1 The description of the economy x = f (k, l) = k 1/2 + l1/2 y = f (k, l) = k 1/2 l1/2 uA (x, y) = xy uB (x, y) = x + y Person A owns firm x Person B owns firm y and 10 units of k and of l Normalize: px = 1 2 Profit maximization 2.1 Profit maximization for firm producing y: max py k1/2 l1/2 − pk k − pl l Since the production function is constant returns to scale ("takal") we know that in a competitive equilibrium, if the firm produces then it is indifferent about the level of production. Specifically, if profits = py k 1/2 l1/2 − pk k − pl l > 0 for some k ∗ , l∗ then by doubling to 2k ∗ and 2l∗ the firm will double its profits, and hence at these prices the firm will produce an infinite amount and therefore this cannot happen in a competitive equilibrium. So either the firm does not produce and py k1/2 l1/2 − pk k − pl l ≤ 0, or it is indifferent about the level of production, and then py k 1/2 l1/2 − pk k − pl l = 0. Let’s continue to solve assuming it does produce. (We know that the firm will produce if person A has any income, because if A has income then A will demand some y so in equilibrium the firm must produce.) So we have the equation ¡ ¢1/2 ¡ D ¢1/2 py kyD − pk kyD − pl lyD = 0 ly (1) and of course the production equation ¡ D ¢1/2 ¡ D ¢1/2 ky = yS ly (2) Taking derivatives and set equal to zero gives: py M Pk = pk and py M Pl = p l1/2 p k1/2 y y = pk , and 2l = pl . Since the level of k and l are pl . That is 2k 1/2 1/2 not determined by these conditions, because of the constant-returns-to-scale technology discussed in the preceding paragraph, we know that these equations only determine the relative use of k and l. So dividing one by the other we get py l1/2 py k1/2 / 2l1/2 2k1/2 = pk /pl , or D ly kyD = pk pl , so lyD = pk D k pl y 1 (3) We can substitute equation 3 into equations 1 and 2 to obtain simpler relations. ¡ ¢1/2 ¡ D ¢1/2 ¡ ¢1/2 ³ pk D ´1/2 −pk kyD −pl lyD = 0 so py kyD −pk kyD − ly First, py kyD pl ky ³ ´ ³ ´1/2 ³ ´1/2 kyD − 2pk kyD = 0, so py ppkl − 2pk = 0, so pl ppkl kyD = 0, so py ppkl ³ ´1/2 , so py = 2pk ppkl 1 (4) (py )2 = pk pl 4 ³ ´ ¡ ¢1/2 ¡ D ¢1/2 ¡ D ¢1/2 ³ pk D ´1/2 D pk Second y S = kyD ly = ky k = k y pl y pl . Thus S y = 2.2 kyD µ pk pl ¶ (5) Profit maximization for firm producing x: ¡ ¢ max px k 1/2 + l1/2 − pk k = pl l Solution (recall px = 1): 2k11/2 = pk and kxD = 1 2l1/2 = pl , so 1 1 and lxD = 2 4p2k 4pl (6) Therefore ¡ ¢ x = f kxD , lxD = S s 1 + 4p2k s 1 1 1 = + 2 4pl 2pk 2pl (7) and π x = px x − pk k − pl l = 3 3.1 1 1 pk pl 1 1 + − 2 − 2 = + 2pk 2pl 4pk 4pl 4pk 4pl (8) Consumer utility maximization Consumer A This person spends half his income on each good. His income is his demand for x and y is µ ¶ 1 1 1 1 A xD = + + /2px = 4pk 4pl 8pk 8pl ¶ µ 1 1 1 1 A yD = /2py = + + 4pk 4pl 8py pk 8py pl 2 1 4pk + 1 4pl , so (9) 3.2 Consumer B This person buys only y if py < 1, only x if py > 1 and is indifferent as to how to spend her income if py = 1. Her income is 10pk + 10pl . We will look for an interior solution where py = 1, and if this fails try an alternative. So for now py 10pk + 10pl = 1 and D = px xD B + py yB (10) We will substitute this into all the equations above, and therefore will only have pk and pl as variables to find. In particular, using equation 4 we have pk pl = 1/4, so 1 (11) pl = 4pk 4 4.1 Market clearing Market for x ³ ´ 1 1 D S D S D xD + x = x , so using equation 9 we have x = x − x = + A B B A 2pk 2pl − ³ ´ 1 1 so 8pk + 8pl 3 3 3 3pk + = + xD (12) B = 8pk 8pl 8pk 2 where the last equality uses equation 11. We continue to substitute equation 11 wherever possible below, and hence do not specify this each time. D Therefore by equation 10 we have yB = 10pk + 10pl − 8p3k − 8p3 l = 10pk + ³ ´ 17 10 4p1k − 8p3k − 31 = 17 2 pk + 8pk . Thus 8 4pk D = yB 4.2 17 17 pk + 2 8pk Market for y ³ D D yA + yB = y S , so using equations 13 and 9 we have that y S = 17 2 pk + ³ ´ ³ ´ ³ ´ 1 1 17 17 1 1 9 8pk + 8pl = 2 pk + 8pk + 8pk + 8(1/(4pk )) = 9pk + 4pk Therefore, using 5 we have µ ¶ µ ¶ 9 pk pk = kyD = kyD 9pk + = 4kyD p2k 4pk pl 1/ (4pk ) 4.3 (13) 17 8pk ´ + (14) Market for k kxD + kyD = 10, so kyD = 10 − kxD , so using equation 6 we have kyD = 10 − 3 1 2 4 (pk ) (15) 5 Putting the last two equations together and obtaining all the values From equations 14 and 15 we have à ! 9 1 9pk + = 4 10 − (pk )2 2 4pk 4 (pk ) (16) The only real solution is pk = 12 . So then using equation 11 we have pl = 1/2. Substituting this in all the other equations yields the following. y S yS kyD lyD D yB xD B xA D A yD xS lxD Check µ ¶1/2 µ µ ¶¶1/2 1 pk 1 = 10 − 2 =9 10 − 2 4pk pl 4pk 1 1 = 10pk + 10pl − − =8 2pk 2pl 1 = 10 − 2 = 9 4p µ k ¶ pk 1 = 10 − 2 = 9 pl 4pk 3 3 = 10pk + 10pl − − = 8.5 8pk 8pl 3 3 = + = 1.5 8pk 8pl 1 1 = + = 0.5 8pk 8pl 1 1 = + = 0.5 8pk 8pl 1 1 = + =2 2pk 2pl 1 = =1 4p2l : lxD + lyD = 1 + 9 = 10 = lS 4