulating that for appointments at the level of section head and below as well as for other non-leadership positions, the methods of public examination, equal competition and merit based recruitment should be adopted. In 2006, the Central Organization Department began implementing the “Scientific Outlook on Development‟s Pilot Methods for the Comprehensive Evaluation of Local Party and State Leading Groups and Cadres.” Within these methods, it required a commitment to integrity and talent, real accomplishment and publically accepted principles. In order to evaluate ethics and ability, it suggested a variety of methods, including democratic nomination, democratic assessment, opinion polls, and 18 analyses of accomplishment and individual conversations. Conclusion 24. China‟s spectacular record in pro poor economic growth is a significant testimonial to its policy for inclusive development. Viewed top down, from the perspective of international development, it is difficult to endorse how consultative this process has been or whether the tight time frame in which economic growth has been achieved was indeed arrived at in a consensual manner or whether the costs to individual freedom were justified using a cost benefit approach. Against this is the fact that China has lifted more than 600 million citizens out of poverty over the last thirty years and today enjoys international political and economic status. These achievements are plausibly the result of explicit policy choices. These policy choices have emphasized nation building over individual freedom. The Party processes represent the democratic choices of the citizens. To the extent this remains true, citizens drive State action. China explicitly recognizes and facilitates local initiatives in the management of development, within a national policy framework. China has a State led market oriented economy. Significant effort is expended to enhance the effectiveness of the State in implementing national policy. Capacity development for aligning the behavior, mind set and skills of the Party and State cadres with the evolving needs of the nation is a key input into enhancing State effectiveness. Performance management is similarly a priority and is universally applied through the prescription of quantitative targets for State entities and individuals. The targets are based on aggregate results related to economic growth and development rather than the provision of inputs or the achievement of intermediate processes. While the technical efficiency of a “performance for results” system is not well established 19 the fact that performance against targets is linked to individual rewards and sanctions provides powerful incentives and motivation for the Party and State cadres to compete, enhancing thereby system effectiveness. This performance management system has served the State well during the phase of rapid economic growth. It is unclear however, whether the same system can be adapted to subsequent phases of slowing economic growth and enhanced citizen demands for deeper consultations and participation in decision making. The commitment to use merit as a criteria for initial appointment and subsequent career progression, coupled with rising incomes and the benefits from enhanced levels of human development, enabling larger numbers to enter the competition for Party and State jobs, provides the basis for inclusive nation building. All developing countries face the dilemma of State building in terms of striking the right balance between State power and individual rights. The intrusiveness of State power is also closely linked to the alignment of individual interests with national interests, as interpreted by the State. States which seek to emulate external models of governance, without testing these first against the context in which they are to operate, face the possibility of State objectives becoming increasingly divergent from individual interests, resulting in increasingly negative, often violent, interfaces between the State and citizens, sparking of a vicious cycle of State repression and citizen protest. This is a challenge which the Party has addressed by showing remarkable capacity to adapt and change. In many ways, the pervasive influence of the Party has enabled this change to be implemented, even when the demand for enhanced democratization has arisen because of the incompetence of corrupt local Party officials. With enhanced human development levels and incomes and the technology revolution, has come the challenge of managing social expectations and 20 adapting to the convening power of social media. It is not known how the Party will respond to the increasing ability of citizens to mobilize virtually, including across borders and what changes in Party structures and systems would be necessary to address the enhanced political expectations of citizens. However the Party has three key strengths which are likely to enable it to bridge the transition without losing its dominance. First, the system of merit based selection of cadres and leaders provides equal opportunities to citizens, to share in political power and participate in decision making, thereby diluting opposition. Second, the Party is extremely conscious that its legitimacy rests on remaining responsive to citizen concerns, within the framework of its dominance. Third, the growing non ideological orientation of the Party will continue to focus its efforts on the delivery of results on the ground, with respect to citizen satisfaction. These strengths are likely to enable the Party to transcend current international trends in political pluralism. 25. The key lessons for developing economies are that inclusive, pro poor economic growth is a useful tool for nation building and establishing the legitimacy of the State. Investments in social and human development are key for sustained economic growth and for sustaining the credibility of the State. Sustained single party dominance can only be ensured by testing leaders through inner party democratization, intensive cadre management, including capacity development and aligning the party objectives with the interests of citizens. Accountability and contestability are key for performance management in party or government structures. Results orientation is a key ingredient of development effectiveness which grounds the complex systems and processes of the State, in the reality of the lives of citizens. None of these conclusions are new. However, what this paper seeks to hypothesize is 21 that China has internalized all these aspects of political and administrative governance. It is therefore fertile ground for further research on performance management, inclusive growth, effective capacity development and the adoption of “best fit good governance” principles. 22 References: 1. Brandt, L. and Rawski, T (Eds) (2008) China’s Great Transformation: Origins, Mechanism, and Consequences of the Post-Reform Economic Boom. New York: Cambridge University Press. 2. Chen, M. and Goodman, D. (2012) „The China Model: one country, six authors‟, Journal of Contemporary China 21(73): 169-185. 3. Chen, S. and Ravallion, M. (2008) „The developing world is poorer than we thought, but no less successful in the fight against poverty‟, Development Research Group, World Bank. 4. CPC Central Committee Editing Council (1994) Selected Works of Deng Xiaoping: vol. 2. Beijing: People‟s Press. 5. Ding, X. (2011) Debating the “China Model”. Beijing: Social Sciences Academic Press. 6. Ministry of Civil Affairs (2010) „2010 Social services development statistical report‟, available at http://www.mca.gov.cn/article/zwgk/mzyw/201106/20110600161364.shtml. Accessed DATE. 7. Ministry of Foreign Affairs and UN China (2008) China’s Progress Toward The Millennium Development Goals 2008 Report. 8. Ministry of Health (2010) China Health Statistical Yearbook-2010. Beijing: China Union Medical College Press. 9. Montalvo, J. and Ravallion, M. (2010) „The pattern of growth and poverty reduction in China‟, Journal of Comparative Economics 38: 2-16. 10. National Bureau of Statistics (2011) China Statistical Yearbook-2010. Beijing: China Statistics Press. 11. National Bureau of Statistics (2011) „People‟s Republic of China 2011 National Economic and Social Development Statistical Bulletin‟, available at http://www.stats.gov.cn/tjgb/ndtjgb/qgndtjgb/t20120222_402786440.htm. Accessed DATE. 12. Naughton, B. (2007) The Chinese Economy. Cambridge: MIT Press. 13. PRC Central Organization Department General Office (2002) Overview of Party Organizational Work Accomplishments Since the Thirteenth-Third Plenary Session. Beijing: Party Building Reader Press. 14. PRC State Council News Office (2011) „New progress in China‟s rural poverty reduction‟, white paper. 15. Rueschemeyer, D. (1977) „Structural Differentiation, Efficiency and Power‟, American Journal of Sociology 83(1): 1-25. 16. Shambaugh, D. (2008) „Training China‟s Political Elite: the Party School System‟, China Quarterly 196: 827–844. 23 17. Shambaugh, D. and Lu, Z. and Wang, X. (trans.) (2011) China’s Communist Party: Atrophy & Adaptation. Beijing: Central Compilation and Translation Press. 18. Sun, Y. (1956) Sun Yat-sen Anthology: vol. 1. Beijing: People‟s Press. 19. Townsend, J. and Womack, B. (2004) Politics in China. Jiangsu, China: People‟s Press. 20. Wan, F. (2001) Grand Dictionary of the Building of the Communist Party of China. Shandong: People‟s Press. 21. World Bank: World Development Indicators database, available at http://data.worldbank.org.cn/indicator/NY.GDP.MKTP.KD.ZG?page=6. Accessed DATE. 22. Zhao, S. (2010) „The China Model: can it replace the Western model of modernization?‟, Journal of Contemporary China 19(65): 419-436. 23. Zhou, L. (2004) „Government officials‟ incentive and cooperation within the promotions gamble: a discussion of local protectionism and the causes of long-term superfluous construction‟, Economic Research 6: PAGES. 24. Zhou, L. (2007) „Study of the Chinese local officials‟ promotions contest model‟, Economic Research 7: PAGES. 25. Zhou, L., Li, H. and Chen, Y. (2005) „Relative performance evaluation: empirical research on China‟s local officials promotions system‟, Economic Research 1(1): PAGES. 26. Zhou, T. (2008) China Administrative System Reform. Shanghai: People‟s Press. 24 Annex 1 Fiscal management in China since the 1980’s 1 Beginning in 1980, the central party-state switched from the past system of fiscal administration, namely, unified collection and allocation, to that of “eating in separate kitchens” (分灶吃饭). This reform emphasized that the central and local government “divide revenue and expenditure and delegate responsibilities” (划分收支、分级包干). In 1985, central and local government put into practice the fiscal administration system of “dividing taxes, auditing revenue and expenditure, and delegating responsibilities” (划分税种、核定收 支、分级包干), improving upon the former system of “eating in separate kitchens.” Three years later, due to the decline in the proportion of central revenue, the central party-state initiated the fiscal responsibility system. And although this system raised the proportion of central revenues, it failed to increase them at the same rate as the country‟s economic growth. More damagingly, it triggered interregional fiscal competition and closed-off local markets. 2. In 1993, the State Council issued its “Decision on Implementing Fiscal Management of the Tax-Sharing System,” and a year later, put it into effect. The principles and content of the tax-sharing system reform include: in accordance with the division of authority between central and local government, rationally determine the expenditure limit at level of the financial administration; based on the principle of integrated authority and financial control, designate each type of tax as either central, local or shared, and establish separate central and local tax collection mechanisms; scientifically audit local revenues and expenditures, progressively carrying out a relatively regulated central transfer system; and establish a strong separated budgetary system, hardening budget constraints at every level. This tax system 25 reform stipulated that central, local and shared taxes all had to be legislated at the central level, ensuring unified national policy and equal competition within an integrated domestic market and among enterprises. The 1994 Tax-Sharing System accomplished the central party-state‟s objective of a unified tax authority and stripped local government‟s right to levy and/or reduce taxes. Local government could only adopt adaptive measures (e.g., fees, funds and tax returns) to raise or reduce taxes. Table 1 lists the distribution of taxes between the centre and local governments. Table 1: Types of Central and Local Taxes Domestic value-added tax Central Tax Local Tax √(75%) √(25%) Domestic sales tax √ Import value-added and sales taxes Export value-added and sales taxes √ √ (92.5%) √ (2.5%) √ √ Enterprise revenue tax √ (60%) √ (40%) Personal income tax √ (60%) √ (40%) Business tax √ Natural resource tax Urban maintenance and construction tax √ √ Property tax Stamp tax √ √ (97%) √ (3%) Urban land-use tax √ Land value-added tax √ Vehicle tax √ Shipping tax √ Vehicle purchase tax √ Customs tariff √ Arable land occupation tax √ Contract tax √ Tobacco tax √ 26 Other taxed income or √ revenue Source:National Bureau of Statistics,China Statistical Yearbook-2010. 3. √ Under the current division of tax authority between central and local government, the central fiscal administration is principally responsible for expenditures related to national security, foreign affairs, ministerial operations, national economic restructuring, regional development coordination, macro-level regulation and the development of centrally-run public institutions. More specifically, this includes: expenditures for national defence, military police, diplomatic affairs, foreign aid, central administration, centrally-owned enterprises technical upgrading and prototype design, geological exploration, centrally-planned agricultural support, repayment of domestic and international debts, central public security authorities and programs related to culture, education, health and science. The local fiscal administration is principally responsible for the expenditures of local authorities and the development of the area‟s economy and public institutions. Specifically, this includes costs related to local administration, public security, military police, the people‟s militia, project planning and basic investment, local enterprise technical upgrading and prototype design, agricultural supports, urban maintenance and construction, improvement of local culture, education and health, price subsidies and other supports. Table 2 provides data on central and local government revenues and expenditures‟ Table 2: Proportion of Central and Local Revenue and Expenditures, 1978-2009 Proportion of Fiscal Revenue Proportion of Fiscal (%) Expenditure (%) Year Central Local Central Local 1978 15.5 84.5 47.4 52.6 1980 24.5 75.5 54.3 45.7 27 1985 38.4 61.6 39.7 60.3 1990 33.8 66.2 32.6 67.4 1994 55.7 44.3 30.3 69.7 1995 52.2 47.8 29.2 70.8 2000 52.2 47.8 34.7 65.3 2005 52.3 47.7 25.9 74.1 2009 52.4 47.6 20.0 80.0 Source: National Bureau of Statistics, China Statistical Yearbook-2010. 4. In 1994, to prevent the tax-sharing system from causing a decline in local financial resources, the central party-state created a system of fiscal transfers. Using this mechanism, it managed to achieve uniform public service provision across different localities. The fiscal transfer system primarily includes tax returns, transfer payments, organizational and settlement grants and special project transfer payments. The transfer payments include those for general purposes, minority regions, wage adjustments, rural tax reform, and county-village award stipends, among others. Special transfer payments include social security, health and sanitation, science and technology, education, waterworks, etc. As the central party-state has not placed too many restrictions on fiscal transfer funds, local government can be relatively flexible with spending. The special transfer payments, by contrast, can only be used for particular projects as directed by the central party-state. At the same time, they also require local government to provide matching funds. 28