NAFTA and Convergence in North America: High Expectations, Big Events, Little Time [with Comments] Author(s): William Easterly, Norbert Fiess, Daniel Lederman, Norman V. Loayza, Patricio Meller Source: Economía, Vol. 4, No. 1 (Fall, 2003), pp. 1-53 Published by: The Brookings Institution Stable URL: http://www.jstor.org/stable/20065449 Accessed: 18/08/2010 14:24 Your use of the JSTOR archive indicates your acceptance of JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use, available at http://www.jstor.org/page/info/about/policies/terms.jsp. JSTOR's Terms and Conditions of Use provides, in part, that unless you have obtained prior permission, you may not download an entire issue of a journal or multiple copies of articles, and you may use content in the JSTOR archive only for your personal, non-commercial use. Please contact the publisher regarding any further use of this work. Publisher contact information may be obtained at http://www.jstor.org/action/showPublisher?publisherCode=brookings. Each copy of any part of a JSTOR transmission must contain the same copyright notice that appears on the screen or printed page of such transmission. JSTOR is a not-for-profit service that helps scholars, researchers, and students discover, use, and build upon a wide range of content in a trusted digital archive. We use information technology and tools to increase productivity and facilitate new forms of scholarship. For more information about JSTOR, please contact support@jstor.org. The Brookings Institution is collaborating with JSTOR to digitize, preserve and extend access to Economía. http://www.jstor.org WILLIAM EASTERLY NORBERT FIESS DANIEL LEDERMAN NAFTAand Convergence inNorth America: High Expectations, Big Events, Little Time Free Trade Agreement (NAFTA) was formally on 1 January 1994 by the United States, Canada, and implemented the This treaty instantly gained global notoriety following Mexico. American he North T in 1991, not only because the initiative negotiations trade agreements in history, represented one of the most comprehensive in establishing free trade but also because it seemed to be a breakthrough initiation of formal and developing countries. The among developed catch high expectations were that trade liberalization would help Mexico ratio northern The of Mexican GDP with its per capita to up neighbors. in goods and services that of the United States did increase after unilateral trade reforms were in the in 1986 and also after the implementation of NAFTA implemented other Latin American aftermath of the so-called tequila crisis. However, also grew faster than the U.S. economy after the mid-1980s, a to it is not obvious Costa Rica. Thus lesser extent, and, especially in Mexico catch up with that NAFTA was particularly helping important the United States.1 economies Chile are with the World is with New York University. Fiess and Lederman Bank. Easterly to Craig Burnside, Gerardo Esquivel, Andrew Harvey, Norman We are grateful Loayza, William Patricio Ernesto Messmacher, Meiler, Maloney, Miguel L?pez-C?rdova, Guillermo Maurice Schiff, and Luis Serven for helpful discussions Perry, Roberto Rigobon, on earlier versions. in this paper belong to the The opinions expressed the views of the World Bank. and do not represent in that this econ 1. The experience of Puerto Rico offers an interesting counterpoint, similar toMexico's in the late 1950s and achieved omy started with a level of development an unprecedented level of economic and institutional in States integration with the United and comments authors the fastest rates of economic in the developing 1952. It subsequently experienced growth An analysis of the Puerto Rican experience is beyond the scope Latin American economies. of this paper as it would data for many years prior to 1952, when require the use of historical the island became for suggesting a commonwealth territory of the United States. We thank Patricio Melier this analysis. 1 2 Fall 2003 ECONOM?A, This paper assesses the extent to which these high expectations It examines trends and determinants of income be materializing. seem to and pro across as in observed North both countries well as America, ductivity gaps were within Mexico. The high expectations for NAFTA supported by neo classical growth and trade theories. The seminal work of Solow states that grow faster than rich countries owing to the law of returns, as long as production diminishing population technologies, are the same across countries.2 The neoclassical growth, and preferences trade model (the Stolper-Samuelson theorem) similarly predicts that as the capital-poor countries so will factor prices, including real prices of goods and services converge, across Hence income levels borders will also tend to converge as wages. economics assumption of neoclassical prices converge. A key simplifying use the same production technologies, exhibiting either or diminishing returns to scale. There is a lively debate about the evidence the impact of concerning is that all countries constant on income convergence across countries, as well as an literature on economic within countries.3 At least convergence of the publication Barro's early work, the economics has profession trade liberalization extensive since in cer been aware that convergence might be conditioned by convergence to cause economic tain fundamentals While that are believed growth.4 there is admittedly much uncertainty about what these fundamentals are, can as in the evidence of conditional be evidence convergence interpreted that there are fun favor of the neoclassical growth model or as evidence differences that prevent income convergence.5 For Easterly and Levine, as well as Pritchett, the "big story" in interna is that the rich grew richer while the poor got tional income comparisons in the levels differences poorer.6 Some studies focusing on cross-country damental are (or GDP per worker) argue that these differences Other factors.7 factors besides different institutional largely explained by fundamentals, however, might impede economic convergence among geo even areas in of free trade. the presence graphic of income per capita 2. Solow(1956). 3. On cross-country On within-country see Slaughter and Ben-David (2001) and and Sala-i-Martin (1995) convergence, convergence, see Barro (1996). 4. Barro (1991). 5. Doppelhofer, Mille, 6. Easterly and Levine 7. Hall and Jones and Sala-i-Martin (1999); (2001); Pritchett Acemoglu, (2000). (1997). Johnson, and Robinson (2001). 1996). (2001, Sala-i-Martin 3 William Easterly, Norbert Fiess, and Daniel Lederman recent More across cal differences of growth with theories increasing returns or technologi in income levels and predict divergence flows might help international Trade tech regions.8 is embodied in goods and when technical knowledge regions rates across growth nology diffusion services, and theories of technology diffusion via trade have been the sub literature.9 A related literature focuses on the barri ject of a fast-growing ers that impede technological in the levels adoption to explain differences of trade can thus facilitate con of per capita income.10 The liberalization even when production differ across countries, vergence technologies in convergence of tend to be detected (divergence) although this would total factor productivity (TFP) levels within industries across countries.11 to import production if trade liberalization allows poor countries from advanced countries, productivity levels might not con technologies Even are different, to the mismatch owing in poor countries and the sophisticated gaps within technologies imported from the rich countries. Productivity even across countries therefore if industries trade facilitates might persist verge if the factor endowments labor skills available between technological convergence.12 literature The recently resurgent on economic transport geography, and is not optimistic costs, scale, knowledge spillovers on economic about the impact of trade liberalization For convergence.13 transport costs will remain as barriers to trade and economic example, are removed.14 In addition, if integration even if all policy distortions on an and innovation then will also be trade, learning depend geography to convergence via technological diffusion.15 These factors impediment economies of across countries.16 Economies of scale might hamper income convergence some and knowledge make spillovers might geographic regions more of than others because the cumulative effects of initial prosperous simply such as the density conditions 8. See the pioneering work of economic of Romer Helpman(1991). 9. Eaton and Kortum 10. Parente 11. Bernard (1999); Keller and Prescott (2000). and Jones (1996). (1986, activity.17 1990); Lucas (2001). 12. Acemoglu andZilibotti (2001). 13. Krugman (1991); Fujita, Krugman, 14. Eaton and Kortum (2002). and Venables 15. Keller (2002); Eaton andKortum (2002). 16. Redding 17. Ciccone and Venables and Hall (1996). (2001). (1999). (1988); and Grossman and 4 ECONOM?A,Fall2003 In the case of Mexico, the Zapatista rebels took up arms in the southern state of Chiapas on the day of NAFTA's Later that year, implementation. was to in December was fol Mexico forced the which float 1994, peso, lowed by a deep banking crisis and severe recession. Domestic investment a sharp deterioration underwent before the Mexican economy began to recover in late 1995.18 These big events coincided with the implementation from a long-run perspective, the post-NAFTA Moreover, is still short. This combination of big events and a short experience of NAFTA. period with NAFTA increases the difficulty of empirically identifying the impact on income and productivity the agreement gaps in North America. we use assess to various methodologies NAFTA's effect on Nevertheless, income and productivity differences. of as follows. The next section uses is organized on the income to the techniques identify impact of NAFTA and the United States. To deal with the big-events gap between Mexico little-time problem, we apply two time series methods. First, we follow The times rest of the paper series a structural time series exercise in conducting that might be able Harvey to separate transitory effects (such as the tequila crisis) from the long-term effects expected from NAFTA.19 Second, following Bernard and Durlauf, we apply cointegration to see whether there is an observable analysis between the United States and Mexico.20 process of income convergence to test for any structural change in the equilibrium We do this recursively GDP using quarterly data from 1960 condition between U.S. and Mexican to 2001. We find that the debt crisis in the early 1980s and the tequila cri sis temporarily which convergence, interrupted a process of economic resumed after 1995. Convergence in the trade liberalization after Mexico's might have been faster prior to the debt cri economies that other Latin American also grew late 1980s and after NAFTA sis. However, given quickly during this period, we also provide of the differences between Mexico-specific effects. These results indicate that Mexico's and 1993 was not that different omy, but it was significantly ous exception of 1995. 18. Lederman 19. Harvey 20. Bernard and others (2002). and Durlauf (2003). (1995, 1996). annual estimates and Latin American between income 1986 performance econ the average Latin American with the obvi positive after NAFTA, from more econometric William Easterly, Norbert Fiess, and Daniel Lederman The across section looks at the per capita income subsequent the extent to which in 2000 and estimates countries observed differences income differences. This 5 differentials institutional exercise explain in using settlers' mortality Johnson, and Robinson Acemoglu, as instruments for currently observed differences colonial times follows rates from in institu and Kraay.21 We find that the tional quality, based on data from Kaufmann can largely be States and Mexico the United income gap between the We then institutional variables. gap plus geographic by explained examine States the evolution in Mexico of the institutional gap with respect annual estimates to the United of Mexican by, again, comparing our to the average Latin American results indicate thatMex effect; more not than those of other Latin American ico's institutions did improve effects countries in the post-NAFTA convergence period. Accelerating institutions?NAFTA effort to improve Mexico's will require a major thus is not enough. The following section studies the impact of NAFTA on TFP differentials within manufacturing industries across the United States and Mexico. Based on a panel estimation of the rate of convergence across twenty-eight manu we find that the post-NAFTA period was characterized by facturing industries, a substantially faster rate of productivity convergence than in previous years. this time, however, we cannot say whether the productivity-convergence result was due to increased imports of intermediate goods from the United At States (as argued by Schiff and Wang), competitive pressures tial access to the U.S. market (as argued by L?pez-C?rdova), and preferen or increased resulting from a variety of factors, including increased research and development (R&D) efforts and patenting aided by the enhanced protection of intellectual property rights contained inNAFTA (as argued by Lederman and Maloney).22 Mexican innovation domestic The paper then looks at the impact of NAFTA on economic convergence across Mexican states. This issue is of particular interest to many Latin in view of the proposed Free Trade Area of the Amer American economies icas (FTAA). This hemispheric economic integration would theoretically lead to the establishment of free trade and in some cases, such as in Central America to and perhaps in the Southern Common Market (MERCOSUR), of economic which would countries, among integration deeper forms 21. Acemoglu, and Robinson and Kraay (2002a). Johnson, (2001); Kaufmann Schiff and Wang and Maloney (2002); L?pez-C?rdova (2002); Lederman 22. (2003a). 6 ECONOM?A,Fall2003 a single economic entity. The unequal economic performance of a states under NAFTA thus be of differential might prelude under the FTAA or other proposed arrangements, such as the Cen resemble Mexican effects tral American Free Trade Agreement (CAFTA). We test the conditional across on Mexican states, but focus exclusively convergence hypothesis states grew faster that might explain why some Mexican initial conditions than others during 1990-2000. We find that the initial skill level of the density played an important role. We interpret that trade liberalization might indirectly induce even across coun if induces it countries, convergence and telephone population these results as evidence within divergence tries. The research related final section a and proposes findings on the questions raised by our findings the main summarizes agenda focusing mainly to TFP convergence in manufacturing. Time Series Evidence process is to separate simple way to gain insight into the convergence trends and cycles from the relative output gap between the United States a and Mexico, trend in the output gap indicates con whereby decreasing A how filter can create serious distortions, vergence. The Hodrick-Prescott as can the Baxter-King band pass filter.23 We therefore follow ever, Harvey and Trimbur and, in a later work, Harvey, who argue that trends and cycles are best estimated by structural time series models.24 We esti a bivariate mate between allows in which time series model, convergence is captured through a similar-cycle model that coun across to be correlated the driving cycles common fac a direct link between cointegration, structural two economies the disturbances tries.25 Harvey provides tors, and balanced growth models.26 He also shows that the balanced growth model results as a special case of the similar-cycle model, when a common 23. On trend restriction the distortions associated 24. filter, band-pass and Trimbur Harvey 25. Harvey and Koopman Harvey 27. Harvey (2002). and Carvalho (1999) King 26. is imposed.27 with see references (2001); (1997). (2002). Harvey the Hodrick-Prescott in Harvey (2002). (2002). filter and the Baxter and 7 William Easterly, Norbert Fiess, and Daniel Lederman The analysis in this section is based on quarterly data on real per capita over the period 1960:1 to 2002:4. for the United States and Mexico are The per capita GDP figures adjusted for purchasing power parity (PPP) GDP and are taken from the Penn World Tables 5.6. We applied the following a to create data series. Quarterly GDP quarterly PPP-adjusted procedure were for Economic Cooperation and obtained from the Organization data were as and the series constructed (OECD), population Development averages of annual figures spread across four quarters. quarterly moving GDP U.S. GDP data were seasonally adjusted by the provider; Mexican We the converted data were seasonally adjusted using X-12-ARIMA. dollars using quarterly average nominal exchange then deflated by the U.S. consumer price index dollars. For the PPP adjustment of the quarterly series, data into U.S. Mexican rates. Both series were (CPI) to 1995 U.S. we estimated rate bias following Summers and Ahmad, by the exchange the GDP figures on an annual exchange annual PPP-adjusted regressing rate adjusted GDP series from the World Development In a Indicators.n rate bias to our series of exchange GDP per capita figures.29 quarterly exchange-rate-adjusted to the logarithms of quar We then fit a similar-cycle bivariate model terly per capita GDP in the United States and Mexico.30 A model with two final step, we the predicted applied appears to describe the data well, and the second cycle appears to inMexico around the 1980s. capture large movements two trends. This PPP-adjusted 1 shows ratio of the the gap Figure cycles until the setback of the 1980s associated convergence resumed around 1987, which coincides debt crisis. Convergence of the Mexican unilateral liberalization economy implemented exhibits with the with the in 1986, the recession of also reflect the recovery after this might although 1982-1984. The data also indicate that the tequila crisis represented a tem porary setback. The downward slope of the income gap is somewhat steeper after the 1980s, suggesting that convergence between Mexico and 28. Summers andAhmad (1974);World Bank (2003). 29. GDP To (yPPP) estimate the exchange rate bias, rate adjusted GDP on exchange Mexico: United we regressed (ye). Standard log-transformed PPP-adjusted errors are in parentheses: + 1.111*^, R2 =0.987; yP?P =-0.2944 (0.1608) (0.0200) = -0.2944 + 1.111*^, R2 =0.992. States:ym (0.0121) (0.1203) 30. Following Harvey (2002). 8 ECONOM?A,Fall2003 FIG U R E 1. TheU.S.-MexicoGDPper CapitaGap:Similar-Cycle Modelwith Quarterly PPP-AdjustedData, 1960 to 2002a Ratio _i_i_i_i_i_i_i_U 1965:1 1970:1 1975:1 1980:1 1985:1 1990:1 1995:1 2000:1 Source: Authors'calculations. a. Thedotted line isthe ratioof the U.S./Mexicotrendcomponentsof GDPper capita;the solid line isthe observed ratio. the United occurred States to have vergence appears To investigate at a faster rate after trade liberalization. lost momentum the speed of convergence Con however. during 2000-2002, the fol further, we estimated lowing model: GAP, = 0.162 + 0.935GAP,,-0.025NAFTA_GAPM (0-013)* (0.092)* (0.032)** + 0.005 LIB _GAPM (0.016) R2 = 0.91 +1.083TEQUILA,, income gap, is the U.S.-Mexico and where GAP and is a dummy for the 1994 tequila crisis (1994:4-1995:1), are for unilateral trade and dummies Mexico's NAFTA_GAP LIB_GAP both of liberalization and NAFTA (1994:1-2002:4), (1986:1-1993:4) errors are in which are interacted with the lagged income gap. Standard where TEQUILA William Easterly, Norbert Fiess, and Daniel Lederman 9 one asterisk means at 5 percent, and statistical significance parentheses, at 1 percent. We find that NAFTA, two mean significance but not unilat a on had the speed of eral trade liberalization, significant positive impact a the half-life of one unit shock to the income convergence. With NAFTA, fallen from 2.6 to 1.8 years. The fact that unilateral is does not appear to be significant for income convergence a in similar result later the paper, when analyzing the interesting. We find on productivity NAFTA of unilateral liberalization and impact growth. gap appears liberalization to have (ointegrationAnalysis to Bernard and Durlauf, between two or long-run convergence According more countries if the long-run forecasts exists of output differences are two to have converged In zero.31 other economies said words, approach if the difference between ditions, stability implies convergence ary. Absolute relative or conditional them, ytt, is stable. If we abstract from initial con two series is station that the difference between requires that the mean convergence the two series has a constant mean. of yt is zero, while that the difference between requires If two series are cointegrated, but with are comoving the economies (that is, they a vector different from (1,-1), are driven by a common trend) but not necessarily to identical converging levels of output. Cointegration between economies alone is therefore a If a con necessary, but not sufficient condition for absolute convergence. stant is introduced into the cointegration to test for space, it is possible zero. A constant to absolute and relative convergence the by restricting zero constant supports absolute convergence.32 Following Fuss, we intend vector of the form ( 1, -1 ) at the end to interpret evidence of a cointegration of the sample, together with a rejection of this vector parameterization in as an of of evidence subsamples, ongoing process convergence.33 31. 32. between on Bernard and Durlauf Introducing stochastic 1996). (1995, into the cointegration and deterministic convergence, a trend it possible to distinguish space makes a homogeneity where restriction (1,-1) to stochastic and homo convergence with a trend corresponds coefficients a trend to deterministic con As we reject stochastic (1,-1) without convergence. in favor of deterministic in our data, we only report the findings vergence convergence in the cointegration con based on a constant space, which we view as a test of deterministic the GDP geneity ditional convergence. Fuss (1999) postulates = a + bx + u, then the results y 33. at the end of the period, that if y and x are cointegrated evidence of the following: provide with 10 Fall 2003 ECONOM?A, TABLE 1. Cointegration Analysis for the United States and Mexico, 1960:4 to 2002:4 L-max Eigenvalue 0.164429.64*** 0.0171 2.85 Trace H0:r 32.49*** 0 1 2.85 p-rL-max90 10.29 2 Trace90 17.79 1 7.50 7.50 Source: Authors'calculations. ***Statisticallysignificantat the 1percent level. A cointegration GDP, with a con analysis between U.S. and Mexican stant and four lags in the cointegration space over the full sample from vector (see table 1). A 1960 to 2002, reveals one significant cointegration to (1, -1) cannot be the cointegration space according = = over the full sample; this provides evidence 0.23) 1.45,p rejected (%2[1] = in favor of convergence 1960-2002: 0.720, with GDPUS GDPMX during a standard error of 0.082.34 restriction of The estimate of the constant in the cointegration vector is greater than zero, and the standard error for the constant is relatively small. We interpret this as evidence of incomplete convergence, in the sense that Mexico is toward the U.S. level of income up to a point. That is, the converging observed process of convergence is likely to lead not to absolute conver gence, but rather to a constant income differential. The estimated constant will reach a maximum of about 40 to 50 percent of suggests that Mexico the U.S. per capita GDP. Whereas the evidence applies to the whole period, this process of conditional convergence may hold only for certain years. Recursive cointegration analysis reveals that the (1, -1) restriction does not hold in all subsamples (see figure 2). The graph in figure 2 is scaled in such a way that unity represents the 5 percent level of significance. A test can of convergence statistic below one thus indicates that the hypothesis not be rejected. We find strong evidence for divergence the 1980s during (debt crisis), in spite of the fact that we estimated the cointegration vector a = 0 and b = a <> 1 indicates that the series are converging; 0 and b = 1 indicates that the two series are converging a > 0 and b < a<0 1 implies and b > 1 implies and b > 1 implies a < 0 and ??< 1 implies a>0 34. A similar dard error of 0.044. result that x converges that y converges divergence toward toward x; (x falls behind (y falls behind divergence is obtained for annual up to a constant; y\ data: GDP?/S y); and z). - GDPMX = 0.881, with a stan 11 William Easterly, Norbert Fiess, and Daniel Lederman FIGURE 2. TraceTests for Cointegrationbetween U.S.andMexico (Log)QuarterlyGDP, 1960:4 to 2002:4 (RecursiveEstimates) Multiples of the Critical-TraceTest Statistic 5 i?''V-" Without tequiladummy 1974:1 1976:3 1979:1 1981:3 1984:1 1986:3 1989:1 1991:3 1994:1 1996:3 1999:1 2001:3 Source: Authors'calculations. with that properly dummies the key first and fourth quarters identify of 1982.35 the impact of the 1994 tequila crisis on the convergence we process, analysis with and without perform a recursive cointegration a dummy for the tequila crisis. As shown in figure 2, which plots the coin tegration trace test over time, the tequila crisis had an impact on the con To assess vergence The process. convergence process convergence hypothesis 35. The debt crisis relevant tended tests showed that other dummy variables for the specification the estimates of the cointegration rank and coefficient restrictions. of three subsamples finds a result similar to that reported above. A test model to bias A separate analysis of the (1,-1) restriction 1961:01 can be rejected to 1975:04 1976:01 to 1988:04 1989:01 to 2002:04 This whole supports sample of a crisis dummy reveals a resumed the tequila dummy, the 1987 onward. Without is rejected around the time of the crisis. This sug inclusion from a similar (figure (%2(l) = in the following 1.12, p subsamples: 0.29), = = (x2(l) 8.86, p 0.00), and = 0.61, p = 0.43). (%2(\) convergence/divergence 2). = pattern as a recursive analysis over the 12 Fall 2003 ECONOM?A, conver that the tequila crisis temporarily interrupted an ongoing in the late 1980s. gence process The evidence from time series analyses can be summarized as follows. gests Structural time series modeling and recursive cointegration analysis both of and between Mexico and the convergence identify periods divergence United States during 1960-2002. Both econometric evi find techniques that the tequila crisis only temporarily interrupted a convergence the estimates of structural process that started in the late 1980s. However, in the of the income gap coefficient U.S.-Mexico changes autoregressive seems to be faster than in the rest indicate that the speed of convergence dence of NAFTA. of the sample only after the implementation seems to have a limit. of convergence In any case, this process Mexico'sPerformance RelativetoOtherLatinAmericanCountries in the region may in figure 3, other economies As highlighted relative to the United just as fast as or even faster than Mexico have grown States after process of conver identify the Mexico-specific we compared Mexico's level of development, per the per capita income gap relative to the United the late 1980s. To better toward gence formance the U.S. States with in closing the equivalent reformed their economic NAFTA. This of Latin American countries that performance not of but did the benefits policies enjoy statistical difference testing for a significant a countries and the for group of Latin American involved the year effects to Mexico. The dependent variable was the (log) year effects specific ratio of per capita GDP of the countries relative to the United States. The that test was conducted with two samples of Latin American countries between include Mexico: Group with nine countries.36 36. Costa of twenty-two countries, and Group 2, in figure 4.37 Mexico's year effects are statisti different from the rest of Group 1 at a 10 percent confi results are shown The cally 1, consisting significantly The Rica, twenty-two Dominican Group Republic, 1 countries Ecuador, are Argentina, El Salvador, Bolivia, Guatemala, Brazil, Chile, Guyana, Trinidad Colombia, Haiti, Hon and Tobago, Peru, Panama, Nicaragua, Paraguay, are Argentina, The nine Group 2 countries Brazil, Chile, Colom and Venezuela. Rica, Mexico, Peru, Uruguay, 37. The estimated model was yc,t - c + ?, Dt + ?,MEXA DMEX, where y is the log of and DMFX is the per capita GDP ratio with respect to the United States, Dt is a year dummy, aMexico 4 dummy. Figure plots ?,,MEX ?,. duras, Jamaica, Mexico, and Venezuela. Uruguay, bia, Costa William Easterly, Norbert Fiess, and Daniel Lederman FIG U R E 3. 1960 to 2001 13 Per CapitaGDPRelative to the United States, Selected Economies, GDPper capita (PPP)/U.S.GDPper capita 1970 1965 1975 1980 1985 1990 2000 1995 Source: Loayza,Fajnzylber, and Calder?n(2002);PennWorldTables5.0;World Bank (2003). 1982 onward. In other words, the annual observations in figure 4 are significantly different from zero only after 1982. With respect to the smaller comparator group, Mexico's annual effects are and 1999-2001.38 However, these differ also different during 1982-1994 dence level from shown ences tended to be significantly richer simply reflect the fact that Mexico than other regional economies these The real is years. during question whether richer than other Latin American grew significantly these which should be reflected in upward move years, during shown in figure 4. This only of the country-effects differentials Mexico economies ments occurs after 1995 with group of Latin American occurred in 1986-1993. 38. Wald American tests for and Caribbean respect to both comparator groups. For the larger and Caribbean economies, this might also have of the difference significance are not reported. effects between Mexico and average Latin 14 ECONOM?A,Fall2003 FIGURE 4. Mexico Year EffectMinus RegionalYear Effect9 u_i_i_i_i_i_i_i_i_i_u 1961 1965 1969 1973 1977 1981 1985 1989 1993 1997 2001 Source: Authors'calculations. a. Log (GDP per capita/U.S.GDPper capita) (PPP).Theexcludedyear is 1960.See tableA1 inthe appendixfor summarystatisticsfor data used and definitionof the groups. did not catch up to the United States significantly countries (the eight included in Group 2) about the possibility thatMexico's unilateral reforms spurred The fact thatMexico faster than other middle-income raises doubts to a greater extent than reforms in In contrast, the post-NAFTA period Mexico-U.S. income gap, which declined with the United States convergence countries such as Chile or Costa Rica. is characterized by a declining included in both samples. This faster than for the average Latin economies result is consistent with previously discussed estimates of the acceleration of convergence sections identify only after 1994. The following of the U.S.-Mexico constraints convergence process. lying the under IncomeGaps and Institutional Gaps the role in the introduction, a substantial literature highlights in per in producing differences variation institutional cross-country As discussed of William Easterly, Norbert Fiess, and Daniel Lederman FIGURE 5. 15 InstitutionalGaps inNorthAmerica,2000 to 2001 Variable ranges from -2 to+2 for all countries ICanada Voiceand accountability Political Government Regulatory stability effectiveness Ruleof law Control of quality corruption Source: Kaufmannand Kraay(2002a). trade liberalization and the institutional harmo capita income.39 Despite nization intellectual (for example, requirements imposed by NAFTA and environmental investor standards), obvi property rights, protection, ous institutional gaps remain between the United States and Mexico. Fig ure 5 draws on data from Kaufmann and Kraay to show the gaps along six In 2000-2001, Mexico its North clearly lagged behind all institutional dimensions, partners along corrup especially tion and rule of law. If these institutional differences persist, absolute dimensions.40 American as predicted by neoclassical will proba economics, even if trade is completely liberalized. These types are difficult to identify with time series to convergence of impediments as in the previous section, mainly because such those analyses, presented can be rooted in history and tend to vary little over time. institutional gaps income convergence, bly never materialize The experience of Puerto Rico on how medium-term perspective 39. Hall 40. Kaufmann and Jones (1999); Acemoglu, and Kraay (2002a). (recall figure 3) can provide a useful institutional convergence might affect Johnson, and Robinson (2001). 16 ECONOM?A,Fall2003 ter convergence. When Puerto Rico became a commonwealth of the United States in not free in it trade 1952, ritory goods gained only and factors of production, but also some of the political and regulatory economic institutions available incentives for in the United In addition, firms received tax in the island. Consequently, the States and Puerto Rico narrowed States. setting up operations gap between mainland United over the next 50 years, especially significantly income compared with the income and other Latin American countries. The remainder of this gaps of Mexico the role of institutional section estimates gaps in maintaining long-run income gaps. DataandMethodology To investigate of Acemoglu, of exogenous the impact of institutional gaps, we follow the methodology involves using a set Johnson, and Robinson.41 This basically to related variables characteristics geographic (namely, variables, latitude, and dummy landlocked-country dummy, a for oil and commodity constructed trade share indi exporters), cator that takes into consideration countries' size and geographic factors, regional dummies an indicator of ethnolinguistic fractionalization, the Kaufmann-Kraay indicators of institutional and a composite index of as 2000-2001 from quality variables of per capita income (in PPP-adjusted U.S. dollars) explanatory as of 2000.42 Table A2 in the appendix contains the summary statistics for our data set. Our methodology is two-stage least squares (2SLS). Since the indicators of institutions and the corresponding composite we need to find to the level of development, index can be endogenous instruments for this variable. Also, the institutional variables are measured with error, as explained by Kaufmann and Kraay and Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson. A priori, it is difficult to say which effect will predominate, since the endogeneity problem whereas improves institutions, duce an attenuation bias. could bias the estimates the measurement upward error problem if income could pro rates show that the (log) mortality Johnson, and Robinson Acemoglu, can a of settlers be good instrument for current institutions. These authors on a literature linking the importation of political and rely long historical 41. 42. and Robinson Johnson, (2001). Acemoglu, The trade share indicator is from Frankel and Romer the average of the six individual components. (1999); the composite index is William Easterly, Norbert Fiess, and Daniel Lederman 17 institutions to the extent to which colonies were settled by their sources for the extraction as opposed to becoming colonizers, European Where commodities. of high-priced settled, they imported Europeans had incentives not to "good" institutions. At the same time, Europeans settle in places where the climate and other historical factors reduced life economic It thus seems logical expectancy. centuries teenth and nineteenth to use settler mortality rates in the eigh as instruments for institutions in the present. Results 2, 3, and 4 present our results. Table 2 presents the 2SLS effects of the key variables on the (log) PPP-adjusted per capita of 2000. Table 3 shows the first-stage regressions, in which the index of institutional quality is the dependent variable. Table 4 Tables ordinary least squares (OLS) regressions, corresponding the assumption that institutions are exogenous. which estimated income as composite shows the depend on In the five specifications shown in table 2, the instrumented composite index of institutions is positively and significantly correlated with income. In fact, across the four models the relevant coefficient is quite stable, rang 1.35 to 1.94. The only other robust explanatory variable is the oil which with for appears consistently exporters, dummy positive and sig nificant coefficients. The Frankel-Romer trade openness indicator is not a of income per capita: virtually identical results significant determinant ing from were obtained for average share.43 These we when 1965-1990 used the Sachs-Warner policy openness instead of the Frankel-Romer constructed index trade can be interpreted as an indication either that the of countries is mainly determined by the long-run level of development or of domestic institutions that the correlation between the instru quality results ments used by Frankel and Romer to estimate the exogenous portion of the trade-to-GDP ratios (the so-called geographic gravity variables) and the rates is so high that it is quite difficult to really identify settlers' mortality the marginal effects of institutions and trade separately.44 results for the first-stage OLS regressions in table 3 show that the are rates (log) settlers' mortality good predictors of institutional quality in 2000. The mortality variable is always statistically significant and has the The 43. Sachs and Warner 44. Dollar and Kraay (1995). (2003). 18 ECONOM?A, TABLE 2. Fall 2003 Two-Stage LeastSquares Regressions of LogGDPper Capita2000a (1) Explanatory variable Institutional index Net oil exporters Net commodity exporters 1.35** 1.39** 1.40** (0.19) (0.20) (0.20) Americas Log constructed trade share (Frankel-Romer) 1.37*** (0.25) 0.87*** 0.69** 0.72** 0.73** 0.71*** (0.18) (0.21) (0.20) (0.21) -0.16 (0.13) -0.21 -0.16 (0.16) -0.12 -0.16 (0.16) -0.10 -0.16 (0.16) -0.14 (0.42) (0.59) (0.35) (0.38) (0.38) 0.98 0.45 0.59 0.60 0.55 (0.73) (0.38) (0.43) (0.43) (0.48) 0.70 0.53* 0.61* 0.62* 0.59 (0.53) (0.30) (0.33) (0.33) (0.38) 0.43 0.26 0.27 0.28 0.26 (0.43) (0.24) (0.27) (0.27) (0.30) -0.04 (0.12) 0.02 0.00 (0.09) (0.10) Ethnolinguisticfractionalization Landlocked (5) (0.30) 0.22 East Asia and the Pacific (4) 1 94*** (0.18) South Asia 0) (0?53) -0.22 Africa (2) 0.00 0.00 0.00 (0.00) (0.00) (0.00) -0.05 0.26 (0.28) (0.39) -0.02 Latitude (0.01) 0.72 R2 0.84 0.84 0.83 0.84 Source: Authors'calculations. * * ** * statisticallysignificantat the Statisticallysignificantat the 10 percent level; statisticallysignificantat the 5 percent level; 1percent level, a. Robuststandarderrorsare inparentheses. of the OLS and 2SLS estimates of expected negative sign. A comparison the institutional coefficient shows that the OLS estimates are significantly suffer from attenuation lower. These results suggest that OLS estimates bias owing errors afflicting the institutional variable. results shed light on the these econometric The last bar between the United States and Mexico. to measurement 6 illustrates Figure income gap observed how in the log of PPP-adjusted on the right is the income gap (the difference as 1.2. The penultimate of is which 2000, per capita GDP) approximately income gap (from column one of table 2). estimated bar shows the model's show the marginal effects of the statistically significant status of on the (log of) the U.S.-Mexico income gap. Mexico's a net exporter of oil tends to reduce the income gap by about 0.88. In con The other bars variables trast, the first six bars on the left side of the graph show the contribution of each institutional dimension. The sum of the individual institutional con William Easterly, Norbert Fiess, and Daniel Lederman 19 First-StageRegression for Institutional Index9 TABLE 3. variable Explanatory (1) -0.17** Logmortality (0.07) Oilproduction dummy -0.37** dummy Commodity -0.37* (0.08) -0.45** -0.18** (0.08) -0.45** (0.20) (0.18) 0.03 0.00 0.00 (0.16) (0.16) (0.20) (0.18) (0.18) EastAsia and the Pacific -0.52 Americas -0.35 (0.34) (0.33) -0.65* (0.30) -1.00* (0.34) -0.52 (0.33) -0.35 -0.69** (0.34) -1.07** (0.41) -0.45 (0.45) -0.35 (0.24) (0.24) (0.26) 0.04 0.04 0.05 (0.11) (0.11) (0.12) Ethnolinguistic fractionalization -0.43* R2 -0.42** -0.18** 0.04 -1.00*** Latitude (0.08) (0.18) Asia South Landlocked -0.18** 0.04 (0.30) Log constructed trade share (Frankel-Romer) (0.07) (0.18) -0.65** Africa (2) (3)(5) (4) -0.17* -0.43* -0.69** (0.34) -1.12** (0.39) -0.48 (0.44) -0.36 (0.26) (0.18) -0.69** (0.34) -1.12*** (0.39) -0.48 (0.44) -0.36 (0.26) 0.00 0.00 (0.00) (0.00) -0.43* -0.45* -0.45** (0.20) (0.20) (0.22) (0.22) 0.02* 0.02* 0.02** 0.02* (0.22) 0.02** (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) (0.01) 0.62 0.62 0.63 0.63 0.63 Source: Authors'calculations. ** *** * Statisticallysignificantat the 10 percent level; statisticallysignificantat the 5 percent level; statisticallysignificantat the 1percent level, a. Robuststandarderrorsare inparentheses. tributions bit more is about 2.5, but gaps in rule of law and corruption seem to be a errors in important than the other institutions. The measurement each category probably make this last observation ever, since we cannot be sure that these institutional In any case, States and Mexico the others. different from between the United less meaningful, how are gaps significantly the large income gap observed is readily explained by institu were not an oil exporter, it would tional features. Moreover, if Mexico be it than the full model predicts a poorer probably actually is. Finally, log ratio of U.S. over Mexican GDP per capita of about 0.62, which trans lates into a 0.54 ratio of Mexican GDP per capita over the U.S. GDP per capita. It is perhaps a coincidence that this is more or less the limit to the convergence process estimated with the cointegration analysis above. thus hamper convergence in North America. Institutional gaps might This does not mean that NAFTA, in particular, did not have an effect on 20 ECONOM?A,Fall2003 TABLE 4. OLSEstimates of LogGDPper Capita2000a variable Explanatory (1) (2) Institutional index 1.10*** Oil production dummy (0.11) (0.11) (0.11) 0.58*** 0.59*** 0.60*** 0.57*** (0.16) (0.16) (0.20) (0.17) (0.17) -0.15 -0.57** (0.29) (0.33) EastAsiaandthePacific (0.24) -0.02 (0.20) -0.03 -0.56* (0.29) 0.18 0.19 (0.38) 0.29 0.29 (0.24) 0.05 0.030.02 (0.21) (0.22) (0.11) -0.12 -0.14 (0.16) (0.15) -0.57* -0.56* (0.30) (0.24) (0.30) 0.12 (0.36) 0.24 (0.24) (0.22) (0.22) (0.00) (0.00) (0.36) 0.01 0.01 -0.01 (0.09) (Frankel-Romer) (0.16) (0.28) 0.00 0.12 (0.32) 0.160.25 (0.22) SouthAsia Log constructed trade share -0.14 (0.13) -0.65** Americas 1.08*** 0.51*** (0.13) Africa (5) 1.11*** 1.11*** (0.11) -0.17 Commodity dummy (4)(3) 1.11*** (0.09) (0.10) 0.00 0.00 0.00 Ethnolinguisticfractionalization (0.00) Landlocked -0.18 (0.17) Latitude -0.01 -0.20 (0.19) (0.00) No.observations 6161 68 68 61 Source: Authors'calculations. * ** *** Statisticallysignificantat the 10 percent level; statisticallysignificantat the 5 percent level; statisticallysignificantat the 1percent level, a. Robuststandarderrorsare inparentheses. institutional gence was Our time series analyses convergence. suggest that conver in fact present after NAFTA. Was this due to institutional convergence? PerformanceinMexico versustheRestof theRegion Institutional of the impact of institutions on the level of devel that institutions tend to change little over time, and thus opment presumed the instrument that Johnson, and Robinson? by Acemoglu, proposed The previous namely, the estimates settlers' lysts expected 45. Acemoglu, mortality that NAFTA Johnson, rate?is would and Robinson appropriate.45 exert direct (2001). However, some and indirect pressures ana on William Easterly, Norbert Fiess, and Daniel Lederman FIGURE 6. 21 TheContributionof InstitutionalGaps to the U.S.-MexicoIncomeGap GDP andObserved percapita/Mexico percapita Explained (log)U.S.GDP of Total AccountabilityPolitical GovernmentRegulatoryRuleof law Control corruption institutional stability effectiveness quality gap Explained Observed gap (2000) gap Source: Authors'calculations. to improve its institutions.46 The direct pressures came from spe cific elements of the trade agreements, including those related to investor intellectual property rights, labor, and the environment, which protection, Mexico explicitly focus could on Mexico's have enforcement emanated pressure States regarding Mexico's from of its own the political laws. The debate indirect in the United to implement its commitments. Our over rare but view is that institutions probably change little time, although uncommon or events other in institutions might profound changes political 46. NAFTA. An anonymous reviewer ability suggested that this might be the strongest impact from 22 ECONOM?A, Fall 2003 FIGURE 7. Mexico Year EffectsRelative to Regional Year Effects, Institutional Index(ICRG) Source: Authors'calculations(see text). a. Theexcludedyear is 1984.See tableA1 inthe appendixfor summarystatisticsfordata used and definitionof the groups. change the quality of public institutions.47 We therefore toMexican institutions before and after 1994. pened To test whether Mexican institutions changed more analyze what hap than those of other similar to those con countries, we estimated regressions in 4. The the income gaps presented figure dependent variable was cerning institutional the country's the difference between indicator, composite Latin American of three indexes of institutional quality provided by the Inter composed national Country Risk Guide (ICRG) and the U.S. value of this index. The index was constructed using factor analysis of ICRG's bureaucratic qual ity, law and order, and absence of corruption variables. These data cover 1984-2001. Again, for the comparisons we used the Group 1 and Group 2 samples (Group 1 includes Cuba in this analysis). Figure 7 shows the to use the Acemoglu instrument while also sound contradictory follow that the might change over time, it does not necessarily on the level of per capita income are uninfor is useless and that the regressions contains various com mative. The exogenous quality most probably portion of institutional to more recent some related to long-term historical and some related heritage ponents, over time might not be in institutions innovations. This implies that the variation exogenous 47. itmight Although that institutions believing instrument William Easterly, Norbert Fiess, and Daniel Lederman InstitutionalChanges in LatinAmerica TABLE 5. or Country NAFTA Before (1984-93) group NAFTA After (1994-2001) Change -1 Mexico Argentina Brazil -1 23 -1 80 -1.46 0.34 49 -1.05 0.43 -1.57 .00 Chile -1 55 -0.73 Colombia -1 -0.57 0.82 80 -1.91 South America -1 ,68 -1.59 CentralAmerica -2, Andean countries -1 -0.11 0.09 51 -1.61 0.90 ,98 -1.60 0.39 ,83 -1.53 0.30 LatinAmerican countries -1 Source: Authors'calculations,based on data from International CountryRiskGuide. year effects for the whole period were not statistically from the first group of Latin American countries, but they were seems to from different the 1994. Mexico after group average statistically results. Mexico's different relative to the regional average during this period, have underperformed or stable negative difference is reflected in a declining between which Mexico and the average regional effects. improved its institutions relative to the United though Mexico in the post-NAFTA period, the results in figure 7 are due to the fact in the region also improved their institutions without that other countries Even States benefiting from NAFTA. Table 5 shows the changes in the gap relative to index before and after institutional the United States of the composite that improved their institutional gap the most after 1994. The countries 1994 were Chile and the Central American group, whereas Mexico's norm was rather the for the whole improvement region. Moreover, Mex took place after 1999 and thus was probably related ico's big improvement to the political transition, as was the case in Chile and Central America. data are consistent with the findings of Lederman, and Loayza, has a positive effect in Soares, who find that political democratization terms of reducing corruption in a large sample of countries.48 NAFTA alone is unlikely to contribute to the institutional development of Mexico areas covered outside the specific the agreement. by Consequently, These fully stationary. exogenous The component historical of instrument the level of this issue. Rigobon for highlighting 48. Lederman, and Soares Loayza, the can still be valid, institutional (2002). an since it captures however, are grateful to Roberto index. We 24 ECONOM?A,Fall2003 Mexico's tions need policy efforts to combat to be pursued further. and improve general corruption institu Productivity Gapswithin Industries, across the United States and Mexico IfNAFTA trade liberalization helped technological adoption and modern we should observe an acceleration inMexico, in the rate of TFP within industries. To between the United States and Mexico convergence ization examine between this channel the United of convergence, and Mexico States we calculated in manufacturing TFP differentials sectors. The fol the data, methodologies, and econometric discuss lowing paragraphs on TFP convergence. the impact of NAFTA results concerning Dataand TFPEstimates measure the in total factor productivity (TFP) following and Diewert, which is used in approach suggested by Caves, Christensen, context by Keller.49 They calculate a multilateral the cross-country (bilat We differences eral in our present case) and flexible InTFPd, (1)__ TFP index of the following form: = (inYcit -ta?;)-a~t(lnLat -ETZ^) -(\-Gcit)(\nKclt-\nKu), c is the country index (Mexico and the United States), i represents industries, and t is time, y is total output, L is labor, and K is capital stock, labor share of output. The Caves, Christensen, while a is the cost-based of the log output, labor, and cap and Diewert approach entails de-meaning where ital series, using the geometric averages of both countries. The resulting index in each country and industry is based on a vector of outputs and inputs that are common to both countries. An intuitive reading is that this index tells us what the productivity level in each country and industry TFP be if they had the same labor cost shares. and factor shares come from Data on production would United Nations 49. Caves, Industrial Development Christensen, and Diewert (1982); Organization Keller (2002). the OECD (UNIDO) and the and cover William Easterly, Norbert Fiess, and Daniel Lederman 25 at the three-digit industries International manufacturing twenty-eight code.50 The Classification Standard Industrial (ISIC) output data were deflated using the U.S. industry deflators from Bartelsman, Becker, and (2000). The capital stock data were constructed using the permanent rate per year, based assuming a 5 percent depreciation inventory method, on fixed investment data from UNIDO, and were deflated using the PPP investment price levels from the Penn World Tables 6.O.51 Tables A3 and Gray in the appendix contain summary statistics for Mexico and the United States, respectively. A4 for the industry-level data EstimationStrategy To assess how the rate of (log) TFP convergence changed after the imple we estimated an autoregressive model with struc of NAFTA, with coefficient and in the autoregressive tural change industry fixed mentation effects and year effects: = (2) ylJt a, + y, + ? yM + ?XW?,-i where i= Wand 1, 2,..., As mentioned, maximum number t= 1,2,..., + ?Ata + elV, T. number of industries is N = 28, and the = is T 25. In the context of the fixed-effects our maximum of years to control for industry-specific is designed effects, a,, by could leftand both the variables produce a right-hand-side de-meaning to the correlation between the coefficients bias in the estimated owing estimator, which lagged mean of y and the contemporaneous error, e/r The bias is inversely to T. Also, as mentioned, there are no good data on Mexico's proportional unit price for industry-level output, such that the use of the U.S. deflator error that is endogenous a to (that is, measurement might have introduced efforts. This is a concern because is affected by) the trade liberalization and thus the trade reforms reduced the prices of capital goods inMexico, are biased upward after liberalization. We TFP estimates for Mexico therefore used the Arellano-Bond got our data from the OECD. 50. We from UNIDO, differences which, estimator in turn, received to estimate the Mexico directly 51. Output and capital inputs were PPP deflator series from the Penn World and U.S. the data in constant 1987 prices. The investment expressed Tables and the industry deflators from Bartelsman, end in 1996. We applied the average growth rate of the investment and Gray (2000) Becker, PPP deflator for the available years to the rest of our sample ending in 1999. 26 ECONOM?A,Fall2003 model in equation 2.52 This estimator helps reduce the influence of the errors by using lagged levels of the TFP biases induced by measurement to instrument the changes differentials in these differentials. Hence we for unobserved effects. Time effects, yt, are industry-specific for by the inclusion of year dummy variables. In equation 2, the autoregressive coefficient, ?, provides an indication A coefficient of less than 1 can be interpreted of the speed of convergence. as evidence of convergence in TFP levels between the United States and also control controlled was associated with gence, then the estimated able should be negative. coefficient of the corresponding Mexico. If NAFTA an acceleration of TFP conver interactive vari Results 6 reports the results from the Arellano-Bond differences estimator to 2 for the model additional controls suggested by equation plus applied the potential effect that Mexico's unilateral liberalization (from 1985) Table focuses on the The second model have had on TFP convergence. are not affected these data in for labor since gap comparisons, productivity a for fixed investment deflator the the lack of Mexican by twenty-eight industries. In both cases, the models pass the specification manufacturing tests, indicating that the instrument set is adequate and there is no serial might are not biased owing to that the coefficients suggests error in the output series. Also, in both cases, NAFTA was associated with a faster rate of manufacturing convergence, productivity as indicated by the highly of the and negative coefficients significant correlation. This measurement differen dummy variable interacted with the lagged productivity tial. The TFP results (column 1, table 6) imply that the half-life of a unit to 0.7 afterward. shock to the TFP gap fell from 1.6 years prior to NAFTA NAFTA The corresponding change for labor productivity from 2.5 to 1.7 years. These results are consistent change in the degree cussed above. of persistence (column 2, table 6) was with the estimates of the of the U.S.-Mexico income gap dis that the NAFTA results strongly In sum, the econometric suggest a in manufac was with associated faster convergence significantly period are that the trade agreement tempted to postulate turing TFP levels. We 52. Arellano and Bond (1991). 27 William Easterly, Norbert Fiess, and Daniel Lederman on Manufacturing TFPConvergence3 The Effectof NAFTA TA B LE 6. (V (2) 0.65* 0.76*** Explanatory variable Log productivity differential (f-1) x Logproductivity NAFTA differential (f-1) x Logproductivity LIB differential (f-1) -0.28* -0.09*** -0.03 0.04 0.25 0.39 0.32 0.87 Specification test Sargan overidentification test (p value) Second-order serial correlation test [p value) Summary statistic No. observations 462 28 No. industries 482 28 Source: Authors'calculations. *** Statisticallysignificantat the 1 percent level. a. Thedependent variable incolumn 1 isthe logTFPdifferential(UnitedStates andMexico); in column2 it is the logoutput per workerdifferential(UnitedStatesandMexico).Thefiguresreportedare first-stepestimatesof regressionsrunusingArellano-Bond gen eralmethod ofmoments. Thesampleperiod is 1980to 2000. Yeardummiesare not reported. had an important positive effect on Mexican manufacturing with firm-level evidence results are consistent provided TFP. These by L?pez data presented by Schiff and Wang.53 How and industry-level the former study argues that this effect was related to preferential C?rdova ever, access but not to import competition, imports of intermediate goods. In contrast, the study by Schiff and Wang benefited from imported intermediate goods from the argues thatMexico on the extent of R&D efforts in the United United States, depending market to the United States States. Our results seem to indicate and brought something to the table that was not necessarily liberalization, accomplished by unilateral but we have not speculated about the exact channels of influence. In our view, this issue remains that NAFTA an open question for future research. Initial Conditions and Divergence within Mexico reviewed the times series evidence income conver concerning TFP and the evidence between the gence convergence panel concerning we now turn to the impact of NAFTA within United States and Mexico, If geography Mexico.54 and initial conditions play an important role in Having 53. L?pez-C?rdova (2002); Schiff andWang (2002). 54. This section is based on Esquivel and others (2002). 28 ECONOM?A, economic income Fall 2003 then NAFTA convergence, across Mexican differentials might states. have had a notable impact on It is standard practice in the analytical work on economic growth to a set of in determinants of entities potential growth geographic using econometric techniques.55 Both Esquivel and Messmacher apply this examine approach to the case of Mexico.56 Here we use the same standard variables that deter approach, but we focus on a small set of policy-related state. The following in each Mexican mined initial conditions paragraphs describe the data and methods used to address these questions. Data andMethodologies to explain the growth rate of state GDP per capita during constant 1993 prices).57 This is the period during which (at trade liberalization and NAFTA must have been felt, and it is sufficiently We want 1990-2000 long that the cumulative growth rate during this whole period could reflect such as medium-term rather than just short-lived conditions phenomena, the economic crisis of 1995. Figure 8 shows the evolution of the ratio of per capita GDP Federal District in a selection of northern and southern states relative to the since 1940. The big story is, (the capital of the Republic) was that the Federal richer and District stayed richer for the last again, or so. to states of in None these catch up significantly sixty years managed has existed terms, despite the fact that free trade within Mexico for a long time. Also, it looks like the 1990s were characterized by a slight states of the southern the northern and catch-up by continuing divergence absolute states relative to the Federal District. factors might explain why some states grew more than others? the role of geography the issues raised by the literature concerning one set of costs in hampering convergence, and transport or coordination What Given variables key explanatory munications infrastructure, 55. See the textbook by Barro indicators of transport and com encompasses which we measured by the kilometers of paved and Sala-i-Martin (1995). 56. Esquivel (1999);Messmacher (2000). de M?x from El Colegio 57. The data were graciously Esquivel by Gerardo provided in of oil revenues, which ico, Mexico City. The GDP series were adjusted for the allocation and Information, Institute of Statistics, the original series (from the National Geography, to different in practice allocated states, although INEGI) had been periodically they are shares. allocated to according probably population William Easterly, Norbert Fiess, and Daniel Lederman FIGURE 8. 29 Ratio of State GDPper CapitaRelative to the FederalDistrict, 1940 to 2000 State / FederalDistrict 6DP per capita i_i_i_i_i_i_i_i_i_i__ 1940 1950 1970 1960 1980 1988 1990 1993 1995 2000 Source: Authors'calculations. highways per worker and telephone density.58 We also used the distance from the U.S. border as an additional explanation of economic growth to assess the argument that being far from the United States was an impedi ment to growth.59 It is conventional wisdom that the level of education of the adult popu lation might be related to the growth rate. Hence, we also examine the impact of educational attainment in 1990 as an explanation of growth rates 58. with respect to the surface area of because we would need to know however, meaningful territory. In any case, when we used the ratio over surface area of each state, the results are virtually identi The coverage of paved state. This measure might the surface area of economically each of paved roads or highways cal to those discussed herein. 59. distance The distance from from the major roads the U.S. city could also be in each be measured imprecise, border was measured state to the closest in two alternative major city near ways: (1 ) by the the border, plus the 30 ECONOM?A,Fall2003 In this way we can be sure that the subsequent period 1990-2000. cause not of We also experimented with did the level education. growth instead of the years of schooling. literacy rates of the adult population during they receive argued that poor states grow slower because resources to One such finance their argument, growth. public do not provide sufficient is that private capital markets for example, to various for of the types lagging regions owing financing development It is often insufficient to private financing related to insufficient information about areas to of firms operating in those pay back loans. However, of obstacles the capacity it is also possible that large public sectors can be a drain on economic the local labor markets (for example, raising wages growth by distorting above what private enterprises can pay) or by raising the costs of capital that would otherwise have gone to the private sector (that is, the so-called To assess these alternative of public expenditures). at the size of the public sector, measured look the of arguments impact on the growth as the share of public employment in total employment, states. rates of Mexican crowding out effect we To assess Oaxaca?had and the really poor states?Chiapas, Guerrero, for their prospects that hampered characteristics a included dummy variable that identifies these states. whether other we development, Finally, we included tional convergence the initial level of per capita GDP to test the condi hypothesis. Results tech 7 reports some of our results, based on standard statistical least report results based on ordinary niques. The first two columns an alterna from results the columns and fourth and third report squares, Table regressions, which is less sensitive to outliers. The the initial per capita of conditional convergence; in all four exer coefficient and statistically significant tive technique, median table shows evidence GDP has a negative It thus seems that poor states do grow faster if they have similar poli cies to the rich states. cises. The other explanatory variables, except the variable that identifies the states (Chiapas, Guerrero, and Oaxaca), also seem to be important for growth, and they are generally statistically significant. As expected, southern distance of the latter to the border tal city of each state to the closest itself; major and U.S. (2) by city. the geographic distance from the capi William Easterly, Norbert Fiess, and Daniel Lederman TABLE 7. 31 Potential Determinants of Growthof State GDPper Capita, 1990 to 2000a variable Explanatory (2) (1)(3) (4) 1990 InitialGDPper capita, (in natural logarithm) Initialeducation (years of schooling -0.15** -0.15** -0.14** -0.12** (-2.35) (-2.32) (-3.95) (-2.09) 0.24 0.22 over15yearsofage),1990 ofpopulation 0.08* Telephone density,1990 (1.38) (1.09) (3.40) 0.08* (1.91) (1.93) Public employment (log of share 1990 total employment), of 0.27* 0.05** (2.86) (1.86) 0.05 (1.39) -0.12** -0.12* -0.07* -0.09 (-2.13) (-1.98) (-1.97) (-1.54) -0.01 Not included Not included States of Chiapas, Guerrero, and Oaxaca (dummy variable) 0.27** -0.021 (-0.02) (-0.33) Summary statistic 0.31 0.28 Adjusted/?2 Pseudo/?2 No. observations 0.21 0.21 32 32 32 32 Source:Authors'calculations. * ** Statisticallysignificantat the 10percent level; statisticallysignificantat the 5 percent level. a. The regressionsestimate the effect of a 1percent increaseinthe correspondingvariableon the cumulativeGDPgrowth rateper capita, 1990-2000. Columns1and 2 are estimatedusingOLS;columns2 and 3 are estimatedusingmedian regressions.A constantwas were includedinthe regressions,but itscoefficientsare not reported.NumerousadditionalspecificationsinOLSandmedian regressions estimatedusingthe followingexplanatoryvariables:(a) literacyrates insteadof yearsof education;(b)two alternativemeasures of dis tance fromthe UnitedStates insteadof and inadditionto the Chiapas,Guerrero,andOaxacadummy;(c)paved roadsand double-lane highwaysover surfaceareaor perworker insteadof telephonedensity; (d)the shareofmanufacturingGDPover totalGDPin1988;and (e) urbanizationrates.See the text fora discussionof the alternativeresults.Finally,t statisticsare inparentheses. effect on growth. However, estimates density has a positive over roads and two-lane roads worker surface (or per paved using paved correlated with growth area) reveal that these variables were negatively telephone that building there is no evidence during the period.60 Hence suggesting more roads will lead to higher growth in the future. This result might be due to the existence of economically infrastructure that does unnecessary not serve a useful purpose The results concerning for existing economic activity. the role of distance from the U.S. border (not was a not that this variable statistically significant reported here) to economic impediment growth in most exercises, although the coeffi the distance variables cient is always negative.61 However, introducing not the statistical the direction drove down of the (but significance indicate 60. District, These which OLS has had relatively high 61. We estimated note one four models with a sample excluding the Federal to high population density and which used the two distance variables discussed above in foot were estimated In only via OLS and two via median regressions regressions. was at the 10 percent the distance variable these four models level, significant 37. Two of results did not change when we low paved roads per worker owing rates of growth. 32 ECONOM?A,Fail2003 variables. This evidence indi effects) of the other explanatory that the states located farther from the United States suffer from low estimated cates of education levels and telephone which density, hamper their growth prospects. at the beginning of the period has no statistically on important impact growth in the OLS estimates. This result might be due to the fact that human capital can migrate to dynamic regions, and thus this variable does not have any discernible it impact on the states for which level of education The was calculated literacy rates were used instead of educa coefficient was positive and statistically the estimates based on median force regressions in 1990. When tional attainment, the estimated significant. Moreover, fully show that educational between attainment does initial GDP matter. The correlation and initial education per capita, telephone density, of the impact of education rather difficult. might make the identification The share of public employment had a negative effect on economic shows 9 the correlation between these two vari activity. Figure simple it is negative. This negative correlation might be due to some obser the median vations that appear in the lower right of the chart. However, are to influ which less be estimates, likely disproportionately regression ables; enced by strange observations, also show that this variable had a negative effect on economic growth although it is not statistically significant, after of the southern states (see for other unobserved characteristics controlling the fourth column of table 7). in growth To be sure that these explanations of the observed differences we conducted rates across Mexican states are not misleading, additional in which we controlled for the share of manufacturing exercises produc in Esquivel and others, the tion over total state GDP in 1990. As discussed southern states have never had a high share of manufacturing production, as a whole some manufacturing industries (and some of manufac grew quite rapidly in the 1990s.62 The performance and for the country services) turing relative to natural resource or agricultural industries could have been due to changes in relative prices. For example, the international price of coffee began to decline in the late 1980s. Our statistical analyses indi although fications. other 62. several of the other were These results between variables explanatory are due to the correlation explanatory variables. Esquivel and others (2002). in these speci also not significant and the the distance variables William Easterly, Norbert Fiess, and Daniel Lederman 33 Relation between Growthand Public Employment inMexican States, 1990sa FIGURE 9. Cumulative growth of income per capita, 1990-2000 (percent) 0.01 0.02 0.03 0.04 0.05 0.06 0.07 0.08 0.09 Public employment, 1990 (percent of total) Source: Authors'calculations. a. y=-2.2719x+0.0787;tf2 = 0.1282. cated that the qualitative nature of the OLS results presented in table 7 are share of production. by the inclusion of the manufacturing the inclusion of the share of in the relevant median regressions, However, not affected affected the sign of the education and public production variables, employment although none of them were statistically signifi cant. This influence of manufacturing production on the estimated effect manufacturing of education tion between a negative could stem from a positive correla and public employment education and manufacturing (which is 0.5) and production correlation with the share of public employment (which is, seems to In other words, manufacturing -0.5). production coincidentally, in states with either high levels of education or low levels be concentrated of the high mobility of new cap of public employment. The combination ital and the relative irre ver sibility of past investment probably makes sensitive activities particularly capital-intensive in a state, such that manufacturing environment to the initial economic is implicitly capturing 34 ECONOM?A,Fall2003 things such as the rule of law, instability, by the state. crime, or excessive intervention thus suggests that hope for the southern states is not lost: of conditional and some key policy convergence, the of economic growth observed variables help explain patterns Our evidence there is some evidence sensitive across Mexican states during (measured by telephone associated with economic positively In particular, communications density) ismore likely to have been activity than paved roads or high 1990-2000. infrastructure ways. Also, the evidence does not support the idea that increasing the size of the public sector can be a force for economic However, convergence. seem to have had important effects the big story remains: initial conditions on economic growth within Mexico in the 1990s. States that were initially better prepared to reap the benefits of NAFTA grew faster during this period, while the poor states of the south fell further behind. Conclusions and Final Remarks and sources of convergence the dynamics analyzed and the United States. Time series analyses of the con facts about the U.S. process interesting stylized produced and identified and convergence process periods of convergence This paper has between Mexico vergence Mexican suffered a major setback in the 1980s as a convergence divergence. While result of the debt crisis, the tequila crisis only temporarily interrupted a when Mexico that started in the late 1980s convergence process opened its we only found evidence of incomplete convergence, economy. However, sense in the that the constant in the cointegration space was greater than toward a constant income dif is converging zero, indicating that Mexico ferential between of about 50 percent of the U.S. GDP per capita. The comparison relative income effects and average Latin Amer annual Mexican toward the United States ican effects indicated thatMexico's convergence was especially after 1995. important in institutional fea evidence showed that differences The cross-country income from history play an important role in producing of effects much estimated estimates larger produced on incomes than the OLS estimates, thus indicating that mea error is an important source of attenuation bias in these rela tures inherited gaps. The institutions surement 2SLS William Easterly, Norbert Fiess, and Daniel Lederman 35 tionships.63 The use of historical instruments for current institutional qual ity is also interesting on its own, since institutions tend to persist over time for a long time. and thus might remain a source of income divergence research could yield additional of institutional quality. determinants about the role of political institutions Future practical insights if it focuses on the In particular, further understanding the quality of gover in determining what could types of reforms may help identify policy overcome Recent of research the weight history. along these lines has help already proved fruitful.64 Yet little is known about how accountability can help improve national institutions. In the case of North mechanisms nance and economic in the long run might economic international convergence to on to the standards of its neighbors. catch up Mexico's capacity depend In fact, the econometric indicated that the model with institu analyses America, and trade predicts an income gap of the Mexico-U.S. tions, geography, similar GDP per capita ratio of about 54 percent, which is coincidentally to the incomplete estimated convergence using cointegration analysis. institutions did not improve signifi the quality of Mexican Furthermore, cantly more than those of other Latin American NAFTA period. countries during the post within manufacturing The analysis of TFP convergence industries pro the impact of NAFTA. The evi results concerning duced more optimistic in the rate dence indicates that NAFTA was associated with improvements these the United States and Mexico. While of TFP convergence between results are broadly consistent with other studies, these studies contradict in terms of the channels through which NAFTA is thought to have improved Mexican TFP.65 manufacturing Namely, L?pez-C?rdova each other access to the U.S. market (for example, the argues that it was preferential tariffs faced by Mexican exporters to the United States) and import pene tration, but not imports of inputs from the United States. Schiff and Wang were due to the R&D content of imported argue that TFP improvements inputs. We can also think of other alternative hypotheses. One possibility is that NAFTA, either through its demanded ment in the protection of intellectual property rights or through 63. This is consistent with previous studies, including Acemoglu, son (2001) and Kaufmann and Kraay (2002b). 64. Persson and Soares (2002); Lederman, (2002). Loayza, 65. L?pez-C?rdova (2002); Schiff andWang (2002). Johnson, improve increased and Robin 36 ECONOM?A,Fall2003 international competition incentives tries), provided Meza and Mora, patenting. and exporting indus (for import-competing in private R&D efforts and for improvements as well as Lederman and Maloney, find that the increases in post-NAFTA period was, in fact, characterized by significant R&D expenditures.66 inventors improved Patenting activity by Mexican as this well. Yet the significantly during existing literature remains period, this particular force toward convergence. An examination of on of patent these issues would require empirical work the determinants a on across focus the of trade with countries, impact policies ing special silent about policies. Much work remains to be done in this area, an emerging is literature.67 Lederman and Maloney show there although that, in fact, the protection of intellectual property rights tends to increase and innovation relative to GDP in a broad panel of countries and that these are in the sense that they tend to rise with improve expenditures cyclical ments in short-term growth.68 It is thus very likely that NAFTA helped its intellectual Mexico its innovation property rights improve through R&D efforts regime and by helping Mexico hand, Lederman and Maloney recover after the tequila crisis. On the other also show that the emerging manufacturing sectors under NAFTA telecommunications (namely, road vehicles, equip are not yet characterized and appliances) by significant improve in patenting the presence of significant suggests activity, which related to the lack of linkages between R&D per efficiency problems ment, ments formed the public by and higher-education sectors and the productive sector.69 showed Our study of growth patterns within Mexico during 1990-2000 states grew faster. We that initial conditions determined which Mexican interpret this evidence as showing that trade liberalization might be asso economic ciated with initial conditions. divergence In the Mexican within countries owing telecommunications to differences in infrastructure case, and human capital were especially important. In addition, it is commonly and that the poor states suffer from poor public institutions understood states faster The have grown poor during this might instability.70 political period if they had been adequately 68. (2002); Lederman Porter, and Stern (2002). and Maloney Lederman (2003b). 69. Lederman 70. Esquivel 66. Meza 67. and Mora Furman, and Maloney (2003a). and others (2002). prepared and Maloney to reap the benefits (2003a). of free William Easterly, Norbert Fiess, and Daniel Lederman 37 in North America might not materialize trade. Economic convergence under free trade or under any trade regime as long as fundamental differ ences in initial conditions some of these persist over time. Fortunately, fundamentals should be sensitive to policy changes. Appendix: Supplementary Data TABLE A1. SummaryStatistics for Data Used for EconometricResults on Institutional Gapsand IncomeGaps (Figures4 and 7) No. Variable Sample3 Group1 observations ICRG variables" GDP Log(country's GDP percapita/USA Standard Mean deviation Minimum Maximum 414 -0.4069638 0.558766 -1.75361 923 -1.715673 0.579324 -3.65967 162 -0.1312372 0.4356544 -1.00386 378 -1.328616 0.3673385 -2.19757 0.6972296 -0.3095284 per capita) 2 Group ICRG variables" GDP (country's Log GDP percapita/USA percapita,PPPadjusted) 0.6972296 -0.3095284 a. Group 1:Argentina,Bolivia,Brazil,Chile,Colombia,CostaRica,Cuba,DominicanRepublic,Ecuador,ElSalvador,Guatemala, Guyana,Haiti,Honduras,Jamaica,Mexico,Nicaragua,Panama,Paraguay,Peru,Trinidadand Tobago,Uruguay,andVenezuela;Cuba is not includedinthe GDPsample.Group2: Argentina,Brazil,Chile,Colombia,CostaRica,Mexico,Peru,Uruguay,andVenezuela. b. Weighted averageof the ICRG variables(absenceof corruption,lawand order,and bureaucraticquality). TABLE A 2. SummaryStatistics for Data Used inAnalysisof InstitutionalGaps and IncomeGaps No. Variable observations Standard Mean 68 0.1323529 Landlocked Openness (Sachs andWarner, 1995) Log constructed trade share deviation Minimum Maximum 0.3413936 0 63 0.2252768 0.3423797 0 68 2.721456 0.7672238 0.94 68 Latitude 6.318064 1 1 4.586000 (Frankel-Romer) Ethnolinguisticfractionalization EastAsiaandthePacifie Oilproduction Commodity Institutional per LogGDP dummy dummy index capita 19.691030 1 61 46.377050 29.430240 68 Africa 0.3382353 0.4766266 68Asia 0.0588235 0.2370435 South 68 0.0735294 0.2629441 0 68 Americas 0.3970588 0.4929263 68 0.2647059 0.4444566 68 0.6764706 0.4713010 68 -0.1134657 68 4.588946 Logmortality 68 7.794468 0.7704978 1.2550750 1.1091530 -41.81407 61.06258 90 0 0 1 1 1 0 0 0 -1.978333 2.145931 5.252923 1 1 1 1.585833 7.986165 10.031100 38 ECONOM?A,Fall2003 TABLE A3. Mexico: SummaryStatistics of Variables and Data Used for TFPConvergence Analysis, by Industry (Log) Industrycode3 311 313 314 321 322 323 324 331 332 341 342 351 352 353 354 355 356 361 362 369 371 372 381 382 383 384 385 390 output 15.77 15.08 13.65 14.35 13.11 12.52 12.86 11.91 12.49 14.61 13.29 14.98 15.09 13.23 12.72 13.66 14.00 12.08 13.81 14.41 15.38 14.31 14.24 14.02 14.64 15.95 12.15 12.21 (Log) Labor (Log) Obs labor 25 25 25 25 17 7 17 25 17 25 17 25 25 7 25 25 17 17 25 25 25 25 25 25 25 25 17 17 12.98 13.87 12.72 13.68 10.36 11.50 12.50 13.41 11.33 11.44 10.01 10.87 11.19 11.70 9.85 11.77 10.49 10.55 12.08 14.35 11.38 11.67 12.48 14.16 12.89 13.49 10.49 11.94 Obs capital 9.84 12.44 11.69 12.90 11.83 12.70 10.13 9.04 11.86 13.12 12.05 14.36 12.59 14.84 11.34 12.73 12.08 12.58 11.78 11.97 12.57 13.02 13.15 14.22 9.76 10.19 10.34 10.86 Source: UnitedNations Industrial DevelopmentOrganization(UNIDO), a. See tableA5 fora listof the industriesby code. Obs share Obs 25 25 25 25 17 7 17 25 17 25 17 25 25 7 25 25 17 17 25 25 25 25 25 25 25 25 17 17 0.06 25 25 25 25 17 7 17 25 17 25 17 25 25 7 25 25 17 17 25 25 25 25 25 25 25 25 17 17 0.10 0.04 0.16 0.17 0.08 0.19 0.13 0.14 0.08 0.15 0.09 0.11 0.07 0.06 0.14 0.12 0.14 0.15 0.10 0.07 0.06 0.12 0.11 0.13 0.07 0.10 0.16 William Easterly, Norbert Fiess, and Daniel Lederman TABLE A4. United States: SummaryStatistics of Variables and Data Used for TFP ConvergenceAnalysis, by Industry Labor (Log) (Log) (Log) Industrycode3 output Obs labor Obs capital Obs share Obs 19.47 25 17.06 25 18.08 25 25 0.09 17.50 25 15.19 25 16.74 25 25 0.10 16.85 18.14 17.64 25 25 25 14.03 16.45 16.12 25 25 25 15.37 17.21 15.86 25 25 25 250.06 25 0.18 25 0.22 15.35 25 13.66 25 14.11 25 25 0.19 15.32 25 13.81 25 14.72 25 25 0.22 17.64 25 15.92 25 16.79 25 25 0.18 17.27 25 15.86 25 15.61 25 250.24 18.46 18.57 18.67 25 21 25 16.58 17.21 16.36 25 21 25 18.15 17.48 18.54 25 21 25 250.15 21 0.26 250.10 18.46 25 16.36 25 17.34 25 25 0.12 18.62 25 14.86 25 17.90 25 25 0.02 16.58 21 13.88 21 15.12 21 210.10 16.99 25 15.45 25 16.20 25 250.21 17.95 14.72 25 25 16.32 13.56 25 25 16.93 14.03 25 25 25 0.19 25 0.32 16.64 25 15.14 25 16.15 25 17.62 69 25 15.97 25 16.92 0.19 25 71 18.09 17.74 18.73 25 25 25 16.43 15.69 17.25 25 25 25 18.15 0.19 25 16.97 25 17.62 25 19.31 25 17.78 25 18.21 25 25 0.22 19.15 25 17.60 25 18.07 25 250.22 19.66 18.21 17.25 ?90 25 25 25 17.88 16.81 15.71 25 25 25 18.43 25 16.98 25 16.10 0.21 25 Source: UnitedNations Industrial DevelopmentOrganization(UNIDO), a. See tableA5 fora listof the industriesby code. 250.23 25 25 250.13 25 0.23 250.17 250.25 25 39 40 ECONOM?A,Fall2003 TABLE A 5. Listof Codesand IndustriesUsed in TFPConvergenceAnalysis ?SIC Code Industry 311 Foodproducts 313 Beverages 314 Tobacco 321Textiles 322 Wearing apparel, except footwear 323 Leather products 324 Footwear, except rubberor plastic 331 Wood products, except furniture Furniture, except metal 341 Paper and products 332 342 Printing andpublishing 351 Industrial chemicals 352 Other chemicals 353 Petroleum refineries 354 Miscellaneous petroleum and coal products 355 Rubber products 356 Plastic products Pottery, china, earthenware 362 Glass and glass products 369 Other nonmetallic mineral products 361 371 Ironand steel 372 Nonferrous metals 381 Fabricatedmetal products 382 Machinery, except electrical 383 Machinery, electric 384 Transport equipment 385 Professional and scientific equipment 390 Other manufactured products Comments Bill Easterly, Norbert Fiess, and Daniel Lederman V. Loayza: in North have written a serious and comprehensive study on convergence after NAFTA. The authors approach the subject from many dif America ferent perspectives, perhaps to make up for the little time available for Norman a definitive of NAFTA's evaluation aftermath. The paper's conducting to making has contributed is the extent to which NAFTA main question to that of the United and income closer States Canada. Mexico's per capita To provide an answer that would address the various aspects of the ques and microeconomic the authors examine macrodata; use time and panel econometric and consider series, cross-sectional, techniques; cross-state both cross-country and (Mexican) evidence. This may seem but there is a rationale for each exercise. Microeconomic excessive, (firm tion, level) data can resolve aggregation biases and concentrate on productivity in specific industries. Macroeconomic, and time-series, convergence can common events for control evidence inter cross-country taking place for comparison, and thus help us under nationally, provide a benchmark stand the effects of the unique Mexican experience with NAFTA. Finally, cross-state evidence allows an evaluation of the differing effects Mexican on Mexico's of NAFTA regions, a necessary undertaking given this coun try's large size and diversity. to the paper's emphasis on income convergence A possible objection should consider other more could be that a proper evaluation of NAFTA such as trade volumes and aspects of the agreement, prices, foreign investment flows, capital costs, and innovation trends. This is unwarranted, however, on considering that this paper is part objection more generally of a larger research project that evaluates NAFTA and relevant or direct and other Latin American countries. implications for Mexico are this in from the volume collected project being resulting papers Lessons from NAFTA, edited by Daniel Lederman, William Maloney, and Luis Serven. draws policy The 41 42 ECONOM?A, The authors NAFTA Fall 2003 arrive at a nuanced correctly reflects income closer success. to that are preventing Mex this partners faster. I believe and limitations of NAFTA the achievements of the U.S., but institutional and governance to its North American ico from converging conclusion on NAFTA's conclusion to bringing Mexico's has indeed contributed factors on income I convergence up to this point. At the end of my comments, offer additional evidence supporting it.My criticism of the paper resides not in its conclusions, but in some of its methodology. Isa DynamicProcess Convergence The the issue of convergence from two differ ent methodological In their firm-productivity and cross-state standpoints. as a transitional convergence analyses, they regard dynamic, phenomenon. authors implicitly address To examine vari it, therefore, they estimate dynamic (lagged-dependent most treatment This is the of convergence for able) models. appropriate countries. Conversely, when the authors turn to their cross developing country analysis, The econometric as a steady-state phenomenon. they regard convergence to this perspective is the estimation of static counterpart models, based on the comparison of output levels via cointegration analy sis or cross-country how regressions. This is of only limited usefulness, ever, for countries that are rapidly evolving. The first consideration is whether cointegration analysis can help deter extent to Bernard mine the of income convergence. and According two countries exists if the long between Durlauf, long-run convergence run forecast of their output difference is stable.1 The challenge for imple this concept is how to assess the long-run stability of the income menting to use cointegration choose difference. and Lederman Fiess, Easterly, can to if the said be U.S. and Mexican income be analysis: converging per capita output series cointegrate between is the case, the stationary difference countries' vides a measure denotes of the extent of convergence, a (1,-1) vector. If this the two income levels pro with in which convergence. The problem with this approach is that it requires be stable over ference between the two countries whereas stable a zero difference absolute that the income the concept of convergence only requires in the long run. The cointegration approach would 1. Bernard dif the sample period, that this difference be and Durlauf (1995). be appropriate if William Easterly, Norbert Fiess, and Daniel Lederman 43 FIGURE 10. Steady-State and TransitionalConvergence the two countries had already arrived at their steady states, but it is incor if they are at different points on the path toward their rectly as Mexico and the United States are bound to be. The long-run positions, first panel of figure 10 represents the convergence process that is implied restrictive in cointegration tries are always analysis: the income the two coun between differences stable over the sample period. The second convergence process, in which the income (stochastically) panel represents amore general difference is allowed a transition period and stability occurs only toward and the United States for the sample period are probably not the income differences (1960-2002), the end. In the case of Mexico under consideration stable, but declining (as in the left portion of the second panel). Therefore, as statistically, as well analysis may not be conceptually cointegration for analyzing appropriate I now turn to convergence income-level regressions. in this case. After years of cross-country to rely on output-level com it has become fashionable growth regressions, so across to the level of is different development parisons explain why countries. Acemoglu, and Easterly and Levine are Johnson, and Robinson two of the most influential papers of this literature.2 An evaluation of this approach should start by asking what is likely to explain output differences among countries. The answer depends on how the world distribution of output across countries behaves over time. If this distribution has achieved across countries would be output differences in that the is, highly persistent country very long run, explained by factors such as political and social institutions and economic characteristics its steady state, then can be identified with power relations. In this case, output differences measures if the world distribution of the extent of convergence. However, of output across countries is changing over time?following, for instance, 2. Acemoglu, Johnson, and Robinson (2001); Easterly and Levine (2003). 44 ECONOM?A, FIGURE 11. Fall 2003 U.S.andMexican IncomeDifferences inthe Transitiontoward the Steady State U.S. income Mexican income *t-1 a dynamic transition pattern?then among countries output differences would be explained not only by such long-run factors, but also by eco nomic policies, international and domestic shocks, and, most importantly, the In this case, we would be interested in measuring initial conditions. con extent of of rather than the (a dynamic concept), convergence speed (the static counterpart). vergence Consider the stylized paths of output over time for the United to understand in figure 11. If one wants the output Mexico States and difference in the steady state (Tss), it is best to focus on if both countries are evolving dynami long-run factors only. However, not tell the whole story with regard to out these factors do long-run cally, between the two countries at, say, time t. Initial conditions, put differences represented by the output in the previous period, t - 1, are likely to be fundamentally difference current differences between Mexico and the in explaining important United States. How do these points translate into econometric Given specifications? across not of output countries has reached a that the world distribution steady state, a static output (Y) regression is misspecified: William Easterly, Norbert Fiess, and Daniel Lederman 45 (1) I? = 7Z?+e?. It should be replaced by a dynamic regression tial conditions (Yit_A) and shocks and policies institutional factors that takes into account (X), in addition ini to long-run (Z): (2) ^^a^+?X.+yZ^e,,, the subscripts / and t represent country and time, respectively. in natural logs, then If, as is standard, output per capita is expressed as a can 2 be rewritten dynamic equation growth regression, which can be where estimated cross-country using pooled (3) YUt Y^ =(a- and time-series data: \)YU_X+ ?*,r + yZ, + e,,. EvidencefromGrowthRegressions a return to growth regressions, I now use this method that NAFTA has indeed had a pos evidence advocated Having to offer circumstantial ology itive effect on Mexico's The exercise growth performance. supports conclusion that Mexico has approached Fiess, and Lederman's in terms of per capita income after NAFTA started. Easterly, the U.S. The like to present is taken from a recent paper on in Latin America and the Caribbean, written by C?sar growth Pablo Fajnzylber, and myself.3 There, we estimate a growth and using panel data on a worldwide sample of countries evidence economic Calder?n, regression I would nonoverlapping five-year periods spanning 1960-99. We consider a large of variety growth determinants, which we group into categories related to transitional convergence, cyclical reversion, structural reforms (including institutional and external conditions. We factors), stabilization policies, control for unobserved effects and the likely endogeneity country-specific of the explanatory variables. We use the estimated parameters to explain the growth changes experienced by individual Latin American countries in recent decades. This model can be applied to account for the change in to 1996-99, that is, roughly growth rates from 1991-95 NAFTA. Table 8 shows the results for Mexico. 3. Loayza, Fajnzylber, and Calder?n (2002). before and after 46 ECONOM?A,Fall2003 TABLE 8. Mexico: Determinants of the Change inGrowth Rates, 1991-95 to 1996-99 Percentage points Growthdeterminant Projected contribution to change ingrowth rate Transitional convergence Cyclical reversion 1.23 0.03 Structural reform0.66 Stabilization policies External conditions 0.31 0.06 Total projected change Actual change 3.88 Growth premium (actual 2.29 projected) 1.59 The actual change in growth rates inMexico before and after NAFTA 3.88 percentage points, while the projected change was only 2.29 per a growth premium of 1.59 per thus experienced centage points. Mexico for a centage points that we cannot explain despite having accounted was set of growth determinants, initial conditions, comprehensive including financial development, trade inflation rates, burden, volume, government rate misalignment, real exchange financial crises, terms of trade shocks, infrastructure facilities, and world conditions. Still, this growth premium may not be particular could be attributable to either a feature of the model to other countries, particularly in Latin America. toMexico, but rather or an event common To dismiss this possibil TABLE 9. LatinAmericanCountries:Difference between Actual and Projected Change in GrowthRates, 1991-95 to 1996-99 Premium Country -2.04 Argentina Bolivia 0.36 Premium Country Honduras Nicaragua0.99 0.01 Paraguay -3.12 Brazil -2.08 Chile -2.54 Colombia 1.27 Costa Rica 0.30 Ecuador El Salvador -2.79 Mean -1.20 Median -1.30 -1.61 1.59 Mexico Peru Uruguay -1.75 -0.94 Venezuela -3.86 William Easterly, Norbert Fiess, and Daniel Lederman 47 we per ity and verify that the size of this premium is unique toMexico, the change in growth rates between form the same exercise of explaining countries (see table 9). 1991-95 and 1996-99 for fifteen Latin American Mexico has the largest growth premium of all the countries in the sample, only by Costa Rica. Sixty percent of the countries had negative growth residuals, with the typical country in the region having an shortfall in the growth rate of more than one percentage point. unexplained followed closely Granted, this evidence circumstantial. Given on the beneficial the little itmay be the most event, however, impact of NAFTA time available for judging telling macroeconomic is indirect, or such a large evidence at our disposal. Fiess, and Lederman present the following Easterly, are between scheme, (i) There the United per capita income differentials on States and Mexico, its Mexican (ii) NAFTA, impact through positive a should of income, convergence per capita (iii) The generate growth, Patricio Meiler: authors test the existence of convergence income differentials Mexico's per capita those of selected Latin American To accelerate the evolution of by comparing vis-?-vis the United States with countries; Mexican little difference is found, (iv) Mexican convergence, they suggest improving the paper also addresses a quite different (v) Finally, on regions within Mexico. the differential effect of NAFTA institutions, issue, namely, in the title its main problem: the "big events, lit The paper recognizes tle time" effect. Can a long-run phenomenon like income convergence an to event like NAFTA, which has so far really be measured with regard had only a marginal impact? In a nutshell, a free trade negotiation implies are divided the following. Goods to the into three categories according zero: at to tar which its will be reduced the fast tariffs whose group, speed iffs are reduced to zero at the time of the signature of the free trade agree in which the medium-speed tariffs are reduced to zero category, ment; over three to four years; years. The fast category takes more than four set, which a marketing it includes ploy, because and the slow is really not much can those goods that already have a zero tariff. Consequently, in first three The the dataset in used the years. paper covers only happen three years after NAFTA was signed. Breaking the annual data into quar ters increases span. The the number of observations, but it cannot increase the time to trying to measure the economic task of the paper is equivalent 48 ECONOM?A,Fall2003 of America in Spain prior to the year 1500. The impact of the discovery a long-run phenomenon time period is simply too short to measure like convergence. A more to involves the paper's reference suggestion could test their methodology with the Puerto to check Rican case, that is, they could use the first five years (1960-1965) the income convergence forecast forty years later. In the first five years of Puerto Rico. the Puerto respect constructive The Rico to the U.S. omy forty years to the data, even as the United authors the per capita income differential (with experience, income level) went from 0.30 to 0.36. It took the econ to reach half the U.S. though Puerto Rico States. per capita income level, according had the same institutional framework NAFTA constitutes the paper's main explanatory factor, yet the authors do not use a trade theoretical framework. The theoretical framework usu the ally used to link trade and the labor market is the Stolper-Samuelson orem. A key mechanism on is the for explaining the trade effect wages behavior of prices. There are several papers examining the U.S.-Mexican evolution of wage differential during the 1990s; there is no comparison in this the empirical results of this literature with the results obtained paper. The empirical methodology used in the paper is the so-called dynamic that econometric data for many is, convergence, regressions combining countries. Income per capita is the left-hand-side variable, and on the right-hand side appear all sorts of ad hoc and arbitrary variables; there is no limit to the number of variables included, and the empirical measure ment of most of them is highly questionable. This has become a standard in the literature, but I have serious doubts that this type of procedure research generates anything useful. Institutions, for example, have become a key explanatory how variable today, yet I have problems understanding on not and it is clear the right-hand side of the regressions, they appear how they are measured. important trade-related in the issue involves Mexico's competition own that Chinese exports com U.S. market. In my research, I have found pete with Mexican exports in the U.S. market. How does this fact influence An the Mexican-U.S. convergence? NAFTA What FTA with the so-called certainly tequila crisis. helped Mexico to Mexico in 1994 if there had not been a would have happened agreement? Perhaps Mexico would have followed a path similar to William Easterly, Norbert Fiess, and Daniel Lederman 49 the external crisis of 1982. The macroeconomic that following stability of to the Mexican main contribution the 1990s may represent NAFTA's economy. in the paper. On the one hand, institu Finally, there is an inconsistency the main explanatory factor of why Mexico tions are considered has not achieved faster convergence with the United States. On the other hand, the reveals that some regions have convergence analysis of regional Mexican a than others. However, all regions have the same had higher convergence type of (Mexican) institutions. rates? convergence How, then, could some regions have higher 50 ECONOM?A,Fall2003 References Acemoglu, Daron, Simon Johnson, and James A. Robinson. 2001. "The Colonial Origins of Comparative Development: An Empirical Investigation." American Economic Review 91(5): 1369-401. Acemoglu, Daron, and Fabrizio Zilibotti. 2001. "Productivity Differences." Quar terly Journal of Economics 116(2): 563-606. Arellano, Manuel, and Stephen Bond. 1991. "Some Tests of Specification for Panel Data: Monte Carlo Evidence and an Application to Employment Equa tions." Review of Economic Studies 58(2): 277-97. Barro, Robert J. 1991. "Economic Growth in a Cross Section of Countries." Quar terly Journal of Economics 106(2): 407-44. Barro, J., and Xavier Robert Sala-i-Martin. 1995. Economic Growth. McGraw Hill. Bartelsman, Eric J., Randy A. Becker, and Wayne B. Gray. 2000. "NBER-CES Industry Database." Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Manufacturing Research. Economic Mimeographed. 1999. "Measuring Business Cycles: Baxter, Marianne, and Robert G. King. Approximate Band-Pass Filters for Economic Time Series." Review of Eco nomics and Statistics 81(4): 575-93. Ben-David, -. 1996. Dan. International "Trade Economics 2001. "Trade and Convergence 279-98. and Liberalization Journal of International Economics Andrew Bernard, -. Countries." Journal Income A Convergence: Comment." 1995. in International "Convergence 10(2): 97-108. Output." Journal of Applied Econometrics 1996. "Interpreting Tests of the Convergence Hypothesis." Econometrics 71(1-2): 161-73. Andrew Bernard, and Charles B., Economic Journal Caves, Douglas W., 106(437): Laurits of 55(1): 229-34. N. Durlauf. and Steven B., among 40(3-4): I. Jones. 1996. Journal of and Convergence." "Technology 1037-44. R. Christensen, and W. Erwin 1982. Diewert. lateral Comparisons of Output, Input, and Productivity Index Numbers." Economic Journal 92(365): 73-86. Using "Multi Superlative Ciccone, Antonio, and Robert E. Hall. 1996. "Productivity and theDensity of Eco nomic Activity." American Economic Review 86(1): 54-70. Dollar, David, and Aart Kraay. 2003. "Institutions, Trade, and Growth: Revisiting the Evidence." Policy research working paper 3004. Washington: World Bank. Doppelhofer, Gernot, Ronald I. Mille, and Xavier Sala-i-Martin. 2000. "Determi nants of Long-Term Growth: A Bayesian Averaging of Classical Estimates Approach (BACE)." Working paper 7750. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research. William Easterly, Norbert Fiess, and Daniel Lederman Easterly, William, and Ross Levine. 2001. "It's Not Factor Accumulation: ized Facts and Growth Models." World Bank Economic Review 51 Styl 15(2): 177-220. -. 2003. nomic Eaton, Journal Development." Jonathan, Theory 2002. How Crops: of Monetary 1999. "International Economic International Influence Eco 3-39. 50(1): Technology Review 40(3): Diffusion: 537-70. and Trade." Econometrica Geography, "Technology, Endowments Economics Kortum. and Samuel and Measurement." -. and Germs, "Tropics, 70(5): 1741-80. 1999. "Convergencia regional en M?xico, 1940-1995." Esquivel, Gerardo. Trimestre Econ?mico 66(264): 725-61. Esquivel, Gerardo, and others. 2002. "Why NAFTA Did Not Reach the South." Washington: World Bank, Office of the Chief Economist for Latin America and the Caribbean. Mimeographed. Frankel, Jeffrey, and David Romer. 1999. "Does Trade Cause Growth?" Ameri can Economic Review 89(3): 379-99. Paul R. Krugman, and Anthony Fujita, Masahisa, Cities, Economy, and Regions International J. Venables. Trade. MIT 1999. The Spatial Press. Furman, Jeffrey L., Michael E. Porter, and Scott Stern. 2002. "The Determinants of National Innovative Capacity." Research Policy 31(6): 899-933. Fuss, Catherine. 1999. "Convergence among Industrialized Countries: A Time Series Investigation." Brussels: National Bank of Belgium. Grossman, Gene and Elhanan M., 1991. Helpman. Innovation and Growth in the Global Economy. MIT Press. Hall, Robert, and Charles I. Jones. 1999. "Why Do Some Countries Produce So Much More Output perWorker thanOthers?" Quarterly Journal of Economics 114(1): 83-116. Harvey, Andrew of Economic C. 2002. "Trends, edited Growth, Cycles by Norman In The Challenges and Convergence." and Raimundo Soto. Santiago: Loayza Central Bank of Chile. Harvey, Andrew and V. C, mies." University Harvey, Andrew C, Series Models." edited by C. Heij Carvalho. 2002. "Models for Converging Econo of Cambridge. Mimeographed. and Siam J. Koopman. 1997. "Multivariate Structural Time In System Dynamics in Economic and Financial Models, and others, 269-98. Chichester: Wiley and Sons. Filters for Harvey, Andrew C, and T. Trimbur. 2001. "General Model-Based Extracting Cycles and Trends in Economic Time Series." Discussion paper 0113. University of Cambridge, Department of Applied Economics. Kaufman, Daniel, and Aart cators for 2000-01." Bank. Kraay. 2002a. "Governance Matters II: Updated Indi Policy research working paper 2772. Washington: World 52 ECONOM?A,Fall2003 -. 2002b. "Growth without Governance." World Washington: Bank Insti tute. Mimeographed. 2001. "International Technology Diffusion." Working Keller, Wolfgang. 8573. Cambridge, Mass.: National Bureau of Economic Research. -. 2002. "Geographic Localization of International Technology American Economic Review 92(1): 120^42. paper Diffusion." Krugman, Paul R. 1991. Geography and Trade. MIT Press. Lederman, Daniel, Norman Loayza, and Rodrigo Soares. 2002. "Accountability and Corruption: Political Institutions Matter." Washington: World Bank, Office of the Chief Economist for Latin America and the Caribbean. Mimeographed. Lederman, -. F. Maloney. and William Daniel, 2003a. "Innovation in Mexico: NAFTA Is Not Enough." Washington: World Bank, Office of the Chief Econ omist for Latin America and the Caribbean. Mimeographed. 2003b. "R&D and Development." Washington: World Bank, Office of the Chief Economist for Latin America and the Caribbean. Mimeographed. Lederman, Daniel, William F. Maloney, and Luis Serven. 2003. "Lessons from NAFTA." Washington: World Bank. Mimeographed. Lederman, Daniel, and others. 2003. "The Recovery of Mexican Investment after the Tequila Crisis: Basic Economics, Confidence Effects or Market Imperfec tions?" Journal of International Money and Finance 22(1): 131-51. Pablo Fajnzylber, Norman, Loayza, in Latin Growth America and 2002. and C?sar Calder?n. the Caribbean: Stylized Facts, "Economic and Explanations, for Latin Forecasts." Washington: World Bank, Office of the Chief Economist and America the Caribbean. J. Ernesto. L?pez-C?rdova, ductivity: An Empirical Inter-American Lucas, 1988. "On "NAFTA Bank. y otras Manufacturing reformas Pro Data." Washington: Mimeographed. the Mechanics ofMonetary Economics 22(1): 3-42. Messmacher, Miguel. 2000. "Desigualdad TLCAN and Mexico's Investigation Using Micro-Level Development M. Robert Mimeographed. 2002. estructurales." of Economic regional en M?xico. Research Journal Development." working El efecto del paper 2000-4. City: Bank of Mexico. Meza, Liliana, and Ana Bel?n Mora. 2002. "Why Mexican Firms Invest inR&D." Washington: World Bank, Office of the Chief Economist for Latin America and the Caribbean. Mimeographed. Mexico Parente, Stephen L., and Edward C. Prescott. 2000. Barriers to Riches. MIT Press. Persson, Torsten. 2002. "Do Political Institutions Shape Economic Policy?" Econometrica 70(3): 883-906. Pritchett, Lant. 1997. "Divergence, Big Time." Journal of Economic Perspectives 11(3): 3-17. William Easterly, Norbert Fiess, and Daniel Lederman 53 Redding, Stephen, and Anthony Venables. 2001. "Economic Geography and International Inequality." Discussion paper 495. London School of Economics, Center Romer, Performance. for Economic Paul. 1986. "Increasing -. 1990. Returns and Long-Run Growth." of Polit Journal 1002-37. ical Economy 94(5): "Endogenous Journal Change." Technological Econ of Political omy 98(5): S71-102. Sachs, Jeffrey and Andrew D., Warner. "Economic 1995. Reform and the Process of Global Integration." Brookings Papers on Economic Activity 7(1995): 1-95. Sala-i-Martin, Xavier. 1996. "The Classical Approach to Convergence Analysis." Economic Journal 106 (July): 1019-36. Schiff, Maurice, and Yanling Wang. 2002. "Regional Integration and Trade Related Technology Diffusion: The Case of NAFTA." Washington: World Bank, Office of the Chief Economist for Latin America and the Caribbean. Mimeographed. Slaughter, Matthew A vergence: J. 2001. "Trade Liberalization Difference-in-Differences Analysis." and per Capita Income Con Journal of International 55(1): 203-28. Solow, Robert M. 1956. "A Contribution to the Theory of Economic Quarterly Journal of Economics 70(1): 65-94. Economics Summers, Robert, and Sultan Ahmad. 1974. "Better Estimates Growth." of Dollar Gross Domestic Product for 101 Countries: Exchange Rate Bias Eliminated." Dis cussion paper 297. University of Pennsylvania. World Bank. 2003. World Development Indicators. Washington.