JOURNAL OF ECQNOMlC THEORY 16, 151-l 66 (1977) Some Results on “An Income Fluctuaticx Pr JACK SCHECHTMAN Uafversity Federal of Rio de Janeiro/IkfUFRJ,+ Rio de Janeiro, Brazil Rio de Janeiro, Brazil AND VERA L. S. ESCUDERO Wniversity Fedeval of Rio de JaneirojCOPPE, Received May 18, 1976; revised October 21, 1976 A consumer at each period, given the income available, y, has to decide how much to consume and save. If he consumes c > 0 units he gets u(c) units of satisfaction or utility, and if x = y - c > 0 is the amount saved then the available income in the next period is PX + w*, where wB is a random variable, and I’ is an interest factor that is assumed to be known with certainty. Infinite time horizon problems are considered, and it is shown tbat if 0 < 6r < 1, where 0 < 6 < 1 is a discount factor, then the limiting policy is optimal. Questions about the behavior of the stock level, such as bouudness, are considered, and an example is given that shows that the stock level might converge almost surely to infinity. Finally an economic explanation is given. In this paper we consider the following situation. A consumer has a t period planning horizon, and at each period he must decide how much to consume and save, in order to maximize the total expected utility accumulated in the t periods. If y is the available income at the kth period, and. 0 < x < y is the amount saved at that period, then the available income in the next period is YX + 02, where 03 is a random variable and r is an interest factor * This research has been partially supported by the Ofhce of Naval Research under Contract NOOOI4-76-C-0134 and the National Science Foundation under Grants %X7515566 and MPS74-21222 with the University of California. The U. S. Government’s right to retain a nonexclusive royalty-free license in and to copyright covering this paper is acknowledged. T Now at the Instituto de Matematica Pura e Aplicada IMPA:‘CNPq, Rio de Janeiro, Rrazii. Copyright Ail rights Q 1977 by Academic Press, Inc. of reproduction in any form reserved. :ssK 00:2-0531 152 SCHECHTMAN AND ESCUDERO that is assumed to be known with certainty. If c = y - k units are consumed in period k, this produces 8%(c) units of satisfaction or utility to the consumer, 0 < 6 < 1 is a discount factor. It is assumed that u(c) is strictly concave, increasing, and differentiable and that the random variables wk are i.i.d. In Section 1 we describe the model and state the general results that are going to be used; they are basically the concepts of competitive prices and policies for the stochastic case. In Section 2 we consider the deterministic case, i.e., w = a. It is shown that the limiting policy is optimal when 0 < 6r < 1, and the behavior of the consumption, except for the infinite time horizon problem, is studied. In Section 3 we consider the stochastic case; i.e., w is a nondegenerated random variable. For the case 0 < 8 < 1, r = 1, it is shown that the limiting policy is optimal and also that the level of income is bounded above. For 0 < 6 < 1, 6r < 1, and Y > 1, it is also shown that the limiting policy is optimal, but it is not necessarily true that the stock level will always stay in an interval [0, j?]. An example is given for which the stock level converges; almost surely, to infinity. Sufficient conditions are obtained in order to assure the existence of a bound for the stock level. We should also mention that some of the results of this paper were presented in the First Brazilian Symposium in Probability held at Rio de Janeiro in 1974. 1. THE MODEL AND SOME GENERAL RESULTS Finite Time Horizon ProbIem A consumer is faced with the following situation. He has a t period planning horizon, and at each period he must decide how much to consume and save, in order to maximize the total expected utility accumulated in t periods. If y is the available income at the kth period, and 0 < x < y is the amount saved at period k, then the available income in the next period is rx + wk, where wk is a random variable and r is an interest factor that is assumed to be known with certainty. If c = y - x units are consumed in period k, then this produces 8%(c) units of satisfaction or utility to the consumer, and 0 < 6 < 1 is a discount factor. We wiI1 assume that u(c) is strictly concave, increasing, and differentiable and that the random variables mk are i.i.d. The range of w is an interval [a, A], A < + co and Prob[w = a] > 0. More formally our problem is maximize AK INCOME FLUCTUATION PROiBLEM 153 subject to the stochastic constraints C7G + 7.X7c-l xlc = yk, + wk-l = yk, co + XQ= yQ, CT = yT, for 1 < k < T. cL > 0, 9 3 0 for 1 3 k < a, and y” is the initiai income available. If V,(y) is the maximum expected utility that we can get when y is the income available and we have t periods to go, then the usual dynamic programming formulation leads us to the functional equations: It can be shown that V6(y) inherits the basic properties of u(c), i,e., V,(y) is increasing, strictly concave, and differentiable. The derivatives of V,(y) will be denoted by p,(y) and the solution of (1.1) will be denoted by (ct( y), x,(y)). The following properties of (ct( y), x,(y)) and pl( y) will be stated without proof (for proofs see [3]): (1.2) pt(y) is a positive decreasing function, p,(y) > ptU1(y) for ally and all t, and if U’(C) is a convex function then pt( y) is also a convex tknction for all t. (1.3) c,(y), x,(y) are nondecreasing continuous functions and ci(y) < ct-,t~9 txd~> >, xt&)) for all t. (,1.4) The functions ct( y), x,(y) satisfy the following relations: (I .5) pt( y) >, &Ep,-,(rx,( y) + W) with equality if x&y) > 0; (1.6) pt(y) > u’(c,(y)) with equality if et(y) > 0. Notation. If w E u (a constant), then the corres~o~d~~g prices and policies will be denoted by p,“(y) and (c,~(Y), x,“(y)). Now we will state a theorem that permits us to compare p&y) and consewen~iy c,(Y> with P?(Y) with PP(Y)>, P~~(Y~?(Y)), and P*~(Y)(c~~~Y)~ where ~3is the Ew. A proof of it can be seen in [3]. THEOREM 1.1. The following relations are true: (i) pi(y) <p,“(y) for all t, and consequentZy et(y) 3 Ct”(y); (ii) pt( y) > p/(y)f~r all t and consequently c,(y) < c/(y); (iii) if u’(c) is a convex firnction thea pt( y) >, p;O(y) and ~Q~seqLie~t~~ c,(y) < cha(y), where 6 = Ew. 154 SCHECHTMAN AND ESCUDERO Infinite Time Horizon Problems Now the consumer objective is to maximize subject to the stochastic constraints & + Xt = &t-1 + for t > 1, (O-1 co -+ x0 = y”, ct 2 0, xt 3 0 for t >, 0. DEFINITION. A policy is a pair of functions (c(y), x(y)) such that c(y) > 0, x(y) > 0, c(y) + x(y) = y. If y is the stock of capital available then c(y) > 0 tells us how much to consume and x(y) > 0 how much to save. Given a policy (c(y), x(y)) the stock of capital available at period t will be denoted by yt (observe the superscript). For some cases the series E[CE, S”u(c”)] might diverge and in order to compare the return of policies we will introduce the following definition; for a more detailed discussion see [l]. DEFINITION. A policy (c(y), x(y)) is said to overtake another policy (6(y), a(y)) if starting from the same initial stock yl, the policies (c(y), x(y)), (6(y), k(y)) yield (stochastic) consumptions paths et and P that satisfy I > 0 for all T > some To . A policy is said to be optimal if it overtakes all other policies. Now we will state without a proof a theorem that gives sufficient conditions for the optimality of a policy (c(y), x(y)). A proof of it for a similar problem can be seen in [2]. DEFINITION. THEOREM 1.2. If there exists a positive and nor&creasing function p(y), and a policy (c(y), x(y)) that satisfies the following conditions, then the policy (c(y), x(y)) is an optimalpolicy: (1.7) p(y) 2 u’(c( y)) with equality if c( y) > 0; (1.8) p(y) 3 SrEp(rx(y) (1.9) limt-, + W) with equality $x(y) > 0; EGtp( ye) yt = 0. 1 Observe the superscript ct indicates the consumption from the first period. at the tth period, now counting AN INCOME FLUCTUATION 155 PROBLEM In general it is not easy to find an optimal policy to infinite time horizon problems. Natural candidates are of course the limiting policies c(y) = lim,-, et(y) and x(yj = Em,-, x,(y) which are continuous nondecreasing functions. If bounds for pt(y) can be found, limits in (1.5) and (1.6) can be taken and they yield and where p(y) = Bim,,, pt( y>. Hence whenever a bound for plj y) can be foun to show that the limiting policy is optimal it will sufhce to show that lim,,, E@p( y”) y* = 0, where yt is the stock available at the tth period when we use the limiting policy. In this section we will consider the case w EZ a :> 0, 0 < 6 -=z1, r Z I, and 6r < I. We will obtain bounds for the prices p,(y), study the behavior of the income level when we follow the limiting policy, and finally it will be shown that the limiting policy is optimal. Proof. Suppose not, i.e., x,(a) > 0. Hence from (15) and (1.6) we get Pt(Y> = ~~Pt-,k%(.Y~ + 4 < Pt-~(xt(Y) + 4 G P&(Y) So, a: >, uxt( yj + a, by the monotonicity LEMMA 2.2. + 4 by (1.2). ofp,( y), which is a contradiction. g-0 4 6 < 1, Y > I, 6r < 1 then c,(y) b [(Y - 1)/r] yfor nli Y. Proof. e proof depends on the value that x*(y) assumes: (a) xt( y) = 0. Then ct( y) = y and consequently ct( y) 3 [(P - 1)/r] y. (b) x&j > 0. From the optimality condition we get pt(yj = 8p.p,-, (vxt(yj $ a). Now, from (1.2), the monotonidty of pi(y) and the fact that Sr < 1 we get pi(y) < &m,(y)) and consequently we get y/r > x,(y) and C*(Y) 2 Kf- - Wl Y. a 156 SCHECHTMAN AND ESCUDERO From Lemmas 2.1 and 2.2 it follows that p,(y) I u’[(Y - 1)/r] a}. So, the limiting policy satisfies the relations with equality if x(y) > 0, P(Y) 3 kPb(Y) + 4 C(Y) > 0. P(Y) = U’(4Y>>5 (2.0 (2.2) We should mention at this point that if we assume that u’(0) < co, we could drop the assumption that a > 0, and bounds for the prices would then be u’(O). The next theorem tells us how the stock level behaves when we follow the limiting policy. THEOREM 2.3. For the limiting policy yt+l < yt (c(y”+l)) 5 c(yt), and if y” 2is the initial stock, then there exist a T( y”) such that yt = afor all t > T( y”). Proof. First we will show that y $+l < yt. If yt > a and x( yt) = 0, then Yt+l = a and so yt+l < yt. If yt > a and x( yt) > 0 then from (2.1) we get P(Y”) = arp(ytfl) < P( Yt+l)* So, yt > yt+l by the monotonicity of p( y). If yt = a from Lemma 2.1 we get that x(y”) = 0 and hence that yt+l = a, so ytS1 < yt. To show the existence of T( y”) we will argue by contradiction, i.e., suppose that yt > a for all t, hence x( yt) > 0 for all t. So, from (2.1) we get P(Y”) = @Myt) for all t, but 0 < 6r < 1 and p(y) < u’(a) and consequently all t. 1 (2.3) (2.3) cannot hold for From the previous theorem it follows that the sequences yt converge to a in a finite number of periods. The behavior of the sequence of capital (y”>, consumption {ct>, and saving (xt) can be represented by the following graphs: 2 We will assume without loss of generality that v0 > a. AN INCOME FLUCTUATION THECREM 2.4. The limiting policy PROBLEM 157 is optimal. Proof. It suffices to show that lim,,, Pp( yt) yt = . From Lemma 2.2 and Theorem 2,3 we have that p( y’) < d([(r - 1)/r] a] nd yt < y* for all t. ence 0 < 8p(yt) yt < GW{[r - 1)/r] a} y”, for all t. So, lim,,, 8p(yt) yt = 0, since 0 < 8 -=c1. 3. STOCHASTIC CASE, I. E.,w Is ANONDEGENERATED ~A~~O~~AR~A~LE In this section we will study the stochastic case in which w E [a: A]? A < a is a nondegenerated random variable, and Prob[w = a] = 01 > 0. For the deterministic case we have shown that in a finite number of periods, when we follow the limiting policy, the stock level reaches the level a. The analog for the stochastic case would be a renewal process. This is in fact true whenever 0 < 6 < 1 and I” = 1, the stock { yt) evolves in an interval (a, j7j and a is a renewal point. But, for 0 < 6 < 1, 61~< 1, r* > 1 this result is not necessarily true, we will give an example in which (~“1 -+a.s. cx:. (a) Tl~eGaseO<6~1,~=1 Will show that the limiting policy is optimal, ounds for the prices pt( y). Proof. but first it is necessary to fin From Theorem 1.1 and Lemma 2.1 we get Pt(Yl < PtYY) < u’(a) for all y 2 CI (3.1) and all f, consequently et(y) 2 eta(y) > a. THEOREM Pro@ 3.2. The limiting First the limiting policy is optimal. policy satisfies the conditions P(Y) > @P(X(Yl i P(Y) = I’), a>, (3.2) (3.3) which is obtained from the optimality conditions (1.5) and (1.6) after taking the limits and using Lemma 3.1. To prove that the limiting policy is optimal it suffices to show that lim,,, EG*p( y”) yt = 0. From Lemma 3,1 we have that p(y) < u’(a). Now as w < A we have that yt < rA + y”. So, 15x THEOREM SCHECHTMAN 3.3. AND ESCUDERO There exists a j such that for ally > j7 x(y) f A < y. ProoJ First we will show that there is a 7 such that x(j) f A < j7. By contradiction suppose not, i.e., for all y, x(y) + A > y; hence, c(y) < A for all y. So, lim,,, c(y) = A4 and lim p(y) = u’(M) > 0, y-m since M 3 c(~l) > 0 for y > 0. (3.4) From (3.2) and (3.3) we have P(Y) = WMY) + w> < Mx(.Y) f a). (3.5) Now, taking the limit in (3.5), using (3.4) and the fact that lim,,, x(y) = cc we get that A4 < 8M which is a contradiction since 0 < 8 < 1. The theorem now follows from the fact that c(y) is a nondecreasing function which implies that c( I>) 3 A for all y 3 jj and consequently that x(y) + A < y for all Y2.P. 1 From the previous theorem it follows that the process evolves in an interval [a, J], For the deterministic case we were able to show that {y”] converges in a finite number of periods to a (whenever the process reaches the stock level a we will say that the process is in state a; for the stochastic case we will show that the process { y”} is a delayed renewal process, in which state a is a renewal point, i.e., each time the process reaches state a it starts all over again. Let X0 be the number of periods that it takes to reach for the first time state a. And let Xj be the number of periods that elapses between the (j - 1)th time we reach state a and the jth time we reach it again. The random variables x, ) Xl ). .. , xj ). .. are independent and X1 , X, ,..., Xj , are identically distributed. Hence the process Xj is a delayed renewal process. To show that it is nonterminating we need to show that EXi < 03. In order to show that Xj has finite expectation we will consider an artificial process that is described below. Consider a process with T’(j) = T(j) + 1 states, where T(y) is the number of periods that it takes to reach the state a when we assume that w = a and we follow the optimal policy (see Theorem 2.3); jj is an upper level for which yt < J for all t, which existence we have shown before. Now returning to the stochastic case, at each period we observe the value of w. If w = a and we are at state 1 cj < T’(y) then we move to statej - 1 and if we are at state 1 we stay at that state. If w + a and we are at state 1 < j < T’(y) we move to state T’(J). The following picture describes the process, where the numbers in the arrows are the transition probabilities. If z is the random variable that represents the number of periods that the process takes to reach the state 1 having started from state T’(J), it can be shown that 1 + EZ = 01 + . .. + aTW) &Ybl 2 AK iNCOME FLUCTUATION t PROBLEM 159 ?+I and it is easy to see that X, < Z and so consequently we wilt have that EXj<03. Using a well-known result from the renewal theory (for instance, see [4, p. 3651, we can state the following theorem. THEOREM has a limiting 3.4. Zf w is a denumevable random aariabk, then the process ( y”> distribution. (b) Case 0 < 6 < 1, )’ > 1,6v < 1 First we have from Theorem 1.1 and Lemma 2.2 that p,(y) d p,“(y) < u’{[(r - 1)/r] 4’) 2 u’([(r - l>/ Y1)a f or all y >, a and all t. Hence, the limiting policy satisfies (3.6) P(Y) 3 of%@+) + 44 (3.7) P(Y) = e4.v>>. THEOREMS 3.5. The limiting policy is optimal. ProoJ Tt suffices to show that lim,,,, ,Wp(yt) yt = 0. Now, yt < rt { y” + [(r - 1)/r] A) andp(yt) < ~‘{[(r - 1)/r] a), so Taking the limit and using the fact that Sr < 1, we get the desired result. When 0 < 6 < 1, r = 1, we were able to show that there exists a jj such that x(y) t A G y for all y > J. We could expect this result holds for I’ > 1, 6u < 1. The following example will show that in some cBses we coul -:y”> -B.S. co. Consider the following problem expressed in its dynamic ~ro~ramrn~ng formulation. PROBLEM 1. V,(y) = Max(--eee + GEV~-,(~x t- CO)), c t x = t’, c > 0, x 20, V,(y) = -e-u. 160 SCHECHTMAN AND ESCUDERO To find an explicit solution of Problem I is “very difficult,” and as a metter of fact, we are not going to solve it. We will find the solution of another problem, and then show that for the limiting policy the stock level {ytj of Problem I converges almost sure to +co. Consider the following problem, in its dynamic programming formulation. PROBLEM II. Vt(y) = Max{+-” f SEV,&x $ w)), c+x=y, V,(y) = -e-“. Observe that now we do not impose the condition of nonnegativeness on c and x. This fact will allow us to find an explicit solution of Problem II. This solution is given in Appendix A, and the limiting policy is r-l C(Y) = 7 Y - ---&f x(Y)=;+ log 8rE[e-W(+l)lr], (3.9) (3.10) log 8rE[e-w(T-1)/T]. The solution of Problem II, its prices, and the stock level will be denoted by MY), 3Y)l, F(Y), and {jtj and the corresponding ones for Problem I by MY>, x(AL MY% and in”>. From (3.10) we get the following relation for the stock level Y-t+l = jt + [r/(r l)] log GrE[e-[(V-l)/rlW] + w; - i.e., {j?} is a random walk in which the random variable is w’ = w + [r/(r - log l)] BrE[e-[(T-l)/rlw]. Now, if we take Prob[w = 0] = 1 - 8 and Prob[w = A > 0] = 8 we will have that Ecu'= eA + -& i0g 6r + i0gp - e+ ee-A+lq -& for a given 0 if we choose A sufficiently large, and we will have that Ew' > 0 and so {Jt} -a.S. + cc. Now, we will show that Jt < Y* for all t, but first we need a lemma, whose proof is given in Appendix B. LEMMA 3.6. 3~) < 4~) THEOREM for y 2 0. 3.7. jt < yt for all t, if y” = j”. AN 1NCOME FLUCTUATION PROBLEM 161 Proo$ The proof will be done by induction. First, it is true for f = 0 since y” = j?. N ow assume that it is true for t, i.e., j? < yt. Xfjt” < 0 then j”+l < yt+l since yt 2 0 for all t. if jP+l > 0, we have jw by monotonicity we get = rX(jF) + cot < rx(j7”) + LLIt of .Z(.) and the induction hypothesis. Now, using Lemma 3.6 Y-t+1 = I”qyy + o)t < rqy) + 03 < rx(yt) + c0* = yt+l. From the previous results we could state that if u(c) = -ET-~ and for a given 8 A is sufficiently large, then (y”] -fse6. foe. Since in general it is not necessarily true that there exists a jj such that yt E 10, 71 for all t, it would be interesting to &ad conditions under which yt E 10, j] for some J. 3.8. A suj5kient condition for the existence of a p such that -t A < y for ally >, 7 is that THEOREM rxly) (3.11) ProoJ From (3.11) we have that given an E > 0 there exists a 3 such that ewe, P(Y) <Ii-E Wrx(y) t A) and P(Y) p(r-4.d + 4 < Sr + E&. If, E < (I - 8r)/&, thenp( y) < p(vx( y) + A) for all y > j and consequently y 3 Ix(-y) + A for all y 3 j. g One case that immediately satisfies the Last theorem is the case u(c) = Kc + g(c), where K > 0 is a constant and g(c) is a strictly concave f~mctisn, increasing and differentiable. he last result would be of limited application if we were restricted to the lash example. But as we will see, using the concept of exponent of a function (used by Brock and Gale in [l]) we will be able to apply it to a very generat class of nroblems. 162 SCHECHTMAN DEFINITION. AND ESCLJDERO The exponent of the function f at the point x is 44 = hU(,u), and the asymptotic exponent e, off is lim,, ef(x>. If f(x) is a positive function, then the following fact can be shown (see [I] for a proof). If x > X’ and a < e, < a then for x large (x’/x)” < f(x)/f(x’) < (x/x’)5 (3.12) THEOREM 3.9. If u’(c) has an asymptotic exponent ef , then there exists a 7 such that rx( y) + A < y for ally 2 jj. Proof. If lim x(y) = K, then for y > tK + A, rx(y) + A < y. lim,,, x(y) = co then the proof is as follows. 4drxb9+ w>G ,drx(Y)+ 4 ~~r-4Y) + 4 pW(A+ 4 + a>>( c(rx(u)+ A) p for y large, - u’(c(rx(y) u’(4r-Q) + -4 ’ i 4r.U -t 4 1 If (3.13) by (3.12), and using the fact that lim,,, c(y) = ~0 and C(tX(Y) i- A) > +X(Y) + a>. Now, c(vx(~> + A) = c(rx(y> + a> + h(y)(A - 4, were 0 ,< NY) G 1. Hence, from (3.13) we get 44rx(y) + w>< cb4.d + 4 + h(y)(A - a> oi 1 p(rKd + 4 ’ ( c(r-4.d + 4 1 + NY)@ - a> * Xy) zz= for y large. 1 i Now, taking the limit as y + CCwe get @(KC(~) + w)/[p(rx(y) + A)] = 1. The theorem now follows from Theorem 3.8. Now, whenever there exists a j such that VX(y) + A < y for all y >, 7, we will have that the process evolves in an interval [a, y]. As in the case 0 < 6 < 1, r = 1 .it follows also that the process {y”} is a delayed renewal process, as are its consequences. In order to give some economic flavor to our result we should first mention that there is a close relationship between the limiting exponent of the marginal utility u’(y) and the Arrow-Pratt relative risk avertion measure RR(y) = -u”(y)/u’( y). In [7, p. 1 lo], it is shown that if RR(y) < R for all y > y. for some y0 then u’(y)/u’(yJ > (yJy>” for all y b y,, , that is inequality (3.12) obtained from the existence of the limiting exponent for the marginal utility also holds. A possible economic explanation of our result could be argued in AN INCOME FLUCTUATION PROBLEM 153 the following way: At each period the consumer is guided in his choice between consumption and saving by the values of an extra unit in face of his actual wealth, y, and his next PX(y) + w, a random variable, that depends on his next income w. Those values are expressed by p(y) and p(~x + w), the latter being also a random variable. His uncertainty is about the changes in the value p(rx t IV). Now, if p(rx + A)/[Ep(rx L A)] is “close” to i, we could say that the consumer for-sees small variation of p(rx: i W) with respect to p(rx f A). If we assume that the consumer’s behavior could be expressed by a utility function whose marginal utility has a limiting exponent or a uniformly bounded relative risk avertion for large values of y we will have that hm,,, (p(rx(y) + A)/&+(y) t w)]) - I (see theorem 3.9) and if we also take into account the fact that Sr < ! we will have that for sufl% cientiy large value of y the consumer will behave as in the deterministic case, i.e., his wealth is going to decrease no matter what happens with his future income.3 The utility function e-Y does not have a uniformly boun risk avertion. nor does its marginal utility have a limiting exponent, that is the varia’bihty of p(rx + w) with respect to p(rx + A) might not decrease to aa extent that makes him behave as in the “deterministic case.” This is in fact what our previous example shows, namely, given a binomial distribution for w if we choose A sufficiently large the sequence of weahhs (yt3 that we get when we follow the optimal policy converges almost surely to infinity. 8n the other hand if A is sufficiently small, for instance, A < --log &, it can ‘be shown that +vt > A implies yt > yt-’ for all t. A reason for this resuh could be given in a similar way as before. First, for different values of the wealth ~(2:) 7 1’;: the greatest difference in consumption is A, and if A is ‘“small” this will imply from the continuity of u’(;:) that p(rx + W) do not vary relatively 9.0p(rx + A) to a great extent. We also should point out a fact observed early by Pratt [a] that the function z{‘(y) = 6~ in spite of its nice graph has great relative variations when we compare va!ues that differ in a relatively small proportion. For instance, if i’ = 10” and y’ = y + IO-5y ()r y’ = 106 - 10 we have that e-v/e-“’ = P5 which is a very large number! APPENDIX A In this Appendix we will find the solution of the problem: Maximum E fj stu(ct) i=O 3Frorr the fact that lim[p(tx + A)/E’(rx + A)] -+ 1, the optimality condition p(y) == GrE’(vx(yf i w) could be replaced by p(y) N (6r f e)p(r.xCy) + A), where E cars be made arbitrarly small by choosing y arbitrarly large. 164 SCHECHTMAN subject to ct $ xt = yt, AND ESCUDERO O<t<T Y t+1 = rxt + J and XT = 0, CT = yT, where u(c) = -e+, The dynamic programming CJ E [a, A] 09 are i.i.d. formulation Vt(y) = maxi-e+ leads to the functional equations: + GEV,&x + at)}, (A.11 X+C=Y, and Vi(y) = -e-“, and Cl(Y) = Y> Xl(Y) = 0. We claim that the solution of (A.l) for any t > 1 has the form +-1 dJ) = -;“A __--- + . .. + 1 y - At log 6r - B, ,4 e-2 + ... + 1 Xt(Y) = +1 + ... + 1 y + At log & + Bt . It is true for t = 1. Now assume that is true for t, then Bt+l = (4 + log Eexp (- yt-l it::. + 1 w)) x r~~~..‘.“$l From the recurrence relation, we will have that the limiting log 6r - -& 4Y.l = APPENDIX log 1. policy is E[e-(tr-l)l~hJ], B In this appendix we will obtain a result that permits us to compare the optimal policies for the problems: PROBLEM I. Max c @u(c~) t=o 4 Where the sum in the denominator ranges over L’s such that t - i > 0. AN INCOME FLlJCTIjATION 165 PROBLEM Subject to Yt+1 = rxt + d, 36 + ct = y, xi > 0, ct 2 0. Max i Gfu(ci) t=o Subject to p1 = rxt f wt, .xt + et = Yt, CT = y+, XT = 0. The prices and policies for Problem I will be denoted by &y)), (et(y), x5(y)] and the corresponding ones to Problems II by P&y)% (Et(y), XL(y)). THEOREM B1. FOV y 2 0, X&y) < xt(y) rind conseqziently X(y) < x(y), PTS~I The proof will be done by induction. It is true for t = 1 since x,(y) = 0 and 5&(y) = 0. Now, assume that it is true for t - 1, i.e., .xtll(y) > Zt-:(y) for y > 0 and by contradiction that xt(y) < .Tt(y). Then y - ei(y) < y - C,(y) and consequently ctJy) > G&y) and p&y) < j?-,(y). From e optimalities conditions we get I%(Y) = ~Pt-l@xt(Y) 3 J%-lo%-ICY) i w> + a> (3.1) since ptel( .) is nonincreasing and Y%& y) > x,(y) >, 0. But from the induction hypothesis we have that ctM1(y) < C,,(y) and so, &+(;J) > pttl(y). Then @.I) implies PdY> 2 ek-l&G-l(Y) + w> = Pt-l(Y), which is a contradiction. 4 ACKNOWLEDGMENTS I would like to thank Professor David Gale for his comments and fzx the opportunity of being back at Berkeley, and Professor 3. A. Sheinkman for helpfuu2 cowersation. But the authors are stiil responsible for the errors left. 166 SCHECHTMAN AND ESCUDERO REFERENCES 1. BROCK AND GALE, Optimal growth under factor augmenting progress, Rev. Econ. Stud. 1 (1969), 229-243. 2. D. LEVHARI AND T. N. SRINIVASAN, Optimal savings under uncertainty, Rev. &on. Stud. 36 (1969), 998-1019. 3. J. SCHECHTMAN, “Some Applications of Competitive Prices to Dynamic Programming Problems Under Uncertainty,” ORC 73-5, Operations Research Center, University of California, Berkeley, March 1973. 4. W. FELLER, “An Introduction to Probability Theory and Its Applications,” Vol. 11, Wiley, New York, 1966. 5. Y. YOUNES, “Monnaie et Motif de Precaution Dans une Economic d’gchange ou Les Ressources des Agents Sont Aleatoires.” 6. N. VOUSDEN, Depletion resource, J. Icon. Theory 6 (1973), 126-143. 7. K. T. ARROW, “Essays in the Theory of Risk-Bearing,” Markham, Chicago, 1971. 8. T. W. PRATT, Risk avertion in the small and in the large, Econometrica 32 (1964), 122-36.