BRIEFING PAPER Number 7177, 14 May 2015 Transport 2015 By Louise Butcher Alex Meakin, Tom Rutherford Inside: 1. Introduction 2. 2015 election manifesto commitments 3. Policy focus 1: devolution 4. Policy focus 2: local bus services 5. Policy focus 3: rail franchising 6. Policy focus 4: cycling 7. Policy focus 5: airport expansion 8. Statistical Appendix: transport trends since 2010 www.parliament.uk/commons-library | intranet.parliament.uk/commons-library | papers@parliament.uk | @commonslibrary Number 7177, 13 May 2015 Contents Summary 5 1. Introduction 6 2. 2015 election manifesto commitments Conservative Party Green Party Labour Party Liberal Democrats Plaid Cymru Scottish National Party (SNP) UK Independence Party (UKIP) 9 9 10 12 13 16 17 17 3. 3.1 Policy focus 1: devolution What’s the issue? Scotland and Wales largely devolved Northern Ireland has its own transport powers The English regions want more control over transport The EU and other global players take an increasing number of decisions Why devolve transport policy? Local accountability The ‘North/South divide’ Where are we with devolution of transport policy? Scotland Wales England What about funding? Barnett Central Government Raising money locally What might devolved transport policy and planning look like in England? Issues for the 2015 Parliament What kind of devolution are we going to get? Does devolution create cross-border transport problems? Is devolution irreversible? Is the EU ‘a problem’? 19 19 19 20 21 23 24 24 25 26 26 26 27 28 28 29 30 31 33 33 34 34 35 Policy focus 2: local bus services What’s the issue? Local bus travel is in long term decline Buses are overlooked in policy-making Bus travel is expensive Deregulation has been a failure What is deregulation and why was it introduced? What did the bus market look like before the 1980s? White Paper on buses, 1984 Legislation Minor subsequent changes by the Conservative Government -1997 38 38 38 38 40 41 42 42 43 45 45 3.2 3.3 3.4 3.5 3.6 4. 4.1 4.2 Contributing Authors: Louise Butcher & Alex Meakin, Transport Policy Tom Rutherford, Transport Statistics Cover page image copyright: Westminster Bridge by Joe Dunkley. Licensed under CC BY 2.0 2 3 Transport 2015 4.3 4.4 4.5 4.6 4.7 5. 5.1 5.2 5.3 5.4 5.5 5.6 6. 6.1 6.2 6.3 The exception: London Sale of municipal bus companies What happened after deregulation? Service levels and costs Labour’s changes Why do people think deregulation is broken? A free market, not a public service Lack of on-the-road competition Subsidies Who supports deregulation and why? What is the alternative? Quality Contract Schemes Partnership schemes What powers would the metropolitan areas outside London like to have? Issues for the 2015 Parliament Why are bus routes being cut? Is bus funding fit for purpose? Would regulation improve services and cut costs? What do we do about the bus pass in England? 46 49 49 49 51 52 52 53 53 55 56 57 59 60 61 61 63 64 66 Policy focus 3: rail franchising What’s the issue? Rail travel is expensive Privatisation has been a failure What is privatisation and why was it introduced? What did the rail market look like before the 1990s? Policy decision by the Conservative Government Railways Act 1993 What happened after privatisation? Service levels and costs Railtrack A lack of continuity West Coast re-let 2012 Who supports privatisation and why? What are the alternatives? Nationalisation Public sector franchisees More privatisation and ‘proper’ competition Issues for the 2015 Parliament Why is rail travel so expensive? Are the rail management and governance structures fit for purpose? Why are there so many ‘Direct Awards’? Can anyone ‘guarantee’ a public sector operator under the current system? Should franchising be devolved? Do EU rules prevent nationalisation? 69 69 69 70 72 72 74 76 76 78 78 80 83 85 86 87 90 92 94 94 96 99 100 101 104 Policy focus 4: cycling What’s the issue? Cycling is on the increase Government is keen to encourage more cycling There are too many barriers to cycling What has happened since 2010? Fatalities External pressure driving cycling up the political agenda Funding has increased What do cyclists want? Safer cycling infrastructure 107 107 107 107 109 110 110 111 113 114 114 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 6.4 6.5 7. 7.1 7.2 7.3 7.4 7.5 8. Reformed ‘rules of the road’ What about other road users? Pedestrians Motorists HGVs and buses Issues for the 2015 Parliament Will cycling remain a political priority? Should government provide more funding? Is cycling just a London issue? Should local authorities have cycling targets? 115 116 116 117 119 120 120 120 121 124 Policy focus 5: airport expansion What’s the issue? The UK needs more airport capacity The local noise impacts of aviation are significant What is the Airports Commission? Why was it set up? What has it done? When will it report? Will the recommendations of the Airports Commission be implemented? Political parties not committed Parliament has a limited role Onus is on the airports to put in application for a DCO Local opposition What else has happened since 2010? LHR had a plan ready to go in 2010 and withdrew it Air Passenger Duty Airspace change Airport failures, closures and nationalisations Issues for the 2015 Parliament What is the role of the National Policy Statement for aviation? How much is a new runway in the South East likely to cost the taxpayer? Is new runway capacity compatible with environmental commitments? How do we support regional connectivity? 126 126 126 129 132 132 133 138 138 138 139 139 139 140 140 141 143 145 146 146 147 148 150 Statistical Appendix: transport trends since 2010 Overall Modal share Transport Expenditure Aviation Road Traffic Vehicle registrations Driving Licences Concessionary Travel Road Accidents Trams and Light Rail Rail Performance Conclusions 152 152 153 153 154 157 157 158 158 160 161 162 4 5 Transport 2015 Summary The political profile of transport as a policy area has increased since 2010, in large part due to the coincidence of decisions (taken or still being discussed) on a number of big infrastructure projects. These included High Speed 2; the ongoing lack of a decision over a new airport runway in the South East of England; the ‘London 2012’ effect on cycling; and the knock-on impacts of cuts to central and local government budgets, particularly affecting local transport such as buses. In 2010 there was broad agreement across the main parties on many aspects of transport policy. Only on airport expansion did views diverge significantly. Going into the 2015 election, however, manifesto commitments were much more diverse, particularly as regards the involvement of the state (in one guise or another) in running public transport. Labour and the Greens (especially) both supported more public ownership and operation of buses and trains than did the Conservatives, UKIP and the Liberal Democrats. While all parties agreed that more transport powers should be exercised ‘closer to the passenger/commuter/individual’ there was no real consensus on whether revenue raising powers should be devolved at the same time. Also of more public interest in this election has been the prominence of the nationalist parties in Scotland and Wales. Likely transport changes in those countries were largely set out by the Smith and Silk commissions respectively, before the election, though the SNP may push for further devolution now they have a sizeable Commons presence. This paper provides an overview of the transport commitments given by the main political parties in the run up to the 2015 General Election; a broad summary of transport trends over the course of the 2010 Parliament; and looks at some of the possible transport ‘hot spots’ post-2015, specifically devolution; local bus services; cycling provision; rail franchising; and airport expansion. The big decisions facing the new Conservative Government are about whether and where to make further spending cuts; whether to give the go ahead to transport schemes such as Crossrail 2 and High Speed 3; how to keep costs down for bus and rail passengers; how to ensure that train services improve; and whether to approve any planning application for a new or extended runway at Heathrow or Gatwick. It will also have to honour commitments made prior to the election about devolving more power to Scotland and Wales and deal with the ‘English question’ insofar as it relates to the devolution of transport powers and budgets. Finally, it will have to have an eye to the long term – on healthy, liveable cities and sustainable, green transport including automated and carbon-free private cars. Their policies may even have to reach much, much further than that. If entrepreneurs like Sir Richard Branson and Elon Musk have their way, human commercial spaceflight might not be as far off as we imagine, and perhaps we might all one day be sharing Musk’s vision of a rocket re-fuelling station on Mars… Number 7177, 13 May 2015 1. Introduction The 2010 General Election resulted in a Conservative-Liberal Democrat Coalition Government, the first time the UK had been governed by a formal coalition for over fifty years. Following Conservative leader David Cameron’s “big open and comprehensive offer” to the Liberal Democrats in May 2010 the Conservatives and the Liberal Democrats went into government together.1 The foundation of that government was the Coalition Agreement, drawn up in May 2010 following the post-election negotiations.2 It set out the two parties’ joint ambitions for government and in most areas represented a compromise between the commitments made in the two parties’ manifestos for that election.3 Overall patterns of travel and transport usage have not changed significantly over the past five years. The long-term trend for the overall distance travelled within the UK to rise continually was reversed during and immediately after the 2008-09 recession, but the overall pattern since then has been of a return toward previous levels of travel. Car travel remains by far the dominant mode of transport within the UK, although trends in rail use and cycling have been increasing at a significant rate. The defining characteristic of the 2010 Parliament was the Government’s policy to reduce public debt and borrowing, which had soared following the financial crisis. The Department for Transport (DfT) saw its budget cut by 17.7% between 2010 and 2015; but at the same time, capital spending on transport infrastructure projects increased from £7.7bn in 2010/11 to £10.1bn in 2015/16 – a 31% increase.4 At the time of the publication of the first National Infrastructure Plan in October 2010 the Chancellor of the Exchequer, George Osborne, explained his decision to spend on infrastructure: Tackling this budget deficit is unavoidable. The decisions about how we do it are not. There are choices, and today we make them. Investment in the future, rather than the bills of past failure: that is our choice. We have chosen to spend on the country's most important priorities: the health care of our people; the education of our young; our nation's security; and the infrastructure that supports our economic growth. We have chosen to cut the waste and reform the welfare system that our country can no longer afford.5 Unlike previous administrations, the Coalition Government showed little enthusiasm for ‘integrated transport strategy’ policy making, preferring instead locally decided initiatives to deliver improvements. “Election: Cameron makes offer to Lib Dems on government”, BBC Election 2010, 7 May 2010; “David Cameron and Nick Clegg pledge 'united' coalition”, BBC Election 2010, 12 May 2010 2 HMG, The Coalition: our programme for government, May 2010 3 for more information on this see section 1 of HC Library research paper RP 11/22, 2 March 2011 4 HMT, Public Expenditure Statistical Analysis 2014 (PESA), Table 5.4 5 HC Deb 20 October 2010, c949; the NIPs for 2010-2014 can be found on the Gov.uk archived website 1 6 7 Transport 2015 Minister after minister was pressed on the question of ‘joined up’ multi-modal policy making in appearances before the Commons Transport Select Committee over the course of the Parliament and the Department was issued with a number of recommendations urging it to look at a more integrated or joined-up strategy. In response to one early recommendation in this vein in early 2011 the DfT responded: The Department has set out its objectives for transport spending in the Business Plan. The Department's vision is for a transport system that is an engine for economic growth but is also greener and safer and improves quality of life in our communities. The Business Plan clearly sets out how we are going to deliver this, including the development of a new highspeed railway, tackling carbon and congestion on the UK's roads and promoting sustainable aviation. […] In respect of local schemes, communities should be free to decide what their priorities are and will be able to set their budgets according to local - not national - priorities. For example, the move from twenty six grant streams to just four maximises local flexibility and minimises bureaucracy. The Government believes that this is the most effective way to increase the sustainability of local transport systems.6 In response to a July 2014 recommendation the Department said: We recognise that getting the most out of this significant investment means making the whole system work as well as it can. However, we need to be realistic about the best way of integrating transport planning and decision-making on investment and delivery. Previous top-down attempts at integrated, multi-modal transport planning have been big on rhetoric, but in practice have failed to improve or speed up the planning and delivery of real improvements for transport users. Bottom up approaches have often descended into huge multimodal studies, consuming large amounts of time and resources, producing vast quantities of analysis but rarely delivering commensurate or timely improvements in infrastructure or transport outcomes. We also need to be realistic about the extent to which different modes can provide genuine, sensible and proportionate alternatives to solving specific transport problems, where the best solutions may depend on the local circumstances, including the location of existing transport networks and the extent to which journeys can switch between modes. In many cases, individual projects have demonstrated the potential for effective integration between national and local transport networks where decisions are taken in a joined-up way.7 One could argue that there is less of a need for a comprehensive strategy in a more fragmented governmental environment: extensive transport powers are devolved to Scotland, Wales and Northern Ireland, London and the major English cities and all levels of local Government response to the Committee’s Third Report of Session 2010–12 (Fourth Special Report of Session 2010–12), HC 962, 6 May 2011, pp4-5 7 Government Response to the Committee's Fifteenth Report of Session 2013–14 (Fourth Special Report of Session 2014–15), HC 715, 24 October 2014, p6 6 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 government. At the other end of the spectrum, transport is one of the policy areas where the European Union (EU) and other transnational bodies have a great deal of influence on national law and its application. This is examined in more detail in section 3, below. A further, noteworthy trend over the 2010 Parliament was not transport-specific, rather it was the growth in social and other electronic media and portable electronic devices that enable people – from constituents to commentators – to scrutinise the work of government in far more detail than has been possible in the past. Government has largely embraced these trends and the connected issue of how it can use the data generated by social media to inform its policy decisions.8 This paper provides a high-level overview of transport trends over the 2010 Parliament and picks out five policy areas which are likely to be particularly prominent during the 2015 Parliament. These are: devolution, local bus services, rail franchising, cycling and airport expansion. By only choosing five areas there are of necessity some important transport issues that are not considered; these are covered in other briefings available on the Transport Topic pages of the Parliament website. One of these is HS2, the controversial high speed rail project between London and the north of England, via the West Midlands. This is covered in detail in a number of HC Library briefings available on the Railways Topic page of the Parliament website. It was not included in this paper because although it remains contentious outside Parliament there is a broad consensus in its favour across the two main parties, as well as amongst the SNP and the Liberal Democrats. 8 “Social media presents a growing body of evidence that can inform social and economic policy”, LSE blog, 2 October 2013 8 9 Transport 2015 2. 2015 election manifesto commitments The election manifestos of the seven main parties standing in Great Britain at the 2015 General Election were published between 13 and 20 April. The transport commitments contained in those documents are set out below, by party, in alphabetical order. Where the Conservative and Labour parties published more detailed policy announcements in the areas discussed in the rest of this paper, these are discussed therein. Conservative Party The Conservative manifesto, Strong Leadership, A Clear Economic Plan, A Brighter More Secure Future, included the following commitments:9 By connecting up the North with modern transport links, we will enable its great cities and towns to pool their strengths. We will invest a record £13 billion in transport for the North. We will electrify the main rail routes, build the Northern Hub, and provide new trains for the North. We will upgrade the A1, M62, M1 and A555 link road. And that is on top of our £50 billion commitment to build High Speed 2 – the new North-South railway linking up London with the West Midlands, Leeds and Manchester – and develop High Speed 3 to join up the North. [p11] To help attract growth and new businesses we will improve connections to the South West with major investment in the M5, A358, A30 and A303, and the electrification of the Great Western Main Line – bringing new fast trains on the route. [p11] We will make the Midlands an engine of growth. We will back business by investing a record £5.2 billion in better transport, upgrading the M1 and M6, and electrifying the Midland Main Line from St Pancras to Sheffield – putting the Midlands at the centre of a modern, inter-connected transport network for the UK. [p13] We will improve rail connections to East Anglia, delivering ‘Norwich in 90 minutes’ and ‘Ipswich in 60 minutes’ and upgrade key roads like the A11 and A47. [p13] We will devolve far-reaching powers over economic development, transport and social care to large cities which choose to have elected mayors. [p13] We will deliver on our National Infrastructure Plan and respond to the Airports Commission’s final report. [p14] We will invest £38 billion in our railway network in the five years to 2019. Electrification of the railways is a key part of our investment programme, with work already underway across the North, the Midlands, and South Wales; there are plans to go further in the rest of the country, including East Anglia and the South West. [p14] 9 Conservative Party, Strong Leadership, A Clear Economic Plan, A Brighter More Secure Future: The Conservative Party Manifesto 2015, 14 April 2015; emphasis added Number 7177, 13 May 2015 10 In addition to rolling out our national high-speed rail network, with High Speed 2 and High Speed 3, we will complete the construction of the new east-west Crossrail across Greater London, and push forward with plans for Crossrail 2, a new rail route running through London and connecting Surrey and Hertfordshire. [p14] We will support a fairer deal for taxpayers and commuters: we will keep commuter rail fares frozen in real terms for the whole of the next Parliament – regulated fares will only be able to rise by Retail Price Inflation, and train operating companies will not have any flexibility to raise ticket prices above this. We will also introduce smart ticketing and part-time season tickets and require train companies to improve compensation arrangements for passengers when trains are more than a few minutes late. [pp14-15] We will invest £15 billion in roads. This will include over £6 billion in the northern road network, with the dualling and widening of the A1 north of Newcastle and the first new transPennine road capacity in over 40 years. We will take action to tackle some of the most notorious and longstanding problems on our road network, including improvements to the A303, A47 and A27. We will add 1,300 extra lane miles to our roads, improve over 60 problem junctions, and continue to provide enough funding to fix around 18 million potholes nationwide between 2015 and 2021. [p15] Our aim is for almost every car and van to be a zero emission vehicle by 2050 – and we will invest £500 million over the next five years to achieve it. [p15] We want to double the number of journeys made by bicycle and will invest over £200 million to make cycling safer, so we reduce the number of cyclists and other road users killed or injured on our roads every year. [p15] We will continue to support local shops and residents in tackling aggressive parking enforcement and excessive parking charges, and take steps to tackle rogue and unfair practices by private parking operators. [p53] We will build new roads and railways in a way that limits, as far as possible, their impact on the environment. This includes investing £300 million in cutting light pollution from new roads, doing more tunnelling, building better noise barriers and helping to restore lost habitat. We will also replace locally any biodiversity lost in the construction of High Speed 2. [p55] We will maintain all the current pensioner benefits including … free bus passes … for the next Parliament. [p67] We will clarify the division of powers between Wales and the UK Government. We will: … implement other recommendations of the second Silk Report where there is all-party support as set out in the St David’s Day Agreement; this will include devolving to the Welsh Assembly important economic powers over ports. [p70] Green Party The Green manifesto, For the Common Good, included the following commitments:10 10 Green Party, For the Common Good: General Election Manifesto 2015, 14 April 2015; emphasis added 11 Transport 2015 Extend free local public transport to young people and students, spending up to £4 billion a year. [p28] Keep the pensioners’ bus pass. [p30] Support 20 mph zones, cycle schemes and public transport to make our streets safe and useful for older as well as young people [p30] Reintroduce the fuel duty escalator, raising £2.2 billion in 2015 and an additional £2.2 billion in each successive year through the Parliament. [p52] Put aviation on a level playing field with other modes of transport by making it subject to fuel duty and VAT, raising £16 billion in a full year. If outdated international law makes this impossible, introduce a flight tax dependent on distance and aircraft type that has the same overall economic effect. [p52] Allow local authorities to run local public transport … entirely as they wish, including using publicly owned and run services and employing social enterprise and voluntary sector organisations. [p59] The Green Party is committed to bringing rail services into public ownership and control … making them belong to you and me, run by rail workers for passengers. [p64] We would not support HS2 (the proposed high-speed network). The money to be spent on this hugely expensive project … would be much better spent on improving conventional rail connections between various major cities, improving the resilience of the existing network to climate change and reopening lines and stations that have been closed. [p65] End the wasteful and destructive national major roads programme, saving £15 billion over the Parliament [and spend it on] improving and subsidising public transport, with an average fare reduction of 10% costing £8 billion over the Parliament, fixing potholes in existing roads and investing in walking and cycling. [p65] Support walking and cycling. In particular, we would ensure that pedestrians and cyclists get their fair share of road space and would spend at least £30 per head on them every year over the Parliament. [p65] Support the re-regulation of bus services to provide a better, more reliable service. [p65] Stop airport expansion, in particular no new runways at either Heathrow or Gatwick, and ban night flying. [p65] Invest in electric vehicle charging points for buses and taxis, and for cars where there are gaps in the network of public and community transport. [p65] Develop regional smart payment systems with integrated ticketing, like the London Oyster system. [p65] Work for a road transport system that results in zero deaths or serious injuries by systematically reducing sources of danger on the roads … enforce speed limits with speed cameras and policing … Motor vehicle drivers should be presumed liable for injuries to pedestrians and cyclists … Reduce the alcohol limit for drivers to as close to zero as possible. Require newly manufactured lorries to be equipped with best practice technology to make sure that drivers are fully aware of the Number 7177, 13 May 2015 12 presence of all pedestrians and cyclists … Reduce lorry activity and road freight volume by improving rail freight services, reducing the number of empty or partially loaded trips, and using cargo bikes for last minute deliveries to replace some white van trips. [p66] We need to rescue our towns and cities from traffic and turn them back into places where we want to be. The Green Party support and Active Travel Bill for England in order to achieve this … Help schools and workplaces to support active travel to and from work, and encourage local authorities to assist this by linking their public health and transport functions … introduce road pricing schemes such as the London congestion charge and road-user tolls for heavy lorries. Begin consultation with a view to developing a framework for the progressive elimination of diesel exhaust emissions … Introduce Ultra Low Emission Zones … Reduce parking spaces in new developments … Eliminate pavement parking …Provide cycle parking throughout towns and cities at locations where there is demand and invest in on-street secure cycle storage is residential streets. [p66] Make sure that rural areas are not neglected when transport budgets and planning for our cities and city regions are under discussion. Develop networks of community and public transport to provide regular links to onward transport networks. Introduce speed limits of 20 mph in villages and 40 mph on rural roads. [p67] Labour Party The Labour manifesto, Britain can be better, included the following commitments:11 Nor will we raise VAT, and we renew our pledge not to extend it to … public transport fares. [p18] We will continue to support the construction of High Speed Two, but keep costs down, and take action to improve and expand rail links across the North to boost its regional economies. We will support long-term investment in strategic roads, address the neglect of local roads, and promote cycling. [p19]12 Following the Davies Review, we will make a swift decision on expanding airport capacity in London and the South East, balancing the need for growth and the environmental impact. [p19] Labour will reform our transport system in order to provide more public control and put the public interest first. We will review the franchising process as a priority to put in place a new system and avoid a repeat of the Conservatives’ franchising fiasco. A new National Rail body will oversee and plan for the railways and give rail users a greater say in how trains operate. We will legislate so that a public sector operator is allowed to take on lines and challenge the private train operating companies on a level playing field. [p26] 11 Labour Party, Britain can be better: The Labour Party Manifesto 2015, 13 April 2015; emphasis added 12 the figures involved are reportedly an extra £89 million for cycling and walking and £300million to fix an additional six million potholes to be funded by delaying upgrades to the A27 and the A358 [see also below] and an additional £89 million for local active travel projects and infrastructure schemes [“Labour Party makes £300m General Election pledge to end Britain’s ‘pothole crisis’”, The Mirror, 20 April 2015] 13 Transport 2015 Rail fares will be frozen next year to help commuters while we implement reforms. A strict fare rise cap will be introduced on every route for any future fare rises, and a new legal right for passengers will be created to access the cheapest ticket for their journey. [p26]13 City and county regions will be given more power over the way buses are operated in their area. They will be able to decide routes, bear down on fares, drive improvements in services, and bring together trains, buses and trams into a single network with smart ticketing. [p26] … there will be no … changes to … bus passes for pensioners. [p49] We will embark on the biggest devolution of power to our English city and county regions in a hundred years with an English Devolution Act … This will include control over local transport systems so that in future, local bodies can integrate trains, buses, trams and cycling into a single network. [p64] We will take forward proposals from the Silk Commission to extend the power the people of Wales have over their elections, transport and energy. [p66] Liberal Democrats The Liberal Democrat manifesto, Stronger Economy. Fairer Society. Opportunity for Everyone., included the following commitments:14 Devolve more economic decision-making to local areas, building on the success of City Deals and Growth Deals, prioritising the transfer of transport, housing and infrastructure funding, skills training and back-to-work support. [p26] Set out 10-year rolling capital investment plans [for transport]. [p30] Develop a comprehensive plan to electrify the overwhelming majority of the UK rail network, reopen smaller stations, restore twin-track lines to major routes and proceed with HS2, as the first stage of a high-speed rail network to Scotland. [p30] Invest in major transport improvements and infrastructure [including] the Transport for the North strategy to promote growth, innovation and prosperity across northern England … more modern, resilient links to and within the South West peninsula to help develop and diversify the regional economy … East-West rail, connecting up Oxford and Cambridge and … London’s transport infrastructure. [p30] Work to encourage further private sector investment in rail freight terminals and rail-connected distribution parks. We will set a clear objective to shift more freight from road to rail and change planning law to ensure new developments provide good freight access to retail, manufacturing and warehouse facilities. [p30] Ensure our airport infrastructure meets the needs of a modern and open economy, without allowing emissions from aviation to undermine our goal of a zero-carbon Britain by 2050. 13 this would reportedly be funded by delaying upgrades to the A27 and the A358 [“A27 and A358 road cash to fund rail fare freeze, Labour says”, BBC News, 13 April 2015] 14 Liberal Democrats, Manifesto 2015: Strong Economy. Fairer Society. Opportunity for Everyone., 15 April 2015; emphasis added Number 7177, 13 May 2015 14 We will carefully consider the conclusions of the Davies Review into runway capacity and develop a strategic airports policy for the whole of the UK in the light of those recommendations and advice from the Committee on Climate Change. We remain opposed to any expansion of Heathrow, Stansted or Gatwick and any new airport in the Thames Estuary, because of local issues of air and noise pollution. We will ensure no net increase in runways across the UK. [p31] Ensure new rail franchises include a stronger focus on customers, including requirements to integrate more effectively with other modes of transport and a programme of investment in new stations, lines and station facilities. [p31] We will continue the Access for All programme, improving disabled access to public transport. [p31] We will encourage Local Authorities to consider trams alongside other options, and support a new generation of light rail and ultra-light rail schemes in towns and cities where local people want them. [p31] We will retain the free bus pass for all pensioners. [p47] Ensure rail fares rise no faster than inflation over the Parliament as a whole. [p50] Work to introduce a new Young Person’s Discount Card, for young people aged 16–21, giving a 2/3rds discount on bus travel, as resources allow. [p61] Review access to transport for students and apprentices in rural areas where no scheduled services may be available. [p61] Pass a … Green Transport Act to cut air pollution [… to include] a statutory target of 2030 by which time all major, regularly used rail routes will need to be electrified … a requirement that every new bus and taxi is Ultra Low Emission from 2030 and every car on the road meets that standard by 2040 … the creation of Low Emission Zones as part of a national air quality plan, including a legal requirement for the most polluted towns and cities … a new statutory framework that all new rail franchises include a stronger focus on customers … [and] updates to roads regulation to promote innovation in transport like driverless cars and personal electric vehicles. [pp76&91] Our National Air Quality Plan for consultation will include: a legal requirement targeted at the most polluted towns and cities, to create Low Emission Zones; new incentives for local schemes that cut transport-related pollution, and encourage walking and cycling; a review of the MOT process, to see whether changes could be introduced to cut emissions from existing vehicles [and] support for new EU proposals on air quality targets. [p87] Support ambitious EU vehicle emission standards, and reform Vehicle Excise Duty to drive continuous reductions in greenhouse gas and other pollutants from the UK car fleet and return revenues to levels projected in 2010. This will include introducing separate banding for new diesel cars. [p87] Encourage the market for electric vehicles, including with targeted support for buses, taxis and light freight, and early requirements to use low emission vehicles in the public sector. We will set a target of 2040 for the date after which only Ultra- 15 Transport 2015 Low Emission vehicles will be permitted on UK roads for nonfreight purposes. [p87] Work with industry to accelerate the commercial introduction of zero emission fuel cell electric vehicles, and facilitate the UKwide introduction of hydrogen fuelling infrastructure. [p87] Review the best way to keep our regulatory framework updated to permit use of driverless and personal electric vehicles. [p87] Support options for an intercity cycleway along the HS2 route, within the overall budget for the project. [p87] Implement the recommendations of the Get Britain Cycling report, including steps to deliver a £10 a head annual public expenditure on cycling within existing budgets. [p88] Carry out a review of bus funding and bus policies and introduce a five-year investment plan to give the industry and Local Authorities certainty and help plan investment. We will support local areas that want to bring forward plans for regulating the bus network in their area. [p88] Give new powers to Local Authorities and communities to improve transport in their areas, including the ability to introduce network-wide ticketing like in London [and] support the expansion of smart ticketing systems. [p88] Continue funding for local economic and sustainable transport infrastructure through the Local Growth Fund. [p88] Help bus companies trade in older, more polluting buses and coaches for newer, low emissions ones, helping develop the market for low-carbon buses. [p88] Continue the fuel discount scheme for remote areas implemented by Liberal Democrat Ministers and work with the European Commission to extend it to further remote areas with high fuel costs. [p89] Work with Local Authorities to integrate transport networks in rural areas, building on the work of Liberal Democrat Ministers’ Total Transport pilot. [p89] Update planning law to introduce the concept of ‘landscape scale planning’ and ensure new developments promote walking, cycling, car sharing and public transport and improve rather than diminish access to green spaces. [p97] Make it easier to get around by: making more stations wheelchair accessible and giving wheelchair users priority over children’s buggies when space is limited … bringing into effect the provisions of the 2010 Equality Act on discrimination by private hire vehicles and taxis … improving the legislative framework governing Blue Badges … building on our successes in improving wheelchair access to improve accessibility of public transport for people with other disabilities, including visual and auditory impairment … [and] setting up a benchmarking standard for accessible cities. [p109] We will consider the work of the Government’s review on devolution of Air Passenger Duty (APD), with a view to devolving long-haul APD [to Wales] … [transfer] powers from the UK Parliament to the National Assembly over … transport … [devolve] funding of Network Rail in relation to the Wales network … [and] we will abolish the economically distorting tolls on the Severn Bridge once the debts are paid off. [p134] Number 7177, 13 May 2015 16 Plaid Cymru The Plaid manifesto, Working for Wales, included the following commitments:15 We will improve Welsh town centres by attracting people back to the high street, improving public transport. [p9] We support the public ownership of railways in which profits are reinvested into better services, and the transfer of powers over railways to Wales, including the transfer of full funding for railway infrastructure. We will work with Network Rail to deliver this. [p41] We support the electrification of railways in Wales, with the aim of all major lines being electrified by 2034 and will ensure electrification of the North Wales Main Line in the next Control Period [and] we will make best use of stock by increasing the number of services in diesel-operating areas so that there are more services in West Wales, mid-Wales and north Wales. [p41] We support a South Wales Metro around the Cardiff Capital Region, which will link with economically developing Valleys and coastal communities. [p41] … we will fund a feasibility study for re-opening former railway lines, particularly between Carmarthen and Aberystwyth and we will support the maintenance of the Cambrian Coast Line. [p41] The next franchise in Wales should include the introduction of a Welsh transport Smart Card compatible with other forms of transport. [p41] We support the ‘Blue Route’ M4 improvements. [p41] We will bring the Severn Bridges into Welsh public ownership, cutting the tolls and re-investing any profits into Welsh transport infrastructure. [p41] We will push for improvements to the A55, including the construction of a third Menai Bridge, and we will improve roads between north and south to improve access to all parts of Wales. [p41] We will create a fuel duty regulator to prevent sudden spikes in fuel prices. We will also seek European agreement for fuel price reductions in rural areas, recognizing the additional costs of living in rural parts of Wales, as already introduced in the Highlands and Islands of Scotland. [p41] We will introduce additional electricity charging points in Wales to encourage the use of electric vehicles. [p41] We will keep free bus passes. [p41] We will protect bus services in all parts of Wales and ensure early morning and late evening services for workers. [p41] We will expand Traws Cymru into a dedicated Welsh national coach company, linking our towns and cities with regular services, especially where train links are not an option. [p41] We will extend the Bwcabus scheme currently running in South Ceredigion and North Carmarthenshire into other rural areas to 15 Plaid Cymru, Working For Wales: 2015 Westminster Election Manifesto, 16 April 2015; emphasis added 17 Transport 2015 connect communities across Wales where traditional bus services are not viable. [p41] We support the transfer of powers over air passenger duty, both short and long haul, to the Welsh Government and we will support Cardiff Airport in creating an improved freight and passenger development strategy. [p41] We will not support the creation of a major new UK airport to the east of London. [p41] We will develop a ports and freight strategy for Wales, using European funding to improve infrastructure. [p41] We will ensure funding for urban cycle paths and between communities, particularly in travel to work areas. [p41] We will ensure that the Welsh Transport Commissioner is based in Wales, unlike at present. [p41] We will work with local authorities to ensure that all Blue Badge holders have access to free parking. [p57] Scottish National Party (SNP) The SNP manifesto, Stronger for Scotland, included the following commitments:16 We will … seek adequate transport infrastructure investment, with a particular aim of improving transport and communication links across the north of these isles. That includes connecting Scotland to HS2 as a priority, with construction beginning in Scotland as well as England, and a high speed connection between Glasgow, Edinburgh and the north of England as part of any high-speed rail network […] High Speed Rail should be constructed both from the north down and from the south up. [pp10&12] We will continue to support older Scots, by retaining key policies such as the free bus pass. [p16] We will press the UK government to reinstate an emergency towing vehicle on the west coast of Scotland and to ensure that delays in recruitment don’t leave vital coastguard stations understaffed. [p21] As the Scottish Government, we are consulting on measures to reduce emissions in Scotland, including looking at the creation of Low Emission Zones. [p32] UK Independence Party (UKIP) The UKIP manifesto, Believe in Britain, included the following commitments:17 Save £4 billion a year in capital expenditure by scrapping the HS2 vanity project, which will benefit the few at the expense of many. [pp8&37] We will invest £200 million to make parking at English hospitals free for patients and their visitors. [p17] The final report of the Davies Commission into airport capacity and connectivity in the UK will be published later this year. UKIP will consider its recommendations and then take a position on the basis of what we genuinely believe to be in the long-term 16 17 SNP, Stronger for Scotland: SNP Manifesto 2015, 20 April 2015; emphasis added UKIP, Believe in Britain: UKIP Manifesto 2015, 15 April 2015; emphasis added Number 7177, 13 May 2015 18 best interests of the country. However, we firmly believe that part of the solution to address the lack of airport capacity in the South East is to re-open Manston Airport. [p37] UKIP will only allow installation of speed cameras when they can be used as a deterrent at accident black spots, near schools and in residential areas where there are specific potential dangers. We will not permit speed cameras to be used as revenue-raisers for local authorities. [p37] We will remove road tolls where possible and let existing contracts on running road tolls expire … UKIP opposes ‘pay-asyou-go’ road charging schemes and attempts to introduce them by stealth. [p37] From October 2015, the EU will require all new cars to be fitted with the ‘eCall’ system. Ostensibly a road safety measure, this system tracks vehicles using GPS and reports back to a central database. This capability would enable introduction of a Europe-wide road pricing system, on a miles travelled basis, which the EU Transport Commissioner is keen to introduce. We will scrap mandatory fitments of eCall and allow owners who already have eCall installed to disable it on their vehicles. [p37] The Driver Certificate of Professional Competence (DCPC) is an expensive second-tier requirement, which is causing job losses, because of the added administration and expense to hauliers. We will scrap the DCPC for professionally licensed drivers. [p37] After leaving the EU the [HGV road user] levy would cease to apply to UK vehicles, but the Vehicle Excise Duty on UK vehicles would be adjusted by the equivalent amount to make this aspect of the change revenue neutral for both UK hauliers and the government. The current levy tariff will then be doubled to a maximum of £2000 per annum and only apply to foreign registered HGVs … It will achieve exactly the same effect as UKIP’s original ‘Britdisc’ proposal. [p37] To help protect the enduring legacy of the motor industry and our classic and historic vehicles, UKIP will exempt vehicles over 25 years old from Vehicle Excise Duty. [p37] We will push every local authority in the country to offer at least 30 minutes free parking in town centres, high streets and shopping parades, to encourage shoppers into our town centres and boost local business. [p44] 19 Transport 2015 3. Policy focus 1: devolution 3.1 What’s the issue? Whether we are talking about devolution to lower tier government in England and devolved governments in Scotland, Wales and Northern Ireland, or about decision-making being taken at the trans-national UN or EU level, the proportion of transport policy decisions taken at Westminster has likely never been lower. The Labour and Coalition governments devolved many transport responsibilities to the administrations in London, Edinburgh, Cardiff and Belfast. The UK Government in Westminster develops the policy and provides the bulk of the funding for local transport in England, including: buses, walking, cycling and local transport (highways and rail) more generally; in other parts of the UK this is provided by the relevant devolved administration. Westminster retains reserved powers for ‘national’ transport, such as aviation and maritime policy, and strategic road and rail. The EU legislates across all transport modes, but in particular the UK must follow its lead in terms of infrastructure standards, market liberalisation and harmonisation in areas such as driver and vehicle licensing and testing, transport safety and security, and railway interoperability. Northern Ireland has long managed its own road, rail and bus systems. Scotland specifies and lets its own rail franchise, manages its own highway network, sets its own speed limits and drink drive limits, provides its own bus passes and other concessions and manages its own parking. Wales is also looking forward to letting its own rail franchise: it already manages its own highway network, provides its own bus passes and other concessions and manages its own parking. In England a great deal of responsibility rests on the shoulders of the various tiers of local government as well as on Local Enterprise Partnerships, the Integrated Transport Authorities in the metropolitan areas outside London and on the elected Mayor and Transport for London in the capital. These entities can impose road, workplace and parking charges, provide concessions, plan and finance local infrastructure projects like roads and railways and they have responsibility for accessible and sustainable transport such as cycling. Taken together, these represent a significant shift of power away from Westminster – and more is likely to come.18 Scotland and Wales largely devolved Some parts of the transport system have long been separated between England and Wales on the one hand and Scotland on the 18 this section incorporates work by HC Library colleagues Paul Bowers (devolution) and Mark Sandford (local government); information about Northern Ireland contributed by Des McKibbin from the Research and Information Service (RaISe) of the Northern Ireland Assembly Number 7177, 13 May 2015 20 other. For example, much of the Highways Act 1980 which applies to England and Wales is mirrored in the separate Roads (Scotland) Act 1984. But in more recent times, it was the decision by the Labour Government in 1997 to provide for new devolved legislatures and governments in Scotland and Wales that led to the devolution of significant transport powers. This was initially achieved in Scotland by the Scotland Act 1998 and in Wales by the Government of Wales Act 1998.19 This has led to significant amounts of transport legislation becoming the responsibility of the Scottish and Welsh Governments, leaving the Department for Transport in Westminster primarily responsible for aviation, shipping and infrastructure as well as transport generally in England. Northern Ireland has its own transport powers The devolution of powers relating to transport in Northern Ireland was legislated for in the Northern Ireland Act 1998. Devolution followed the Belfast/Good Friday Agreement in 1998 and also led to the establishment of the North-South Ministerial Council (NSMC), a body intended to address matters of mutual interest, one of which is transport. The NSMC Transport Sector meets in order to make decisions on common policies and approaches in areas such as cooperation on strategic transport planning, including road and rail infrastructure, public transport services and road and rail safety. The Department for Regional Development (DRD) has overall responsibility for transport policy and planning in Northern Ireland. These policies are delivered by TransportNI, a business unit within the DRD which is, in effect, the roads and public transport authority in Northern Ireland. Currently the Department for the Environment (DoE) has responsibility for vehicle registration, road safety and Driver and Vehicle Agency (DVA) functions. However, the Stormont House Agreement of 23 December 2014 included a commitment to reduce the number of Government Departments from 12 to nine in time for the 2016 Assembly election. Assuming this goes through, a new Department for Infrastructure will exercise the existing responsibilities of DRD, but will also take on transport-related functions currently exercised by the DOE.20 Local authorities in Northern Ireland have no statutory responsibilities with regard to transport policy or planning. However, they are expected to have a prominent role in the production of local transport plans as these emerge following the commencement of local government reform. Responsibility for aviation and shipping matters remains reserved. However, issues around air connectivity and the impact this has on the Northern Ireland economy has led to calls for a separate air transport strategy for Northern Ireland to take account of the region’s 19 for more information on transport devolution to Scotland and Wales see HC Library briefing papers SN3192 and SN3156 respectively 20 Northern Ireland Assembly, 2 March 2015 21 Transport 2015 unique position within the UK whereby it is almost entirely reliant on air transport for, in particular, business and leisure travel. The Northern Ireland Affairs Select Committee conducted an inquiry on this topic in 2012, examining issues such as the devolution of Air Passenger Duty (APD) and the importance of maintaining links between Northern Ireland and London.21 The vast majority of public transport services are provided by the subsidiary companies of the Northern Ireland Transport Holding Company (NITHC) - a statutory body (public corporation) established by the Transport Act (Northern Ireland) 1967 to oversee the provision of public transport in NI. The three subsidiary companies, Citybus (which operates Metro bus services), NI Railways and Ulsterbus, have operated under the overall brand-name of Translink since 1996, although the companies are separate legal entities. The 1967 Act remained the primary transport legislation in Northern Ireland for over 40 years until it was updated by the Transport Act (Northern Ireland) 2011. The purpose of this legislative change was twofold: to facilitate an improved and more accessible public transport system and also to take account of the modern operating environment including requirements to comply with European legislation. The Northern Irish parties all published manifestos for the 2015 General Election containing a range of transport commitments.22 The English regions want more control over transport Local and regional authorities of one sort or another, supported by various commissions, pressure groups and think tanks, have been calling for more powers to plan, fund and manage transport in their areas for decades. Successive governments have legislated to reform local and regional transport delivery, sometimes through more general machinery changes but also via specific transport-related initiatives. Over the past couple of years there have been a slew of reports looking at this issue. One of the first was the ‘City Centred’ campaign, launched by leaders of London and the UK's Core Cities in September 2013,23 calling for more devolution, including fiscal powers, from central government. In July 2014 Lord Adonis published his Growth Review for the Labour Party, recommending the setting up of more city and county region Combined Authorities, to take direct 21 NIA Committee, An air transport strategy for Northern Ireland (first report of session 2012–13), HC 76, 30 November 2012; APD is further discussed in section 7.4, below 22 in alphabetical order: APNI, Step Forward, Not Back: Manifesto for 2015: Westminster Election, 16 April 2015; DUP, Westminster Manifesto 2015, 21 April 2015; SDLP, Prosperity Not Austerity: Westminster Manifesto 2015, 15 April 2015; Sinn Fein, Equality Not Austerity: 2015 Westminster Election Manifesto, 20 April 2015; UUP, One Day, One Vote, One Chance for Change: Westminster Manifesto 2015, 17 April 2015; note: Lady Sylvia Hermon stood and won as an independent in North Down 23 the ‘Core Cities’ are Birmingham, Bristol, Cardiff, Glasgow, Leeds, Liverpool, Manchester, Newcastle, Nottingham, and Sheffield Number 7177, 13 May 2015 22 responsibility for transport and other economic functions, on a similar basis to the Mayor of London.24 In September 2014 the Passenger Transport Executive Group (pteg) argued that cities outside London should have more powers over their bus networks and ‘meaningful’ devolution of local rail services, which together would allow them to deliver ‘Oyster-style’ smart and simple ticketing;25 single, integrated transport networks and a clearer interface with the public, local businesses and investors on service delivery and development.26 This was echoed by the RSA City Growth Commission in October 2014, which recommended that there should be ‘accelerated connectivity’ between metropolitan areas in the North and Midlands to “create larger economic powerhouses, to encourage complementary poles of growth in relation to London and the South East”. Over the medium to longer term, the Commission believed that connectivity between these and other major metropolitan areas would be a key economic driver. It also recommended an ‘Oyster card for the North’ (see section 3.5 below for further information).27 Also in October 2014 the Campaign for Better Transport (CBT) called for more powers for cities outside London to allow for the introduction of smartcards and integrated transport networks; the creation of new multi-authority ‘transport consortia’ outside the big cities to join up different councils and deliver smart tickets and other transport improvements; and regional groupings to manage strategic roads and local rail services.28 In March 2015 the Coalition Government and the leaders of Northern councils published a report announcing the establishment of a body called Transport for the North (TfN), under the leadership of an independent Chair, to bring together ‘all the relevant parties’ to work in partnership to establish a “clear, long-term, strategic transport vision for the North of England that is shared by all parties and allows the North to speak with a single voice and execute that vision”. It would be tasked with developing strategic, prioritised transport investment opportunities and the Government would provide financial certainty via a “clear future budget envelope to be agreed at the Government’s Spending Review in 2015”.29 At about the same time IPPR North published a report on transport in the North of England, calling for further devolved and integrated transport powers to be delivered in three phases between 2015 and 2025. This would involve extending the powers of TfN, devolving rail franchising and strategic road network powers, smart ticketing, and 24 Lord Adonis, Mending the Fractured Economy, July 2014, p8 when people say ‘Oyster-style’ they mean an integrated, contactless payment system or similar which enables users to easily switch between modes of transport across a region (as in the London Oyster Card) 26 pteg, Policy Futures - Urban Transport outside London, September 2014 27 City Growth Commission, Unleashing Metro Growth, October 2014, p34 28 CBT, Making Transport Local: devolution for transport in England outside London, October 2014 29 HMG, The Northern Powerhouse: One Agenda, One Economy, One North, March 2015, p39 25 23 Transport 2015 the setting of five-yearly budgets fully devolved from the Treasury to TfN.30 The EU and other global players take an increasing number of decisions Generally speaking, the EU acts on transport issues where there is a transnational element – such as on almost all aviation and maritime issues, type approval of road vehicles, licensing, transport networks etc.31 The EU’s authority to act on transport policy ultimately derives from Article 4(2)(g), Title VI (transport), and Title XVI (Trans-European Networks) of the Treaty on the Functioning of the European Union (TFEU).32 Specifically, it provides for: common rules applicable to international transport to or from the territory of a Member State or passing across the territory of one or more Member States; the conditions under which non-resident carriers may operate transport services within a Member State; measures to improve transport safety; and any other appropriate provisions. EU action on transport really only gained momentum in the mid1980s after the European Parliament (EP) took the Council to the European Court of Justice (ECJ) for its failure to act in adopting the common transport policy under Article 90.33 A ‘common transport market’ has largely been achieved, apart from rail transport. It essentially involves opening transport markets to competition and creating fair conditions in which that competition can flourish. This has involved the harmonisation of national legal and administrative regulations, including the prevailing technological, social and tax conditions. The successes of this model have been falling prices and increasing patronage since the 1980s across the EU as a whole. However, this is increasingly off-set by concerns about how to safeguard ‘fairly priced and efficient mobility for people and goods’ and minimise external costs (mainly environmental and health-related). The most recent White Paper from the Commission was published in 2011. It set out an ambition to reduce greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions by at least 60 per cent by 2050 compared with 1990 without curbing transport growth or impairing mobility. The Paper set 30 IPPR North, Transport for the North: A blueprint for devolving and integrating transport powers in England, March 2015, summary 31 further information on EU transport policy can be found in a suite of briefing papers produced by the European Parliament and available on its website [accessed 8 April 2015] 32 the EEC or ‘Common Market’ was established in 1957 by the Treaty of Rome and came into being in 1958; the European Community, which replaced the EEC in 1993, formed one part of the European Union or EU; the EU was the over-arching structure, comprising the Community and two inter-governmental ‘Pillars’; the Treaty of Lisbon, which entered into force in December 2009, changed this structure, and we now have only the European Union or EU; for more information, see: HC Library briefing paper SN3689 33 Case 13/83, 22 May 1985 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 24 out ten objectives for transport to 2030 (e.g. shifting a third of road freight to rail or waterborne modes; and tripling the length of the high speed rail network). It also provided details of the measures required to deliver these objectives, the most fundamental of which were the Single European Sky, Single European Railway Area; a ‘Blue Belt’ in the seas around Europe; opening markets in combination with quality jobs and good working conditions; improved security and transport safety; better guarantees of passenger rights across all modes of transport and better accessibility of infrastructure. It also posited that in future transport users would have to pay a larger proportion of costs, and cites in particular would face higher energy taxation and emission trading systems.34 Other notable international bodies that have a significant impact on UK transport policy formation are the UN’s shipping and aviation agencies – the International Maritime Organization (IMO) and the International Civil Aviation Organization (ICAO) – and the UN Economic Commission for Europe (UNECE). IMO and ICAO are the international fora in which the global frameworks regarding safety and security in those sectors are established; the treaties signed under their auspices usually form the foundation of both EU law and that of the UK. UNECE is particularly influential when it comes to road transport as its vehicle regulations form the basis of EU and UK law on vehicle design and construction. 3.2 Why devolve transport policy? Local accountability In opposition all major parties tend to agree that decisions should be taken at the lowest practical democratic level. They do not always uphold this principle when they are in government; or rather their rhetoric does not always match the reality. Labour and the Coalition when in Government devolved, or have proposed to devolve, significant powers to Scotland and Wales, though not enough for some. The argument for this sort of devolution is simple enough in practical terms and is not so different from those arguments put forward for lower-level decision-making in England: that people feel most ownership of and accountability for policy if it is made at a closer level to their daily lives. There is also a more profound political argument, based on principle, made particularly vocally by the Scottish and Welsh nationalist parties, that Englishdominance of policy making for other countries within the UK has repeatedly resulted in the policies of parties elected with a majority in England but not in Scotland or Wales being undemocratically enforced in those countries. In terms of England, since 1997 there has been a plethora of changes to how local transport is planned and funded: tiers of government have come and gone, agencies, quangos and partnerships have all 34 EC, Roadmap to a Single European Transport Area, COM(2011) 144 final, March 2011 25 Transport 2015 featured as vehicles for the planning process, and funding has usually been short term and has fluctuated year-on-year. Capital funding has tended to be in the gift of central government and has been doled out through various funds in response to bids from local authorities and other bodies. Revenue funding is provided on a biannual basis. There is a long running debate about the true extent of devolution within England. While decision-making powers have certainly devolved, it is debatable how local bodies can make the most of those powers when they still overwhelmingly rely on the largesse of the Treasury.35 The ‘North/South divide’ One of the tropes that we heard much of, particularly in the latter half of the 2010 Parliament, was the imperative to ‘close the North/South divide’ in England.36 One of the policy areas put forward as a means by which to achieve this aim is transport, in particular in terms of spending per head on local infrastructure. On the basis of GVA (gross value added),37 we can get a broad picture of where the UK’s economic output is being produced. The most recent official figures show that in 2013 London and the South East together accounted for 38 per cent of UK GVA. This was more than the Midlands and North of England combined (33 per cent). GVA per head in London went from 60 per cent above the UK average in 1997 to 72 per cent above it in 2013 – the fastest growth rate of any region. Over the same period, GVA per head in both the East and West Midlands region fell from 10 per cent below the UK average to 17 per cent below – the worst performing regions since 1997 on this measure.38 In terms of transport, there has long been disquiet about the disproportionately large amount of transport funding that London receives as opposed to the rest of the UK. The argument goes that London is in part successful because it is better connected and that if other parts of the country (e.g. Manchester) had the sorts of powers and amount of funding allocated to London they could grow more vigorously and would be better placed to resist recessions. The most recent figures show that in 2012-13 transport spending per head in London was £4,529, compared to £1,876 in the North West (the next highest) and £554 in the North East (the lowest); in Scotland the figure was £2,866.39 If we look at transport spending alongside GVA we can see that the areas that produce the most benefit for the country also receive the most investment. 35 details of what the Labour and Coalition governments did in terms of devolution within England are set out in two HC Library briefing papers: SN4351 and SN5735, respectively 36 some include Scotland when talking about this issue, but not always 37 GVA is GDP excluding taxes and subsidies on production (e.g. it does not include VAT) 38 for further information see HC Library briefing paper SN5795 39 op cit., Public Expenditure Statistical Analysis (PESA), table 9.8(e) Number 7177, 13 May 2015 26 3.3 Where are we with devolution of transport policy? Scotland The most recent proposals for further devolution are a consequence of a commitment made by the three main unionist party leaders prior to the Scottish independence referendum in September 2014, in the event of a No vote. After the referendum, which did deliver a No, Prime Minister David Cameron set up a Commission under Lord Smith of Kelvin (the Smith Commission), to reach an agreement among all the parties in the Scottish Parliament. The Smith Commission published its final report in November 2014.40 In terms of transport, it recommended permitting a public sector operator to bid for the Scotrail franchise; giving the Scottish Government the power to set speed limits in Scotland and to make its own road signs; devolving the functions of the British Transport Police; and giving the Scottish Government a formal consultative role on the Maritime and Coastguard Agency and the Northern Lighthouse Board, with respect to their activities in Scotland.41 In January 2015 the Government published a command paper responding to Smith, which included draft clauses. This was to demonstrate what legislative proposals might be contained in a final Bill (published sometime after the 2015 General Election and thus subject to change by the new government, of whatever composition). Clauses 26-30 and 35-37 relate to transport matters and cover those recommendations made by Smith in November 2014.42 Wales The most recent proposals for further devolution are a consequence of the second report of the Commission on Devolution in Wales, chaired by Paul Silk (the Silk Commission), published in March 2014. This recommended moving the devolution settlement in Wales onto a ‘reserved powers’ footing (the model used with regards to Scotland).43 In terms of transport, it recommended further devolution of powers on rail, ports, bus and taxi regulation, speed and drink drive limits, and the functions of the Traffic Commissioner in relation to buses. It further stated that whilst inter-city cross-border rail franchises should remain reserved, the Welsh Government should have a greater role in the appointment of a new franchise operator. On roads, it did not recommend any changes in powers but did say that there should be closer co-ordination between the two Governments to “ensure a more 40 Smith Commission, Report of the Smith Commission for further devolution of powers to the Scottish Parliament, November 2014 41 ibid., pp19&21 42 HMG, Scotland in the United Kingdom: An enduring settlement, Cm 8990, January 2015, chapter 7 43 Silk Commission, Empowerment and Responsibility: Legislative Powers to Strengthen Wales, March 2014; the first report of the Silk Commission resulted in the Wales Act 2014, which includes enhanced powers to the Welsh Assembly and Welsh Government over elections and taxation 27 Transport 2015 strategic approach and good quality cross-border routes, both eastwest and north-south”.44 In February 2015 the Coalition Government published proposals for further devolution to Wales as part of the St David’s Day Agreement, based on the second Silk Commission report, the knock-on effects of the Smith Commission recommendations in Scotland and further proposals regarding fiscal devolution. On transport it pledged to take forward Silk’s recommendations in full, excepting devolution of the funding of Network Rail in relation to the Wales network and drink drive limits.45 In their 2015 manifestos the Labour and Conservative parties both committed to implementing the Silk recommendations. England Devolution within England is in many ways more complex than that to Scotland and Wales, where there is broad (though not universal) agreement on what should be devolved, how and when. In order to understand the various proposals for transport organisation and devolution at the local and regional level it is important to provide a brief word on how the broader governance arrangements currently work.46 English local government is divided in some areas into county councils (the upper tier) and district councils (the lower tier). The two tiers have distinct functions, though they overlap in some matters. In other areas, ‘unitary authorities’ carry out all local government functions. There are 353 local authorities in England, of which 27 are county councils, 201 are district councils, and 125 are unitary authorities, of which 32 are London boroughs and 36 are metropolitan boroughs. The Greater London Authority (GLA) exercises a range of functions in transport, policing, planning, fire and rescue, housing and economic development. It is not a local authority for most purposes. In other parts of England, central government manages some of the functions that the GLA undertakes for London.47 Five Combined Authorities (CAs) have been established in England under the Local Democracy, Economic Development and Construction Act 2009. These are not local authorities but joint legal bodies through which groups of authorities can work together. The CAs in Greater Manchester and Sheffield have been offered additional powers by the Government.48 Overlaid on this structure are Local Enterprise Partnerships (LEPs). The first cohort of LEPs were announced in late 2010; they are non44 ibid., p74; for full details see chapter 7 of the same document HMG, Powers for a Purpose: Towards a Lasting Devolution Settlement for Wales, Cm 9020, February 2015, chapter 2.5 46 for a fuller explanation of the various components there are a number of briefings available on the Local Government topical page of the Parliament website 47 for further information on the GLA see HC Library briefing paper SN5817 48 for further information on combined authorities, see HC Library briefing paper SN6649 45 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 28 statutory bodies which have assumed many of the responsibilities of Regional Development Agencies (RDAs) and have responsibility for Enterprise Zones.49 There is also a patchwork of transport authorities, including county and unitary councils, Integrated Transport Authorities and city-wide entities like Transport for London (TfL) and Transport for Greater Manchester (TfGM). The Government has also proposed a new body called Transport for the North (TfN). These bodies all have different responsibilities for transport planning and funding. Proposals for English devolution vary between political parties.50 As set out above, in their manifesto the Conservatives committed to devolving “far-reaching powers over economic development, transport and social care to large cities which choose to have elected mayors”; to a pilot to allow local councils to retain 100 per cent of growth in business rates; and to devolve further powers over skills spending and planning to the Mayor of London.51 3.4 What about funding? Barnett The non-statutory Barnett formula is part of the mechanism used to determine the budgets of the devolved administrations. It has long been subject to some controversy. As the devolved administrations have limited revenue raising powers their spending is largely funded through grants from the UK Government. These grants are commonly referred to as block grants. Annual changes in the block grants are determined by the Barnett formula. 52 There are three elements to the Barnett formula calculation: the change in planned spending in England by UK Government Departments covering devolved matters; the comparability percentage; and the population proportion in each country. The comparability percentage captures the extent to which spending by a UK Government Department is comparable with the equivalent services carried out by the devolved administration. For example transport has a comparability factor of 100% or close to 100% for Northern Ireland and Scotland, where transport is largely devolved. In Wales, where some elements of transport remain reserved, transport has a smaller comparability factor of around 75%. The population proportions used depends on the coverage of the UK Government Department concerned. In most cases, this is England only, so the proportion of the English population is used. The Barnett formula works by multiplying these three factors together. For example, if the change in spending by the Department for Transport was £100 million, the increase for Scotland would be: 49 for further information on LEPs see HC Library briefing paper SN5651 for further information on detailed proposals see HC Library briefing paper SN7029 51 op cit., Strong Leadership, A Clear Economic Plan, A Brighter More Secure Future: The Conservative Party Manifesto 2015, p13 52 for further information on Barnett, see HC Library research paper RP 07/91 50 29 Transport 2015 £100m x 98% [transport comparability percentage for Scotland] x 10%53 [Scotland population percentage] = £9.7m Figures calculated via this method are sometimes referred to as ‘Barnett consequentials’. This calculation is carried out for each relevant department and the sum of these results is the net increase in the devolved administration’s budget. The devolved administrations have discretion over how to spend the funds that are allocated to them under the Barnett formula. For example, there is no requirement that they spend the Barnett consequentials from increased spending by the Department for Transport on transport. Critics of the Barnett formula argue that it produces an unfair distribution of public spending in the different parts of the UK and that it fails to provide financial accountability or give the devolved legislatures any tools of economic policy, such as control of tax rates. There is particular concern in Wales about how Barnett applies to that country in comparison to Scotland. The IFS recently reported: Analysis of the 2010 and 2013 Spending Reviews suggests that Scotland and Northern Ireland have benefited significantly from the fact that the Barnett formula has passed on only a small fraction of the large cuts to the CLG:LG [local government] budget, but fully passed on the protection of NHS and education spending in England. Calculations suggest Scotland and Northern Ireland benefiting to the tune of £600 million and £200 million a year in 2015–16. This has allowed them to deliver substantially smaller cuts than required in the rest of the UK, which is arguably unfair to the people in England and Wales.54 Central Government Local authorities currently receive a proportion of their funding in the form of central government grant. The majority of this is allocated annually by the Department for Communities and Local Government (DCLG), with some grant programmes administered by other departments. Most of the DCLG grant can be spent as local authorities see fit, though a small number of items are ring-fenced, i.e. they can only be spent on particular matters. Currently, central government revenue and capital grant funding is fixed on an annual basis in the Government’s Local Government Finance Report. In recent years, indicative funding levels for a second year have been provided by the Government. There have been a number of proposals for local authorities to have additional flexibility over budgets, and for a reduction in central government’s role in the annual grant-making process. The two most significant are: 53 54 Single or ‘pooled’ budgets, based on the idea that public services can be more efficiently provided by local integration based on mid-2013 population estimates IFS, Business as usual? The Barnett formula, business rates and further tax devolution, IFS Briefing paper BN155, November 2014, p43 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 30 between, for instance, health, employment, housing, transport and skills policies; and Multi-year budgeting, where government provides for example a five-year revenue (and possibly capital) budget running the length of a Parliament so that local authorities could move funds between years to facilitate forward planning and flexibility. As indicated above, both major parties support further fiscal devolution to Scotland and Wales, including income and corporation taxes. It remains to be seen if London, Manchester and other English cities will see any further fiscal devolution. Raising money locally There are different ways in which local authorities could be allowed to raise money locally to pay for their own transport schemes and services (as well as much else). The two most often discussed are borrowing and property taxes.55 The purpose of proposals to increase local authority borrowing powers is to allow authorities to invest in infrastructure. Local authorities cannot borrow to meet revenue spending requirements. The majority of proposals of this kind relate to housebuilding, though the same principles could apply to other forms of infrastructure too. Tax increment financing (TIF) schemes enable local authorities to borrow to invest in infrastructure, and repay the loan from increased tax revenues resulting from the investment. ‘Earn back’ is a principle whereby a local authority is given a sum of money in respect of a particular, centrally-set policy for a fixed number of years. The authority is then permitted to spend the funds as it sees fit on delivering that policy, and if it saves any of the funds allocated, to retain a proportion of the saving. In terms of property taxes, London and other metropolitan (large urban) areas of England have recently argued for the devolution of full control over business rates and council tax, plus stamp duty, annual tax on enveloped dwellings, and capital gains tax. However this would not be suitable for all: some parts of England have smaller tax bases – meaning less capacity to raise additional tax revenue – than other parts. If areas with larger tax bases were able to retain their own tax revenues, less funding would be available for redistribution to other areas. There have also been proposals to devolve elements of the Government’s role in the council tax system to local authorities, including a power for local authorities to introduce more bands or revalue in their area, and to allow local authorities to retain more of their business rates. There are also suggestions for a number of powers to impose additional levies, or to localise control over other types of charge, such as assigning a proportion of revenue from specified taxes to local government. The proportion(s) would be specified in advance, meaning that local authorities could be assured of receiving their 55 further information on all the schemes discussed below can be found in HC Library briefing paper SN7046 31 Transport 2015 share of revenue. In principle, assigned revenue systems can be used to give local authorities incentives to increase tax revenues through their policies, as they would benefit directly from the increased income. Suggested tax areas where this policy could apply are fuel duty, exploitation of energy resources (e.g. fracking) and VAT on soft drinks, fast food and confectionery. As regards local transport authorities, Transport for London (TfL) has probably gone furthest in terms of a mix of funding. TfL is funded by fares income (approximately 40 per cent of all funding); grant funding from the Department for Transport (DfT) and the Greater London Authority (GLA) (about 25 per cent); other income, including advertising income, property rental and income from the Congestion Charge; Crossrail funding; and borrowing and cash movements.56 There is one other commonly-discussed income-raising measure specific to transport: raising money via bonds. This was discussed widely about 15 years ago when the then Mayor of London, Ken Livingstone, proposed a bond option to raise money to invest in the London Underground. Many people at the time considered that lessons could be learned from the way the New York Metropolitan Transportation Authority (MTA) had been restructured. They suggested that TfL could be granted the authority to establish a capital budget that would be separate from the operating budget, and to issue bonds that would be secured by pledged revenues.57 3.5 What might devolved transport policy and planning look like in England? A ‘one size fits all’ approach to devolution of transport powers seems both unlikely and undesirable. The ‘London model’, for example, is one approach and the proposals for Greater Manchester are different again. Outside of the main metropolitan areas, the ‘elected mayor’ model with attendant consolidated transport powers may not be the best option, particularly for more rural or geographically diffuse areas where public transport is sporadic and the populace is largely cardependant.58 The ‘London model’ is now about 15 years old. Under the Greater London Authority Act 1999, London's buses, trains, Underground system, traffic lights, taxis and river transport, were devolved to a single institution, Transport for London (TfL). The Mayor of London was given responsibility for policy and a duty to produce an integrated transport strategy for London. All statutory duties rest with the Mayor. TfL implements the Mayor's transport strategy and oversees transport services on a day-to-day basis. The London Assembly approves the integrated transport strategy and the transport budget, scrutinises the 56 TfL, How we are funded [accessed 14 April 2015] for further information on bond financing in relation to the London Underground, see section 6 of HC Library briefing paper SN1307 58 information on difficulties experienced in these areas can be found in a recent report by the Transport Select Committee, see: Passenger transport in isolated communities (fourth report of session 2014-15), HC 288, 22 July 2014 57 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 32 performance of TfL and the Mayor, and is able to conduct wider investigations of transport issues.59 In terms of London railway services, there is a duty on the Secretary of State and TfL to co-operate on rail matters, including a requirement that the Secretary of State must consult TfL before issuing a rail franchise Invitation To Tender (or when entering a franchise agreement for which an ITT has not been issued) for railway passenger services to, from or within London. There are also relaxed contractual restrictions on TfL, limiting the prohibition on TfL to enter into agreements with rail franchisees without the consent of the Secretary of State. Finally, TfL, as part of the franchise specification process, can propose and pay for extra train services or improvements to stations on a number of ‘inner suburban’ routes (TfL is required to consult with local transport authorities in the affected areas beyond the boundary and London TravelWatch before it does this). On roads, the 1999 Act created a network of key roads for which the Greater London Authority (GLA) would be the highway authority; these are called ‘GLA roads’. The initial GLA roads were designated by order by the Secretary of State and when trunk roads became GLA roads they ceased to be trunk roads (i.e. a highway for which the Secretary of State, rather than a local authority, is the highway and traffic authority). TfL is the traffic authority for GLA roads. For roads in Greater London that are not GLA roads or trunk roads, the traffic authority is the relevant London borough or the Common Council. TfL may place traffic signs on nearby roads (for which the relevant London borough council is the traffic authority) in connection with a GLA road. The signs may be placed on any structure on that road, whether or not the structure belongs to TfL. TfL may carry this out in connection with traffic regulation and experimental traffic orders and in other circumstances, provided they consult the relevant borough. Finally, TfL assumed the Secretary of State's statutory functions for traffic control systems in Greater London for all roads other than trunk roads.60 TfL also has some responsibilities for road safety and traffic reduction. In November 2014 the Chancellor, George Osborne, and leaders of the Greater Manchester Combined Authority (GMCA) signed a devolution agreement, which is intended to result in new powers and responsibilities being devolved to Greater Manchester, and Greater Manchester adopting a directly elected mayor for the city-region.61 The transport offer, which forms part of the deal, compares with London’s powers as follows: 59 for further information on transport governance in London, see HC Library research paper RP 08/36 60 traffic control systems can be defined as electronic systems which provide regulation, instruction, information or guidance to road users and to authorities from installations on or adjacent to the highway (e.g. traffic signals and signalled pedestrian crossings) 61 HMT, Devolution to the Greater Manchester Combined Authority and transition to a directly elected mayor, 3 November 2014 33 Transport 2015 Funding is on a comparable basis to how TfL’s multi-year budget is currently set; Bus powers have the potential to be the same as in London, if this is what the GMCA decides it wants; provision for devolved funding for the bus system including the Bus Service Operator Grant and the statutory concessionary travel scheme are the same as those of TfL/the Mayor in London; Rail powers appear broadly the same as TfL/the Mayor’s rail powers in London (though the devil will be in the detail and at the current time it is not possible to see where any differences may lie). Further, there is no mention of penalty fares (where London has separate powers) or of an independent body to monitor GMCA and represent passengers (e.g. as London TravelWatch does); and In terms of roads, the agreement states that the Government and Greater Manchester will “deliver the proposals on roads on joint working with the Highways Agency on operations, investment and maintenance”. While not entirely clear, this does seem to be different to (and less than) London’s road powers in that there is no mention of GMCA becoming a highway authority in the way that TfL is; nor is there any mention of other powers currently undertaken at a county/unitary or borough level becoming the responsibility of GMCA as they are of TfL (e.g. taxi licensing). 3.6 Issues for the 2015 Parliament What kind of devolution are we going to get? In their 2015 manifestos all major parties committed to further devolution for Scotland and Wales and some sort of devolution for England. In terms of Wales and Scotland, both major parties are committed to implementing the recommendations of the Silk and Smith commissions respectively. This would appear to give some certainty moving forward. However, it may be that the large number of MPs from the SNP could mean changes to or extensions of these powers beyond what is currently being proposed. Although the words used are often similar, there is no clear agreement what devolution in England might look like. While the UK now has a Conservative Government, it is worth looking at the differences in emphasis between the Conservative and Labour proposals made before the election. In their manifesto, the Conservatives said that they would “devolve far-reaching powers over economic development, transport and social care to large cities which choose to have elected mayors”.62 Specifically, this would involve the devolution of ‘powers and budgets’ with a view to the creation of a directly elected Mayor for Greater Manchester; a pilot allowing local councils in Cambridgeshire, Greater Manchester and Cheshire East to retain 100 per cent of growth in 62 op cit., Strong Leadership, A Clear Economic Plan, A Brighter More Secure Future: The Conservative Party Manifesto 2015, p13 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 34 business rates;63 further powers over skills spending and planning to the Mayor of London; more ‘bespoke’ Growth Deals with local councils, where locally supported; and ongoing support for Local Enterprise Partnerships. Labour said that they would “embark on the biggest devolution of power to our English city and county regions in a hundred years with an English Devolution Act … This will include control over local transport systems so that in future, local bodies can integrate trains, buses, trams and cycling into a single network”.64 Labour were also in favour of allowing city and county regions to retain 100 per cent of additional business rates raised from growth in their area; restore ‘fair funding’ across England; and introduce longer term multi-year budgets. However, as set out in section 3.3, above, none of this explains whether new structures and financial powers would replace or supplement what currently exists; whether any existing tiers of local transport planning or finance will be replaced, or how different arrangements in different localities will rub along together ‘at the edges’. Does devolution create cross-border transport problems? Great Britain is an island with no land borders with other states. For this reason it is easy for travellers, particularly vehicle drivers, to understand transport laws as they have long been the same across Great Britain. Northern Ireland of course has a land border with the Republic and the two countries have had to work out a comprehensive system of cross-border co-operation to ensure that transport across the border is smooth and that travellers are well informed of the different laws that apply either side of the border.65 In theory travel between Scotland, England and Wales where there are different laws in place (e.g. regarding speed limits and drink driving limits) should be no more difficult than driving in France or Ireland: the onus is on the traveller to make themselves aware of the law in the country they enter. However, where changes to the law are recent and there has not been adequate publicity, there could be a danger of those crossing a border finding themselves unwittingly subject to criminal penalty. For example, a BBC report in December 2014 found concerns about a lack of signage about the lower drink drive limit in Scotland for those entering the country from England.66 Is devolution irreversible? The government in Westminster is the government for the whole of the United Kingdom and, as has been seen with Northern Ireland in 63 already committed to in Budget 2015, see: HMT, Budget 2015, Cm 1093, 18 March 2015, p38, para 1.111 64 op cit., Britain can be better: The Labour Party Manifesto 2015, p64 65 Centre for Cross Border Studies, Your guide to North/South and cross-border transport co-operation, October 2006 66 “What do those on Anglo-Scottish border think of drink-drive change?”, BBC News, 3 December 2014 35 Transport 2015 the past, any powers devolved to a Parliament in Scotland, Wales or Northern Ireland, or to any locality within England, could in principle be returned to Westminster. However, this would be likely to require primary legislation. Taking NI as an example, direct rule was restored in 2000 by means of primary legislation. Section 1 of the Northern Ireland Act 2000 suspended the NI Assembly so long as the section was in force. There were powers to restore – and to re-suspend – by Order bringing section 1 in and out of force. That Act is now repealed, so to reintroduce direct rule, a government would have to create another Act that gave it the power to do so. Such an Act could work in the same way, or by a simpler mechanism whereby the Act itself could suspend the Assembly and restoration would be by Order. To abolish the Assembly altogether one would need an Act of Parliament to repeal the Northern Ireland Act 1998. Naturally all that would do is remove the Assembly – the laws it had passed would remain. If there were a specific problem, e.g. a disagreement over a detail of policy, there are other options: the UK Parliament retains the right to legislate on all matters, even devolved ones, or it could redefine a matter as non-devolved.67 In any case, this would be a less draconian alternative to complete abolition. So practically devolution is reversible, but there is a more fundamental issue of whether it would be politically possible. Unless there were a crisis of some sort, possibly involving national security, it is difficult to see any circumstances in which a UK Government would be able to persuade a majority of MPs to reverse devolution. Indeed, concerns that have been expressed about the principle of devolution have tended to be on the side of it leading to complete separation, rather than the reverse.68 Is the EU ‘a problem’? There is much to be said for trans-national arrangements in some areas of transport. Aviation and shipping clearly lend themselves to this sort of agreement, as the international nature of those industries mean that common rules on safety, security, aircraft and ship design and passenger treatment and compensation are generally more appropriate than dozens of differing national rules. One could also make a case that Europe as a continent of nations, where movement of people and goods by road and rail across borders is continually increasing, benefits from common rules on infrastructure, vehicle and driving standards – up to a point. However, it is self-evidently the case that over the past twenty years or so the European Union, usually in the form of the European Commission, has begun to legislate in ever more areas with ever more complexity. This has led to concerns that the ‘balance of 67 the details of this might vary according to how the matter became devolved in the first place (e.g. if it was by Order, that Order could simply be repealed) 68 see e.g. Michael Ancram’s speech at Second Reading of the Scotland Bill: HC Deb 12 January 1998, cc35-47 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 36 competencies’ between the Commission and Member States has tilted too far in the former’s favour. In its February 2014 report on this issue the UK Government found general support from stakeholders for liberalised free trade in the EU, and a desire for this to go further (e.g. in aviation) and frustration where this aspiration had been held back by ineffective implementation or lack of enforcement of existing regulation. Stakeholders also recognised the value of common operating and technical product standards (e.g. in rail interoperability), but there was some concern at the perceived use of common standards in other fields (e.g. safety) to ‘claw back market freedoms’ and allow the potential imposition of national barriers, possibly in a protectionist way. There was a broad welcome for EUlevel action internationally where that can open world markets, but there was also frustration: … particularly in maritime transport, over EU initiatives to legislate in areas where, in their view, regulation at United Nations agency level would be preferable because of the need for global standards to ensure a level playing field across the world.69 While stakeholders supported EU action where transport crossed borders between Member States, there was a feeling that in some cases EU action failed to take account of the distinct circumstances of Member States with peripheral geographic locations, such as the UK: It imposes the same cross-border rules on local and domestic transport which operates solely within the UK and so does not affect the Single Market. While the concept of the single market in transport services is generally strongly supported, so too are the principles of subsidiarity and proportionality.70 The review looked at future options and challenges under two broad headings: improving the Single Market; and better regulation. In terms of the former, stakeholders broadly wanted the EU to focus on implementing the existing laws underpinning the Single Market (e.g. in rail where there was concern at the failure of some Member States to open their domestic rail markets). Regarding the latter, there was a general view that the European Commission should focus less on making proposals for new legislation and concentrate more on enforcement of existing legislation. Furthermore, stakeholders felt that before making proposals for legislation, the Commission should undertake more openly evidenced impact assessments setting out clearly the potential costs and benefits and generally “legislate with a less heavy hand, or not at all, when it comes to non-intraEuropean issues and to allow greater scope for national handling of purely domestic issues”.71 In terms of powers that should revert to Member States, some (e.g. those representing recreational aviation and motorcycle training interests) suggested delegating responsibilities back to a national 69 HMG, Review of the Balance of Competences between the United Kingdom and the European Union: Transport, February 2014, executive summary 70 ibid. 71 ibid. 37 Transport 2015 level where they felt that recent EU action had harmed essentially local interests with no significant Single Market dimension. Generally, the evidence received from transport stakeholders reflected a broad consensus that: … the single market in transport services is at the core of the EU’s transport policy, that it has driven growth and prosperity in the UK and in other Member States, and that it should continue to do so. However, the evidence suggested that much further liberalisation is possible and that barriers, both formal and informal, remain. There was a general view among stakeholders that the way to achieve further liberalisation was, in many cases, through more effective implementation and enforcement of existing legislation rather than through continually seeking new legislation. 72 The question is often asked: what would happen if the UK were to leave the EU? This question became more pertinent after the Conservative victory in the 2015 General Election, as the Party has committed to holding an in-out referendum on the UK’s EU membership before the end of 2017, after negotiating “a new settlement for Britain in Europe”.73 In transport terms, if the UK left the EU, it would remain a member of the UN and its attendant agencies, and it is thus unlikely that the broad framework of our law on aviation and shipping would change; similarly we would also likely apply those vehicle rules set down by the UNECE. One could also envisage the UK and the EU agreeing to maintain common rules on driver and vehicle licensing to ensure continued free movement across the continent. It may well be that the UK would then negotiate an agreement with the EU in the same way that other countries such as Russia and the US have, on air routes, safety and security etc. There would likely be some areas (the aforementioned general aviation and motorcycling perhaps being two) where the UK would liberalise the arrangements agreed to across the EU. However, it is important to note that this is merely speculative and it would of course depend on the Government of the day and its priorities. 72 73 ibid. op cit., Strong Leadership, A Clear Economic Plan, A Brighter More Secure Future: The Conservative Party Manifesto 2015, p72 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 38 4. Policy focus 2: local bus services 4.1 What’s the issue? Local bus travel is in long term decline Bus travel has been in long term decline since the 1950s: current levels are less than half of those seen in the immediate post-war years.74 Deregulation in the mid-1980s was intended in part to address this problem both in terms of the number of routes and the number of passenger journeys. As set out in section 4.3 below, there has been mixed success. In its 2006 policy paper the Labour Government said that after 2010, on current trends, it expected bus patronage, particularly outside London, to resume its long-term decline. This in turn would put further pressure on supported services and local authority expenditure, creating a risk of an on-going spiral of declining services and rising subsidy taking hold in more local communities.75 It illustrated this with the following graphic: Buses are overlooked in policy-making Buses have often been referred to as a ‘Cinderella service’ in that they are neglected in the round of transport policy. Buses are by far the most popular form of public transport – in 2013/14 there were more than three times as many bus journeys as rail journeys76 – and yet they command a relatively small proportion of attention from central government. Bus travel would also appear to be overlooked by politicians – over the 2010 Parliament there were 11 debates on buses in the House of Commons (including Westminster Hall), as opposed to 20 on railways (excluding HS2). Furthermore, of the 56 reports published by the Transport Select Committee over the 74 DfT, Local bus passenger journeys (BUS0101), 17 March 2015 DfT, Putting passengers first, December 2006, p32 76 HMG, Transport Statistics Great Britain 2014 (TSGB), 11 December 2014, Table TSGB0102 75 39 Transport 2015 Parliament, four were about or had a significant element on buses, compared to 13 reports on rail-related issues (three of which were specifically on HS2).77 Buses have had an unglamorous reputation for many years now.78 In its 1997 transport White Paper the Labour Government said: “people will not switch from the comfort of their cars to buses that are old, dirty, unreliable and slow. Too often buses have been treated and seen as 'second class' transport. It doesn't have to be like this and is certainly not the case in many other European countries”.79 This is a far cry from the early days of the motor omnibus. An advertisement placed by the London General Omnibus Company in The Times in July 1914 read: Very shortly the whole country will be mapped out into motoromnibus service areas, which, though in each case selfcontained, will be so arranged and overlap in such a manner as to render it possible to establish direction connexions from one end of the country to the other. It will then be possible for those who do not possess motors of their own to enjoy the luxury, hitherto the prerogative of the rich, of motor touring at a merely nominal cost. […] Next to possessing a touring car of one’s own, there is no more pleasurable experience on a fine day – and though it may not be believed by the foreigner, the climate of England provides a very large number of days upon which out-door driving may be enjoyed – than that of travelling on the top of a well-built motor-omnibus or in one of the magnificent char-abancs specially built for pleasure touring purposes. There is no cheaper and healthier form of enjoyment, and this is being rapidly discovered by the millions who love the open air, and who also love the beauty of the English countryside. Recognizing this phase of the British character, and confident in the experience already gained with certain types of chassis, motor-omnibus companies are springing into existence and undertaking the exploitation of practically the whole country from one end to the other.80 77 for a full list, see the Transport Committee website, note not every inquiry resulted in a report [accessed 23 April 2015] 78 this was memorably captured in a remark likely mis-attributed to former Prime Minister Baroness Thatcher, that: "A man who, beyond the age of 26, finds himself on a bus can count himself as a failure" [for information on attribution, see Wikiquote: Margaret Thatcher, accessed 14 April 2015] 79 DETR, A new deal for transport: better for everyone, Cm 3950, July 1998, para 3.14 80 “The All-conquering Motor-Omnibus”, The Times, 20 July 1914; reproduced by kind permission of Transport for London Number 7177, 13 May 2015 40 Bus travel is expensive The average bus fare in England rose by 143% between 1995 and 2014.81 However, this disguises significant regional variation: fares in London rose by 131% over the same period, compared to a rise of 167% in the other metropolitan areas outside London and 142% across England (outside London) as a whole. Fares in Scotland over the equivalent period rose by 113% and in Wales by 135%.82 Between 1997 and 2010 fares across England as a whole (including London) rose by 84%; between 2010 and 2014 fares rose by 20.7%. Fares in Scotland over the equivalent period rose by 66% and 16% and in Wales by 91% and 16%.83 However, there is evidence that increases have been slowing. Since 2009 the TAS Partnership has published a bi-annual National Fares Survey, which seeks to benchmark bus fares within Great Britain. The most recent survey, published in 2013, showed that the average median single fare increased by 5% between 2011 and 2013, compared to an average increase in mean and modal fares of over 11% over the same period. The distribution (or spread) in single fares increased between both surveys, showing a wide variation in fare for a typical three-mile bus journey: The minimum fare was £0.80 (up from £0.70 in 2011); The average (median) fare was £2.00 (up from £1.90 in 2011); and The maximum fare was £5.00 (up from £3.85 in 2011). The average ticket value for day and weekly tickets also increased between the 2011 and 2013 surveys.84 TAS further noted that: 81 1995 is the earliest year for which comparable figures are available DfT, Costs, fares and revenue (BUS0405A), 17 March 2015 83 ibid. 84 TAS Partnership, TAS National Fares Survey 2013, February 2014, p3 82 41 Transport 2015 Whilst the cost of a median single bus fare may have risen by over 5% (two years) and 11% (four years), the increase is less than two national economic indicators (RPI of 7.3% and CPI of 5.4%). The increase is also less than comparable figures for national rail fares and motoring costs (particularly diesel cars) during the same period. A national correlation can be seen between the lowest fares, population density and greatest bus use, particularly in the PTE areas [metropolitan areas outside London], with Scotland and North West England being exceptions. In addition, a northsouth divide emerges between car ownership and estimated bus use, with those in south GB having greater car ownership and using the bus less than their northern counterparts.85 Overall, TAS concluded that whilst the average cost of bus travel increased between 2011 and 2013, the increases were, on average “less than those experienced in the wider national economy and in comparable modes (diesel car and rail)”.86 Deregulation has been a failure Almost since the moment it was introduced in October 1986 there has been a sizeable number of people and organisations consistently asserting that deregulation has been a failure leading to cuts in services, higher fares and profiteering by bus companies. Deregulation, they say, has led to a ‘free for all’. Critics of deregulation argue that the introduction of commercial operators into local bus markets has failed to substantially improve competition and has caused a diminution in levels of service. There is a general acceptance that commercial operators cannot now be forced out of the market and that there can be no return to the municipal bus model that existed before the mid-1980s. However, critics argue that commercial operators should be compelled to deliver a better service than is currently the case and that there should be some democratic accountability via control by local authorities or other locally elected transport bodies. The twentieth anniversary of bus deregulation in October 2006 prompted several reviews of how the industry stood and whether it was fit for purpose.87 In particular, the Transport Select Committee published a report heavily criticising the deregulated system and calling for the Government to make it easier for local transport authorities to take control of bus services in their areas.88 There are a number of reasons why some PTAs, local authorities and passenger groups take issue with the deregulated system and many of them come down to the same basic issue – deregulation has not benefitted the passenger. The industry is dominated by the ‘big five’ operators – Arriva, First, Go-Ahead, National Express and Stagecoach – who 85 ibid., p5 ibid., p5 87 for example: Public Accounts Committee, Delivery chain analysis for bus services in England (Forty-third report of session 2005-06), HC 851, 23 May 2006; and NERA, The Decline in Bus Services in the English PTE areas, August 2006 88 Transport Committee, Bus services across the UK (eleventh report of session 2005-06), HC 1317, 26 October 2006 86 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 42 effectively run monopolies in many areas. Even where two or more of the ‘big five’ operate in the same area, this has not always (or often) led to streamlined, co-ordinated services and cheaper fares. 4.2 What is deregulation and why was it introduced? What did the bus market look like before the 1980s? The regulation of passenger-carrying motor vehicles was introduced by the Road Traffic Act 1930. The Act established a system of road vehicle licensing controlled by regional Traffic Commissioners. This covered quality regulation – of the operators, vehicles and drivers – and quantity regulation of the number and types of services operated. It provided for the award of licences to operators to run a service defined by a route and timetable with a specified fare scale. Once granted, a licence in effect conferred local monopoly rights on the operator, particularly where local services in urban areas were concerned. Such services were developed on a comprehensive basis and provided a co-ordinated network, parts of which were usually dependent on cross-subsidy. Ownership of the local services was predominantly public. The structure of the bus industry changed little over the 50 years to 1980, but the market in which it operated altered dramatically with the increased use of the private car and bus patronage halved between the 1960s and 1980s.89 Concomitant with this, operating costs, fares and levels of subsidy were on the increase. Almost all companies suffered from a shortfall between revenue from fares and their operating costs and local authorities played an increasing role in sustaining public transport through revenue support payments. To retain the network of services and maintain fares at acceptable levels, local authorities were asked to make good the losses by subsidy payments. The level of support provided varied considerably from area to area. Because of the extent of cross-subsidy between routes, it was often difficult to assess the value for money obtained. Bus services in large parts of rural Britain, together with many commuterbased rail and bus networks in the conurbations, continued in existence only because of public subsidy. At the time the bus industry was dominated by public sector companies. In the six English metropolitan counties and Greater Glasgow the vast majority of urban bus services were planned, funded and operated by Passenger Transport Authorities (PTAs). A number of other cities and towns had, by historical precedent, municipal bus companies under the control of the relevant district council in England and Wales, or the regional council in Scotland. Most of the remaining urban services and a high proportion of interurban and rural routes were operated by subsidiaries of the state owned National Bus Company (NBC) in England and Wales, and by the Scottish Bus Group (SBG) subsidiaries in Scotland. 89 op cit., Transport Statistics Great Britain 2014 (TSGB), Table TSGB0102 43 Transport 2015 White Paper on buses, 1984 These trends provided the background to the changes introduced by the Conservative Government after 1979. That government was strongly in favour of bringing private investment and management into public transport. It argued that this would improve the passenger experience by making buses and trains more efficient. It therefore developed policies to reduce subsidies to buses, to reduce the role of local government in planning and controlling bus systems and to increase competition between bus companies. It decided that the way to deal with the decline in bus services, rising costs and increasing subsidies was to deregulate the industry and allow services to be subject to competition. The basic argument was set out in the 1984 buses White Paper: For 50 years from 1930 to 1980 local bus services were subject to a highly restrictive licensing system. Within this system the belief grew up that the way to provide comprehensive public transport is to protect the existing operators so that their profits from popular routes can cross-subsidise services for which there is less demand. The result of these worthy intentions has been to maintain a pattern of services developed for a different age and to neglect the best parts of the market. There has been too little incentive to develop markets, to woo the customer. Operators have been hampered by a philosophy that is defensive and inward-looking. [...] There is good evidence that services could be improved and costs reduced if we went about it in a different way. Without the dead hand of restrictive regulation fares could be reduced now on many bus routes and the operator would still make a profit. New and better services would be provided. More people would travel. This is not idle speculation. In 1980 the Government removed regulation from the long-distance coach services. As a result fares have come down, new services have been provided, the number of people travelling has gone up, new vehicles with greater comfort compete for custom. Competition has done all this – and the customer is the beneficiary. If the customer has the final say, bus operators will look keenly to see where and when people want to travel. If one operator fails to provide a service that is wanted, another will. 90 The White Paper and its associated consultation documents provoked an enormous response from interested organisations and from the general public. Much of the response was hostile. Thus, when the implementing legislation was published, the Department of Transport took the unusual step of issuing an accompanying document to respond in detail to its critics and explain the differences between the White Paper and the Bill.91 There was support from The Economist, Public Money92 and the then director of the right-of-centre think tank, the Social Affairs Unit, Digby Anderson, who argued that the introduction of a ‘contestable market’ 90 DoT, Buses, Cmnd 9300, July 1984, paras 1.4-1.6 DoT, Changes to the Government's proposals following consultation, January 1985 [HC DEP NS 1315] 92 “Buses: the Freedom Road”, The Economist, 14 July 1984; “A management buyout for National Bus?”, Public Money, Volume 4, Issue 3, September 1984 91 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 44 was essential, so that “new entrants can come into the bus business and that the existing companies should be uncomfortably aware of that”. He also took on the issue of whether buses should be a public service: There are those who do not want buses to be an efficient transport service but an inefficient social service. They advocate a vast nationalized system because it enables the profit-making routes to subsidize loss-making routes and the town services to subsidize the country. While the rich in society should help the poor, this is a silly and perverse way to go about redistribution. It is not the rich who use and pay for profit-making routes but, often, the poor, and the loss-making routes are well used by the rich.93 These arguments in favour of a free market were not, on the whole, endorsed either by the industry itself or by most other commentators. The Financial Times said that the White Paper overstated the case for complete deregulation of local bus services and warned that no other industrialised country had ever tried anything of the kind on a comparable scale. The results might be “a return to the chaos of the 1920s ... The danger is that in his rush towards unfettered competition Mr. Ridley [Nicholas Ridley, then Secretary of State for Transport] may have overlooked some attractive half-way houses that would constitute a better interim solution”.94 The Conservativecontrolled Association of District Councils said that the plans showed “an apparent lack of understanding of the way in which municipal buses operate and have done so efficiently for many years” and that while they had no objection to forming private bus companies, they did object to this being “foisted upon them by edict”.95 The Labourcontrolled Association of Metropolitan Authorities said the proposals would “lead to a bleak future for the travelling public [and] destroy the properly planned, integrated services that are absolutely vital to the conurbations”.96 The Bus and Coach Council [now the Confederation of Passenger Transport] said that the proposals in the White Paper would in practice have ‘an unduly adverse effect on the public’.97 On publication of what became the Transport Act 1985 (see below), The Times described it as: “the most characteristic of all the bills the Government has brought forward this session” and that it represented “a major act of faith in the market and its ability to meet the actual needs of consumers more satisfactorily than a system of provision planned from above can ever do”. While it acknowledged that deregulation was “a leap into the unknown”, it also argued that the Bill was far from “a reckless jettisoning of all controls regardless of consequences”.98 The Guardian predicted that the Bill would “inevitably be fought out in ideological primary colours” and predicted that: “Let buses pull out all the stops”, The Times, 25 July 1984 “Buses running out of control”, Financial Times, 18 July 1984 95 “Tory councils attack Ridley bus proposals”, The Guardian, 14 July 1984 96 Association of Metropolitan Authorities press notices, 14 September 1984 & 14 November 1984 97 BCC press notice, 25 July 1984 98 “Setting free the buses”, The Times, 2 February 1985 [editorial] 93 94 45 Transport 2015 … services will be sacrificed to savings all along the line. Any merit in, for example, the encouragement of shared taxis and minibuses will be swept aside in the unremitting cost cutting logic which is at the heart of the Bill. It gives carte blanche to the lowest bidder. This means that even the existing profitable services will be slashed to the bone, leaving a skeletal network of peak hour services running on Mondays to Fridays only throughout those parts of the country where there is still sufficient economic activity to just them.99 Legislation Legislation to deregulate the industry outside London was introduced in the Transport Acts of 1980 and 1985. The former dealt with express coach services and the latter with the traditional, ‘local’ bus service. The Secretary of State for Transport at the time, Nicholas Ridley, stated that the aim of deregulation was "to halt the decline that has afflicted the bus industry for more than 20 years".100 Part I of the 1985 Act abolished road service licensing in Great Britain, except in London, from October 1986. It replaced the licensing system with a system of registration and removed the duties of local authorities to co-ordinate public passenger transport in their areas. Thus, a bus company could register any service that it chose to operate on a commercial, i.e. unsupported, basis. The licensing authorities (the Traffic Commissioners) lost many of their former powers. Once the Act was implemented, any licensed bus operator merely needed to register its intention to set up a service with the Commissioner responsible for the area, giving at least 42 days' notice. The operator was then obliged to run the service according to the specification in the registration.101 Individual bus operators were responsible for the timetable and the introduction of new services depended on the operator's opinion of the demand for it and its commercial viability. There was no requirement in the 1985 Act or its consequent regulations for the commercial bus operator to consult before making changes to the timetable and the position of bus stops. The criteria for registration did not include any reference to public demand or to existing services and objections could no longer be made by other operators or local authorities. Local authorities were given powers to secure, using subsidy, socially necessary services which were not provided by the commercial market and to specify fare levels, type of bus and so on for these services, on the condition that they went out to open tender. Minor subsequent changes by the Conservative Government -1997 The 1985 Act resulted in dramatic changes to both the operating environment and the pattern of ownership in the bus industry but “A bus that may run over Mr Ridley”, The Guardian, 2 February 1985 [editorial] HC Deb 12 February 1985, c192; information on the changes to coach services under the 1980 Act can be found in section 2.1 of HC Library briefing paper SN1534 101 Public Service Vehicles (Registration of Local Services) Regulations 1986 (SI 1986/1671), as amended 99 100 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 46 there was criticism about predatory behaviour and the powers of the regulatory authorities. The conflicts between rival operators highlighted the absence of a regulatory framework, leaving an ad hoc policing arrangement to the competition authorities, the Office of Fair Trading and the Monopolies and Mergers Commission.102 Following a consultation exercise on local bus services in 1993, the then Transport Minister, Roger Freeman, ruled out major changes to the legislation but announced a package of minor rule changes.103 These included clarifying the powers of the Traffic Commissioners to make it clear that they could regulate the number of buses used in providing a service and control the use of duplicate buses.104 In January 1996 the Government further announced measures aimed at improving bus performance and service stability, including: high quality accessible vehicles; convenient waiting areas; ticketing schemes; good passenger information; and traffic management measures.105 The exception: London Buses in London were not deregulated in the 1980s with those in the rest of Great Britain. The reasons for this are complex and highly political. In the 1980s there was a fundamental disagreement between the then Labour-run Greater London Council (GLC) and the Conservative Government. The GLC was created in 1963 and took control of London transport in 1970 when a London Transport Executive (LTE) was set up. The GLC was responsible for the general policy of the LTE and part-funded it via grant (the rest coming from fares). The Conservative Government in the early 1980s had concerns about two aspects of transport in London: the GLC’s ‘fare’s fair’ policy (which was in direct conflict with the Government’s policies to contain the size of the public sector and local authority spending) and the general decrepit nature of the public transport and roads systems in London.106 The GLC was ultimately abolished in 1986. In July 1983 the Government published a command paper on reform of public transport in London. This painted an excoriating picture of transport provision in the capital; highlighting poor organisation and services, see-sawing fares and a general ‘shabbiness’ that needed to be rectified. It announced the Government’s intention to transfer control of the LTE from the GLC to the Secretary of State for Transport, where it would be reconstituted on the pattern of a small 102 now merged as the Competition and Markets Authority (CMA) press notice, “Freeman to act on results of bus consultation”, 16 November 1993 [PN 93/455] 104 DoT press notice, “Freeman to introduce new measures to help ease bus congestion”, 19 July 1994 [PN 94/264] 105 DoT press notice, "Norris announces measures to improve bus performance", 8 January 1996 106 this paper does not go into detail about ‘fare’s fair’, but the legal case and controversy about the scheme ultimately came down to how it was funded; for further information see the Commons debate that followed the legal judgement: HC Deb 22 December 1981, cc889-929; and Philip S Bagwell, The Transport Revolution 1770-1985 (1988), pp408-409 103DoT 47 Transport 2015 holding company, with its bus and Tube operations established as separate subsidiaries. The holding body would be renamed London Regional Transport (LRT).107 The paper also outlined the Government’s plans to reform buses in London: At present local bus services may be operated in Greater London only by London Transport or with their agreement. Road service licences are not required for such services. LRT will be responsible for approving services and changes in services by its own subsidiaries and by other operators who have entered into an agreement with it to provide services. Road service licences will still not be required for these services. Bus operators who wish to run bus services in Greater London without entering into an agreement with LRT will in future be enabled to apply for road service licences from the Traffic Commissioners. These arrangements will avoid the bureaucratic procedures which would be entailed if all services in Greater London were brought under the control of the Traffic Commissioners, while providing for the licensing of competing bus services under the same conditions as apply in the rest of Great Britain.108 What this meant in effect was that LRT would plan and regulate bus services but that private operators could, if they wished, run additional services to provide on-road competition. The London Regional Transport Act 1984 achieved these changes by transferring responsibility for the bus network from the GLC to LRT and requiring London Transport to set up operating subsidiary companies to run bus and Underground services. This was followed by the buses White Paper in July 1984 which announced that the Government did NOT intend to completely deregulate the London bus market ‘for the time being’: The need to take a grip on subsidy has led the Government to take over responsibility for the London Transport Executive from the GLC and reconstitute it as London Regional Transport, with new powers and duties. The London Regional Transport Act 1984 requires changes in the way London’s buses and tubes are run, requires LRT to contract out work whenever suitable and provides for greater involvement by the private sector in the provision of services both as contractors to LRT and in competition with them. In particular, LRT is required by the act to invite tenders from private firms to carry on certain of their activities and to accept satisfactory tenders where this would save costs. In addition, for the first time bus operators will be able to apply to the traffic commissioners for a road service licence to run local bus services in London rather than having to depend, as formerly, on obtaining and agreement from London Transport. These are major changes which will bring a measure of competition into the provision of London bus services. The Government has decided, in these special circumstances, to 107 108 DoT, Public Transport in London, Cmnd 9004, July 1983, para 16 ibid., para 24 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 48 defer deregulation in London while the changes, so recently instituted, bear fruit.109 Subsequently, in 1985 London Buses Ltd was formed as a whollyowned subsidiary and in late 1993 the Government announced that it would defer the previously intended deregulation of buses in London, although privatisation of the bus operating subsidiaries of London Transport would proceed.110 This was achieved in 1994. Bearing all the above in mind then, since 1985 the system in London has been and remains one of competitive tendering of bus operations, in effect ‘regulated competition’ – competition for the market rather than the ‘on the road’ competition of deregulation. Part IV of the Greater London Authority Act 1999 transferred responsibility for London's bus services from LT to Transport for London (TfL). TfL now decides which local services are required for the purpose of providing "safe, integrated, efficient and economic" transport services in Greater London and plans the detailed pattern of bus services, known as the London Bus Network. Only TfL, its subsidiary or someone with an agreement with TfL, may provide a service on the network. London Buses, as part of TfL, plans the bus network and controls fares. At present, London Buses uses a routebased tendering system which groups routes into discrete tranches. This allows neighbouring routes to be tendered together and hence for discounts to be achieved for letting a group of routes to one operator. This also allows review of the service structure of each small network prior to tendering. The bus network is kept under continuous review with up to 20 per cent of the total 700 route contracts re-let each year. In the five years to 2013 TfL reported that real bus subsidy had been reduced by 40 per cent, with London buses requiring a third less subsidy per passenger than other metropolitan areas.111 This system also allows TfL to, for example, specify accessibility and environmental standards. In terms of the former, London’s 8,700 buses are wheelchair accessible and low-floor, with audio visual announcements and it has forecast that by 2016 95% of bus stops will meet the required standard.112 As to the latter, over 10% (about 900) of London’s buses use hybrid technology; TfL expects this to reach 20% (1,700) by 2016. TfL is aiming to reduce nitrogen oxide (NOx) emissions from the bus fleet by 20% through the fitting of selective catalytic reduction (SCR) equipment to Euro 3 engine buses and the introduction of ultra-low emission Euro 6 engine vehicles by the start of 2016.113 In terms of funding, TfL’s financial plan for London Buses from 2014/15 to 2020/21 shows that when everything is taken into 109 op cit., Buses, para 4.18 DoT press notice, “Delivering the best bus services for London”, 8 November 1993 [PN 93/437] 111 TfL, Business Plan 2013, December 2013, p73 112 ibid., p25 113 ibid., p60 110 49 Transport 2015 consideration, running the London bus network is not cheap and it is projected to run at an annual operating deficit of between £530 million and £630 million. In contrast London Rail is projected to be in the black by 2019/20; London Underground will have an annual deficit by the same date of about £360 million.114 Sale of municipal bus companies Part III of the Transport Act 1985 required the sale of the National Bus Company (NBC) subsidiaries to the private sector. The company reorganised its services into 72 separate companies and these were all sold to the private sector or to management and/or employee buyouts by April 1988.115 Forty of the companies were bought by management or employee teams and many of the sales included provision for employee share schemes or profit-sharing schemes. Section 75 of the Act gave local authorities the power to dispose of their bus undertakings, subject to the Secretary of State's approval. Portsmouth City Council was the first municipal bus company to sell its bus operation in June 1988 and by 1997 only about seven per cent of passenger services were attributable to the municipal bus companies.116 London Transport sold its 10 bus companies between September 1994 and January 1995 under the auspices of the London Regional Transport Act 1984. Sale of the Scottish Bus Group (SBG) was concluded in October 1991. Gross proceeds of the NBC privatisation amounted to £323 million, resulting in a net surplus to the Government of £89 million after all debts and privatisation expenses had been accounted for.117 The 10 London bus companies were sold for £233 million (£218 million net).118 The Scottish Bus Group (SBG) was sold for £90 million.119 4.3 What happened after deregulation? Service levels and costs In 1985, three-quarters of bus turnover was in the hands of the public sector; by 1997, this amounted to approximately seven per cent. Many of the more dubious businesses that took advantage of deregulation to run substandard vehicles on profitable routes were squeezed out and those that remained were committed to modern fleets and long term investment. By 1996 the four largest bus operators (Stagecoach, First Bus, Cowie, and West Midlands Travel 114 TfL, Business Plan 2014, December 2014, table 9 (p79) and table 13 (p84) HC Deb 18 April 1988, cc355-57W 116 HC Deb 28 November 1997, cc691-92W; section 71 of the Local Transport Act 2008 removed the requirement to seek the Secretary of State’s approval for such a sale and at time of writing there are very few council-owned bus companies in existence – one press report from mid-2009 put the number remaining at just 13 117 HC Deb 25 January 1989, c575W 118 NAO, The sale of London Transport's bus operating companies (session 199596), HC 29, 14 December 1995, paras 2.41 & 2.43 119 NAO, Sale of the Scottish Bus Group (session 1992-93), HC 884, 23 July 1993 115 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 50 owned by National Express), accounted for half or more of industry turnover.120 Much of the case for deregulating the buses was made in contrast to how they operated at that time and to what was then seen as the successful deregulation of the coach industry four years previously. The main claims were that: fares would go down; it would be cheaper to run services; there would be more choice for passengers; there would be more jobs in the industry; and overall patronage would increase. It also claimed that, over time, competition would end noncommercial cross-subsidy, which in turn would reduce fares and end ‘perverse effects’. It is possible, in some limited circumstances, to compare statistical evidence about these claims (comparing 1986/87 to 2013/14). Fares Data shows that on a local bus fares index, fares across the whole of England increased by 270% between 1986/87 and 2011; in London the increase over the same period was 203%; in the English metropolitan areas it was 340% and in England, excluding metropolitan areas and London, 220%.121 Passenger journeys The number of passenger journeys on local bus services across England as a whole has increased since deregulation, but only because of an increase in journeys in London; in other areas the number of journeys has declined.122 In 1986/87 across England as a whole there were 4.54 billion passenger journeys on local bus services per annum; by 2013/14 that had increased to 4.7 billion journeys. In London the number of journeys doubled from 1.16 billion to 2.38 billion; in the metropolitan areas the number fell from 1.81 billion to 1.01 billion; and in England (ex-metropolitan areas and London) the number fell from 1.56 billion to 1.3 billion.123 Subsidies and financial support In regard to subsidies/support, comparable data prior to 1996/97 is not available. There is some limited information for 1980/81 to 2001/02, but this is not directly comparable with later data.124 Estimated net public transport support paid by central and local government for local bus services, concessionary travel and bus service operators’ grant (BSOG) for the period 1996/97 to 2013/14 120 OFT, The Effectiveness of Undertakings in the Bus Industry, Research Paper 14, December 1997, p4 121 op cit., Costs, fares and revenue (BUS0405A) 122 note: there was a change in the way passenger journeys were recorded in the official figures in 2004/05 resulting in a reduction of about 100 million in the figures for journeys in England, outside London 123 DfT, Local bus passenger journeys (BUS0103), 17 March 2015 124 DfT, Transport Statistics Bulletin: A Bulletin of Public Transport Statistics: Great Britain 2002 Edition, tables 19-21 51 Transport 2015 shows a total increase in funding across England from £797 million per annum to £2.2 billion.125 Government support per passenger journey for local bus travel between 2004/05 and 2013/14 shows a total net increase from 41.6 pence per mile to 46.9 pence per miles across England. This disguises the fact that BSOG and net public transport support decreased over this period while concessionary fare support increased dramatically (during this period free local bus travel for older and disabled people was introduced).126 Jobs in the bus industry DfT has data on staff employed by bus and coach operators from 1965. Two tables are available: one shows staff employed by all bus and coach operators (since 1965), the other shows staff employed by local operators (since 2004/05). There were 167,000 employed in the industry in 1986/87, by 2013/14 this had decreased to 124,000.127 Labour’s changes During its 13 years in office between 1997 and 2010 Labour never seriously considered reregulating bus service en-masse. Instead it proffered some statutory schemes whereby local authorities who chose to could exert more influence on or control over bus services in their local areas. Few local areas have considered using this legislation since it was introduced in 2001, for a number of reasons discussed in section 4.6, below. The Labour Party Manifesto for the 1997 General Election stated that the key to efficient bus services was “proper regulation” at a local level in the form of partnerships between local councils and bus operators, coupled with improved provision and enforcement of bus lanes.128 The transport White Paper, published in July 1998, estimated that car traffic would grow by more than a third in the twenty years to 2018, and the success of the Government's integrated transport policy would rest largely on the increased use of buses. Without it, the paper argued, pollution and congestion would inevitably increase with a corresponding damage to both the health of the population and the economy. In order to address this problem, more people should be persuaded to take more journeys by public transport and fewer by private car.129 More detail of how this could be achieved was given in the subsequent buses policy document, published in March 1999.130 This set out Labour’s overall bus policy and included proposals to give local authorities franchising-like powers to implement what are known as Quality Contract Schemes (QCS). The paper also proposed 125 DfT, Subsidies and concessions (BUS0502), 16 December 2014 ibid., Subsidies and concessions (BUS0503) 127 DfT, Employment (BUS0701), 23 September 2014; note: there was a change in the way the figures were estimated in 2004/05, which resulted in an increase in the number of platform staff 128 Labour Party, New Labour: Because Britain Deserves Better, April 1997, p29 129 op cit., A new deal for transport: better for everyone, paras 3.13-3.25 130 DETR, From workhorse to thoroughbred: a better role for bus travel, March 1999 126 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 52 statutory Quality Partnership Schemes (QPS): an arrangement whereby local authorities and bus companies enter into mutual agreements to provide services and infrastructure. Quality Partnerships and Quality Contracts formed the centrepiece of Labour’s changes to bus policy, legislated for in Part II of the Transport Act 2000. In December 2006 the Labour Government published a paper setting out its proposals to reform bus services. They undertook this reform in the light of the failure of any local authority or ITA to implement a QCS. Its proposals included an enhanced QPS, and a reduction in the burden on local authorities wishing to introduce a QCS.131 These changes were legislated for in what became the Local Transport Act 2008.132 Further information QCS and QPS can be found in section 4.6, below. 4.4 Why do people think deregulation is broken? A free market, not a public service As set out above, some have always maintained that deregulation in principle was bound to fail because it turned the bus market from a public service where income from profitable routes was diverted into a wider socially necessary network into a free market where unprofitable routes were left to wither on the vine. In practice, some of those routes have been maintained by local authorities through subsidy (see below): for some, this is evidence enough that deregulation has ‘failed’. It has long been the case that for many rural and isolated communities the bus is the only form of public transport, but those services are often ‘unprofitable’ and have suffered the brunt of local authority cuts to subsidised services over the past five years. Linked to this is the fact that some routes are dependent on passengers who are also subsidised – through the concessionary bus pass for older and disabled people. Often there is a correlation between those rural and isolated communities and high numbers of subsidised passengers (particularly older people).133 The Campaign for Better Transport (CBT) ran a high profile campaign over the course of the 2010 Parliament to highlight cuts to local subsidised bus services.134 A CBT survey showed that 46 per cent of local authorities reduced their expenditure on subsidised bus services during 2013/14; pteg (the Passenger Transport Executive Group) 131 op cit., Putting Passengers First, p7 details can be found in HC Library briefing papers RP 08/18 and RP 08/49 133 for further information on the difficulties faced by those living in rural and isolated communities, see: Transport Committee, Passenger transport in isolated communities (fourth report of session 2014–15), HC 288, 22 July 2014 134 CBT, Save Our Buses [accessed 15 April 2015] 132 53 Transport 2015 predicted a reduction in annual expenditure of £500 million over the four years from 2010, allowing for inflation.135 Lack of on-the-road competition In December 2011 the Competition Commission published a report on local bus competition which found that head-to-head competition in the supply of local bus services was uncommon, despite delivering significant benefits to customers where it was found. It raised concerns that some operators were in effect dividing areas up between them to avoid competition and that this might be more widespread than the Commission had been able to determine. Four features of local bus markets effectively made head-to-head competition uncommon and limited the effectiveness of potential competition and new entry. These features were: high levels of concentration (that is, the dominance of a small number of operators); barriers to entry and expansion; customer conduct in deciding which bus to catch; and operator conduct (by which operators avoided competing with other operators in ‘Core Territories’, i.e. certain parts of an operator’s network which it regarded as its ‘own’ territory, leading to geographic market segregation). On local authority tendered services, it found that, in most cases, the market worked well. However, in some cases the process of competition was impaired by the way local transport authorities designed tenders and the limited number of potential bidders in some local areas. Overall, the Commission found that the detriment to consumers and taxpayers as a result of the adverse effects of competition (AECs) in the operation of local bus services (both commercial and tendered services) and the tendering of supported services was considerably in excess of £70 million a year and was likely to be between £115 million and £305 million a year. The Commission made a number of recommendations to remedy these problems, such as market-opening measures to reduce barriers to entry and expansion; measures to promote competition in relation to the tendering of contracts for supported services; and changes to the wider policy and regulatory environment, including emphasising compliance with and effective enforcement of competition law.136 Subsidies Grants and subsidies perform a variety of functions in the bus industry and in the provision of services. Some, like Bus Service Operators’ Grant (BSOG), effectively subsidise bus travel for everyone because they go to all bus operators, irrespective of the type of service they run (commercial or local authority-supported). Others, like concessionary travel grants, reimburse operators for “Cuts to tendered bus services – is there another way?”, CBT blog, 17 March 2015 136 CC, Local bus services market investigation, December 2011, summary 135 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 54 carrying certain types of passenger at a discounted or nil fare and are administered via local authorities. Finally, at the most fundamental level there are direct subsidies for specific services from local authorities to bus operators; these tend to help people who live in isolated areas or in places which, for one reason or another, are not able to sustain a commercial bus service. Subsidies account for around 45 per cent of all bus operators’ revenues. The overall net level of Government subsidy (i.e. public transport support, BSOG and concessionary fare reimbursement) for bus services increased dramatically after 1997, rising from approximately £774 million in 1997/98 to approximately £2.2 billion in 2013/14.137 Total expenditure excluding concessionary fares on bus services in England in 2013/14 was £1.17 billion. Of this, £597 million was spent in London, and a further £210 million in the metropolitan areas.138 The main grant sources of funding from central government are BSOG, the Green Bus Fund and the Better Bus Areas Fund.139 The largest and most contested of these is BSOG. It has been reformed by successive governments both in terms of the absolute amount paid and who actually pays it. BSOG is a grant paid by the Department for Transport (DfT) to reimburse bus operators for some of the excise duty paid on the fuel consumed in operating an eligible bus service. It was formerly known as the Fuel Duty Rebate (FDR). In around mid-2002 the Labour Government renamed the rebate the Bus Service Operators’ Grant. The DfT generally pays BSOG to eligible bus operators; this definition was further tightened in 2013 to exclude services which are intended to operate for less than six consecutive weeks; are operated primarily for the purposes of tourism or because of the historical interest of the vehicle; rail replacement bus services; or services for which the fare includes a special amenity element (e.g. bus services between airport terminals and car parks).140 However, due to recent reforms there are two significant exceptions to this: Transport for London/the Greater London authority receive a grant from DfT for bus services operated under franchise to TfL, making TfL the payment authority for these services (this would also apply to any area that adopted a QCS in the future – see above).141 English local authorities administer BSOG to tendered bus services in their areas, this includes school services run on a tendered basis. All eligible bus operators receive BSOG.142 There are variations in the rebate. For example, in Better Bus Areas (BBAs) – currently parts of the cities of York, Nottingham and Sheffield, Merseyside and the 137 op cit., Subsidies and concessions (BUS0502) ibid. 139 information on the GBF and BBA can be found in HC Library briefing paper SN1522 140 DfT Letter to local authorities on BSOG reform, 5 July 2013 141 DfT, Bus Subsidy Reform Consultation Analysis, July 2013, pp6-7 142 DfT, Conditions of Eligibility (PSV360) for Bus Service Operators Grant, October 2008 138 55 Transport 2015 greater Bristol area – BSOG is paid at 75 per cent of the national rate for any eligible services running within these areas. This will eventually be reduced to zero.143 Other variations are the result of additional or incentive payments; there are two of these: for smartcard and GPS/automatic vehicle location and Low Carbon Emission Buses (LCEBs).144 4.5 Who supports deregulation and why? The bus industry believes that deregulation has generally been a success and has delivered significant investment and service improvements since 1986. In its September 2014 manifesto for buses the Confederation of Passenger Transport UK (CPT) set out what it believed to be the industry’s successes: The commercial market has stemmed the decline in bus patronage and provided passengers with greater choice. Passengers in the biggest towns and cities outside London are benefitting from frequent, good value bus networks, with smart and integrated ticketing options, new ways of purchasing tickets, high investment by commercial operators in bus fleets, all giving passengers more choice. Where bus services are under the control of cash-strapped local authorities, fares are higher, the market is less stable, services are being lost, and passenger satisfaction rates are lower.145 In terms of particular achievements it cited the following: improved passenger information and assistance; smart ticketing using a variety of platforms; and contributing to the economy through employment and investment (the bus industry provides 124,000 direct jobs in the UK). In terms of subsidy, CBT stated that in 2012/13 almost 90 per cent of the bus network outside London was run commercially with no subsidy from public funds, an increase of 4.6 per cent over the previous five years, and that while mileage on subsidised services fell by 16.5 per cent between 2006/7 and 2012/13, commercial mileage fell by only 1.7 per cent over the same period.146 Deregulation has also been supported by a number of think tanks such as the Adam Smith Institute and the Institute for Economic Affairs. The case was perhaps put most forcefully by the late Prof. John Hibbs, one of the architects of deregulation, in a November 2005 pamphlet for the IEA. He argued that “after twenty years of comparative freedom the bus industry today has become a commercial success”: Despite failings in some sectors there are many examples of proactive response to the market, with increased investment 143 DfT, New Better Bus Areas, 10 October 2013 DfT, Bus Service Operators Grant – new incentives for the use of smartcards and Automatic Vehicle Location equipment, March 2010 and Certification of a low carbon emission bus, July 2010; a list of operators claiming one or more of these incentive payments as of May 2013 can be found on the Gov.uk website [accessed 9 April 2015] 145 CBT, Making buses better together, September 2014, p1 146 ibid., p4 144 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 56 and some remarkable developments in man-management and consumer sensitivity. The central importance of costing and pricing for the market has been better understood than ever before and the provision of real-time information is making a new breakthrough in marketing. Some of the small firms snapping at the heels of the larger companies provide poorquality vehicles which give a poor impression to the public, but the value of open access is recognised by some of the leading figures in the industry, while many small operators offer a high standard of customer care along with lower prices. While the overall proportion of bus travel continues to fall, there are many examples of substantial growth; restructuring of services in Cambridge has led to an increase in patronage of 45 per cent over three years. What has been sadly lacking ever since 1985 has been a positive attitude on the part of highway authorities. To provide services buses need their own track, like trains. This has to be shared with cars and goods vehicles, but cars are singularly inefficient users of road space and in the absence of road pricing it should be the responsibility of local government to deal with the problem. […] The real problem facing the passenger and freight transport industry, whether by bus, car or train, is the prospect of falling overall motoring costs and rising fuel prices forecast over the coming decade. Subsidy, which is an inevitable consequence of franchise, can be no answer to this. Only an industry made up of professional, profit-seeking businesses can hope to meet the challenge, supported and respected by local government planners.147 4.6 What is the alternative? A number of organisations, including the Labour Party and the Passenger Transport Executive Group (pteg) have proposed that the legislation should be changed to enable local areas outside London to adopt ‘London-style bus powers’. There are some differences in emphasis as to what this would mean in practice. This section sets out the current arrangements for Quality Contract Schemes (QCS) and different forms of partnership working.148 It is also probably worth noting that had Labour won the 2015 General Election is was planning significant reforms to local bus services. As indicated above, the specific pledge in the Labour manifesto for the 2015 General Election was to give city and county regions “more power over the way buses are operated in their area. They will be able to decide routes, bear down on fares, drive improvements in services, and bring together trains, buses and trams into a single network with smart ticketing”.149 This was a substantial change compared to Labour’s policy in Government before 2010. 147 John Hibbs for the IEA, The Dangers of Bus Re-regulation, November 2005, pp65-66; see also: John Hibbs and Matthew Bradley for the ASI, Deregulated decade: ten years of bus deregulation, 1997 148 a fuller explanation is given in HC Library briefing paper SN624 149 op cit., Britain can be better: The Labour Party Manifesto 2015, p26; see also: “Michael Dugher: Time to tackle power of the bus barons”, Yorkshire Post, 4 February 2015; and Michael Dugher Speech to CBT, 11 March 2015 57 Transport 2015 The Conservatives have indicated that they would be prepared to allow some local bus re-regulation in certain circumstances, i.e. as part of a wider city devolution package involving an elected mayor (as in London). This is discussed in section 4.7, below. Quality Contract Schemes Quality Contract Schemes (QCS) have often been referred to as franchising or ‘re-regulation’ by another name. In practice however, in order to implement a QCS a local authority, Integrated Transport Authority (ITA) or Combined Authority (CA) has to jump through a number of hoops set out in the legislation. This has meant that since QCS was put on the statute books in 2000, not one has ever been implemented, despite the obvious desire of many authorities to have more control of their bus services. The question of what a QCS is and whether it is franchising by another name, is a good one. In its 1999 consultation paper on bus reform the Labour Government stated that QCS are “on similar lines to what is sometimes known as ‘franchising’” and “local authorities outside London would be given similar powers to grant exclusive operative rights on defined routes or within a defined area”. It set out the benefits of a ‘contracted’ bus network (network stability, local authority control of fares, service quality and quantity, interoperability with other modes, and cross-subsidy) and the possible disadvantages (less responsiveness to the customer, reduced flexibility, less incentive to innovate, a squeeze on smaller operators, a ‘race to the bottom’ in terms of staff wages and conditions, and costs to local authorities).150 In light of this, the Labour Government stated that it saw “a potential role for [QCS] in some areas, where a case can be made in the light of special local circumstances”. To that end, the onus would be on local authorities “to demonstrate, as part of a local transport plan, that the benefits in terms of modal shift or environmental improvements would not be met by other means, and that any extra costs involved would be offset by other benefits”.151 QCS were legislated for under sections 124-134 of the Transport Act 2000.152 The legislation included the requirement that making a QCS must be “the only practicable way” of implementing the policies set out in the relevant authority’s bus strategy and that a QCS would implement those policies in a way which was economic, efficient and effective. A QCS required approval from the Secretary of State in England, the Scottish Government or the Welsh Assembly. In the years following the implementation of the 2000 Act there was a debate about why no QCS was ever applied for, let alone implemented. This resulted in a December 2006 policy paper from the Labour Government proposing to make QCS a realistic option, while 150 op cit., From Workhorse to Thoroughbred: A better role for bus travel, chapter 6 ibid. 152 introduced by the Transport Act 2000 (Commencement No. 7) Order 2001 (SI 2001/3342) on 26 October 2001 151 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 58 “ensuring that these schemes can only be brought forward where the benefits are sufficient to justify them, and safeguarding the legitimate interests of bus operators”.153 Consequently, sections 19 to 45 of the Local Transport Act 2008 made changes to the arrangements for QCS in England (with some changes also applying to Wales).154 The main changes were the replacement of the requirement that a scheme must be the "only practicable way" of implementing the policies in the local authority's bus strategy with a new set of criteria; abolition of the requirement for schemes in England to be approved by the Secretary of State; a new right of appeal for bus operators; and employment protections for affected workers. The North East Combined Authority (NECA) is furthest along with a QCS proposal. At its meeting on 21 October 2014 NECA resolved to refer the proposed QCS for Tyne and Wear to the QCS Board (see below) for its consideration. NECA subsequently wrote to the QCS Board, requesting it to begin performance of its functions.155 There has been speculation that the first QCS would be challenged in court by any major bus operator currently running services in the area. If a QCS proceeds in the North East, it remains to be seen whether this would happen: Stagecoach, which runs about 40 per cent of the services there, has said: “We believe we're on very strong ground legally. We would take whatever steps are necessary to protect the future of a business we've invested millions in”.156 As noted above, going into the 2015 General Election Labour was proposing to reform the legislation on QCS so that specific groups of local authorities with particular local governance arrangements could implement them more easily. Presumably this would have involved the removal or lowering of the hurdles that have to be cleared in order to implement a QCS. It did not appear to be a proposal to abolish QCS and provide for re-regulation in primary legislation. Though this was also an option and may have ended up being the logical consequence. For example, primary legislation providing for re-regulation might replicate much of what is in the London-specific legislation as it relates to bus services, and could provide that it applied only to areas designated in an Order made by the Secretary of State under that Act. The obvious advantage of such an approach is that it could ultimately mean that local areas could have franchising as and when they were ready/requested it. On the downside this might create uncertainty in the existing market and there would have to be some 153 op cit., Putting Passengers First, p7 they came into force in January 2010 under four statutory instruments: SI 2009/3243, SI 2009/3244, SI 2009/3245 and SI 2009/3246 155 further information can be found via their bus strategy website [accessed 15 April 2015] 156 “Bus test case looms as Tyne & Wear seeks to wrestle back routes”, The Guardian, 2 September 2013; this has always been one of the likely stumbling blocks to a QCS with no authority willing to be the first to have to fight a potentially expensive and protracted court case against a well-funded bus operator 154 59 Transport 2015 provision to prevent private operators from withdrawing prematurely from areas scheduled for franchising. Partnership schemes There are two sorts of partnership scheme: statutory Quality Partnership Schemes (QPS) and non-statutory voluntary partnership schemes (VPS). A QPS is essentially a formal agreement between a local authority and one or more bus operators whereby the former provides particular facilities at specific locations along the routes used by local bus services, e.g. priority measures, bus stations and shelters, and the latter (who wish to use those facilities) agree to provide services of a particular standard through, e.g. new, green vehicles and staff training. There might also be joint measures for the benefit of passengers such as real-time passenger information. In its 1999 consultation paper, the Labour Government was pretty clearly in favour of partnerships rather than QCS. Much of this enthusiasm was on the back of notable local partnership successes in the 1990s in e.g. Aberdeen, Birmingham, Brighton, Bristol, Ipswich, Edinburgh, Leeds Nottingham and Oxford.157 Sections 114-123 of the Transport Act 2000 legislated to put QPS on a statutory footing.158 This allows local authorities to set quality standards for the partnership facilities that they provide such as bus lanes, or access to high-quality shelters with real-time passenger information. Buses that do not meet the standards can be excluded. This gives local authorities extra scope for influencing bus quality, whilst providing operators with the confidence to invest and to decide about service provision and innovation. Compliance with the quality standards in a partnership scheme are enforced through the bus registration system, overseen by the Traffic Commissioners who have powers to impose financial penalties and restrictions on an operator's licence.159 In its December 2006 paper on reforming bus services the Labour Government set out the criteria underpinning successful partnership working: political will at the local level to support bus transport; commitment from local bus company management to making improvements; and the right environment in which to prosper (i.e. bus priority measures, robust parking measures and effective enforcement).160 It also noted that while a number of VPS existed, (although outcomes to date were mixed), the QPS provisions in the 157 op cit., From Workhorse to Thoroughbred: A better role for bus travel, chapter 4; not everyone agreed with this rosy portrayal, see e.g. ETRA Committee, Integrated transport white paper (ninth report of session 1998-99), HC 32, 31 March 1999 and Audit Commission, All aboard: a review of local transport and travel in urban areas outside London, 1999 158 introduced by the Transport Act 2000 (Commencement No. 7) Order 2001 (SI 2001/3342) on 26 October 2001 159 further information on the bus-related powers of traffic commissioners can be found in HC Library briefing paper SN1523 160 op cit., Putting Passengers First, p30 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 60 2000 Act had not been used.161 The reasons given for this were that frequencies, timing and fares could not be included in a QPS. Sections 13 to 18 of the Local Transport Act 2008 made changes to remedy this – within limits.162 One of the main considerations with partnership schemes is their compatibility with competition law. The competition authorities stated in 2003 and 2011 that there was no evidence of partnership schemes posing a threat to competition.163 CBT cites particular successes with partnership working in South Yorkshire.164 This is echoed by pteg which states that the most recent Sheffield Bus Partnership has grown the number of fare-paying passenger bus journeys by nearly 10 per cent.165 The Brighton & Hove Bus Company is also often cited as a successful example of a bus company that dominates a local market working in a constructive partnership with the local authority: it says that it has “successfully grown the market for local bus travel by an average 5% each year since 1993, something which is unique in the bus industry”.166 What powers would the metropolitan areas outside London like to have? In their July 2014 Policy Futures paper on buses the Passenger Transport Executive Group (pteg)167 called for a simplification of the QCS regime and a “more supportive approach from DfT to those Local Transport Authorities who decide to use it”. This would involve removing the QCS Board and the right of bus operators to appeal to the Transport Tribunal from the process; and modifying the Public Interest Test.168 The QCS Board is a specially convened body under the chairmanship of a Traffic Commissioner, which considers the QCS application and judges whether it has met the relevant statutory requirements, in particular the Public Interest Test. The Board can make recommendations to the applicant authority if it does not think these requirements have been satisfied. Authorities have to respond to these recommendations but they do not have to implement them. However, a decision to do that would likely lead to an aforementioned appeal to the Tribunal. pteg has argued that the Board represents an unnecessary delay to the QCS process and that “the introduction of a QCS by a transport authority [should be] treated in the same way as 161 ibid., p38 set out in the Quality Partnership Schemes (England) Regulations 2009 (SI 2009/445), which came into force on 6 April 2009 163 OFT, The Transport Act 2000 ...: Guidance on the Competition Test (OFT 393), October 2003, p15; and op cit., Local bus services market investigation, para 15.388 164 op cit., Making buses better together, p4 165 pteg, Bus regulation: myths and facts, February 2015, p8 166 BHBC, All About Us [accessed 15 April 2015] 167 the umbrella organisation which represents he six strategic transport bodies for the six Metropolitan areas in England outside London - Greater Manchester (Transport for Greater Manchester), Merseyside (Merseytravel), South Yorkshire (SYPTE), Tyne and Wear (Nexus), West Midlands (Centro) and West Yorkshire (West Yorkshire Combined Authority) 168 pteg, Policy Futures paper – Buses, July 2014 162 61 Transport 2015 any other act of a transport authority under the law i.e. reviewable under the inherent jurisdiction of the High Court in judicial review”.169 As regards the Public Interest Test, pteg proposed that it be revised so that a transport authority “must believe that the introduction of a QCS would ‘assist in the realisation of policies set out in the transport authority’s local transport plan’”. This is in contrast to the current fivefold test, which requires that the authority be satisfied that a proposed QCS would: result in an increase in the use of bus services; bring benefits to persons using local services by improving the quality of those services; contribute to the implementation of local transport policies; contribute to the implementation of those policies in a way which is economic, efficient and effective; and limit any adverse effects on operators to those which are proportionate to the improvement in the well-being of persons living or working in the relevant area and to the achievement of the four aforementioned objectives. pteg also proposed a series of supplementary measures to ease the transition period to a first QCS and from a first QCS to a second QCS and a parallel power for the Secretary of State to deliver a QCS on the same (modified) process as local authorities. They proposed that the SoS could describe the areas where they triggered the QC process as ‘Deregulation Exemption Zones’.170 4.7 Issues for the 2015 Parliament Why are bus routes being cut? When we ask this question we are really asking why subsidised or ‘socially necessary’ bus routes are being cut. These are the services that are not deemed commercially viable by private operators and have been supported by local authorities as a result. As discussed above, the viability of these services depends on local authorities having the funds to support them. In England, the National Audit Office (NAO) estimated that there was a 37% real-terms reduction in central government funding to English local authorities between 2010/11 and 2014/15. The Welsh Local Government Association (WLGA) estimated that real terms funding for local government in Wales fell by 6% in real terms between 2009/10 and 2014-15. The latest figures from Audit Scotland show an 8.5%.real-terms reduction in local authority funding from the Scottish Government to Scottish local authorities between 2010/11 and 2013/14.171 169 ibid., p7; for more information on the role of the QCS Board, see: DfT, Local Transport Act 2008 - Quality contracts schemes: statutory guidance, December 2009 170 ibid., pp8-9 171 due to differences in services and funding, direct comparison with the position of councils in each of the three nations is not possible; furthermore, in England the range of responsibilities financed by local authorities varies from year to year making direct comparison between 2010 and later years difficult [sources: NAO, Financial sustainability of local authorities 2014 (session 2014-15), HC 783, Number 7177, 13 May 2015 62 It has therefore been for local authorities to decide where those spending cuts or savings must be made across the whole spectrum of their services. As set out in section 4.4, above, many local authorities have chosen to cut subsidised bus services. While it is probably true that without overall central government cuts to local authority budgets most if not all of these services could have been saved, that is not necessarily the case. One can see this by looking at the question in reverse: if local authority budgets were to increase over the 2015 Parliament, would that mean more subsidised bus services or would local authorities find other priorities on which to spend the new money? The only certain way to improve and increase subsidised services would be for central government to allocate specific amounts of money for the purpose and to legally require that the money be spent on subsidised bus services. At a time when the two major parties seem determined to devolve more power to local authorities to take their own decisions, the trend has been away from this sort of ‘hypothecation’, or ‘telling councils what to spend their money on’. That said, behind this is the bigger question of why subsidised bus services are needed at all. Since deregulation bus companies have been able to drop any services or routes that are not, in their view, commercially viable. As noted elsewhere, many local authorities argue that if they were able to regulate their bus services they could – as is the case in London – ‘bundle together’ lucrative and loss-making services and use the cross-subsidy involved in this process to provide what would otherwise be non-existent or subsidised services. The Conservatives have indicated that they would be prepared to allow some local bus re-regulation in certain circumstances, i.e. as part of a wider city devolution package involving an elected mayor (as in London). Manchester is considering these powers.172 Further, in a November 2014 debate in the House of Commons the Secretary of State for Transport, Patrick McLoughlin, intimated that he was seeking the best local solutions for bus service provision – in some places this could involve franchising or reregulation of some sort. He said: I would like to have a mosaic of transport systems. What is applicable in certain areas will not be applicable in others, but I am willing to have discussions with leaders in other areas and with people who would put an alternative view of how we best approach these matters. It is important not to get obsessed with one-size-fits-all regulation; a common-sense approach is best for each community.173 November 2014; WLGA, Welsh Government draft budget proposals for 2015-16, November 2014, p9; and Audit Scotland, An overview of local government in Scotland 2015, March 2015] 172 HMT press notice, “Manchester to get directly elected Mayor”, 3 November 2014 173 HC Deb 5 November 2014, c904 63 Transport 2015 Is bus funding fit for purpose? As indicated above, there are several different ‘streams’ of bus funding. What we generally mean when we use this term is the Bus Service Operator’s Grant (BSOG), the Green Bus Fund and the Better Bus Areas Fund.174 The largest and the most contentious of these is BSOG. It has been reformed by successive governments both in terms of the absolute amount paid and who actually pays it, but one may well perceive that there is more to do. There are two obvious questions to be asked about BSOG: why does this subsidy for commercial bus operators exist at all and how does it relate to the fuel price (i.e. can it be used to pass on fuel price cuts to passengers)? The fundamental question of why BSOG exists at all, or more specifically why it exists for commercial bus services, is a good one. It was introduced in 1964 by the Labour Government to cover the increased cost of local stage services, following an increase in road fuel duty of 6d: operators had claimed that the increase in fuel duty would have an injurious effect on the provision of services as they faced a declining market and shrinking profit margins. Traditionally the rebate has been kept and increased to help keep fares down and to help provide services that might not otherwise be viable.175 A review by the Labour Government in 2008 stated that BSOG allowed bus operators to “run a wider network of services than would otherwise be the case, and so arguably does incentivise patronage increases. However, it is directly based upon fuel consumption, and so is poorly linked to environmental objectives, particularly climate change”.176 Further, it stated that “BSOG in its current form offers good value for money. It is estimated that bus patronage is around 6.7% higher, services are 7.1% higher and fares are 6.5% lower than if BSOG was completely withdrawn”, but that “the link of BSOG to fuel consumption is problematic given the increasing importance of tackling climate change. This link weakens the incentives for bus operators to invest in more fuel efficient and environmentally friendly vehicles”.177 This led to the introduction of the LCEB incentive payments mentioned above. In its 2012 review of bus subsidies the Coalition Government also indicated its ongoing support for BSOG but stated that as it was paid on the basis of fuel consumed, it was ‘poorly targeted’ on the Government’s objective to reduce carbon emissions from transport.178 This resulted in the devolution of payments to local areas, as set out above. 174 information on the GBF and BBA can be found in HC Library briefing paper SN1522 175 e.g. HC Deb 17 March 1998, c1109 176 DfT, Local Bus Service Support – Options for Reform Consultation paper, March 2008, p6 177 ibid., p11 178 DfT, Consultation on bus subsidy reform, September 2012, p4 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 64 Finally, on the link to the fuel price, the current rate of BSOG (dating from 1 April 2014) varies by fuel type.179 The amount of BSOG an operator receives is based on a basic calculation: Total km travelled by one’s fleet/Litres of fuel used. Operators can also earn additional or incentive payments (see above). The actual ‘dollar amount’ is not linked to the fuel price at all. Rather it is a policy decision by the Government of the day, linked to the duty amount. It used to be the case that the maximum rebate the Secretary of State could provide was set as the full value of excise duty charged on oil and petrol. Full relief continued to be given up until the November 1993 Budget, when the then Chancellor, Ken Clarke, announced a three pence per litre increase in excise duty on petrol and diesel fuels. In addition, he explained that rebate would be frozen at pre-Budget levels. Since the level of rebate is paid under the Secretary of State's discretion, no legislation was required for the rebate to be frozen.180 This is how things have continued to the present. Under Labour BSOG was set at roughly 80 per cent of the duty paid on fuel; the Coalition reduced that to about 60 per cent from 2012. So, for example, the pence per litre subsidy for diesel was cut from 43.21 to 34.57.181 The sharp reduction in the cost of petrol since 2013 (by about 20 to 25 pence per litre) has caused some to wonder whether it might be possible to link BSOG to the fuel price rather than the duty rate: this would mean that when fuel became cheaper the subsidy would go down. As BSOG is set annually and bus operators do not buy petrol at the same rate or in the same way that individual consumers do, this would probably be difficult due to within-year petrol price fluctuations. That said, in principle there would be nothing preventing the Government from reviewing the rebate level more regularly (it has not changed since 2012), or, for example, looking at an annual petrol price fall and reducing the BSOG rate by an amount that would mirror that fall. There is another question as to whether local authorities could ‘afford’ to franchise their bus services or enter into QCS. This is discussed below. Concessionary fares are also dealt with separately, below. Would regulation improve services and cut costs? As indicated above, those in favour of regulation argue that it would enable local authorities to plan proper bus networks and thus improve services and to provide things like smart and integrated ticketing, which would cut costs for passengers. However, in terms of providing a regulated bus service it is more debatable as to whether this would be cheaper for local authorities than the current deregulated model. For example, on the London bus network (which saw passenger numbers increase by more than a 179 DfT, BSOG rates from 1st April 2014, 3 July 2014 HC Deb 30 November 1993, c938 181 DfT, New BSOG rates from 1st April 2012, 2012 180 65 Transport 2015 million between 1997/98 and 2013/14)182 the total amount of subsidy increased from £152 million in 1997/98 to £828 million in 2013/14.183 In 2011 the TAS Partnership looked at the subsidy figures for London in some detail. In particular it stated that the one year in recent history when there was no subsidy (1997/98) was only achieved by depressed driver wages and reduced depreciation charges and that during that year there was “a serious slippage in service standards resulting from staff shortages, which resulted in the only fall in passenger demand seen in London in the fifteen years to 2009”. Both the London authority and operators “quickly concluded that this was not a sustainable business model, and so attempts to break even were abandoned”. TAS concluded that: “to pretend that their success can be replicated elsewhere in the UK simply by changing the regulatory system and at no cost to the public purse is, frankly, not remotely credible”. 184 As discussed above, at present the only form of regulation available is a Quality Contract Scheme (QCS). In its December 2011 report the Competition Commission put the cost of implementing a QCS at up to £1 million with annual running costs of approximately the same amount.185 pteg has argued that the proposed QCS in the North East (see section 4.6, above) is not predicated on additional subsidy. In its 2013 consultation on the proposed QCS Nexus (the Tyne and Wear Passenger Transport Executive) stated that it would reduce public expenditure on bus services by £7 million per annum from the commencement of the QCS, “by both growing commercial fare box income and by achieving better value through competitive tendering of all bus services”.186 In their 2006 report on the bus industry, the Transport Committee was told by pteg that in effect, a QCS was an unsatisfactory halfway house between deregulation and franchising. What they wanted, in effect, was: “a system similar to [the franchised system in London], with the attendant increase in powers and funding, [to] improve bus services and patronage in their own metropolitan areas”.187 It is probably worth asking what the difference is between franchising in London and QCS. It essentially rests on three main pillars: London spends more on its franchising system; Transport for London (TfL) has a strategic transport role, including highways powers; and therefore London can and has implemented extensive priority measures and demand management for private vehicles in the form of the congestion charge. As the Transport Committee reported, in effect Integrated Transport Authorities (ITAs)188 could use a 182 op cit., Local bus passenger journeys (BUS0103) op cit., Subsidies and concessions (BUS0502) 184 “Franchising and the cost of buses in London: some facts”, TAS blog, 29 July 2011 185 op cit., Local bus services market investigation, paras 15.450-51 186 Nexus, Proposal for a Quality Contracts Scheme in Tyne and Wear, July 2013, p8 187 op cit., Bus services across the UK, para 32 188 ITAs are what used to be called Passenger Transport Authorities; pteg continues to speak for ITAs as a whole 183 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 66 combination of their existing powers and QCS to implement schemes which would have similar effects as franchising in the capital.189 The ITAs disputed this.190 In its August 2006 report for pteg, NERA stated, much as the Transport Committee had, that while a QCS might be expected to deliver the step-change in quality that could encourage increased bus use, there were likely to be “significant public sector budgetary implications from achieving this”. In addition, NERA took the view that the success of Contracts or franchising would also require potentially unpopular policies to control demand for the private car: ... greater controls on the use of the car in city centres, by means of controls on city centre parking supply and pricing, improved management of main radial traffic capacity with priorities for buses and, where appropriate, increased provision of park-and-ride schemes. Eventually, congestion-related charging for car users would need to become part of the policy implemented to increase bus use. It is difficult to see this becoming possible without local authority control of the key bus service and fare parameters. The full budgetary implications would be dependent upon the degree to which other measures were employed, notably the extent to which increases in peak capacity were required and the commitment to raising revenue from motorists.191 The ITAs had looked forward to the Competition Commission making some sort of recommendation on franchising in its 2011 report. The CC did not recommend franchising but it did acknowledge that: ... there is existing legislation enabling LTAs to introduce franchising in England, Scotland and Wales [i.e. QCS] and we would not wish to rule out its future application in particular local markets where the respective legislative requirements are met. We also note that LTAs have wider social and policy objectives that are not relevant to this investigation, but which may legitimately lead them to take a different view on the desirability of introducing franchising in relation to the local bus markets for which they are accountable.192 What do we do about the bus pass in England? Note: provision of concessionary fares is devolved across the UK. Scotland, Wales and Northern Ireland have their own schemes and these are not discussed here.193 It costs approximately £1.17 billion per annum to provide the statutory free local bus travel concession in England.194 This is an increase of £117 million since the concession was introduced. In 2013/14 there 189 ibid., paras 32-33 ibid., para 34 191 op cit., The Decline in Bus Services in the English PTE areas, p38 192 op cit., Local bus services market investigation, para 69; the CC’s detailed analysis as to why it did not recommend the introduction of franchising is given in paras 15.343-15.470 of the report 193 for further information on these schemes see sections 6, 7 and 8 of HC Library briefing paper SN1499 194 DfT, Concessionary travel (BUS0811), 16 December 2014 190 67 Transport 2015 were 9.73 million concessionary travel passes issued across England, this puts the average cost at £120 per pass.195 In 2007 the Labour Government legislated to provide free local bus travel for older and disabled people across the whole of England from 1 April 2008.196 It further legislated to increase the qualifying age for the bus pass in line with the rising female state pension age from April 2010 onwards.197 On current plans this would see it increase to 66 by 2020. The bus pass is phenomenally popular amongst older and disabled people: as of 2014 approximately four fifths of those eligible for the bus pass take it up; in London take up is essentially universal.198 It is clear that those in receipt of the bus pass highly value the freedom and independence it gives them. It is also worth noting that across the English local bus network more than one in five journeys is made using a concessionary pass.199 It is not clear whether some of these services could survive without this cohort of passengers. There are those who argue that the universal bus pass is simply not financially viable; that the universality of the bus pass is a waste of resources and that the significant amount of money put aside for bus passes could be better spent if older recipients were means tested. The money saved from not providing the bus pass to those with means to purchase their own bus tickets could be spent on other things, for example a new concession for younger people in higher education or those actively looking for work. In a December 2014 interview Martin Griffiths, chief executive of Stagecoach, said: Are there some passengers who board our buses who could probably afford to pay? Of course they could. As a voter, I want to know bus services are going to be protected. They have to decide what is the prioritisation. They can’t be dishonest just because these people vote – 8 million of them, they all vote … so ooh, don’t tamper with the concession scheme. Politicians are being disingenuous with all of us.200 As indicated above, all major parties committed to protecting the free bus pass for older people in their 2015 manifestos. However, supporters of all three main parties have recommended that they look at means testing so-called ‘middle class benefits’ such as the statutory bus concession after the election.201 Support for the idea 195 ibid., Concessionary travel (BUS0811 and 0820) Concessionary Bus Travel Act 2007; for information see HC Library briefing papers RP 07/19 and RP 07/53 197 Travel Concessions (Eligibility) (England) Order 2010 (SI 2010/459) 198 op cit., Concessionary travel (BUS0820) 199 op cit., Concessionary travel (BUS0821) and Local bus passenger journeys (BUS0103) 200 “Stagecoach boss: free bus travel comes at a cost”, The Guardian, 10 December 2014 201 see, e.g.: “Nick Boles is right to put universal benefits on notice”, Conservative Home, 10 July 2012; “Ed should pledge to scrap ‘middle class benefits’”, Prospect blog, 13 February 2013; and: “Nick Clegg: pensioners' benefits should be means tested”, The Daily Telegraph, 4 December 2011 196 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 68 has also come from the Social Market Foundation and the Centre for Policy Studies.202 202 SMF, Osborne’s Choice, February 2012, p29; and: CPS, 2012 Budget: 21 policies for growth and wealth creation, March 2012, p2 69 Transport 2015 5. Policy focus 3: rail franchising 5.1 What’s the issue? Rail travel is expensive There are two aspects to this: the railway itself costs too much to run (for a number of reasons) and the cost of rail travel for passengers has been increasing year-on-year from an already relatively high base. Before the 2010 General Election the then Secretary of State for Transport, Lord Andrew Adonis, announced that the Department for Transport and the regulator would jointly sponsor a value for money review of the rail industry, to be be undertaken by Sir Roy McNulty, the former Chairman of the Civil Aviation Authority (CAA).203 Sir Roy published his final report [the ‘McNulty Report’] in May 2011. He concluded that the UK rail industry should be looking to achieve efficiency savings of approximately 30 per cent by 2019 and proposed recommendations that, together, could deliver cost savings of between £700 million and £1 billion per annum by 2019. McNulty found that there were ten principle barriers to efficiency in the rail industry, including: fragmentation of rail industry structures and interfaces; the way in which major players in the industry have operated; roles of government and industry; nature and effectiveness of incentives; legal and contractual frameworks; and relationships and culture within the industry.204 McNulty identified a number of areas where the GB railway was performing less well than those in other European countries. In particular he highlighted that other European countries had obtained significant cost reductions from the competitive tendering of services, compared to a 17.1 per cent increase in the unit costs of franchised services in GB (after allowing for changes in service frequency and train length) between 1996/97 and 2005/06.205 He also highlighted an efficiency gap between Network Rail (NR) and the top-performing European railways of between 34 and 40 per cent.206 Work by Infrastructure UK further revealed that: 203 an examination of seven high speed lines across Europe showed that construction costs in the UK were significantly higher, and when compared with the four most directly comparable projects, HS1 costs were at least 23 per cent higher; comparisons of station development costs indicated that the UK was 50 per cent more expensive, for example, than Spain; and HMT, Pre-Budget Report, Cm 7747, December 2009, p110 ORR press notice, “Efficiency savings the key to substantial rail industry growth”, 19 May 2011 205 Sir Roy McNulty for DfT/ORR, Realising the Potential of GB Rail: Final Independent Report of the Rail Value for Money Study, May 2011, p34 206 ibid., p32 204 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 70 total outturn costs that involve significant tunnelling were more expensive than Europe, suggesting higher pre-construction and indirect costs.207 In terms of the cost to passengers (i.e. ticket prices), the average cost per passenger kilometre increased from £0.09 in 2001 to £0.14 in 2013/14; an increase of 54%. In real terms, the increase is 14%.208 Around 45 per cent of fares are subject to regulation. Between 2004 and 2013 annual rises in regulated fares were limited to an average of RPI+1 per cent; since 2014 this limited has been set at RPI. In addition, train companies have traditionally been able to apply the ‘fares basket’ or ‘flex’ rules, which permit them to vary their increases. This has generally been limited to 5 per cent, but was reduced to 2 per cent for 2014 and was abolished for both 2010 and again for 2015. This has resulted in wide variations – for example, in July 2009 the RPI was – 1.4 per cent, so regulated fares for 2010-11 fell by an average 0.4 per cent from January 2010; by way of contrast, in July 2011 the RPI was 5 per cent, so regulated fares for 2012-13 rose by an average 6 per cent from January 2012. In January 2015 all fares rose by an average of 2.2 per cent. This was less than the anticipated 2.5 per cent rise for regulated fares, based on a July 2014 RPI of 2.5 per cent. All other fares are set at a commercial rate by the train operators. Privatisation has been a failure The most cogent case against privatisation has been made by the rail unions. In their June 2012 research report, Rebuilding Rail, commissioned by Aslef, the RMT, TSSA and Unite, Transport for Quality of Life set out the case against privatisation. It argued that the privatised railway is too expensive and too complex, leading to high ticket prices, inefficiencies and a service run for the benefit of shareholders rather than passengers. In summary, it said: There is a widespread concern – shared across the political spectrum – that we are not getting good value from the substantial sums of public money that are invested in the railways every year. Since privatisation, the cost to the public purse of running the railways has risen by a factor of between two and three times … Over the same period, the money going into the railways from passenger fares has also increased in real terms. Much of the increase in cost may be attributed to fundamental problems with the complex privatised railway structure created by the Conservative Government in 1994. Key reasons for the increase in cost include higher interest payments in order to keep Network Rail’s debts off the government balance sheet; debt write-offs; costs arising as a result of fragmentation of the rail system into many organisations; profit margins of complex tiers of contractors and sub-contractors; and dividend payments to private investors. 207 208 ibid., p33 DfT, Rail usage, infrastructure and performance (RAI0103) and Rail finance (RAI0301), 11 December 2014; note: price per passenger km is the best measurement because it takes out the effect of a different proportion of journeys being taken on season as opposed to other tickets 71 Transport 2015 […] The current structure of the railways affects passengers in several ways. Britain has Europe’s highest commuter fares for both day returns and season tickets. Ticket purchase is excessively complex. When things go wrong, there is a lack of clear accountability. […] [I]nnovation is discouraged by the complex and fragmented structure of the privatised railway, and is more difficult now than it was before the railways were privatised. The hoped-for innovation has not materialised. Genuine at-risk private investment (as opposed to private capital expenditure that is underwritten by the Government) makes an insignificant contribution to the railways, representing of the order of one per cent of the total money that goes into the railway each year. This is substantially less than the additional costs posed by the privatised structure. Privatisation has also failed to increase the efficiency of the railways. Notably, this appears to be due to increased numbers of administrators and managers … Fragmentation has produced duplication of functions in the different private companies and new staff to deal with all the interfaces between those companies.209 A 2013 report for the TUC by the Centre for Research on SocioCultural Change (CRESC) at the University of Manchester, stated that the privatised rail network was “a serial shambles creating artificial profits for the franchise holders and hidden costs for the public”: … the privatised rail system requires billions more in tax payer subsidy each year … and has failed to bring in adequate private investment in track or trains … so that average age of rolling stock has actually increased … Rail privatisation created a situation whereby risk and investment averse private companies positioned themselves as value extractors, thanks to high public subsidies. Government effectively took the operating risk, covering operating deficits and supplying investment funds. 210 Compass, the left-of-centre pressure group, argued in 2014 that: The figures, facts and experiences speak for themselves – rail privatisation just hasn’t worked. It was both ill-conceived and poorly executed. Trains are often either over crowded or empty as they run alongside congested motorways. Pricing people off trains is hardly a solution in a world in which connectivity is increasingly both economically and socially essential. The system is fragmented, bureaucratic and wasteful. […] The system is broken and it needs fixing, but it is more than facts and figures that are wrong. What we are losing is something equally precious – places and spaces in which we aren’t just consumers of rail but equal citizens. Railways and trains can’t just be sliced and diced, commoditised and privatised without a great national sense of moral, cultural and emotional loss. Stations and trains are one of the few places left where we literally rub shoulders as equals. Trains don’t just connect the country geographically but socially and culturally. They help build a sense of national, regional and local pride as well as collective identity. This experience should be joyful and rich – not cheap and tacky. When we travel, in public with others, the experience should profit our wellbeing 209 210 TfQL, Rebuilding Rail, June 2012, pp7-8 CRESC, The Great Train Robbery: privatisation and after, June 2013, p14 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 72 not just the bank accounts of those companies taking no risk and making little, if any investment. No railway in the world makes a profit. Pretending they do leaves us all feeling worse off – financially and morally. […] The crux of the issue is that if you want a ‘public service railway’ it will require public subsidy. Passenger revenue alone will not fund a railway that meets social, environmental and wider economic need. So a truly stand-alone commercial solution is untenable, unless you ran a very small number of lines at peak hours only. Given this, it would make sense to maximise efficiency and value for money by retaining that investment within the public service, without leaking public money into private hands. If the private sector was adding significant levels of investment, innovation and efficiency then fair enough, but they clearly aren’t.211 5.2 What is privatisation and why was it introduced? The fundamental objective of advocates of privatisation was to free the nationalised industries from bureaucracy and political intervention and to replace these forces with the disciplines of the market, in the expectation that this would lead to greater efficiency, lower unit costs and a better allocation of resources. The corollary of this, usually welcomed by management, was that enterprises were freed from constraints on investment and on funding imposed as part of public expenditure controls. It was also argued that the very process of privatisation forced consideration of all the rights, duties and constraints affecting an enterprise, which was the basis for a far better identification of social objectives and their means of achievement than the historic process of control of nationalised industries. Opponents of privatisation argued that it was primarily a convenient way of abandoning the traditional social duties of the public enterprise, and of renegotiating, to the disadvantage of employees, their terms of employment. Further, the goals of reduced bureaucracy, greater efficiency, lower unit costs and better allocation of resources would not necessarily result from privatisation and could be achieved by other means. 212 What did the rail market look like before the 1990s? British Rail (BR) was a public corporation established under section 1 of the Transport Act 1962 as a successor to the rail and shipping activities of the British Transport Commission.213 The British Rail Board operated passenger and freight services within Great Britain 211 Compass, All on Board: A publicly owned railway for an interconnected world, July 2014, pp4-6 212 Transport Committee, Financing of Rail Services (third report of session 1986-87), HC 383, 13 May 1987, para 232 213 the BTC was established under the Transport Act 1947 to provide "an efficient, adequate, economical and properly integrated system of public inland transport and port facilities within Great Britain for passengers and goods", excluding transport by air and came into operation on 1 January 1948 when the various interests in shipping, railways, hotels and road transport that were nationalised 73 Transport 2015 and was almost entirely vertically integrated, that is to say it owned its own trains, infrastructure and carried out almost all track and train maintenance itself. Under state control, the railways were expected to run economically but also to cater for not always clearly defined social needs. In compliance with European rules it also operated passenger services on a non-commercial basis where so directed by the Secretary of State.214 The Secretary of State paid BR a grant to cover the cost of providing any loss-making services. The Secretary of State for Transport exercised a number of controls over the BR Board, such as appointment of the Chairman and Board members; setting the external financing limit (EFL) and the public service obligation (PSO) grant; determining the Board’s investment allocation and approval of major investment projects; setting borrowing limits; having the final say on station closures and service cancellations; setting financial targets; and agreeing the business plans. He also approved changes in the organisation of the Board; extensions of BR's fields of activities; and the disposal of businesses and assets. Many of the powers were procedural, or related to financial propriety. The Secretary of State also had various safety and regulatory powers under railways legislation.215 During the 1980s BR was encouraged to develop greater commercial awareness. It did this by reorganising its business and objectives, privatising its ‘non-core’ activities and encouraging private sector involvement.216 These initiatives contributed to BR’s major organisational transformation in the decade preceding its privatisation. The Conservative Government's determination to reduce the level of subsidy flowing to the public sector railway stimulated a drive within BR for substantial efficiency improvements. Central to these reforms was the partial replacement of the existing structure based on regions by one formed around distinct rail business sectors, each with managers meeting objectives in terms of marketing, cost allocation and investment decisions. A further reform came in 1991 with the launch of ‘Organising for Quality’. Completed by April 1992, this initiative finally abolished the old regions (which had continued to physically run the trains) and defined separate profit centres within each of the business sectors. In some respects the substantial reorganisation and the accompanying efficiency improvements undertaken by BR in its final decade generated the conditions that made privatisation a more viable policy. The new business sectors formed at least part of the basis for the privatised railway and showed that the system could be operated as a series of relatively independent components, rather than as a monolithic structure. The reorganisation also led to a called ‘public service obligations’ (PSOs), made under State Aid rules; more information on EU rail policy can be found in HC Library briefing paper SN184 215 powers derived mainly from the Transport Act 1962, Transport Act 1968, Railways Act 1974, Transport Act 1980 and Transport Act 1981 216 for further information see HC Library briefing paper SN1157 214 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 74 marked reduction in the PSO payments paid direct to BR in support of loss-making services.217 As a consequence of all these changes, by the late 1980s BR could be said to be doing well, but after the good times of 1980s, BR's finances collapsed in the early 1990s largely because of increased expenditure on safety following the 1988 Clapham rail crash, the costs of improving lines to the Channel Tunnel and perhaps above all because of the recession, which saw usage fall by ten per cent.218 Policy decision by the Conservative Government Privatisation of the railways had been discussed intermittently since the 1960s and there was apparently an idea to float the Southern Region of BR after the 1979 election, but this never went anywhere. Mrs Thatcher finally agreed to the policy in late 1990, shortly before she left office. John Major was initially more enthusiastic, though the driving force behind the proposal appears to have been the Treasury. There was later confusion between various models of privatisation proposed by the Treasury and alternative suggestions or ‘hints’ from the then Transport Secretary, Malcolm Rifkind and the Prime Minister.219 At the Conservative Party conference in 1988 the then Secretary of State for Transport, Paul Channon, announced his intention to look at the future of BR to see whether privatisation might be a viable way forward. Publication of a White Paper, promised for the end of 1991, was delayed until after the 1992 General Election. The first indication of the Government's intentions came therefore in the Conservative Party manifesto for that election. This stated that: … the best way to produce profound and lasting improvements on the railways is to end BR's state monopoly. We want to restore the pride and local commitment that died with nationalisation. We want to give the private sector the opportunity to operate existing rail services and introduce new ones, for both passengers and freight […] Our plans for the railways are designed to bring better services for all passengers as rapidly as possible. We believe that franchising provides the best way of achieving that. Long term, as performance improves and services become more commercially attractive as a result of bringing in private sector disciplines, it will make sense to consider whether some services can be sold outright.220 The 1992 Queen’s Speech promised that “legislation will be introduced to enable the private sector to operate rail services”.221 On 7 May a ‘paving’ Bill was introduced to confer on the BR Board “powers to participate in the implementation of proposals for the transfer of their commercial activities to the private sector and 217 Transport Committee, Railway finances (fourth report of session 1994-95), HC 206, 5 July 1995, para 9 218 ibid., paras 16-20 219 Wolmar, Christian, Broken Rails: How Privatisation wrecked Britain’s railways (2002), chapter 4 220 Conservative Party,1992 Conservative Party General Election Manifesto: The Best Future for Britain, April 1992, p35 221 HC Deb 6 May 1992, c51 75 Transport 2015 proposals for the establishment of new arrangements with respect to their other functions”.222 In July 1992 the Government published its White Paper outlining proposals for privatising British Rail (BR).223 The core of the Government's proposals was the greater involvement of the private sector in the running of the railways through the sale of some of the BR businesses and the progressive contracting out of the management of passenger services. The principal organisational means of achieving these objectives was the separation of responsibilities for track and operations. The Railways Bill 1992-93 was published on 22 January 1993 and had its Second Reading on 2 February.224 The Bill was essentially an enabling measure, leaving a large degree of discretion to the Secretary of State, the regulator, and Franchising Director. Further, there was no mention anywhere in the Bill of Railtrack – an indication of the sweeping nature of the powers contained in Part II, which enabled the Secretary of State to restructure BR in any way he thought fit. The proposals excited much comment. The Transport Committee published a report on the subject in April 1993 which concluded: It is clear that in terms of previous international railways experience, the form of privatisation adopted by the UK Government is both novel and experimental (in the sense of being untested). It is true that some elements of the Government's proposals have been put into practice or contemplated in various parts of the world. Yet in no country with a rail system of comparable size and density of use is there an example, either in operation or even under consideration, of a complete scheme such as that contained in the Railways Bill. This does not of itself mean that it cannot succeed. To take that argument to its logical conclusion would mean that no innovation ever took place. What it does mean, however, is that because of the lack of previous experience to draw upon, the risk that something could go badly wrong is that much higher. To put it another way, the system of railway operation proposed by the Government probably can work, but, in the words of one witness, it may need to be made to work. The onus lies firmly on the Government to demonstrate that its plans will provide a better service to the travelling public. If all the Government's assumptions are correct about such matter as: 222 the prospects for investment; the practicality of the relationship between Railtrack and operating companies; the British Coal and British Rail (Transfer Proposals) Act 1993 received Royal Assent on 18 January 1993; the Secretary of State explained the purpose of the Bill at Second Reading, see: HC Deb 18 May 1992, cc22-35 223 DoT, New opportunities for the railways: the privatisation of British Rail, Cm 2012, July 1992; this was accompanied by a statement to the House on 14 July, see: HC Deb 14 July 1992, cc971-72; there were further debates on the White Paper in October 1992 (HC Deb 29 October 1992, cc1160-1222) and on an Opposition motion opposing privatisation in January 1993 (HC Deb 12 January 1993, cc771869) 224 HC Deb 2 February 1993, cc156-255 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 76 the response of the private sector to the new opportunities on offer; and the feasibility of combining open access with franchising then there may be the potential for an improved railway system. Whether the Government is right in these assumptions is a matter of political judgement. The final verdict will rest with rail users. 225 Railways Act 1993 The Railways Act 1993 received Royal Assent on 5 November 1993. Part I set out the respective powers and duties of the Secretary of State, the regulator and the Franchising Director. It also specified line closure procedures, conferred upon the High Court powers to issue Railway Administration Orders in the event of default by independent railway operators, and established machinery for consumer representation. Part II related to the Secretary of State's powers to direct BR to reorganise itself and to form companies for various purposes, including franchising and disposal. Part III of the Act contained miscellaneous provisions relating to safety, railway heritage, the British Transport Police, pensions, freight, financial assistance to BR staff in the preparation of management buy-outs or franchise bids, and other matters. Many of the principal changes were brought into effect on 1 April 1994. The legislation radically changed the structure of the railway industry by separating the responsibility for infrastructure and passenger service operations. BR was divided into a body known as Railtrack on the one hand, and a residual BR operating company to run all the other services until they were sold or franchised. The Office of Rail and Road (ORR) was set up to oversee the charges to be levied by Railtrack for the use of the infrastructure.226 5.3 What happened after privatisation? There were a number of problems with the railways in the five years or so after privatisation – some to do with the actual privatisation itself and others due to secondary factors that were not directly linked to the structure of the industry after 1993. Some of these might have been anticipated in the run up to and during privatisation and dealt with but for one reason or another were not. For example, it is debatable as to whether there was sufficient discussion about the structure of the privatisation – Railtrack was not mentioned in the 1993 Act and Ministers were not clear what form the new infrastructure company would take; the requirement for competition and open access was never seriously tackled; and the question of continued public subsidy was largely overlooked. The desire to complete the privatisation before the 1997 General Election, 225 Transport Committee, The Future of the Railways in the Light of the Government's White Paper Proposals (second report of session 1992-93), HC 246, April 1993, paras 523-524 226 this is the rail regulator, it changed its name on 1 April 2015 to include reference to its new role regarding Highways England; for further information on the history of ORR see HC Library briefing paper SN2071 77 Transport 2015 combined with Labour being so far ahead in the polls and committed to renationalisation, led to confusion and issues with methods of sale of the various parts of the industry.227 Privatisation itself involved breaking up BR into around 100 component companies, introducing complexity, and the powers available to the regulator were often unwieldy. The relations between the component parts of the industry were also perhaps over legalistic to the point of engendering confrontation and antagonism rather than co-ordination and cooperation. The privatised railway itself lacked a long term planning body with the sort of strategic duties BR had and Railtrack arguably lacked knowledge of its asset base, contributing to later problems (e.g. dealing with the aftermath of the Hatfield crash). At the beginning there was a lack of clarity about the roles of Franchising Director and Rail Regulator, leading to confusion and there were shortcomings in the range of ‘network benefits (e.g. ticket sales, National Rail Enquiries and passenger compensation). More fundamentally there was evidence of poor management particularly at Railtrack, which appeared to be inept at estimating the costs of large projects and managing its subcontractors while failing to reconcile its public interest objectives with the interest of its shareholders to maximise profits.228 That said, the railways in the immediate period after privatisation were not all bad. Until the Hatfield crash in October 2000, there was strong growth in both passenger and freight traffic; punctuality and reliability were slightly better than in the final years of BR and safety standards were gradually improving. The IPPR think tank wrote in 2002 that “privatisation arguably introduced some useful innovations, notably competition in the delivery of passenger and freight services, performance incentives linked to the passenger's charter, transparent regulation, security of funding and access to private finance for investment”.229 The rest of this section looks at developments subsequent to the immediate aftermath of privatisation. Labour’s May 1996 policy paper Consensus for Change: Labour’s Transport Policy for the 21st Century, said: “Labour is committed to a publicly owned and publicly accountable railway […] An incoming Labour government will use all the levers at its disposal to halt the damage of privatisation, reintegrate the network and generate higher levels of investment. On coming to office Labour will set in place a structured programme to return the railways to an integrated whole. We will build on what is left of British Rail to create a renewed publicly owned company which will be charged with reintegrating the network, protecting the public interest and organising public private partnerships to increase investment […] We will end the franchising process [and] give the powers of the franchising director to British Rail, who will supervise the franchises which have already been let and resume control of these lines when the contracts expire”. This was significantly watered down in the Labour Manifesto for 1997 and the promise to renationalise was removed 228 The Government's Response to the Environment, Transport and Regional Affairs Committee's Report on the Proposed Strategic Rail Authority and Railway Regulation, Cm 4024, July 1998 229 IPPR, Getting back on track, June 2002, executive summary 227 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 78 Service levels and costs At first the railways seem to have performed reasonably well following privatisation. More trains were running (around 1,700 more each day than before privatisation); 30 per cent more passengers were being carried in 2000/01 compared with 1994/95; the amount of freight lifted had increased 40 per cent in the same period; and both punctuality and reliability improved, although performance had declined since the high point of 1996/97.230 Railtrack's initial share price of 380 pence rose to 1,700 pence two years after privatisation, but by 2001 the position was very different and on 1 October 2001 the share price was 265 pence. From 1997/98 to 1999/2000 performance was roughly stable, but it experienced a sharp decline following the Hatfield accident in 2000.231 Railtrack Railtrack was set up on 1 April 1994 under the 1993 Act to manage the rail infrastructure (track, stations, etc.). It was sold to the private sector in May 1996. Railtrack's main sources of revenue were the charges it levied on train operators for track access and the lease income it received for stations and depots. Until 2001 Railtrack did not receive direct revenue subsidy from the Government although it was indirectly dependent on the significant amount of public sector support received by the train and freight operating companies. Railtrack plc was put into administration on 7 October 2001 and came out of it on 1 October 2002. Network Rail took over many of its responsibilities on 3 October.232 Railtrack’s difficulties came about for a variety of reasons. Those offered at the time included: lack of awareness about poor asset condition; privatisation was overly ambitious and financially risky; the complex contractual base of the privatisation; the extent and nature of Government and regulatory intervention; and poor management.233 All of this meant that by October 2001 Railtrack was insolvent, even if it was not bankrupt, and plans for some sort of restructure of Railtrack had been around for some months. The four most widely talked about at the time were: renationalisation (consistently ruled out by Ministers as too expensive);234 Railway Forum fact sheet, Britain’s growing railways (factsheet no. 1), 30 January 2001; and DfT, Rail usage, infrastructure and performance (RAI0101), 11 December 2014 231 DfT, Rail usage, infrastructure and performance (RAI0105), 11 December 2014 232 for more information on Railtrack and its administration see HC Library briefing papers SN1224 and SN1076 233 taken from contemporary comment, articles and reports, e.g. Christian Wolmar, Broken Rails: how privatisation wrecked Britain's railways, 2001; Lord Cullen/HSC, The Ladbroke Grove rail inquiry: Part 2 report, September 2001; "Cabinet simply watched as 'poll tax on wheels' went off the rails", The Times, 8 October 2001; "Disastrous round trip was marked by failure to maintain lines", The Times, 8 October 2001; "Watchdog's severe targets skewed company's judgement", The Times, 8 October 2001; and "Signal failure", The Sunday Times, 14 October 2001 234 because they would have had to buy the company shares at the full market value 230 79 Transport 2015 restructuring, whereby the Government would take an equity stake in the company, suspend the regulator and fund the company directly for a few years until it was in a better position (this was the favoured option of Railtrack’s directors, referred to as ‘Project Rainbow’); converting the company into a not-for-profit entity of some sort (‘Project Ariel’); or breaking up Railtrack into regional businesses. In the event the Government chose a variant of the third option; a decision that was not without controversy, largely to do with the way in which it chose to do it.235 On 7 October 2001 the then Secretary of State for Transport, Stephen Byers, petitioned a High Court judge to put Railtrack plc into ‘railway administration’ under section 60 of the 1993 Act and secondary legislation was discussed in Parliament the following month. Shares were suspended on 8 October.236 In court, the Government argued that Railtrack should be put into administration because the company at the time was then likely to be in the near future unable to pay its debts under section 60(2) of the 1993 Act (the formal test for an Order to be made). The Secretary of State at the time, Stephen Byers, said that he was not prepared to give Railtrack any further financial support.237 The administrators from Ernst & Young were responsible for the running of Railtrack during this period. Performance was not good and in December 2001 it was announced that John Armitt would take over as Railtrack Chief Executive. On 1 October 2002 a High Court judge released Railtrack from administration. On 3 October Network Rail took over its responsibilities. It had offered £500 million to Railtrack Group, including a £300 million Government subsidy.238 It also took on more than £7.5 billion debt and unquantified liabilities, including any potential criminal or civil liability arising from past accidents.239 Railtrack had about 256,000 shareholders holding approximately 520 million shares. According to the annual report, 82 per cent of the shares were held by institutional shareholders at 1 May 2002 (compared with 42 per cent on 20 May 1996). Many of the remainder were held by small shareholders who bought shares at privatisation or were employees of the company.240 Mr Byers made it clear that shareholders should have realised that the company was in dire 235 for the purposes of understanding the administration, please note that Railtrack Group plc was the company in which shareholders had shares; its main operating subsidiary was Railtrack plc, which was responsible for the management of the national rail infrastructure and it was this company that was placed in administration 236 the previous Friday they had closed at 280 pence a share, valuing the company at £1.46 billion 237 HC Deb 15 October 2001, c955 238 HC Deb 25 March 2002, cc581-82 239 HC Deb 17 July 2002, c327W 240 Railtrack Group plc, Railtrack Annual Report and Accounts, Year Ended 31 March 2002, October 2002, p69 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 80 financial straits and that there would be no compensation.241 There followed a legal battle after the Railtrack Private Shareholders issued a writ in the High Court against the Government on 2 December 2003 alleging ‘misfeasance’, i.e. that the Government and the then Secretary of State for Transport, Stephen Byers, acted within the law but in bad faith, and a breach of human rights for confiscation of assets. On 14 October 2005 the presiding judge dismissed the case against the Government. After the case was settled there was a wider debate as to the veracity of the Government’s statements about Railtrack’s financial viability in the petition to the High Court.242 In a debate in late 2005 the Conservative Party laid a motion for debate on the Labour Government’s conduct regarding the administration of Railtrack, charging that it had deliberately driven Railtrack into administration to, in effect, renationalise it for free.243 A lack of continuity In addition to Railtrack, there were other changes to the railway in the 15 years or so following privatisation that caused uncertainty. There was an almost constant complaint from the industry about Government ‘meddling’ with rail structures. In a 2004 paper for the Centre for the Study of Regulated Industries at the University of Bath School of Management, Stephen Glaister, Professor of Transport and Infrastructure, Imperial College London argued that Labour, having chosen (or adopted from the previous government) a particular model to deliver rail services, had a responsibility to maintain that policy unless there were ‘good reasons’ for changing it. Further: … whilst alternative models could have equally been made to work, the government has acted to undermine the chosen model - a competitive rail industry - without explicitly choosing an alternative model. This is likely to achieve the worst of all outcomes [that] acts as a cautionary tale for regulatory policy and accountability in general.244 During its 13 years in power Labour published three major rail White Papers, each proposing structural changes to the industry, during its five years in power the Coalition published one significant review and one White Paper. The biggest changes came about between 2000 and 2005, beginning with the Transport Act 2000 and ending with the Railways Act 2005 and the legislative changes contained therein, but this period also encompassed the collapse of Railtrack (see above), which had long term knock on consequences for the industry. 241 HC Deb 15 October 2001, c955 questions were initially asked by the Opposition during a debate in late 2001, see: HC Deb 13 November 2001, cc715-771 243 HC Deb 24 October 2005, cc30-31; for the Government’s rebuttal, see cc42-45 244 Stephen Glaister for the CRI, British Rail Privatisation: Competition destroyed by politics, Occasional Paper 23, 2004, preface, see also pp53-54 242 81 Transport 2015 Two areas which demonstrate this lack of continuity are the creation and abolition of the Strategic Rail Authority (SRA), all in the space of five years, and the ever-morphing remit of the Regulator.245 Following privatisation there was a great deal of criticism of the performance and reliability of the train companies, of Railtrack and the amount it was investing in the infrastructure and in the safety regime. Labour was particularly concerned about whether the Regulator had sufficient powers to deal with the private sector companies who ran the railways and about the supervision of public funds. With that in mind, its 1998 transport White Paper stated that the rail industry needed an element of stability and certainty if it was to plan its activities effectively.246 Particularly, the Government was concerned that there was “no focus within the privatised industry for long term strategic planning”; that the Franchising Director's remit was “too narrowly focused on the passenger railway”; that too many key policy decisions on the future of the rail industry lay in the hands of a statutorily independent regulator; that the sanctions available to the regulatory authorities were ‘unwieldy’; and that investment was not sufficiently prioritised.247 It therefore proposed setting up a Strategic Rail Authority (SRA) to address these problems, asserting that this would provide the rail industry with the strategic leadership lacking since privatisation and the fragmentation of the sector. It would ensure the railways were run in the public interest, would promote their use and would ensure they were properly integrated with other forms of transport. The SRA would tell the TOCs what services and network benefits the Government wanted to buy. It would ensure that the railway was properly integrated with other forms of transport and that the railway system was run as a network, not merely a collection of different businesses, particularly when franchises were re-let or re-negotiated. It would also ensure that the plans of freight operators were taken into account in the planning of the network as a whole. Part IV of the Transport Act 2000 gave statutory backing to the SRA from 1 February 2001. It transferred the functions, rights and liabilities of the Franchising Director and the residual functions, rights and liabilities of the British Railways Board (including responsibility for the British Transport Police) to the SRA. It set out its objectives and functions and established its structure and procedures and the terms and conditions of its members. The legislation also transferred the Regulator’s responsibilities for consumer protection to the SRA and the responsibility for railway closures to the Secretary of State. 245 further information on the SRA can be found in HC Library briefing paper SN1344; information on the regulator can be found in SN2071 246 op cit., A new deal for transport: better for everyone, para 4.22 247 The government's response to the environment, transport and regional affairs committee's report on the proposed strategic rail authority and rail regulation, Cm 4024, July 1998, paras 6-11; responding to: ETRA Committee, The proposed strategic rail authority and rail regulation (third report of session 1997-98), HC 286, 18 March 1998 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 82 The SRA was set up to provide leadership for the rail industry but it lacked the power to bring together the various elements of the industry. It did have some successes. For example, it helped to get a grip on major projects which were running out of control, such as the West Coast Main Line route modernisation project; it developed and implemented a strategy to upgrade the electricity supply for rail services south of the Thames; it began the process of reforming the franchising regime; and it promoted better use of the network through its Route Utilisation Strategies (RUS). The SRA also developed a stronger regional focus, working to promote community rail partnerships and to promote joint working between the different parts of the industry and to drive up performance.248 The problems in the rail industry, however, turned out to be greater than realised in 2000 – there was the aftermath of the Hatfield accident; increasing infrastructure costs; Railtrack’s entry into administration; and the subsequent transfer of its responsibilities to Network Rail. Consequently, the Regulator played a more pivotal role during these years and the SRA found itself in an increasingly difficult position. A leadership model based on influence and persuasion was not strong enough. As a result, the 2004 rail White Paper proposed that the SRA’s strategic and financial responsibilities would pass to the Department for Transport, as would its responsibility for awarding the passenger franchises. The Secretary of State would take responsibility for setting the national-level strategic outputs for the railway industry, in terms of capacity and performance. Operational matters would remain the clear responsibility of the industry. The SRA’s role in monitoring the performance of the train companies and drawing up timetables would be taken over by Network Rail.249 Section 1 and Schedule 1 of the Railways Act 2005 abolished the SRA and transferred its powers to the relevant bodies. This took place on 8 June 2005.250 The Regulator is responsible for a number of regulatory areas: ensuring that the rail network performs smoothly and, where it does not, to remedy any problems and hold those responsible to account. It is responsible for safety regulation, the performance of, access to and investment in the network. Its role has developed considerably since privatisation. Initially the Regulator was that – a singular person whose job was to issue and enforce the licenses held by the various parts of the industry to operate; enforce competition law; determine the track access charges paid by the train companies to Railtrack (later Network Rail); and protect consumers. The 2000 Act strengthened the power of the Regulator to require the improvement and development of the railway, for example by directing the owner of railway facilities such as stations and tracks to improve or replace them. The 2000 Act also imposed a new duty on the Regulator to have regard to "any general guidance from the SRA press notice, “Britain’s railway ‘rehabilitated’”, 15 July 2004 DfT, The future of rail, Cm 6233, July 2004 250 Railways Act 2005 (Commencement No. 1) Order 2005 (SI 2005/1444) 248 249 83 Transport 2015 Secretary of State about railway services or other matters relating to railways". Guidance was issued in September 2002 which emphasised the importance of working with Network Rail and others to secure a firm and sustainable financial foundation for the provision of railway infrastructure services.251 In July 2004 the Regulator was replaced with an Office of Rail Regulation (ORR) and in its 2004 rail White Paper the Labour Government announced its intention to transfer safety responsibility to the ORR. This was legislated for in the 2005 Act. The ORR became both the economic and safety regulator for the rail industry on 1 April 2006 when it took over the safety regulation responsibilities of the HSE. These include the power to authorise a person to investigate and make a special report on a major incident. West Coast re-let 2012 Since privatisation the vast majority of passenger rail services have been operated by franchisees who operate a contracted service on a particular part of the rail network under licence from the Government and the regulator. Franchising involves the Government setting out a specification for what it would like a franchise to do over a set period (level of service, upgrades, performance etc.). Companies then bid for the right to operate a franchise to that specification. The Government picks the company it thinks will deliver the best overall package for the franchise and give the best value for money. Franchise agreements include details of the performance standards that franchisees must meet and arrangements for the termination of a franchise in the case of failure to meet these standards.252 In 2012 the rail franchising system in England essentially collapsed, causing systemic and long term issues for the future franchising of rail services that will persist to the end of the decade. This was caused by the failure of one particular franchise re-let – for the West Coast franchise, run by Virgin Trains since 1997. Following the usual competitive tendering process, the Government awarded the West Coast franchise to First Group in August 2012. It was intended that the franchise would run until spring 2026, with an option to extend the franchise to the end of 2027.253 Following the announcement, there was an unprecedented level of debate about the award. Both First Group and Virgin discussed the franchise in the media and both the founder of Virgin Group, Sir Richard Branson, and the First Group chief executive, Tim O’Toole, appeared before the Transport Select Committee after Virgin announced that it would take the Department for Transport to Judicial Review over the award.254 251 DfT, Statutory guidance to the Rail Regulator, September 2002 for further information on rail franchising and the events summarised in this section, see HC Library briefing paper SN6521 253 DfT press notice, “New operator for West Coast rail passengers”, 15 August 2012 254 “Sir Richard Branson blasts 'flawed' bid system as Virgin Rail loses West Coast Main Line franchise to FirstGroup”, The Independent, 15 August 2012; and 252 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 84 However, before the hearing could take place the Secretary of State for Transport, Patrick McLoughlin, announced his decision to cancel the award following the “discovery of significant technical flaws in the way the franchise process was conducted”. The franchising process would therefore be re-started. Mr McLoughlin also announced two independent reviews: the first by Sam Laidlaw, Chief Executive of Centrica, to examine what happened during the West Coast procurement and why, and the second by Eurostar chairman Richard Brown to examine the wider rail franchising programme. In the meantime, the outstanding franchise competitions were ‘paused’ pending the outcome of the Brown Review, in order to ensure future competitions would be “robust and deliver best value for passengers and tax payers”.255 The Laidlaw Report was published in December 2012. The work of the inquiry was focused on the calculation of the Subordinated Loan Facility (SLF) for the West Coast franchise and the application of the relevant guidance to that calculation.256 Laidlaw’s main conclusion was that: “in seeking to run the complex and, in some respects, novel … franchise process, an accumulation of significant errors ... resulted in a flawed SLF sizing process. The responsibility for this flawed process rests with the DfT, rather than with any of its external advisers”.257 Laidlaw recommended a number of measures to help to restore confidence in the DfT’s conduct in rail franchising and procurement.258 The Department for Transport’s response to the report was published on the same day. This stated that the Laidlaw report made for ‘sombre reading’.259 Mr McLoughlin, said that the Department would “ensure that all future franchise competitions are delivered with a clear timeline, rigorous management and the right quality assurance” and that it would create a simpler and clearer structure and governance process for rail franchise competitions.260 The Brown Report was published in January 2013. Brown’s main conclusion was that “the rail industry works, and that there is no credible case for major structural change” but that “concerted effort is required on a significant, though manageable, number of key areas, from which lasting and tangible improvements will flow”.261 He made a number of recommendations to achieve this end.262 Looking forward, Brown urged that the franchising programme be restarted, but that the Department should be mindful of what it and the market could Transport Committee, Rail 2020 (seventh report of session 2012-13), HC 329-II, 7 January 2013, Ev 81+ 255 DfT press notice, “West Coast Main Line franchise competition cancelled”, 3 October 2012 256 the SLF is the amount of money the DfT requires the parent companies of bidders to put up to mitigate the risk of insolvency during the course of the franchise 257 DfT, Report of the Laidlaw Inquiry: Inquiry into the lessons learned for the Department for Transport from the InterCity West Coast Competition, HC 809, 6 December 2012, para 3.1 258 ibid., para 3.13-3.14 259 DfT, Response to the Report of the Laidlaw Inquiry, 6 December 2012, para 2 260 HC Deb 6 December 2012, cc1018-19 261 DfT, The Brown Review of the Rail Franchising Programme, Cm 8526, January 2013, para 1.4 262 ibid., para 1.11-1.20 85 Transport 2015 resource, and seek to avoid ‘bunching’ franchises, increasing the vulnerability of the programme to peaks and troughs in the economic cycle.263 The Government responded to the Brown Report by announcing a new franchising schedule that would provide “a more sustainable schedule for rail franchising by delivering no more than 3 to 4 competitions per year, and staggering the 2 principal Intercity franchises, West Coast and East Coast, so they will not be let at the same point in the economic cycle”.264 The schedule has been updated twice since then, most recently in October 2014.265 The practical consequence of this is that there have been an increasing number of ‘Direct Awards’ rather than fully competitive refranchising of lines since 2013 [see section 5.6, for more information]. 5.4 Who supports privatisation and why? As indicated in the other parts of this section, since the early 1990s there has been continued criticism of the privatised rail system, from those who want to see more integration and public ownership to those who want to see more private competition. However, the existing system does have its supporters: notably the companies who bid for and operate the rail franchises and who own the freight and train companies. The Rail Delivery Group (RDG), set up in 2011 on the back of the McNulty Report (see above), and made up of representatives of all the industry’s main players, has said that the success of the railways since they left public ownership is ‘inarguable’ in terms of annual growth: The industry has plenty to be proud of over what it has achieved in recent years. We have increased capacity not so much by laying hundreds of miles of new track, but by using the network much more intensively through a modest increase in the size of a modernised fleet. We have seen reliability of the network improved very significantly following the challenges posed to us after the Hatfield incident back in the early 90s… 266 Sir Richard Branson, the founder of Virgin Group, which under its Virgin Trains moniker operates services on the East and West Coast main lines, praised the investment of previous private incumbents of the East Coast long distance franchise when Virgin took over the route in March 2015. He said: “since the bad old days of nationalisation, there have been improvements under various operators such as GNER, so we’re not starting from ground zero like we were with the West Coast line [which Virgin took over in 1997 from British Rail]”.267 He also criticised the recent interest in returning the railways to public ownership: “I think even China has realised that government-run businesses don’t work, and in Russia they are beginning to realise that too, so it’s very strange to hear people 263 ibid., paras 1.21 HC Deb 26 March 2013, cc95-98WS 265 DfT, Rail franchise schedule, 10 October 2014 266 “Railroad to Recovery”, The House Magazine, 31 October 2014 267 “Leave Britain's railways alone, Branson tells Labour”, Daily Telegraph, 7 March 2015 264 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 86 talking about switching the clock back to nationalisation and all the horrors that went with it”.268 Successive governments (Labour and Conservative-Liberal Democrat) have all broadly backed the franchising system as a good mix of public and private which has delivered benefits for passengers. In its 2010 rail franchising review the Labour Government said: “as a system, franchising is largely delivering well for both passengers and taxpayers”, though “a greater emphasis on encouraging operator-led improvements and removing current barriers to investment will help rail meet passenger expectations in the coming years, while still delivering good value”.269 A few months later in its rail franchising review the Coalition Government looked at how to unlock further benefits from the franchising model: The Government believes that the existing system of rail franchising has become too prescriptive at the point of bidding, and lacks flexibility once operational. Arguably, the Government now exercises more control over the railways than in the days of British Rail. As set out in the Coalition Agreement, we believe significant private investment could be released by granting longer franchises, resulting in important benefits for passengers […] We also need to move away from a system which sees Whitehall specifying highly detailed and prescriptive inputs in franchises. Instead, we want to see a stronger focus on the quality of outcomes for passengers, giving more flexibility to the professionals who run our railways to apply innovation and enterprise in working out the best way to deliver those outcomes.270 More recently, in the New Statesman, George Eaton reported a Labour spokesman’s view that “the party recognised that there had been some benefits from privatisation, for instance improved customer service” and that it had “no ideological objection to the public sector, we have no ideological objection to the private sector either”.271 5.5 What are the alternatives? There have been many suggestions for reforming the way the rail network currently operates and dealing with its perceived failures. These range across the spectrum from renationalisation to ‘privatisation plus’. Going into the 2015 election, the two parties that formed the Coalition Government after 2010 broadly committed to retaining the current system but driving for more efficiencies and better performance. Labour proposed a slightly more radical approach, including the introduction of a public service operator for rail franchises. 268 ibid. DfT, The Future of Rail Franchising, January 2010, p5 270 DfT, Reforming Rail Franchising, July 2010, p4 271 “Why Labour hasn't pledged to fully renationalise the railways”, The Staggers, 18 July 2014 269 87 Transport 2015 Nationalisation As set out in section 6.1, above, there are some who believe that the privatised rail network has been a failure and that it should be renationalised and reintegrated. This is usually perceived as a gradual process which would take a number of years – train services would not be renationalised in a ‘big bang’ but taken back in-house as they came up for renewal. Network Rail (which owns the infrastructure) is already a public sector company. Some also advocate the renationalisation of freight services and the rolling stock companies that own the trains. Cost estimates for this vary – advocates argue that overall the process would save the taxpayer money. Renationalisation is broadly supported by the general public: a May 2014 YouGov poll found that British people supported renationalising the railways by 60 per cent to 20 per cent. The main reason given was that the railways should be accountable to taxpayers rather than shareholders.272 The main proponents of renationalising the rail network are the rail unions. Their 2012 policy paper, Rebuilding Rail, set out a possible governance structure for a nationalised and integrated ‘GB Rail’, derived from the Deutsche Bahn governance structure in Germany but modified to give broader accountability:273 YouGov press notice, “Why the public want to nationalise the railways”, 11 May 2014 273 op cit., Rebuilding Rail, p72 272 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 88 In effect, the system they proposed was one where the existing infrastructure manager, Network Rail (NR), would become GB Rail Network & Operations, with its ‘essential functions’ of allocating and charging for network capacity hived off to GB Rail Access, but otherwise its current network operations could continue largely intact. Thereafter, the organisational changes to NR would centre around building its capacity to run train operations. It would also involve changes to rolling stock (train) procurement, whereby GB Rail would be able to procure new trains directly, using either government grant or government-backed debt. The report argued that procurement of rolling stock by GB Rail could be carried out in such a way as to support UK train manufacturing industry.274 A slightly different model was proposed by the Centre for Research on Socio-Cultural Change (CRESC) in 2013. They proposed a similar scenario where the contracts of the train and rolling stock companies were brought to an end and a new entity, ‘National Rail’ would be set up to manage and operate trains and infrastructure, built around the core of NR.275 However, ultimately it envisaged a more defuse, regional model of rail provision to “provide a framework for political accountability and financial cross-subsidy as long as the railway system has to provide both an integrated national network and intra274 275 ibid., pp73-4 op cit., The Great Train Robbery: privatisation and after, p162 89 Transport 2015 regional services”. Further, it argued that if regional governments had tax raising powers, in areas like Wales or the North East, some of the regional requirement for subsidy and investment could be met by locally raised taxes while the rest could be met by transfer from the centre.276 Some sort of regionally or locally owned and run public railway has received support from other sources. Compass has said that while a nationally integrated system “is essential, accountability and innovation is best practiced where people are closest to the system”. Therefore, wherever possible, decisions should be made at the lowest possible level of the rail system “to ensure the most effective input of all stakeholders, whilst retaining the benefits of a nationally integrated system”.277 In 2014 Alex Burrows wrote for Progress, a ‘mainstream’ Labour pressure group, that regional rail networks should be set up and devolved from Whitehall to regional rail authorities “who can better judge – and deliver – what is required for their areas”.278 The Co-operative Party and Co-operatives UK have championed a different sort of mutually-owned and run railway. Its 2011 policy document began by arguing for: 276 Explicit ministerial encouragement for the principle of a co-operative for a national train operating company franchise with passenger and public membership. A rapid investigation by ORR on how to reduce barriers to new co-operative entrants and on how alternative models of ownership and finance should be recognised in the franchise process, such as making the encouragement of passenger and employee ownership a positive criterion in new franchises. Introducing a system to allow for the letting of local microfranchises working through existing Passenger Transport Executives, Local Enterprise Partnerships or their equivalent. Facilitating the entry of co-operative ventures as open access operator, by reducing the bureaucratic and financial hurdles they face. Encouraging Network Rail to explore and consult on different mutual options for its membership, with the goal of opening up to a full co-operative membership structure within three years. Promoting a co-operative model for any integrated rail companies covering both operations and infrastructure that emerge from the current review of structural changes.279 ibid., p159 op cit., All on Board: A publicly owned railway for an interconnected world, pp9-10 278 “Make rail regional”, Progress Online, 9 July 2014 279 Co-operatives UK, Co-operative rail: a radical solution, New Insight 6, 2011, p21 [written by Christian Wolmar, the noted transport commentator and a Labour candidate for Mayor of London in 2016] 277 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 90 This was followed in 2012 with a proposal for a mutually-run railway in Wales: a not-for-profit enterprise called Rail Cymru, with ‘strong’ representation from the Welsh Government, rail employees and passengers, and other key stakeholders in Wales and the English borders. Whilst it would not be a full co-operative, “its ethos would fully reflect co-operative principles of social responsibility, democracy, equity and service to the community”. It would operate as an armslength enterprise with ‘close and supportive relationships’ with the Welsh Government (its principal funder), which would specify the outputs required from Rail Cymru, and NR, which would remain the infrastructure manager.280 Green MP Caroline Lucas brought forward a Railways Bill in both the 2013/14 and 2014/15 sessions of Parliament to require the Secretary of State to assume control of passenger rail franchises when they came up for renewal. Neither Bill proceeded beyond First Reading.281 Public sector franchisees As set out above, in its 2015 manifesto Labour committed to “legislate so that a public sector operator is allowed to take on lines and challenge the private train operating companies on a level playing field”.282 The Conservative Government does not support this policy in England. However, under the proposals set out in the Smith Commission and the subsequent draft legislation published before the 2015 General Election, public sector bidders would be permitted for franchises let by the Scottish Government.283 Providing for a public sector franchisee would require primary legislation. Under section 25 of the Railways Act 1993, as amended, all public bodies are forbidden from bidding to operate a franchise.284 To change this one could repeal section 25 in its entirety, allowing any public body to bid to run a franchise, or amend that section to include within it an Order-making power allowing the Secretary of State to designate certain public sector bodies as eligible franchisees on an ad-hoc basis, as he or she saw fit and/or as bodies developed and changed (including e.g. Transport for London, Transport for Greater Manchester or other devolved entities). There might be other related considerations, such as how a public sector body would meet the “appropriate financial position” requirement under section 26(3). In October 2014 Labour MP Andy Sawford brought forward a Ten Minute Rule Bill in Parliament to provide for public sector rail operators. The Bill passed on Second Reading by 196 votes to 38 but did not proceed any further.285 Co-operative Party, Rail Cymru: A People’s Railway for Wales, November 2012 Railways Bill 2014-15 and Railways Bill 2013-14 282 op cit., Britain can be better: The Labour Party Manifesto 2015, p26 283 op cit., Scotland in the United Kingdom: An enduring settlement, pp71-2 284 this ban does not extend to train companies ultimately owned by foreign governments, such as the Netherlands, Germany and France, see e.g. RMT press notice, “Research shows three quarters of UK rail now foreign owned”, 13 October 2014 285 Railways (Public Sector Operators) Bill 2014-15; see also: HC Deb 29 October 2014, cc314-7 280 281 91 Transport 2015 Under this system of allowing public bodies to bid against private bodies to run rail franchises, there would be no guarantee that any public sector bidder would win a franchise. Furthermore, there would be the question of ensuring that the Government of the day (in the guise of the Department for Transport) was not unfairly favouring public sector operators, which would be against EU competition law. This could be addressed by establishing something along the lines of a new independent Office for Rail Passenger Franchising (OPRAF), as existed immediately after privatisation, to assess and award franchises. There could also be more wide-ranging effects: Martin Griffiths, chief executive of Stagecoach, told the FT in July 2014 that this might deter private sector companies from bidding for franchises. He said: “If you start to think it’s not going to be a level playing field then you may stop bidding and in that scenario we would be losing some of our expertise we have built up over a period of time”.286 It is worth noting that public bodies have not always been banned from bidding for franchises. During the Lords stages of what became the 1993 Act the Conservative peer Lord Peyton proposed an amendment to clause 22 (now section 25) allowing British Rail (BR) (or a wholly-owned subsidiary of BR) to become a franchisee. The amendment was agreed on the vote (150 to 112) and added to the Bill.287 When the amended clause 22 came back to the Commons the Government proposed its own amendments in lieu of Lord Peyton’s amendment.288 This amendment became section 25(4-9) of the original 1993 Act. It was repealed from 1 February 2001 by section 274 and Schedule 31 of the Transport Act 2000 and regulations made under it. This was because of the wider changes to railways in that Act, which abolished the Franchising Director and brought both his responsibilities and the residual British Railways Board (all that was left of BR by this time) within a new Strategic Rail Authority (SRA). Thus, worded as it was, it became obsolete. Originally, Labour intended to significantly broaden the power of what became the SRA regarding ‘operator or last resort’ and to effectively allow the SRA to run rail services as it saw fit. In the end, this did not happen. A Railways Bill, published in mid-1999, contained a proposal (clause 9) to give the SRA an express power to provide services for the carriage of passengers and goods by railway as it considered desirable. It could do anything it wished, apparently with no caveats, including providing and operating rail services. However, after Second Reading this Bill was referred to the Commons Environment, Transport and Regional Affairs Select Committee and as a result its provisions were amended and included within the portmanteau Transport Bill, published later in 1999. The “Stagecoach chief warns Labour rail reform would deter bids”, Financial Times, 9 July 2014 287 HC Deb 5 July 1993, cc1068- 1104 288 HC Deb 2 November 1993, cc214-18 286 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 92 original proposals in clause 9 of the Railways Bill were criticised by the Conservative Opposition and by several witnesses who appeared before the ETRA Committee. The Committee recommended in its report that the Government amend the Bill to make it clear that the SRA: … may only operate passenger rail services in the event that no satisfactory bid for a franchise has been received, or that a service has failed. The Bill should also establish the principle that the Authority may only directly operate services under conditions of service equivalent to those that apply to private sector rail companies, and that it should do so through a subsidiary company which has accounts separate to those of the Authority.289 This is the gist of the powers that ended up in the 2000 Act and were subsequently transferred to the Secretary of State after the SRA was abolished by the Railways Act 2005. More privatisation and ‘proper’ competition Some have argued that the failures of the current system – to deliver cheaper fares and better services – are a result of a compromised, ‘imperfect’ privatisation and that proper ‘on the track’ competition could rectify these problems. Stephen Glaister explained the problem back in 2004: The fundamental principle driving the British railways policy of the 1990s was not change of ownership (privatisation). It was the establishment of competition in every aspect of the business in order to achieve cost efficiency and also transparency of policy. The policy was designed so as to maximise the opportunities for effective competition whilst catering for natural monopoly in infrastructure and for the need to continue to pay subsidy in order to preserve the scale of the industry. It was successfully implemented and it started to produce some remarkably good results. We shall never know what the long term outcome might have been if the policy, once implemented had been left alone. It soon fell foul of, and was ultimately destroyed by, two phenomena. First policy risk: the Treasury proved to be unwilling to provide the public funds necessary to allow competition for passengers to operate as originally envisaged. Competition had to be ‘moderated’. There is doubt about whether the degree of on-rail competition originally envisaged in the white paper was even technically feasible. Also, a proper competition was not held for the right to provide by far the most important services to Railtrack, engineering, allegedly because that might have reduced the privatisation sale revenues for the Treasury. Finally, ministers were slow to make up their minds about exactly what they wanted, and execution of policy was unduly rushed because of a late decision to privatise Railtrack in advance of an impending general election. Secondly, political risk: governments proved, in practice, to be unwilling to tolerate the criticism that they feared they would attract if they had allowed the company failures which are essential to an effective competitive processes. When train 289 ETRA Committee, Railways Bill (twenty-first report of session 1998-99), HC 827, 10 November 1999, para 78 93 Transport 2015 operating companies failed government bailed them out. When Railtrack made a fatally bad investment and mismanaged its information systems, government again rescued it for a while, before intervening in a way that destroyed the normal competitive market for corporate control. This greatly weakened the mechanism whereby competitive markets deliver cost efficiency - transfer of the risks of incompetence or paying too much for inputs from the state to the private owners. Perhaps because of this, or perhaps because of other perceived political risks deriving from the special political sensitivities in relation to railway workers, the single most effective potential efficiency gain was not delivered. This would have been the introduction of a competitive market for labour. It had largely accounted for the success in previous privatisations of British utility companies, but unit labour costs in railways have run well ahead of average earnings.290 In 2011 Sir Roy McNulty summarised the main reason why successive governments have been reluctant to encourage ‘on-rail’ competition: The scope for expansion of on-rail competition is determined, to a large extent, by the degree to which Government would accept reduced revenues from franchise competition. It is unlikely that the Government would be willing to see a large expansion of on-rail competition while it continues to provide such a large financial contribution to the rail industry.291 Most recently, the most comprehensive case for more and better competition was put forward by Tony Lodge in a paper for the Centre for Policy Studies (CPS) in 2014. He argued that the principles of the 1992 White Paper had “been betrayed” as “franchised rail operators have an effective monopoly on the core long-distance routes, restricting vital competition”. Further, in those few areas where rail competition has emerged (primarily on the East Coast Main Line and in rail freight): … the benefits are clear: competition has led to new private investment, innovation, new routes, lower taxpayer subsidies, lower transparent fares, more journeys and happier passengers [while] strong competition on the freight network has led to significant investment in new rolling stock, high levels of productivity and reduced costs to satisfy customer demand … A small part of the passenger rail network is also open to some competitive pressures. On the East Coast Main Line (ECML), two non-subsidised “open access” operators – Grand Central and First Hull Trains – compete with the franchise holder East Coast. They have shown that competition leads to more journeys, higher revenues for the train companies, lower fares, more and happier passengers.292 To achieve this, the report recommended that the government place “far greater open-access competition … at the heart of future franchise agreements” and create a new Office of Rail Competition 290 op cit., British Rail Privatisation: Competition destroyed by politics, p53 op cit., Realising the Potential of GB Rail: Final Independent Report of the Rail Value for Money Study, p281 292 CPS press notice, “Rail's Second Chance”, 25 March 2014; for the full report see: Tony Lodge for the CPS, Rail’s second chance: Putting competition back on track, 25 March 2014 291 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 94 and Utilisation (ORCU) “with a clear mandate [to] facilitate and drive and deliver these new opportunities. Competition, not the protection of monopoly, must be the guiding principle behind reform”.293 5.6 Issues for the 2015 Parliament Why is rail travel so expensive? Rail travel has never been (nor for a large portion of its history was it seen desirable for it to be) subsidy-free, though one of the goals of privatisation was to reduce overall government subsidy to the rail industry.294 Indeed, in September 2011 the then Secretary of State for Transport, Philip Hammond, admitted to the Transport Committee the ‘uncomfortable fact’ that “the railway is already relatively a rich man’s toy - the whole railway. People who use the railway, on average, have significantly higher incomes than the population as a whole. That is a simple fact”.295 It is also true that some parts of the network require more subsidy than others.296 As indicated above, passengers and politicians all seem to agree to a greater or lesser extent that rail travel is too expensive and that the costs for passengers should come down. Parties have different policies for achieving this, generally they involve the industry itself cutting overall costs and becoming more efficient (e.g. under the McNulty recommendations and Network Rail’s quinquennial Periodic Review) and costs for the passenger coming down, both ‘naturally’ due to the above efficiency savings being passed on in unregulated fare prices and more directly by the Government controlling those regulated fare levels for which it is responsible. Others argue that the structure of the industry is at fault and that if the railways were renationalised fares would come down as a matter of course. Sir Roy McNulty did not believe this was necessarily the case. His 2011 report said that while there had been “many barriers to efficiency under the privatised structure, including the extent of the fragmentation of structures and interfaces and increased Government involvement”, that many of the arguments for renationalisation were formed from the failings of the existing system. McNulty argued that “much more can be gained by improving the performance of the current system rather than embarking on a costly programme of ibid., Rail’s second chance: Putting competition back on track, p40 this is discussed at length along with the immediate subsidy levels and costs of then then partial privatisation in a 1995 report by the Transport Committee, see op cit., Railway finances (fourth report of session 1994-95); more recently some have argued for the complete abolition of subsidy, see e.g. “Why are rail subsidies so high?”, IEA blog, 22 January 2013 295 Transport Committee, High Speed Rail (tenth report of session 2010–12), HC 1185-II, 8 November 2011, Ev 104, Q553 296 for financial support by train operating company, see: ORR, Government support to the rail industry by TOC - Table 1.7 [accessed 5 May 2015] 293 294 95 Transport 2015 renationalisation, which is unlikely to lead to an overall reduction in costs”.297 As indicated in section 5.5 above, proponents of some sort of renationalisation believe that the transition costs need not be high and that ongoing costs would, overall, be less than the current system. The 2012 report Rebuilding Rail stated that the cumulative quantifiable costs of the ‘privatised and fragmented’ railway system were somewhere in the region of £11.5 billion.298 In its 2007 rail White Paper the Labour Government said that between 1994/95 and 2004/05 the annual total ‘cost of running the railway’ doubled from about £6.6 billion to £12.2 billion and that the biggest factor in this rise was an increase in capital expenditure to “tackle a backlog of previous neglect”, and capacity enhancements which suffered from escalating costs.299 All that said, the key driver of higher fares over the past eight years or so has been a policy decision by consecutive governments to shift the burden of funding the railways from the taxpayer to the passenger. This began in 2004 when the regulated fare cap was changed from RPI-1 to RPI+1.300 In its 2007 rail White Paper the Labour Government explained that “historically there has been considerable (and often year-on-year) variation in levels of subsidy, from 50 per cent of rail funding in 1992/93 to just 15 per cent in 1995/96, reflecting the sales of assets as part of the privatisation process”.301 However, after privatisation there was a consistent increase in the proportion of rail costs funded by the taxpayer, and a pattern of 25–35 per cent subsidy in the second half of the 1990s became 40–50 per cent after 2000. By 2005/06 taxpayers were paying a higher proportion than fare payers. The White Paper stated that “this is clearly not sustainable”302 and said that between 2009 and 2014 ‘cost efficiencies’ would “allow the subsidy requirement to return closer to historic levels”: It has been the taxpayer who for the past several years has funded expenditure increases … As Network Rail brings costs back under control, it is right that the demands on taxpayers should also ease. The balance of the investment programme is met from debt funding. Since the costs of servicing this debt will accrue over the entire asset life of the enhancement, there is an element of ‘beneficiary pays’ to this approach. It would not be appropriate to expect today’s taxpayers and fare payers to bear the entirety of the up-front costs of new trains and new infrastructure which will benefit future generations […] The increasing ability of the rail industry to operate without a high level of dependency on the taxpayer is welcome. However, it is important to note that very few railways in the world operate 297 op cit., Realising the Potential of GB Rail: Final Independent Report of the Rail Value for Money Study, p286 298 op cit., Rebuilding Rail, p18 299 DfT, Delivering a Sustainable Railway, Cm 7176, July 2007, p123 300 SRA, Fares review conclusions, June 2003, appendix C 301 ibid., p126 302 ibid., p126 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 96 wholly without subsidy. It is unlikely that Britain’s railway will be an exception to this rule.303 In its 2012 command paper the Coalition Government stated its intention to bring down taxpayer and fare payer funding for the railway: “we will reduce and then put an end to above-inflation rises in average regulated fares, as well as relieving pressure on taxpayer funding”.304 Information published by the regulator in February 2015 showed that passengers have contributed an increasing proportion of the rail industry's income relative to taxpayers over the past four years – up from 55.6% in 2010-11 to 61.5% in 2013-14.305 Are the rail management and governance structures fit for purpose? There are three main areas of concern with regards to rail governance: whether the Department for Transport has the capacity and experience to properly manage rail franchising; whether Network Rail, as currently structured, is ‘fit for purpose’; and whether the regulator has enough ‘teeth’. In his 2011 report on rail value for money, Sir Roy McNulty said that the rail delivery framework was ‘complex’ and that, arguably, this: … has adverse effects on attitudes and relationships, and engenders significant additional costs in recording and negotiating the various rights, remedies and compensations provided for within it. These adverse effects are exacerbated by … weaknesses … in terms of interfaces that do not work well, incentives that are misaligned, and the relationships and culture within GB rail.306 The Department for Transport (DfT) has come under particular criticism for its capability. McNulty said in 2011 that the Government (largely but not exclusively meaning DfT) should be clearer about its rail policy, “harmonise between different strands of policy, and make clear the links between the different levels of policy, objectives, strategies and implementation”.307 Much of the recent criticism of DfT came in the wake of the failed re-let of the West Coast franchise in 2012 (see section 6.3, above). In his January 2013 report on rail franchising Richard Brown recommended that the key priority for the DfT was to “rapidly strengthen its franchising organisation, including bringing in a number of senior, commercially experienced people” as there was “a sharp asymmetry between the experience and capability of bidders and that of the Department’s franchising teams”.308 303 ibid., pp127-9 DfT, Reforming our Railways: Putting the Customer First, Cm 8313, March 2012, p12 305 ORR press notice, “Rail regulator publishes industry financials report for 2013-14”, 16 February 2015 306 Sir Roy McNulty for DfT/ORR, Realising the Potential of GB Rail: Final Independent Report of the Rail Value for Money Study – summary report, May 2011, p38 307 ibid., p40 308 op cit., The Brown Review of the Rail Franchising Programme, p7; the Government agreed with and implemented these recommendations, see: DfT, Government Response to the Brown Review of the Rail Franchising Programme, Cm 8678, July 2013 304 97 Transport 2015 Brown, Laidlaw and the DfT all agreed post-West Coast that the Department’s organisational structure was not fit for purpose and needed to be restructured so that one senior individual be responsible for specifying and procuring all rail franchises. This individual should be supported by “a greatly strengthened programme management capability” and, together, “the resulting franchising team should be structured as a discrete organisational unit” within DfT.309 Furthermore, and in Brown’s view more profoundly, the capability and experience of the people involved needed to be ‘substantially strengthened’, to which end the DfT should bring in “a range of experienced individuals, with senior level experience in areas such as procurement and commercial negotiation, finance and programme management”.310 In March 2015 the Public Administration Select Committee published a report on Civil Service skills: it cited DfT post-West Coast as a salutary example. Director General for Rail, Clare Moriarty, told the Committee that one of the main lessons learnt by the Department “was that we simply did not have the dedicated resource”, and that in terms of change, every franchise competition “now has a franchise project team leader at a senior level. We have fully staffed and dedicated teams for each franchise competition. We have our financial, legal and technical advisers in place”.311 However, while DfT were publically expressing confidence in the corrective steps that they had taken, PASC cited recent criticism from the National Audit Office (NAO) on DfT capability to deliver Crossrail and procure trains. As a remedy, PASC stressed the importance of “an honest appraisal of where skill gaps lie” across the whole Civil Service, and recommended that the Cabinet Office ask the NAO to carry out a Civil Service wide skills audit on a regular basis to “ensure that results are robust and based on an honest and realistic appraisal of current departmental capabilities”.312 Network Rail (NR)313 was criticised by McNulty for its large size, operation as a single unit and "heavily-centralised decision-making, its often complex and rigid processes, together with a culture which could at times seem arrogant and insufficiently concerned about the needs of its customers”.314 McNulty supported NR’s plans to move towards a more devolved and decentralised structure for its operations while achieving economies of scale by maintaining some central infrastructure management functions, such as procurement and heavy plant. However, more fundamentally, McNulty did not see why devolved infrastructure managers needed to be controlled by a single company. He argued: 309 ibid., p55 ibid., p57 311 PASC, Developing Civil Service Skills: a unified approach (fourth report of session 2014–15), HC 112, 17 March 2015, para 22, p12 312 ibid., paras 25-7, p13 313 for further information on NR, see HC Library briefing paper SN2129 314 op cit., Realising the Potential of GB Rail: Final Independent Report of the Rail Value for Money Study – summary report, p36 310 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 98 Indeed, there are many advantages to diverse ownership or management. Most of NR’s current operating routes are comparable in size and activity to many smaller European networks, and the ability to benchmark the efficiency of domestic comparators would further strengthen competitive pressure for affordability and efficiency. Accordingly, consideration should be given to the central NR structure being more like a holding company, with route-level concessions operated by its subsidiaries or managed by other organisations [… and] that one route-level concession should be let to an independent asset management company by 2014/15.315 In the event, NR was reclassified as a central government body in the public sector; the main effects of this are that NR’s debt (estimated to reach £50 billion by 2019) has moved onto the Government’s balance sheet and the Government is able to exert more direct control over pay and strategy. This took place on 1 September 2014. Prior to the reclassification in 2014 there had been calls for NR’s corporate structure to be overhauled. These largely date back to 2008; for example ‘the People’s Rail’ campaign led by the Co-operative Party called for NR Members to elect a Members Council which would replace the role fulfilled by the Membership and questioned whether the system was open to cronyism and institutional inertia;316 and the Transport Select Committee repeatedly questioned how NR was run.317 Before the 2010 election, both the Conservatives and the Liberal Democrats had promised to reform NR in some way.318 The Coalition Agreement, published in May 2010, stated the Government’s intention to “make Network Rail more accountable to its customers”.319 In the event, the Government’s March 2012 rail reform command paper stated that the Government would continue to encourage NR and the industry as a whole to develop governance reforms which protect taxpayer interests; allow customers to hold NR to account; promote the passenger interest; and support an ‘effective remuneration policy’.320 Prior to the 2015 election Labour said that if elected it would “bring Network Rail and a new passenger rail body together to coordinate track and train operations, and look after passengers”.321 315 ibid., p48 Co-operative Party, The People’s Rail: a mutually run, publicly accountable Network Rail, July 2008, executive summary 317 Transport Committee, The future of the railway (seventh report of session 200304), HC 145, 1 April 2004, para 59; and: Transport Committee, Delivering a sustainable railway: a 30-year strategy for the railways? (tenth report of session 2007-08), HC 219, 21 July 2008, paras 63-64 & 66 318 see, e.g. Liberal Democrats, Liberal Democrat Manifesto 2010, April 2010, p78; Conservative Party, Invitation to join the Government of Britain: the Conservative manifesto 2010, April 2010, p24; and Conservative Party, Conservative rail review: getting the best for passengers, February 2009, section 4.2 319 op cit., The Coalition: Our Programme for Government 320 op cit., Reforming our Railways: Putting the Customer First, para 4.54 321 Mary Creagh speech to Labour Conference, 23 September 2014 316 99 Transport 2015 Finally, for several years concerns have been expressed about the power of the regulator322 to properly sanction NR. Specifically, what real penalty it is to ‘fine’ NR when it is a public sector company (i.e. money is moved from NR via a regulatory fine to the Treasury, which in turn provides funding for NR). This came to the fore again in early 2015 when the regulator found that NR had breached its licence with regards to the severe disruption to the network caused by engineering overruns in December 2014 at King’s Cross and Paddington stations but decided not to impose a fine.323 More broadly, McNulty recommended in 2011 a move towards a single regulator for the rail industry as a whole, to provide greater clarity between the roles of Government and the regulator: … on the basis that the setting of policy direction and the making of politically-sensitive trade-offs between high-level objectives is clearly the role of Government, whereas the dayto-day regulatory decisions are made by the independent regulator, the ORR.324 McNulty envisaged that the regulator might take on the regulatory role in relation to franchises and possibly, at some point in the future, in relation to fares, as well as regulating cross-industry outcomes, general passenger-facing obligations, and reviews of outputs and franchise contract changes for train operators. The DfT would continue to handle procurement of franchises under this scenario. In order to do this McNulty was of the view that the regulator have the resources, skills and standing necessary to fulfil such a wider role.325 In the event, this never happened, though in April 2015 its remit was extended from railways to cover strategic highways. To this end it was renamed the Office of Rail and Road, retaining its ‘ORR’ acronym. Why are there so many ‘Direct Awards’? The current profusion of Direct Awards are a direct result of the failed 2012 West Coast re-let (see section 6.3, above). The nature of these awards varies, but what they mean, in effect, is that the Government negotiates directly with the incumbent operator; there is no competition for the award. The former Rail Minister, Simon Burns, explained the process in a May 2013 letter to the Chair of the Transport Select Committee: In negotiating and approving each direct award, the Department uses a comparator to assess what is reasonable. For previous direct awards, where the contractual terms remained broadly the same as for the previous contract, the start point has been the preceding contract and the outturn for costs and revenues. The assessment of Value for Money in the Direct Awards that form part of the overall franchising programme is therefore done 322 for more information on the regulator, see HC Library briefing paper SN2071 ORR, Office of Rail Regulation investigation report: Disruption caused by engineering overruns on 27 and 28 December 2014 at King’s Cross and Paddington stations, 12 February 2015 324 op cit., Realising the Potential of GB Rail: Final Independent Report of the Rail Value for Money Study – summary report, p67 325 ibid., p67 323 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 100 on an increment/decrement basis against the current provision from the existing operator. We work with Technical Advisors to build a comparator model based on the current and projected performance of the franchise. The submissions from the incumbent for the Direct Award are then compared to this model and challenged where appropriate to bring them into an affordable and value for money position.326 The DfT’s guidance gives further information. On the general principles of making Direct Awards, it states: The direct awards help to manage and sustain a realistic and properly resourced programme of Franchise Competitions and a healthy bidding market for those competitions. In entering into such direct awards, the Department is conscious that the commercial terms have not been tested through a procurement competition. Domestic and European law helps in this by setting out a specific legal framework for “public service contracts” (which encompass rail passenger services) which is intended to ensure that the terms are economically efficient so that the taxpayer (and fare-payer) is not over-paying for services. Should appropriate terms not be achievable, the Department will call upon contingency measures rather than enter into a Direct Award.327 The rail franchising schedule shows the proliferation of Direct Awards: of the 16 franchises managed and let by DfT, to October 2014 the Government had made seven Direct Awards and was anticipating making six more between 2014 and 2020. This means that 12 of the 16 franchises would be subject to re-let without open competition (Great Western counts twice).328 It seems unlikely that there would be any desire on the part of the Conservative Government to move away from this and to retender some of those franchises currently scheduled for Direct Awards. In principle, though, this might be possible. There are four franchises currently slated for Direct Awards that could be refranchised, though the timetable on two of them is probably too tight: East Midlands Trains in October 2015 and London Midland in April 2016; in the longer term the Direct Awards for Cross Country (October 2016) and South Western (February 2017) seem far enough away for a full and fair refranchising process to take place. Whatever the Government were to decide it would want to make a decision relatively quickly to give clarity to the industry and allow it to plan for the long term. Can anyone ‘guarantee’ a public sector operator under the current system? As indicated above, the Labour Party and others proposed reintroducing the right of public sector bodies to bid for franchises. They argued that this would provide a ‘public sector comparator’ for the privatised industry. As indicated above, while this is now off the 326 Simon Burns letter to Louise Ellman, May 2013 DfT, Rail franchising direct awards process guide, 31 October 2014, p1 328 op cit., Rail franchise schedule 327 101 Transport 2015 agenda as far as England is concerned, it remains a proposal for Scotland under the Smith Commission recommendations. However, there is no obvious reason why allowing public sector bodies to bid for franchises would result in one winning a bid and then operating one. The barriers to a public body both practically (rather than legally) being able to bid for, and then win, a franchise are potentially very high. All we can say with any certainty is that a public sector body could legally bid for a franchise, whether one could in practice and second, whether it would have any chance of winning a franchise, is another question and one we have no precedent for. First is the question of the cost of bidding for a rail franchise – which in the case of a public service operator would be borne by the taxpayer: estimates vary from about £5 million to £14 million.329 According to Christian Wolmar bidding also requires the involvement of around 30-40 professional staff, with around half a dozen employed full time for the duration, which is unlikely to be much short of a year.330 In order to qualify as a bidder for a rail franchise a body has to specify certain criteria required under EU public procurement rules (e.g. experience, health and safety and capital requirements).331 Wolmar says: For any hope of success – indeed, even to prequalify – a franchise bidder would be required to show that they had secure financial backing, would need to ensure that the government would agree to their selection as a shortlisted bidder and would have to have an experienced team of managers, both to deliver a winning bid and to establish a new operating company.332 More fundamentally there is the issue of ‘Chinese walls’, i.e. ensuring that where a state-owned company is bidding for a franchise against private companies, that the body which awards the franchise is sufficiently separate from the public sector bidder for the private bidders to have confidence that the process has been free and fair. This would likely be satisfied by a separation or ‘hiving off’ of one or both of these functions to another Government department, agency or body. Should franchising be devolved? As set out in section 3, above, there is a growing trend to devolve transport decision-making and management to the lowest possible level. This includes the letting and management of rail franchises. However, progress in this area in England has been slow. Devolution is already working in some areas – notably Scotland, London and 329 the higher figure was cited by Martin Griffiths, Co-Chair of Virgin Rail Group, when he gave evidence to the Transport Committee on the fallout of the failed West Coast re-let in 2012 (see above); in the same session Sir Richard Branson said that Virgin had spent ‘over £50 million’ on four bids, two for the East Coast Main Line and one each for CrossCountry, and the West Coast Main Line, from: Oral Evidence: 10 September 2012, Ev 81 of HC 329-II, Qq477 330 op cit., Co-operative rail: a radical solution, p18 331 see, e.g. DfT, Rail Franchising: East Anglia Pre-Qualification Questionnaire, February 2015 332 op cit., Co-operative rail: a radical solution, p19 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 102 Merseyside – but the question or how much further it will go is open to debate and particularly in England it will depend on the appetite of the Government not only to give regions franchising powers but to reform how regional rail services are subsidised (some routes currently receive a significant cross-subsidy from premium payments made by other operators).333 In Scotland, the Scottish Government has responsibility for specifying and letting the ScotRail franchise and the new Caledonian Sleeper franchise (hived off from the ScotRail franchise in 2015).334 The Smith Commission (see above) proposed that the power to allow public sector operators to bid for rail franchises funded and specified by Scottish Ministers be devolved to the Scottish Government. In practical terms, the Scottish Government has just let new franchises for ScotRail and the Caledonian Sleeper to 2025 and 2030 respectively. Thus this power would in all likelihood remain unused for the next decade (possibly sooner were a franchise to be terminated early for some reason). In Wales, the Welsh Government is a co-signatory to any franchise that is a Wales-only service or includes ‘Welsh services’ (i.e. any rail passenger service that starts in Wales, ends in Wales or makes at least one scheduled call in Wales). In effect, this is only the Wales & Borders franchise. The Welsh Government is responsible for determining the priorities for local and regional services and setting fares for them. It also has a greater role in developing facilities such as stations and local lines and funding rail improvements. As indicated above, the Silk Commission recommended that the Welsh Government should have a greater role in the consultation process for appointing a new franchise operator for the inter-city cross-border rail franchises (Great Western, CrossCountry and Virgin Trains) and that the Wales & Borders franchise be fully devolved (this might require some redrawing of the franchise boundary and the services it contains).335 In its St David’s Day Agreement the Coalition Government confirmed this would proceed, with the Welsh Government taking over procurement for the Wales & Border franchise in 2018 and that “it is likely that services primarily serving English markets will be placed into other franchises for which the Secretary of State for Transport is the franchising authority”.336 In London, Transport for London (TfL) and the Secretary of State are required to co-operate on rail matters, including a requirement that the Secretary of State must consult TfL before issuing a rail franchise Invitation To Tender (or when entering a franchise agreement for which an ITT has not been issued) for railway passenger services to, 333 op cit., Government support to the rail industry by TOC - Table 1.7 full details can be found on the Transport Scotland website [accessed 28 April 2015] 335 op cit., Empowerment and Responsibility: Legislative Powers to Strengthen Wales, pp70&73 336 op cit., Powers for a Purpose: Towards a Lasting Devolution Settlement for Wales, p31 334 103 Transport 2015 from or within London.337 In July 2007 the DfT announced that TfL, as part of the franchise specification process, would be able to propose and pay for extra train services or improvements to stations on a number of ‘inner suburban’ routes within the Greater London boundary.338 More recently, the current Mayor of London, Boris Johnson, stated that he would like to see TfL assume responsibility for more inner suburban services in London, specifically two groups of services: to the north-east of London, services that are part of the Greater Anglia franchise, and in South East London, local services that are part of the Southeastern franchise.339 In February 2015 the Chancellor, George Osborne and Mayor Johnson announced that TfL would take over rail services between Liverpool Street, Enfield Town, Cheshunt (via Seven Sisters) and Chingford and gain control of most of the stations servicing those routes.340 As to England, there have been proposals for regional devolution of franchises for many years. Under the Railways Act 1993 the PTEs were co-signatories to the franchises which covered their areas. Labour made some changes in this area in 2005, following concerns that PTEs were not directly exposed to the consequences of their decisions on fares and service levels. Sections 13 and 14 of the Railways Act 2005 gave PTEs greater flexibility to make a choice between rail and other modes of transport in their areas if rail services offered poor value for money; and removed the PTEs from being direct parties to franchise agreements.341 In his 2011 report McNulty was of the view that there was still too high a degree of central government involvement in rail franchising. He recommended that there be greater localism, with more involvement in England of local authorities and/or PTEs, with “local decisionmaking brought more closely together with budget responsibility and accountability”.342 In his later 2013 report Richard Brown also recommended further devolution of English franchises to the relevant authorities.343 However, progress has been sluggish. In its March 2012 command paper, the Coalition Government stated that it would look at devolving more responsibility for English rail franchises to local areas and published a consultation document to that end. It was limited in TfL’s rail powers are set out in section 175 of the Greater London Authority Act 1999, as amended and sections 15-17 of the Railways Act 2005 338 HC Deb 18 July 2007, cc23-25WS; and DfT, Guidance on the role of Transport for London in the Department for Transport's rail franchising process, July 2007 339 DfT, Rail Decentralisation - Devolving decision-making on passenger rail services in England: Consultation Responses, November 2012, para 3.20 340 HMT press notice, “Long term economic plan for London announced by Chancellor and Mayor of London”, 20 February 2015 341 for more information on the role of PTEs, see: DfT, The new system for the role of English PTEs in the rail franchising process, July 2006; the Merseyside PTE, Merseytravel, is in a different position, as the Merseyrail network was exempted from the franchising requirements of the 1993 Act by Order, allowing Merseytravel to let a concession to run the services (Merseyrail Electrics Network Order 2002 (SI 2002/1946)) 342 op cit., Realising the Potential of GB Rail: Final Independent Report of the Rail Value for Money Study – summary report, p47 343 op cit., The Brown Review of the Rail Franchising Programme, paras 5.5-5.6 337 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 104 scope, arguing that DfT should retain responsibility for safety and security, accessibility, performance on the strategic rail network; national ticketing policy/strategy; and ‘connectivity enhancements benefiting primarily strategic rail services’.344 It also argued that only category E services (i.e. services linking smaller towns and rural areas with larger towns, cities and the inter-city rail network) were suited to decentralisation, possibly with a limited number of category D services (i.e. local services conveying people into the major cities and conurbations across the country).345 The paper envisioned this sort of decentralisation being delivered by what it called ‘local transport consortia’, comprised of Local Enterprise Partnerships (LEPs), local authorities and/or PTEs. These bodies might end up being cosignatories to a franchise or they could buy local enhancements to the base specification of the franchise. This power currently exists but has been little used – probably because these enhancements have to be locally funded in perpetuity.346 Responses to the consultation were published in November 2012. They were broadly in favour of more local control of rail franchising. The Department concluded that it remained “committed to seeking to implement an appropriate form of decentralisation in those parts of England where it is sensible to do so” and that it would therefore “continue informal discussions with those bodies who have submitted proposals or firm expressions of interest”.347 Nothing happened between then and General Election 2015, although in 2014 reports emerged stating that DfT had blocked a proposal by local authorities in the West Midlands to take full responsibility for the management of local rail services from 2017 or to award the local franchise as a management contract or ‘concession’ (as in London and Merseyside).348 Do EU rules prevent nationalisation? There is a commonly-held belief that EU law ‘bans’ the renationalisation of the rail network. This is a misconception: the current laws do not prevent the state owning and managing the rail infrastructure and (separately) operating train services – this model is commonly employed in other Member States. There are currently proposals being discussed to create stricter separation between the two, but the Council and the Parliament do not agree on the direction to take. The relevant EU law is Directive 2012/34/EU. This is the recast First Railway Package, agreed in 2012. The provisions therein that have often been misconstrued as preventing renationalisation derive from Directive 91/440/EEC, agreed in July 1991. These provisions require that Member States grant rail companies independence from 344 DfT, Rail Decentralisation: Devolving decision-making on passenger rail services in England, March 2012, para 4.4 345 ibid., paras 4.22-3 346 ibid., paras 4.36-4.47 347 DfT, Rail Decentralisation - Devolving decision-making on passenger rail services in England: Consultation Responses, November 2012, section 4 348 “McLoughlin thwarts West Mids’ , Local Transport Today, LTT 644, 4 April 2014 105 Transport 2015 government and introduce commercial management techniques; and separate the management of infrastructure from the management of train services. They sought to introduce greater financial discipline and more operational competition both nationally and across borders. National railways were pressed to separate track infrastructure from train operations or, at the very least, to produce transparent accounts revealing the respective costs and revenues attributable to infrastructure and to services. The 1991 Directive did not require that infrastructure and services be managed in different institutions, nor even in distinct divisions within the same institution, but it did stress that this was possible. It was left up to each Member State to decide how they wished to organise their railways but it had to be possible to attribute costs. In the UK the then Conservative Government decided to separate track and trains via privatisation, putting both into the private sector; no other EU country took this route.349 There was some expectation more recently that the European Commission might push for a permanent and legislative separation of infrastructure from services and mandate competition for services as part of the Fourth Railway Package. This came about because the Commission had some legal difficulties with those countries which, to its mind, had not sufficiently separated infrastructure and services provision, as required under the First Package. European courts struck down this view, most recently in regards to Germany in 2012, but also in Austria, Spain, Hungary and Portugal.350 Both Deutsche Bahn and SNCF (the state-owned rail companies in Germany and France respectively) queried whether further market liberalisation would actually harm rail services. They argued that research into rail markets outside the EU concluded that “common management of railway infrastructure and exploitation (an integrated model) helps improve rail performance”.351 Rail unions expressed similar concerns.352 The Commission consequently acknowledged that it could “accept that a vertically integrated or ‘holding structure’ may also deliver the necessary independence, with strict ‘Chinese walls’ to ensure the necessary, legal, financial and operational separation”, stepping back from the position it took in bringing the cases above to court.353 The European Parliament subsequently diluted the ‘market pillar’ of the Fourth Package: it endorsed the introduction of a right for European railway undertakings to offer commercial domestic 349 for a summary of the infrastructure management of and private sector involvement with other EU rail systems, see annexes 18 and 19 of: EC, Fourth report on monitoring development in the rail market, COM(2014) 353 final, 13 June 2014 350 “Advocate-general says German model legal”, Europolitics, September 2012, [No. 241] 351 “Deutsche Bahn and SNCF fear a hasty decision”, Europolitics, October 2012, [No. 242] 352 e.g. ITF press notice, “European Transport Workers’ Federation denounces railway plans”, 26 September 2012 353 EC press notice, “European Railways at a junction: the Commission adopts proposals for a Fourth Railway Package”, 30 January 2013 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 106 passenger services in all Member States as from 2019, but postponed competitive tendering procedures for public service contracts to 2023 and made them subject to ‘very significant exceptions’. In the Commission’s view the EP amendments also failed to ensure “an effective independence of the infrastructure manager and financial transparency within vertically integrated structures which are essential to ensure an equal and nondiscriminatory access to the network”.354 The Package has progressed no further. Most recently the then Secretary of State for Transport, Patrick McLoughlin, reported to Parliament on the first Transport Council under the Latvian Presidency in March 2015. There was a policy discussion on the Fourth Package, during which Mr McLoughlin “set out the great success of our liberalised market and urged Member States to grasp the opportunity of the market pillar to develop a true single market for rail and support a vibrant, competitive and sustainable rail sector across Europe”. He also reported that on the governance model, “I had strong support from a range of Member States for the approach that a truly separated model was the most effective remedy against potential discrimination by the infrastructure manager towards the railway undertakings, and that additional regulation was not required in such cases”.355 EC Press notice, “Transport: European Parliament adopts equivocal first reading position on fourth railway package”, 26 February 2014 355 HCWS431: EU Transport Council, 20 March 2015 354 107 Transport 2015 6. Policy focus 4: cycling 6.1 What’s the issue? Cycling is on the increase The number of cyclists is increasing: more than 5.1 million people in England cycle at least once a week.356 Government road traffic estimates suggest that in 2013 the distance travelled by bike was 12% more than the 2005–2009 average.357 Government is keen to encourage more cycling While there has been an increase in cycling, it still only accounts for 2% of all journeys.358 British Cycling report that, for most of the country, the growth in cycling has been due to an increase in leisure cycling, which is more likely to take place off-road, or on quiet roads, rather than more people cycling to work.359 In the majority of local authorities in England the numbers of working residents cycling to work declined between 2001 and 2011.360 In 2013 Prime Minister David Cameron called for a “cycling revolution”, building on the success of Britain’s cyclists at London 2012 to encourage “far more people” to take up cycling.361 The Coalition Government argued that increasing cycling would mean “healthier, fitter citizens, less congested cities, less pollution and a more productive workforce”.362 The Cyclescheme organisation estimated that the NHS would save £2.5 billion if 10% of journeys now made by car were made by bike by 2025.363 The All Party Parliamentary Cycling Group said: Too many people in the UK feel they have no choice but to travel in ways that are dangerous, unhealthy, polluting and costly, not just to their own wallets but also to the public purse. Urgent action is required to address Britain’s chronic levels of obesity, heart disease, air pollution and congestion if we are to catch up with other countries in the developed world. There is an alternative. When more people cycle or walk, public health improves, obesity reduces and roads become safer. By changing how people travel, we can create places where people want to live, work, shop and do business. We can make people healthier, happier and wealthier. We can reduce costs to our NHS.364 The Commissioner of Transport for London, Sir Peter Hendy, argued that investing in cycling could alleviate the forecasted pressure on the 356 DfT, Walking & Cycling Statistics; Table CW 0112, April 2014 DfT, Pedal Cycle Traffic: Table TRA 0401, June 2014 358 DfT, How People Travel (Mode): Table NTS301, July 2014 359 British Cycling, Evidence to the Transport Select Committee inquiry “Cycling safety” (CYS 043), January 2014 360 ONS, 2011 Census Analysis - Cycling to Work, 26 March 2014 361 HMG press notice, “Government shifts cycling up a gear”, 12 August 2013 362 DfT, Cycling Delivery Plan, October 2014 363 “NHS will save billions if more cycle to work”, The Times, 30 March 2015 364 APPCG, Get Britain Cycling, April 2013 357 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 108 capital’s Underground and rail network resulting from the predicted growth in population to nine million by 2020.365 The 2010 Coalition Agreement pledged to “support sustainable travel initiatives, including the promotion of cycling”.366 The official target of the Coalition Government for increased cycling was to double the proportion of stages of journeys carried out by bike - from 0.8 billion to 1.6 billion - by 2025.367 Using the metric of journey ‘stages’ enables the Government to measure cycling when it is not the main mode of transport for the journey, for example where the main part of the journey is made by train, but a bike is used for the journey from home to the train station. At present only 1% of all stages are by bike, and the number of stages travelled by bike has figure has fallen by 25% since 1995/96: from 20 bicycle stages per person per year, to 15 stages in 2013.368 In October 2010 the Government announced that Cycling England an independent non-departmental public body with a budget of £60 million per year - would be abolished in 2011, as part of the wider ‘bonfire of the quangos’. Cycling England had been tasked with “working to get more people cycling, more safely, more often”.369 The then Transport Minister, Norman Baker, told Parliament that: … the Government's move towards localism, and particularly in this regard the nature of the new Local Sustainable Transport Fund, for which all local transport authorities outside London are eligible to bid and for which we expect bids for cycling related projects, means that the rationale for a body like Cycling England has weakened.370 The then Secretary of State for Transport, Philip Hammond, said that the decision did not reflect a lack of support for cycling as the Government did not believe that “setting up a quango and maintaining a quango is a measure of your commitment to an agenda”.371 Others did not agree. For example, in 2013 the then Shadow Transport Secretary, Maria Eagle, said the abolition of Cycling England was the first of “policy after policy” which had set back the progress made on cycling by the previous Labour Government.372 In its January 2011 local transport White Paper the Government set out its intention to “encourage sustainable local travel and economic growth by making public transport and cycling and walking more attractive and effective”.373 The public health benefits of cycling were noted as “considerable”, citing the experience of the Cycling Demonstration Towns, in which the public health benefits outweighed Mayor of London & TfL, The Mayor’s Vision for Cycling in London, March 2013 Cabinet Office, Public Body Review published, 14 October 2010 367 op cit., Cycling Delivery Plan, p5 368 DfT, National Travel Survey: England 2013, 29 July 2014, pp 6-7 369 Cycling England Who we are [accessed 5 May 2015] 370 HC Deb 14 March 2011, c99W 371 “Philip Hammond: Fuel duty cut won’t stop government being the greenest ever”, The Guardian, 25 March 2011 372 HC Deb 2 September 2013, c126 373 DfT, Creating Growth, Cutting Carbon, Cm 7996, January 2011, p12 365 366 109 Transport 2015 the cost of the programme by a factor of three.374 The White Paper pledged the Government’s continued support for the Bikeability cycling training programme until 2015.375 The White Paper accompanied the launch of the Local Sustainable Transport Fund (LSTF) - a £550 million fund available for local transport authorities outside of London with the aim of changing patterns of travel behaviour, and increasing the use of sustainable transport methods.376 In evidence to the Transport Committee in 2014 the Department for Transport stated that “94 of 96 Local Sustainable Transport Fund projects” included cycling, and highlighted that these projects accounted for £535 million of Government funding. In 2013/14 29% of the LSTF funds were used specifically for cycling.377 Previous governments have also set ambitious targets for increasing cycling, e.g. in 1996 the National Cycling Strategy set an objective to double the proportion of cycle trips by 2002, and quadruple this figure by 2012.378 While the real amount of cycling journeys did increase, as a proportion of total journeys the figure stayed the same. There are too many barriers to cycling The key factor cited for the failure to get more people on their bikes is safety: British Cycling have claimed that there are 2.75 million people who want to cycle more than they do, but do not, as they feel the roads are too risky.379 Two-thirds of non-cyclists—and half of all cyclists—say that it is too dangerous for them to cycle on the road.380 Women are significantly more likely than men to say that the roads are too dangerous for cycling. The level of concern also increases by age group: three-quarters of those 65 and over view the roads as too dangerous for cycling, compared to just less than half aged between 18 and 24.381 While noting the safety concerns, the Coalition Government argued that “the health benefits of cycling significantly outweigh” the risks.382 A lack of cycling infrastructure is seen as one of the main reasons for safety concerns.383 Many cyclists have been campaigning for segregated cycle lanes and changes to junction design: research by Professor Colin Pooley has suggested that “most non-cyclists and recreational cyclists will only consider cycling regularly if they are 374 ibid., p41 ibid., p41 376 ibid., p30 377 DfT, Local Sustainable Transport Fund Annual Report 2013/14, February 2015, p10; see also: CBT, Strategic Economic Plans review, June 2014; and “West Sussex and the LSTF money – Albion Way”, As easy as riding a bike blog, 7 April 2015; 378 for further information see HC Library briefing paper SN1097 379 op cit., Evidence to the Transport Select Committee inquiry “Cycling safety” (CYS 043) 380 DfT, British Social Attitudes Survey 2013: Public attitudes towards transport, July 2014, p 11 381 ibid., pp 12-13 382 DfT, Creating Growth, Cutting Carbon, Cm 7996, January 2011, p24 383 Ashok Sinha, Chief Executive of London Cycling Campaign has argued that the “greatest dangers” that cyclists faced on the road are from “the poor quality of infrastructure”, see: op cit., Cycling safety, 24 375 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 110 segregated from traffic”.384 Where cycle lanes have been introduced, their quality has been patchy: starting and stopping unexpectedly, and failing to deliver a coherent, consistent route.385 Driver behaviour is also seen as a safety issue, whether behind the wheel of a lorry, car or bus. The Transport Select Committee received evidence that in over half of all serious collisions between a vehicle and a cyclist, the key cause was the driver failing to look properly.386 Cyclists have reported hostility and dangerous driving from motorists, with some suggesting that “the single biggest contributor to poor cyclist safety” was “driver behaviour and attitudes”.387 6.2 What has happened since 2010? Fatalities In 2013 the number of cyclist fatalities in Great Britain dropped from its highest level for five years.388 The number of cyclists experiencing serious injuries increased for the eighth successive year.389 Media coverage of the 2012 figures, and the deaths of six cyclists in London in a period of just a fortnight in November 2013 led to widespread concern about the safety of cyclists.390 The rise in the number of cyclists, however, means that the proportion of cyclists killed or seriously injured has fallen in recent years, reducing the likelihood of death or serious injury for each journey.391 The rate of fatalities per billion miles travelled has been on a downward trend overall (with occasional increases) since the mid1960s: 392 384 ibid., para 24 for examples see ibid., para 26 386 Transport Committee, Written evidence to Cycling Safety inquiry from Richard Armitage, David Hurdle, Adrian Lord and Alex Sully, transport consultants (CYS0128), January 2014 387 Transport Committee, Written evidence to Cycling Safety inquiry from Mark Goddard (CYS0140), January 2014 388 DfT, Reported Road Casualties 2013: Annual Report, September 2014 389 op cit., The Coalition: our programme for government 390 op cit., Cycling safety, para 7 391 op cit., Reported Road Casualties 2013: Annual Report, p31 392 op cit., Written evidence to Cycling Safety inquiry from Richard Armitage, David Hurdle, Adrian Lord and Alex Sully, transport consultants (CYS0128) 385 111 Transport 2015 Andrew Gilligan, the Mayor of London’s Commissioner for Cycling, told the Transport Committee that even with the November 2013 deaths, the fact that only one journey in every 320,000 ended in serious injury in 2012, compared to one in every 299,000 in 2002 meant that it was safe to cycle in London.393 External pressure driving cycling up the political agenda Over the course of the 2010 Parliament media coverage of cycling deaths and serious injuries led to lobbying for central government to do more to improve the safety of cycling. The Times newspaper launched its ‘Cities fit for cycling’ campaign in February 2012, following the severe injuries suffered by Mary Bowers, a journalist on the newspaper, when she was hit by a lorry (the driver was later convicted of careless driving) while cycling to work in November 2011.394 The centrepoint of the campaign was an eight point manifesto to improve safety: 1. Lorries entering a city centre should be required by law to fit sensors, audible turning alarms, extra mirrors and safety bars to stop cyclists being thrown under the wheels. 2. The 500 most dangerous road junctions must be identified, redesigned or fitted with priority traffic lights for cyclists and Trixi mirrors that allow lorry drivers to see cyclists on their near-side. 3. A national audit of cycling to find out how many people cycle in Britain and how cyclists are killed or injured should be held to underpin effective cycle safety. 4. Two per cent of the Highways Agency budget should be earmarked for next generation cycle routes, providing £100 393 394 op cit., Cycling safety, para 7 “Court verdict an insult, says father of Mary Bowers seriously hurt by lorry”, The Times, 14 December 2012 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 112 million a year towards world-class cycling infrastructure. Each year cities should be graded on the quality of cycling provision. 5. The training of cyclists and drivers must improve and cycle safety should become a core part of the driving test. 6. 20mph should become the default speed limit in residential areas where there are no cycle lanes. 7. Businesses should be invited to sponsor cycleways and cycling super-highways, mirroring the Barclays-backed bicycle hire scheme in London. 8. Every city, even those without an elected mayor, should appoint a cycling commissioner to push home reforms.395 Cycling campaigners also called for Ministers to commit to long-term funding to improve infrastructure, and to coordinate policies across the different Government departments, such as Health, Education, and Communities and Local Government. British Cycling policy adviser and former Team GB gold medal-winning cyclist Chris Boardman said: Political leadership is the key here. Governments in countries such as Holland and Denmark, who were headed in the same direction as us in the 1970s, said “no” and created transport policies that put people first, making cycling and walking their preferred modes of transport in towns and cities. And—in less than 40 years—look at the difference. We need our Government to do the same, otherwise what is the alternative?396 In spring 2013 the All Party Parliamentary Cycling Group (APPCG) held an inquiry on the state of cycling, led by MPs Ian Austin, Dr Sarah Wollaston and Julian Huppert. The APPCG published Get Britain Cycling in April 2013, setting out a vision of “the full potential of cycling to contribute to the health and wealth of the nation, and the quality of life in our towns and local communities”. The APPCG called for people of all ages and backgrounds, in urban and rural areas to cycle and for changes to the culture of roads and communities to remove the fears associated with cycling.397 The APPCG recommended a range of measures, including: a cycling budget of at least £10 per person per year, increasing to £20; funding be allocated from a plethora of bodies, not just DfT; more account be taken of cycling when planning roads and communities; cycling along the strategic road network be easier; speed limits be lower; HGVs be made safer; traffic laws be properly enforced; and proper cycle training for children.398 The House of Commons debated the report in September 2013.399 The Transport Select Committee published a report on cycling safety in July 2014. It endorsed the APPCG’s recommendation for £10 per “Cities fit for Cycling manifesto”, The Times, 28 March 2012 “The way we travel now is killing us. We’re the fattest people in Western Europe”, The Times, 24 April 2013 397 APPCG, Get Britain Cycling, April 2013 398 ibid. 399 HC Deb 2 September 2013, cc66-134; and: APPCG press notice, ““Implement the recommendations now” 100 MPs tell Parliament”, 3 September 2013 395 396 113 Transport 2015 head per year of Government spending on cycling infrastructure, to be reached by 2020 and urged DfT Ministers to champion cycling across Government.400 In October 2014 the Government published in draft a plan to increase cycling and walking levels. While publication of the plan was welcomed, particularly as it was a year behind schedule, its contents were criticised for falling far short of the APPCG recommendations. The primary complaint concerned the Government’s funding ‘aspiration’ of: … working with local government, and businesses, [to] together explore how we can achieve a minimum funding packet equivalent to £10 per person each year by 2020-21 – and sooner if possible.401 Paul Tuohy, Chief Executive of cycling charity CTC, described it as “a derisory plan not a delivery plan”, and argued that the Prime Minister’s plans for a ‘cycling revolution’ would be ‘going nowhere’ unless sufficient funding was secured.402 Sustrans, the sustainable transport charity, criticised the ‘aspiration’ to achieve a funding level of £10 per head, and called for the Government to commit to at least this figure, to be delivered through existing funding arrangements.403 While out for consultation the draft cycling plan was superseded by a grassroots campaign to amend what became the Infrastructure Act 2015, to require the Government to produce a Cycling and Walking Investment Strategy for England, setting out not only the Government’s ambitions, but also how they would be funded. Although the Government resisted this throughout the initial stages of the Bill, it changed its mind and inserted the provision into the Bill in January 2015.404 The Bill received Royal Assent in February 2015, and as a result, funding for cycling and walking will be allocated on the same longterm basis as currently applies for the railways and the motorways and main A roads which make up the Strategic Road Network. Funding has increased The Prime Minister’s ‘cycling revolution’ pledge was accompanied by what the Government described as “biggest ever single injection of cash” for cycling: £148 million over a two year period.405 There were further announcements of new funding for cycling; for example, the Cycle City Ambition Grants; Bikeability schemes; and funding for cycle parking at railway stations. Cycling campaigners welcomed these schemes, but criticised cycling funding overall as sporadic and insufficient. Chris Boardman told the 400 op cit., Cycling safety, para 62 DfT, Cycling Delivery Plan, October 2014 402 CTC, “Government cycling strategy ‘a derisory plan not a delivery plan’”, 16 October 2014 403 Sustrans, “Parliamentary cycling debate calls for investment to get Britain on bikes”, 16 October 2014 404 HC Deb 26 January 2015, cc695-79; a letter from the then Transport Minister, John Hayes, explained why the Government changed its mind [DEP 2015-0096] 405 HMG press notice, “Government shifts cycling up a gear”, 12 August 2013 401 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 114 Transport Select Committee in February 2014 that the funding provided for cycling had been “very short term and as one-offs”.406 British Cycling estimated in 2014 that current spending on cycling by the Government was just £2 per head: far lower than the £10 per head that it viewed as necessary to increase cycling levels.407 6.3 What do cyclists want? Safer cycling infrastructure Ahead of the general election cycling campaign groups listed their main priorities for political support. British Cycling’s #ChooseCycling network a consortium of businesses including Santander, Sky, GlaxoSmithKline and The AA set out four commitments it wanted from the party leaders: 1. Fulfil the requirements of the Infrastructure Act to create an adequate Cycling and Walking investment strategy with clear and ambitious targets by 2016. 2. A commitment to invest 5% of Britain’s combined transport spend every year into designing cycling back into our roads and junctions. 3. Setting a meaningful target, to make cycling account for 10% of all trips by 2025. 4. The creation and distribution of uniform design guidance – put together in consultation with world experts - to be followed by all local authorities by 2016.408 The CTC ‘Vote Bike’ campaign listed the key policies it asked prospective parliamentary candidates to support: Ambition: increase levels of cycling to 10% of trips by 2025 and 25% by 2050. Funding: an average government spend of at least £10 per person per year on cycling. Design standards: create consistently high design standards for cycling in all highway and traffic schemes, new developments and planned road maintenance work. Safety: Measures to improve cycle safety by strengthening road traffic law and its enforcement and revising the Highway Code. Positive promotion: support positive promotion of cycling, including cycle skills training, for people of all ages, backgrounds and abilities. The Space for Cycling campaign was launched by the London Cycling Campaign in 2013, and adopted nationally by the cycling charity CTC in 2014. The campaign called for local councillors and transport planners to enable people of any age or ability to travel door-to-door in safe, convenient and enjoyable cycling conditions. The campaign suggested six measures to help achieve this vision, including protecting space on main roads; removing through-traffic in 406 op cit., Cycling safety, para 56 op cit., Evidence to the Transport Select Committee inquiry “Cycling safety” (CYS 043) 408 British Cycling press notice, “Major British businesses urge politicians to #ChooseCyling”, 20 March 2015 407 115 Transport 2015 residential areas; lower speed limits; cycle-friendly town centres; safe routes to school; and routes through green spaces.409 There were also calls for the Government to set a national design standard for new cycling infrastructure. The Institute for Civil Engineers called for “national direction and leadership … to be provided on design guidance”, stating that, “the actions that local highway authorities (and the Highways Agency) take stem directly from the direction and leadership that they see emanating from central government”.410 The Coalition Government rejected this argument, stating that it wanted to: “encourage a combination of measures aimed at ensuring good design - this includes, the sharing of good practice designs which the Cycle Proofing Working Group will take forward in delivering”.411 In evidence to the Transport Committee many cyclists argued that where cycle lanes had been introduced by local authorities, they “very rarely” conformed to the Department’s design guidance.412 Reformed ‘rules of the road’ British Cycling has sought changes to the justice system “to protect and support vulnerable road users”.413 The ‘Road Justice’ campaign, led by CTC and the Cyclist Defence Fund (CDF), has also called for better policing of traffic collisions; better charging and prosecution; and sentences that “reflect the severity of the offence and discourage bad driving”.414 Cyclists have highlighted cases in which they believe one or more of these factors has not been in place. The CDF, which provides “support in legal cases which could clarify the law” relating to cyclists, reported on the decision of a jury to clear a driver of causing the death of an eighteen year old cyclist, Daniel Squire. The driver had admitted using his phone shortly before the fatal collision, and the CDF queried the decisions made in the case by the police and prosecution.415 In a separate case, the CDF is supporting the family of cyclist Michael Mason who was hit from behind by a driver in February 2014 and died the following month. The Metropolitan Police did not refer the case to the Crown Prosecution Service, in what Mr Mason’s family described as a “travesty of justice”.416 Cycling campaigners have also highlighted a decline in the number of prosecutions for death by dangerous driving, following the introduction of the lesser charge, death by careless driving. Roger Geffen, CTC Campaigns and Policy Director said: 409 CTC, Space for Cycling: A guide for local decision makers, 30 April 2014 op cit., Cycling safety, para 27 411 DfT, Response to the consultation on the Draft Cycling Delivery Plan, March 2015, p11 412 op cit., Cycling safety, para 27 413 British Cycling, Time to #choosecycling, February 2014 414 Road Justice, The role of the police, June 2013, p2 415 “An incomprehensible travesty of justice”, CDF blog, 27 March 2015 416 “Family of cyclist killed in road crash hits out at police who gave false hope of prosecution”, London Evening Standard, 19 March 2015 410 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 116 Although the newer offence allows for stiffer penalties in cases which were previously treated as nothing more than “careless driving” (i.e. with the death often not even being mentioned in a magistrates court trial), it has also led to a massive decline in the CPS’s willingness to prosecute for ‘dangerous’ driving offences, exactly as CTC warned.417 However, one should note that one of the reasons for introducing the causing death by careless driving charge was the evidential difficulty of proving ‘dangerous’ driving. The hope was that this would allow more successful prosecutions overall for a ‘causing death’ driving offence.418 Separately, CTC called for employers and contractors to be held to account when they employ unlicensed or unsafe drivers. In April 2015, Barry Meyers, an unlicensed HGV driver who had received five driving bans, and had been convicted of drink-driving and driving while disqualified, was found guilty of death by careless driving. Mr Meyers had jumped a red light when he hit cyclist Alan Neve in London in 2013.419 Cynthia Barlow of road safety charity RoadPeace also called for people with repeated driving convictions to be banned from driving HGVs.420 In the past, cyclists have also called for reforms to the Highway Code to make cycling safer and changes to liability rules so that motorists are automatically responsible for accidents involving cyclists.421 6.4 What about other road users? Pedestrians Policies for promoting cycling and walking are often presented together by the Department for Transport under the banner of ‘active travel’. However, there can be difficulties with this approach. One difficulty posed by considering cycling and walking together is that there can be a conflict between the two. Pedestrians report frustrations with cyclists failing to stop at red lights, or cycling on the pavement. The charity Living Streets (formerly known as the Pedestrians’ Association) has noted that while cycling on the pavement was often due to cyclists being too scared to cycle on the roads, the behaviour caused “great distress in particular to older or infirm pedestrians”, adding that: In some cases, evidenced anecdotally by some of our supporters in London, pavement cycling can result in contributing to the isolation of some people as they may fear Road.cc press notice, “CTC calls for corporate manslaughter prosecutions after Alan Neve case”, 10 April 2015 418 for more information, see HC Library briefing paper SN1496 419 ibid. 420 “Lorry driver banned from the roads five times admits jumping red light and killing cyclist”, London Evening Standard, 9 April 2015 421 for more information on these matters, see section 3.4 of HC Library briefing paper SN2254 417 117 Transport 2015 being hit by a cyclist whilst walking down their street which causes them to decide not to leave their home.422 In 2013 32 pedestrians were seriously injured as a result of collisions with cyclists per billion kilometres cycled, compared with 17 pedestrians injured by collisions with cars.423 However, these figures do not control for the different types of roads which cyclists and car users travel on (i.e. the high percentage of car journey miles undertaken on the Strategic Road Network where there are no pedestrians, and the high use of pedestrian-heavy residential and urban roads by cyclists). Pedestrians and cyclists do, however, have shared concerns about some aspects of road design and use. For example, many cycling and pedestrian campaigners are united in support for an extension of 20 mph speed limits. Living Streets has argued that reducing vehicle speeds on Britain’s streets would be “the single biggest measure to transforming our streets into safe, people-centred streets”.424 Motorists In December 2012 the BBC broadcast a documentary The War on Britain’s Roads, which aimed to explore whether there was a conflict between motorists and cyclists. The programme was criticised as sensationalist, and for failing to reflect the behaviour of the majority of cyclists.425 Throughout the 2010 Parliament, however, there were frequent media reports of a ‘war’ between cyclists and motorists.426 In April 2012 the Chairman of minicab firm Addison Lee, John Griffin, criticised the increase in cyclists on London’s roads: This summer the roads will be thick with bicycles. These cyclists are throwing themselves on to some of the most congested spaces in the world. They leap on to a vehicle which offers them no protection except a padded plastic hat. […] The rest of us occupying this road space have had to undergo extensive training. We are sitting inside a protected space with impact bars and air bags and paying extortionate amounts of taxes on our vehicle purchase, parking, servicing, insurance and road tax. It is time for us to say to cyclists, 'You want to join our gang, get trained and pay up'.427 422 Transport Committee, Evidence to the Cycling Safety inquiry from Living Streets (CYS 37), November 2013 423 DfT, Reported Accidents, vehicles and casualties, Table RAS 40004, September 2014 424 Living Streets, In favour of 20 mph [accessed 5 May 2015] 425 “BBC cycle film condemned as dangerous nonsense”, The Times, 3 December 2012 426 see, e.g.: “Why the war between drivers and cyclists?”, BBC News online, 22 May 2013; “Cyclists vs motorists: a phoney war between two tribes who should be on the same side”, The Independent, 24 November 2013; “The road to hell: will the war between motorists and cyclists ever end?”, Metro, 19 May 2012 427 “Addison Lee minicab boss’s criticism of cyclists angers bike lobby”, The Guardian, 20 April 2012 [cyclists have criticised Mr Griffin’s use of the term “road tax”, which was abolished in 1937] Number 7177, 13 May 2015 118 In November 2012 the President of the AA, Edmund King, noted that there had been a ‘two tribe’ mentality, fostered by both cyclists and motorists and called for better behaviour by both groups: We really must get past the dangerous ‘them and us’ mentality that sours interactions between different groups (and even subgroups) of road users – be they pedestrians, cyclists, motorcyclists or drivers of vehicles large and small. Cycle campaigners often do themselves no favours in this respect, and motorists can be just as bad. Motorists see cyclists running red lights. Cyclists see motorists cutting them up. We need better behaviour all round. We’re not yet like the Netherlands, owning lots of cars, but moving around town by bike. Yet the majority of motorists have bicycles at home and the majority of cyclists have cars. When we release our grip on the steering wheel or handlebars, the differences disappear. We need to change things culturally, and I think this is happening – slowly.428 Cyclists have suggested that one of the root causes of any hostility with drivers has been the road infrastructure. Katja Leyendecker, Chair of Newcastle’s Cycling Campaign, Newcycling, has argued that improving the road layout would make cyclists’ behaviour clearer and more predictable, and help reduce conflict between cyclists and drivers.429 Carlton Reid, executive editor of BikeBiz magazine, argued that a lack of road space caused ‘flashpoints’ between different user groups.430 One such ‘flashpoint’ has been London. For example, Stephen Glaister, then Director of the RAC Foundation, argued that the proposed segregated cycle superhighway in London would cause business costs to rise and deliveries put at risk.431 Roger Lawson of the Association of British Drivers argued that the scheme favoured cyclists over other road users, and had unfairly removed road capacity from motorists.432 In November 2013 the Conservative peer Lord James of Blackheath cited his experiences as a motorist and argued that The Times’ campaign was “creating a new and separate society in London, in which cyclists think they have a superior law and control over everybody in a motor car. This is going to lead to some catastrophic accidents very soon”.433 Successive governments have supported cycling safety through the THINK! campaign, which aims to encourage safer behaviour to reduce the number of people killed and injured on the roads. One of the main premises of the THINK! campaign is that as 80% of cyclists “Chain reaction”, The AA Magazine, Autumn 2012 op cit., Cycling safety, para 24 430 “The road to hell: will the war between motorists and cyclists ever end?”, Metro, 19 May 2012 431 “Mayor of London unveils segregated urban cycleways”, BBC News online, 3 September 2014 432 “Motorist group brands London cycling plan “bonkers”, BBC News online, 7 March 2013 433 HL Deb 20 November 2013, c992 428 429 119 Transport 2015 have driving licences, and 20% of drivers cycle regularly, cyclists and motorists are often the same people.434 HGVs and buses HGVs and buses are disproportionately more likely to be involved in cyclist fatalities.435 For example, in all five cases of cyclists killed in road traffic collisions in London between 1 January and 9 April 2015, the cyclist was hit by an HGV.436 Across the country as a whole, between 2008 and 2013 18% of cycling fatalities involved HGVs, despite the vehicles only accounting for 5% of motor traffic.437 Transport for London (TfL) figures released in July 2014 found that while HGV collisions had been responsible for a greater number of cyclist deaths than collisions with buses, there had been a higher number of serious injuries caused by bus collisions.438 Overall, the number of cyclists killed or seriously injured (KSI) per kilometre was higher for buses than HGVs.439 Cyclists and freight organisations have been lobbying at a European level for changes to the design of HGV cabs to improve the visibility of cyclists. The Department for Transport told the Transport Committee in 2014 that civil servants had “negotiated improved requirements in international (UN-CE) regulations for mirrors on the passenger side of vehicles, which will mean that drivers have a better view of the area adjacent to the cab, which should improve safety for cyclists”, and that ministers had urged the Commission to implement these changes. Further amendments to the design regulations for HGV cabs were agreed by the European Parliament in March 2015, increasing the size allowed for the cabs, improving the visibility of cyclists.440 The amended regulations will not come into force until 2022.441 There have also been calls for better training for HGV drivers, and cyclists, on cycle safety. The Metropolitan Police’s ‘Exchanging Places Scheme’ has since 2007 seen more than 15,000 cyclists taking the opportunity to sit in the cab of an HGV to understand the driver’s view of the road, and learn the location of blind spots from the cab.442 British Cycling has recommended making cycle awareness training a mandatory part of the drivers’ Certificate of Professional Competence (CPC) qualification.443 DfT press notice, “Driver and cyclists agree: “let’s look out for each other””, 20 September 2012 435 DfT, Reported Road Casualties 2013: Annual Report, September 2014, p39 436 Beyond the Kerb, UK Cycling Fatalities 2015 [accessed 9 April 2015] 437 op cit., Reported accidents, vehicles and casualties, Table RAS40004 438 GLA press notice, “News from Darren Johnson AM: Buses as dangerous as lorries for cyclists, but less fatal”, 3 July 2014 439 ibid. 440 ECF press notice, “Safer lorry designs come closer though moratorium locked in until 2022”, 10 March 2015 441 ECF press notice, “Bittersweet EU-decision on lorry design and cycling fatalities”, 24 March 2015 442 Met press notice, “New dedicated Met ‘Exchanging Places’ truck arrives”, 29 January 2015 443 op cit., Evidence to the Transport Select Committee inquiry “Cycling safety” (CYS 043); for more information on the CPC, see HC Library briefing paper SN3060 434 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 120 Some cycling groups have argued that changes to the design and mirrors of HGV cabs, and greater training for HGV drivers would be less successful in reducing cyclist fatalities compared to simply separating cyclists and large vehicles or banning large vehicles altogether.444 6.5 Issues for the 2015 Parliament Will cycling remain a political priority? As set out above, over the course of the last Parliament cycling rose up the political agenda and there is no obvious reason why it would decline in the 2015 Parliament.445 This is because it generally fits in with wider trends that successive governments have seized on to do with better public health and greener public spaces. As the Mayor of London has argued: “helping cyclists will not just help cyclists. It will create better places for everyone” through a reduction in congestion and safer, more attractive, streets.446 The two main parties and the Liberal Democrats all expressed support for cycling in their 2015 manifestos, although the level of this support was criticised by some journalists (see below).447 Should government provide more funding? As set out above, over the 2010 Parliament cycling groups called on the Government to commit a sizeable increase in central funding for cycling on a long term basis. The provision for a Cycling and Walking Investment Strategy in the Infrastructure Act 2015 is a step towards that, though it is far from guaranteed. Further, as successive governments have moved away from hypothecation of funding (i.e. specifying what a pot of money must be spent on), it seems unlikely that any funding could be guaranteed if it came out of the general ‘local government funding’ pot (see section 2, above). In terms of the two main parties, the Conservatives pledged that they would “invest over £200 million to make cycling safer”, a figure which The Times argued was only a fifth of the recommended funding level, and only a third of the investment provided over the 2015 Parliament.448 Labour’s manifesto did not specify what funding would be available for cycling, but it did make a separate announcement.449 Only the Liberal Democrats committed to the APPCG 444 op cit., Cycling safety, paras 38-39 see, e.g. “How cycling has gone up the election agenda in London”, BBC News online, 1 May 2012; “Vote Cycling”, The Times, 30 October 2014 446 op cit., The Mayor’s Vision for Cycling in London 447 “Which party’s manifesto is strongest on cycling”, The Guardian, 18 April 2015; “The #cyclesafe manifesto guide”, The Times, 15 April 2015 448 op cit., Strong Leadership, A Clear Economic Plan, A Brighter More Secure Future: The Conservative Party Manifesto 2015, p15 449 op cit., Britain can be better: The Labour Party Manifesto 2015, p19; the figure involved is reportedly an extra £89 million for cycling and walking [“Labour Party makes £300m General Election pledge to end Britain’s ‘pothole crisis’”, The Mirror, 20 April 2015] 445 121 Transport 2015 recommendation of £10 per head per year of Government funding for cycling infrastructure in their manifesto.450 Responding to the manifestos Chris Boardman criticised the “shortsightedness” of the Conservatives and Labour for treating cycling as a “marginal issue” and failing to “commit to giving cycling the investment it deserves as a legitimate transport option”.451 Is cycling just a London issue? Cycling has grown in London and has been a focus of policymaking for the current and previous Mayor. However, London is not alone in seeing cycle growth, nor in fact is it the leader. In London, the number of people commuting by bike more than doubled between 2001 and 2011 (from 77,000 to 155,000)452 and in 2013 there were more bikes than cars travelling over the main bridges over the Thames, with cyclists accounting for a quarter of all rush-hour traffic on all roads in central London.453 However, London was not the only region to see more people cycling to work: similar trends were seen in Brighton and Hove and the City of Bristol; and in Cambridge 29% of all journeys to work were made by bike in 2011.454 Cambridge, Oxford and the Isles of Scilly also lead the way for the proportion of the population cycling, as shown below: 450 op cit., Manifesto 2015: Strong Economy. Fairer Society. Opportunity for Everyone., p88 451 “The #cyclesafe manifesto guide”, The Times, 15 April 2015 452 op cit., 2011 Census Analysis - Cycling to Work 453 GLA/Mayor of London press notice, “Bikes make up a quarter of rush-hour traffic in central London, new survey shows”, 25 June 2013 454 op cit., 2011 Census Analysis - Cycling to Work Number 7177, 13 May 2015 122 Generally, cycling has been more likely to grow in towns and cities, with large professional or student populations. However, this may mean that the dangers of rural roads, compared to urban roads, are underestimated. Although only 40% of cycle traffic is carried on rural roads, they account for more than half of all cyclist fatalities.455 The Campaign to Protect Rural England (CPRE) criticised the Government’s 2011 road safety strategy for failing to mention that cycling was three times more dangerous on rural than urban roads, or to propose specific solutions to the dangers of rural cycling.456 Claire Francis, head of policy at Sustrans, has argued that the rest of the country has not followed London’s lead with investment in infrastructure to make the roads safer for cyclists.457 There are, however, good examples of cycling infrastructure being introduced outside the capital. Segregated cycleways are being introduced in Bristol, and cycle tracks installed on Oxford Road in Manchester; Hills 455 DfT, Reported Road Casualties 2013: Annual Report, September 2014, p40 CPRE, Written evidence to the Transport Committee’s Road Safety inquiry, October 2011 457 “Pedal power: Why London is ahead of the pack on cycling”, The Guardian, 1 April 2015 456 123 Transport 2015 Road and Huntingdon Road in Cambridge; and Newarke Road, Leicester.458 A year-long trial of a cycle-track on George Street in Edinburgh will conclude in September 2015.459 That said, London has probably been the most high-profile in terms of cycling; in part due to the legacy of the 2012 London Olympics. Support from the Mayor of London, Boris Johnson, and his predecessor, Ken Livingstone, has led to higher levels of investment in cycling in London, compared to the rest of the country.460 The March 2013 Mayor’s Vision for Cycling in London set out plans to continue this trend, pledging “transformative change” for how cycling is treated in the capital.461 It committed to £913 million to be spent on cycling by 2023, more than treble the previously-planned levels.462 The Vision set out a clear standard for cycling infrastructure, committing that: We will segregate where possible, though elsewhere we will seek other ways to deliver safe and attractive cycle routes. Timid, half-hearted improvements are out—we will do things at least adequately, or not at all.463 In February 2015 Transport for London approved the proposals from the Vision for “a true Crossrail for the bicycle […] the longest substantially-segregated continuous cycle route of any city in Europe”. The plans include two new segregated cycle routes as well as a segregated expansion of cycle superhighway 5, from Oval to Pimlico, and upgrades to five other existing routes. There was overwhelming public support for the proposals, with 84% of the 21,500 people who responded to TfL’s consultation in favour of the segregated superhighways.464 While some businesses opposed the segregated superhighways, citing longer journey times between Canary Wharf and Heathrow, many other businesses publically expressed their support for the plans. Companies and organisations such as Deloitte, Unilever, Allen & Overy and the CBI argued that the new routes would increase the safety of their staff, and reduce congestion on London’s roads and public transport.465 The CEO of Microsoft UK, Michel Van Der Bel, wrote to TfL to call for the “vital” new superhighways to be “delivered without delay”: […] As it stands, too many of those who commute by bike today have had close calls where cycles and motor traffic mix. We want the commutes of all our staff to be comfortable and safe and the Cycle Superhighways will be a big step toward that goal. […] Our network of offices in the capital will be knitted together by the Cycle Superhighways, and our employees will “Not just London: Five big UK cycling projects outside the capital”, Cycling Weekly, 1 February 2015 459 ibid. 460 for further information see HC Library briefing paper SN1097 461 op cit., The Mayor’s Vision for Cycling in London 462 ibid. 463 ibid. 464 GLA press notice, “Mayor announces final build plans for “Crossrail for the Bike” with traffic delays along route cut by 60 per cent over previous proposals”, 27 January 2015 465 CyclingWorks, All employers [accessed 18 April 2015] 458 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 124 benefit considerably once they are completed. We look forward to using the protected routes to help us attract and retain the people we need to continue to thrive.466 Should local authorities have cycling targets? The Coalition Government generally took the view that local authorities should not have to meet specific targets for delivering transport outcomes, as priorities differ across localities. Rather they believed it was up to those authorities to report successful outcomes and learn from one another. Labour has generally tended towards the view that targets do deliver outcomes as they incentivise local authorities to prioritise policy areas where they might otherwise put on the backburner, thus delivering better overall.467 In 2011 the then Transport Secretary, Philip Hammond, argued that while central Government had an important role to play in road safety, he believed this role should be based on making it easier for road users to behave correctly “instead of resorting to more bureaucracy, targets and regulation”.468 The Coalition’s 2011 Strategic Framework for Road Safety therefore rejected the road safety targets of the previous Government, suggesting that such “central diktats” could constrain local ambitions for road safety.469 The DfT explained to the Transport Select Committee: While we believe that previous road safety targets have been useful we do not consider that over-arching national targets are still necessary for road safety in Great Britain. This is because we do not believe that further persuasion is needed on the importance of road safety. We expect central and local government to continue to prioritise road safety and continue to seek improvements. Instead we need to move to more sophisticated ways to monitor progress which is why we have developed the Road Safety Outcomes Framework.470 The Committee noted that the only countries in the EU that did not have targets as part of their road safety strategies were the UK, Luxembourg and Malta.471 The Association of Chief Police Officers (ACPO) warned the Committee that: … when chief constables are looking at how they manage their resources and deliver in terms of safety, they will not necessarily look at roads policing because there are no national targets.472 The Chartered Institute of Highways and Transportation (CIHT) has argued that there was “solid evidence” that road casualty reduction targets were successful in reducing road deaths and injury.473 Chris CyclingWorks press notice, “Microsoft backs new London Cycle Superhighway plans”, 30 October 2014 467 these arguments are rehearsed in more detail in HC Library briefing paper RP 11/22 468 DfT, Strategic Framework for Road Safety, May 2011, p5 469 ibid., p8 470 Transport Committee, Road Safety (second report of session 2012-13), HC 506, 18 July 2012, para 8 471 ibid. 472 ibid., para 9 473 Transport Committee, Written evidence from the Chartered Institute of Highways and Transportation (CYS 57), November 2013 466 125 Transport 2015 Boardman criticised the Government in 2013 for the absence of targets or monitoring of local authority activity. He called for a series of targets, set nationally, and with accompanying timescales.474 There is a difference between targets for increased cycling, and targets for reducing the number of cyclists killed or seriously injured. The CTC has called for targets for increased cycle use and also “national and local targets for improved cycle safety, measured both in ‘rate-based’ terms (e.g. risk per mile or per trip) and in terms of public perceptions of cycle safety”. The CTC warned that: … simplistic casualty reduction targets can be even more problematic than having no targets at all. These have in the past created a perverse incentive for road safety officers not to encourage cycling, for fear that more cycle use would undermine those targets.475 In 2012 the then Transport Minister, Norman Baker, made a similar point: Targets are superficially attractive but can produce perverse consequences. For example, any sensible target on the reduction in number of deaths among cyclists would have to take into account the number of cyclists out there and the number of miles that they cycle. That is the relationship that counts. It is the deaths per 100,000 miles or whatever way you want to describe it. That is quite difficult to tie down. 476 Road.cc press notice, “Chris Boardman slams Government “apathy” on cycling & calls for “commitment” to goals”, 21 January 2014 475 Transport Committee, Written evidence from CTC (CYS 53), December 2013 476 Oral evidence taken before the Transport Select Committee, HC 506, 24 April 2012, Q455 474 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 126 7. Policy focus 5: airport expansion 7.1 What’s the issue? The UK needs more airport capacity Even before the liberalisation of the European air travel market in the early 1990s the policy of consecutive governments – Labour and Conservative – was to encourage the growth of airport capacity in the UK.477 This was the ‘predict and provide’ policy that subsequently exercised those who argued that aviation should be managed rather than encouraged, due to its environmental impacts. For example, in its 1978 White Paper the Labour Government said that additional airport capacity would be needed in the South East in the 1980s to meet the forecast demand for air travel and because the scope for diversion of passengers to airports outside the South East was limited.478 In December 1979 the Conservative Government announced, on the basis of the reports of the Study Group on South-East Airports and the Advisory Committee on Airports Policy, its intention to provide additional airport capacity, as the traffic developed, based on the existing airports in the South East, particularly Heathrow, Gatwick and Stansted. The then Secretary of State for Trade, John Nott, said: We have considered whether it would be right to ignore the likely demand so that traffic became increasingly stifled or diverted to the Continent. Such a decision, or lack of a decision, would lead to developing chaos at our existing airports. A modern Western society, heavily engaged in international trade and with a major stake in the airline business, can hardly fail to provide for consumer demand, both for leisure and business. But given the inherent uncertainty of any forecast, the solution that we need is one that meets the demand in London and the South-East only as it develops…479 In June 1985 the Conservative Government published its White Paper on airports policy. This stated that it was the responsibility of government to ensure that there were adequate airport facilities to meet demand and that “failure to provide sufficient capacity will reduce the scope for airline competition to the detriment of the travelling public”.480 In 1990 the Government commissioned the Runway Capacity to Serve the South East (RUCATSE) study; this reported in July 1993.481 The then Secretary of State for Transport, Dr Brian Mawhinney, gave the Government’s official response to RUCATSE in February 1995. He said that RUCATSE's analysis showed “a strong case for additional runway capacity in the south477 a history of failed expansion in the South East, including the Roskill Commission and Maplin Sands can be found in HC Library briefing paper SN4920 478 Secretary of State for Trade, Airports Policy, Cmnd 7084, February 1978, para 154, p43 479 HC Deb 17 December 1979, c36 480 Secretary of State for Transport, Airports Policy, Cmnd 9542, June 1985, para 12.10, pp56-7 481 DoT, Runway capacity to Service the South East: a report by the Working Group, July 1993 127 Transport 2015 east” but that more work was needed to inform decisions on any proposals which operators might bring forward for that additional capacity. Further, the then owner of Heathrow and Gatwick should not consider bringing forward proposals for a third or second runway respectively.482 The Labour Government’s first (and last) White Paper on aviation was published in December 2003. Like its predecessors, it stated that air travel had grown significantly in the past and was projected to grow strongly in the future. It said that “simply building more and more capacity to meet demand is not a sustainable way forward” while acknowledging that there was “an urgent need for additional runway capacity in the South East”. To this end it advocated building two new runways in the South East, first at Stansted (by 2012) and then at Heathrow (by 2020) “but only if stringent environmental limits can be met”.483 A second runway at Stansted failed to receive planning permission and was eventually withdrawn. In one of its last major transport policy decisions before the 2010 General Election, the Labour Government confirmed its support for a third runway and sixth terminal at Heathrow.484 In practice, all the major airports in the South East continually expanded from the 1960s onwards. In particular, after 1979 Heathrow grew by two terminals, including the contentious Terminal 5. However, the last major new runway built in Great Britain was the second runway at Manchester in 2001.485 The question as to whether the UK, and particularly the South East of England, needs new airport capacity rests largely on two points: whether future increased demand would otherwise make travel through existing airports impossible without more capacity and the economic benefits of increased capacity to the UK economy. Aviation is fundamentally an international market, and as the Airports Commission (see below) made clear in its 2013 report, passenger demand for air travel has been on a persistent upward trend since the middle of the twentieth century, and has grown strongly since the 1970s, driven by economic growth, increasing affluence, and realterm reductions in air fares. Demand growth is increasingly coming from emerging economies, particularly in the Asia-Pacific region, which could see something like a three-fold increase in outbound trips between 2010 and 2020.486 The Commission stated that these global developments had driven significant changes in the UK aviation sector. In particular, the consolidation around major hubs “has entrenched the dominance of the London aviation market and particularly Heathrow, the UK’s 482 HC Deb 2 February 1995, cc859-60W DfT, The Future of Air Transport, Cm 6046, December 2003, pp9&13-14 484 for further information on expansion at Heathrow, see HC Library briefing paper SN1136 485 for further information on Manchester’s second runway, see HC Library briefing paper SN101 486 Airports Commission, Airports Commission: Interim Report, December 2013, p41 483 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 128 largest airport”.487 Overall, the UK has the biggest aviation market in Europe, and London the largest OD (origin and destination) market in the world. Historically passenger demand for aviation has risen in line with or faster than GDP since 1960:488 In light of this, the Commission stated that: … problems are starting to emerge and are likely to get worse. Heathrow is effectively full. Gatwick is operating at more than 85% of its maximum capacity, and is completely full at peak times. Capacity constraints are making it more and more difficult for airports and airlines to operate efficiently, lay on new routes, and deal with resilience issues. More intensive runway use also makes it harder to offer appropriate and predictable respite from noise for people living and working near airports. The current approach of forcing ever greater volumes of traffic through the existing infrastructure, if continued, would also have increasingly detrimental effects on the national economy, businesses, and air passengers. The Commission’s analysis suggests that the costs of failing to address these issues could amount, over a sixty-year time period, to: £18-20 billion of costs to users and providers of airport infrastructure. £30-45 billion of costs to the wider economy. 489 Heathrow has long been of special concern as it is considered to be ‘full’. The Commission explained: Heathrow is subject to a planning cap of 480,000 ATMs per annum, which broadly equates to the maximum achievable 487 ibid., p54 ibid., figure 3.1, p56 489 ibid., p55 488 129 Transport 2015 capacity from its two runways operating under segregated mode. It has operated more than 470,000 movements – almost 98% of capacity – in six of the last ten years. Only in 2010, when air traffic across Europe was affected by the Icelandic volcanic ash incident, did average utilisation drop below 95%, and even then by less than 2%. This rate of capacity utilisation is well above the point at which high levels of reliability can be maintained and delays avoided.490 The Commission also stated that Gatwick operates at over 85% capacity over the course of the year and above 90% in the summer peak season, and that almost no take-off or landing slots are unused in the busiest hours of the day.491 The Commission concluded that based on demand projections, without additional capacity, major London and South East airports would be full by the 2040s, even with a carbon cap in place:492 The local noise impacts of aviation are significant The negative externalities of air transport are significant and well known, they include noise, air quality and wider environmental and climate change impacts. This section focuses on local noise impacts; with wider environmental question is addressed below in section 7.5. There is a long-standing, ongoing debate about the relationship between exposure to aircraft nosie and its effect or perceived effects. The Coalition Government’s March 2013 Aviation Policy Framework explains: Although there is some evidence that people’s sensitivity to aircraft noise appears to have increased in recent years, there are still large uncertainties around the precise change in relationship between annoyance and the exposure to aircraft noise. There is evidence that there are people who consider themselves annoyed by aircraft noise who live some distance from an airport in locations where aircraft are at relatively high altitudes. Conversely, some people living closer to an airport seem to be tolerant of such noise […] Average noise exposure contours are a well-established measure of annoyance and are important to show historic trends in total noise around airports. However, the Government recognises that people do not experience noise in an averaged 490 ibid., p78 ibid., p78 492 ibid., figure 4.4, p112 491 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 130 manner and that the value of the LAeq indicator does not necessarily reflect all aspects of the perception of aircraft noise. For this reason we recommend that average noise contours should not be the only measure used when airports seek to explain how locations under light paths are affected by aircraft noise. Instead the Government encourages airport operators to use alternative measures which better reflect how aircraft noise is experienced in different localities […]. 493 The Airports Commission’s July 2013 aviation noise discussion paper attempted to give comparative figures for those affected by aviation noise as opposed to other transport noise: The number of people deemed to be affected by transport noise will depend on the noise metric used […] However, to give a sense of the relative numbers affected from each mode, the strategic noise mapping that took place in England in 2006 estimated that 4.2 million people are exposed to road traffic noise of 65 decibels (dB) (LDEN) or more, and found that the corresponding figures for railways and aviation are 0.2m people and 0.07m people, respectively.494 The Commission categorised the effects of noise by considering them in three groups: health effects, amenity effects and productivity and learning effects.495 In terms of health effects from aviation noise, the Commission stated that the link between noise and hypertension was ‘fairly well’ established and that the 2008 European HYENA study, which focused on a number of major European airports, found that night time aircraft noise was associated with increased hypertension and that aircraft noise events are associated with an elevation of blood 493 DfT, Aviation Policy Framework, Cm 8584, March 2013, para 3.14 & 3.19 Airports Commission, Discussion Paper 05: Aviation Noise, July 2013, para 2.6 495 ibid., fig 2.2., p10 494 131 Transport 2015 pressure.496 In January 2013 the CAA published a literature review on aircraft noise, sleep disturbance and health impacts. It concluded that findings were “not conclusive and are often contradictory, highlighting the practical difficulties in designing studies of this nature”.497 Recent EU research conducted around six European airports found that exposure to aircraft noise at night for more than 20 years could increase the risk of heart disease and stroke.498 A further study published by the British Medical Journal looking at the health of people living in the vicinity of Heathrow found those with the highest exposure were 10 to 20 per cent more likely to be admitted to hospital for stroke, coronary heart disease and cardiovascular disease. There was also an increased risk of death from those diseases. A linked study of the health of more than six million Americans over the age of 65 living around 89 US airports found that, on average, their risk went up 3.5 per cent for every extra 10 decibels of noise.499 On amenity and quality of life the Commission stated that ‘annoyance’ is the most commonly used outcome to evaluate the effect of noise on communities and cited previous studies that showed “the proportion of people being ‘highly annoyed’ at a particular exposure has increased”. In terms of sleep disturbance it said that this was one of the impacts most commonly described by those living with high levels of noise exposure, and one that “can a have a substantial impact upon quality of life”. However, the Commission stated that it was less clear to what extent and at what level noise can cause harmful loss of sleep, and equally whether lesser reactions to noise, which do not involve awakening, can affect general well-being in similar ways.500 Finally, on productivity and learning effects the Commission stated that the European RANCH study found that road traffic students suffered impaired reading comprehension and recognition memory from aircraft noise, likely because of the ‘transient nature’ of aircraft movements, with short term peaks in noise affecting concentration and providing distraction.501 Data from the CAA shows that the top fifteen airports in the UK account for over one-third of the population affected by noise at the European level using standard measurements, with Heathrow accounting for more than a quarter.502 Indeed, the numbers affected at Heathrow is an ongoing topic of debate and concern, particularly in light of proposals to expand the airport. In 2006 there was a separate survey of those living under the Heathrow flight path, commissioned 496 ibid., para 2.25 CAA, Aircraft Noise, Sleep Disturbance and Health Effects: A Review, ERCD Report 1208, January 2013, p65 498 “Aircraft noise at night may lead to long-term health impacts”, Science for Environment Policy, issue 363, 27 February 2014 499 “Aircraft noise may increase risk of heart disease, say researchers”, The Guardian, 8 October 2013 500 op cit., Discussion Paper 05: Aviation Noise, paras 2.13 & 2.17 501 ibid., para 2.31 502 CAA, CAA Insight Note: Aviation Policy For The Environment, p22 [accessed 4 June 2014] 497 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 132 from ICM by the then Mayor of London Ken Livingstone. The survey found that of the 1,001 residents surveyed503 40% were bothered by aircraft noise during the day and 44% felt it had got worse over the previous ten years.504 More recently, Heathrow and the Mayor of London have disagreed as to the numbers of those affected by proposed expansion. Mayor Johnson’s submission to the Airports Commission (more of which, see below) stated that 1,097,200 people live within a 55 decibel noise contour calculated to encompass a three-runway Heathrow; this would be higher if future population growth is factored in). In contrast, he argued that a little over 30,000 would be affected by a four runway airport in the Thames Estuary. Heathrow claims that the number of people impacted by noise would fall by 30 per cent if it is allowed to build a third runway northwest of the existing airport (from 249,000 to 165,000 people based on a 57-decibel contour).505 In its December 2013 interim report the Airports Commission recommended the creation of an Independent Aviation Noise Authority to “provide expert and impartial advice about the noise impacts of aviation and to facilitate the delivery of future improvements to airspace operations”.506 The Commission made this recommendation on the back of a lack of trust between the aviation industry and local communities, in particular: “mistrust amongst local communities in relation to the fairness and transparency of current arrangements for reporting aircraft noise, and for the recording and handling of complaints from members of the public”.507 The Commission noted that such an authority could be well-placed to undertake ‘consistent and regular surveying of attitudes to aviation noise’, including its impacts on health and well-being.508 The Government indicated that it would reserve judgement on whether to proceed with the new authority until after the publication of the final report.509 7.2 What is the Airports Commission? Why was it set up? On 7 September 2012 the Secretary of State for Transport, Patrick McLoughlin, announced that he had asked Sir Howard Davies, the former chairman of the Financial Services Authority, to chair an independent commission tasked with identifying and recommending to Government options for maintaining the country’s status as an international hub for aviation.510 The Commission was tasked with examining the scale and timing of any requirement for additional hub 503 from eight London boroughs - Richmond, Hounslow, Hillingdon, Hammersmith & Fulham, Wandsworth, Lambeth, Kensington & Chelsea and Westminster 504 Mayor of London press notice, “Londoners need peace from aircraft noise, according to poll”, 20 March 2006 505 “Heathrow noise ‘to affect a million’”, The Times, 19 May 2014 506 op cit., Airports Commission: Interim Report, p136 507 ibid., para 5.70 508 ibid., para 5.76 509 HC Deb 15 July 2014, c66WS 510 HC Deb 7 September 2012, c41WS 133 Transport 2015 capacity and identifying and evaluating how any need for additional capacity should be met in the short, medium and long term. The Commission was asked to report before the end of 2013 on: its assessment of the evidence on the nature, scale and timing of the steps needed to maintain the UK’s global hub status; and its recommendation(s) for immediate actions to improve the use of existing runway capacity in the following five years – consistent with’ credible long term options’. The Commission was asked to publish a final report no later than summer 2015 on: its assessment of the options for meeting the UK’s international connectivity needs, including their economic, social and environmental impact; its recommendation(s) for the optimum approach to meeting any needs; its recommendation(s) for ensuring that the need is met as expeditiously as practicable within the required timescale; and to provide materials to support the government of the day in preparing a national policy statement to accelerate the resolution of any future planning applications for major airports infrastructure.511 What has it done? On 17 December 2013 the Commission published its interim report. It concluded that there is a need for one net additional runway to be in operation in the South East of England by 2030 and that there is likely to be a demand case for a second additional runway to be operational by 2050. The Commission announced that it would take forward, for further detailed study, proposals for new runways at Gatwick and Heathrow. The two options for Heathrow are Heathrow Airport Ltd’s proposal for one new 3,500m runway to the northwest and Heathrow Hub’s proposal to extend the existing northern runway to at least 6,000m, enabling the extended runway to operate as two independent runways.512 The Commission’s forecasts indicate that a new runway at Heathrow would be very well-used, with the expanded airport operating at around 80 to 90 per cent of capacity by 2030 and at maximum capacity by 2050.513 The Commission reported that many of the features and impacts of the two Heathrow options are broadly the same. The costs for each would be higher than those for most single runway options considered at other sites, although less than those for the south west runway option at Heathrow. Estimated as costing £13 billion to £18 billion by 2030 they are, however, “much lower than most options with four or more runways, in many cases by several orders of magnitude”.514 DfT press notice, “Airports Commission membership”, 2 November 2012 op cit., Airports Commission: Interim Report, for full details see chapter 6 513 ibid., para 6.88 514 ibid., para 6.91 511 512 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 134 However, each proposal has different, specific impacts, set out by the Commission in its report. For option (a) – one new runway to the north west – these are as follows: a significant increase in capacity of up to 260,000 air traffic movements (ATMs) per year; ‘roughly neutral’ impact on the number of people affected by noise (the new runway would allow a portion of the airport’s traffic to land and take off further to the west than the existing configuration of runways, so those aircraft would fly at a higher altitude over the most densely populated areas); the spread of the noise impact would be over a larger area, meaning that some people would be newly brought within the 57LAeq contour;515 no internationally designated sites would be directly impacted by the proposal (the South West London Waterbodies SPA/Ramsar site would lie within 2km of the expanded airport site, with the potential for some indirect impacts); and requirement for a ‘significant number of demolitions’, totalling approximately 1,500 houses and including the loss of the village of Harmondsworth, much of which is a conservation area. A second conservation area in Longworth would also lose listed buildings (around 30 listed buildings would be lost in total).516 For option (b) – extending the northern runway to the west – the impacts are as follows: a maximum additional capacity of 190,000 ATMs per year; all night flights could use the western portion of the extended runway, resulting in the population falling within the 55 LDen contour, being more than 20,000 lower than for the north western runway option; could potentially encroach upon the South West London Waterbodies SPA/Ramsar site; direct effects on just eight listed buildings (none Grade I or Grade II*) and only indirect effects on the Colnbrook Conservation Area; and relatively few demolitions, with a probable total of 720 properties estimated to be lost.517 The proposal for Gatwick is a new runway over 3,000 metres in length spaced sufficiently south of the existing runway to permit fully independent operation. The Commission stated that its current single runway is already operating at a high level of utilisation and the Commission forecast that it will reach capacity within less than ten years. A second runway could generate more point-to-point movements, possibly to new destinations, which could feed into a ‘hub’ network that might attract a network carrier (like, e.g. BA is at Heathrow). The Commission put the cost of expansion at Gatwick at between £10 billion and £13 billion over the period to 2030, which due to the “relatively strong forecast demand at Gatwick” could “credibly 515 when a noise varies over time, the LAeq is the equivalent continuous sound which would contain the same sound energy as the time varying sound – essentially the average noise level 516 op cit., Airports Commission: Interim Report, paras 6.101-6.106 517 ibid., paras 6.107-6.111 135 Transport 2015 be financed”.518 The Commission estimates that impacts on protected sites, landscape and heritage are limited and there would be no loss of greenbelt land. The proposals would require the development of some 900 hectares of greenfield site (not including road schemes), but this is limited in comparison with some of the larger schemes. On noise impacts, while the proposal “does not offer the same potential to reduce overall noise impacts as a new hub airport”, the number of people affected by noise in the Gatwick area “remain[s] relatively low”.519 In November 2014 the Commission published for consultation its assessment of proposals for additional runway capacity at Gatwick and Heathrow. It invited public comment on its detailed consideration of each proposal. This included analysis of the cost of each proposal, the effect on communities of noise, property loss and construction, and the economic benefits and environmental impacts. The purpose of the consultation was to test the evidence base the Commission had assembled; understand stakeholders’ views as to the accuracy, relevance and breadth of the assessments it had undertaken; and seek views on the potential conclusions that might be drawn from them. There were three separate business cases and sustainability assessments as well as information from the three scheme sponsors (Gatwick Airport, Heathrow Airport and Heathrow Hub) and a number of technical reports.520 The main headline in the consultation was the difference in cost: the Commission projected that the Gatwick scheme would cost approximately £2 billion more and the two Heathrow schemes between £3 billion and £4 billion more than their sponsors originally estimated. However, the consultation paper made it clear that the differences between the sponsors’ estimates and the Commission’s estimates were in large part a result of differing opinions on the application of risk and optimism bias (and for Heathrow Hub/extended runway some smaller differences of opinion on taxiway, land and car parking costs).521 As regards Stansted, the Commission looked at two options for a new hub airport at Stansted: a four-runway and a five-runway airport. It rejected both of these in their own right but also largely in comparison with the Thames Estuary/Isle of Grain hub option. For example, although the £59 billion to £80 billion cost would be less than the Thames Estuary option, Stansted would: 518 not offer the same potential to address noise impacts in the south east of England; have significant environmental and heritage impacts (over 150 listed buildings fall within the proposed footprint for the site, including two Grade I and seven Grade II* buildings, as well as four Scheduled Monuments and one Registered Park and ibid., paras 6.73-6.76 ibid., paras 6.79-6.80 520 Airports Commission, Increasing the UK’s long-term aviation capacity, 11 November 2014 521 ibid., pp26-28, 47-48 [Gatwick], 65-66 [HAHL], and 81-82 [Heathrow Hub] 519 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 136 Garden and it would involve the loss of more than 2,000 hectares of high quality agricultural land and up to six villages); and come with significant risks associated with the level of additional capacity which might be provided.522 In terms of expanding Stansted on a smaller scale (i.e. with a second runway), the Commission did not think there was a strong demand case as the airport is currently running at about half its permitted capacity; costs would be greater than expanding at Gatwick and its 45-to-60-minute catchment area would be smaller.523 The Commission opted not to shortlist any options for Thames estuary airports. While it acknowledged that such proposals had the potential to reduce aviation noise impacts in the South East of England and support economic development on the eastern side of London, they presented many challenges and uncertainties. It also cited expense as a negative factor: the Commission calculated that the cost of an Isle of Grain airport (which it considered the most viable of those presented) could cost up to £112 billion. There were also significant environmental questions and economic uncertainties caused by the fact that a new estuary airport would require Heathrow to close. Taking all this into account the Commission announced its intention to carry out additional analysis in respect of the Isle of Grain option in the first half of 2014.524 On 2 September 2014 the Commission announced its decision not to add the inner Thames estuary airport proposal to its shortlist of options for providing new airport capacity by 2030 on the grounds that the proposal had ‘substantial disadvantages’ that collectively outweighed its potential benefits.525 Generally on regional airports outside the South East, the Commission looked at whether it would be possible to solve the capacity problem in London and the South East by incentivising, or requiring, airlines to make greater use of under-utilised capacity elsewhere. To assess the scope for redistributing traffic, the Commission considered four potential policy levers: taxation (Air Passenger Duty); changes to the slots regime; Traffic Distribution Rules; and, restrictions on aircraft and services at congested airports. It concluded that relatively little scope to redistribute demand exists.526 Furthermore, on issues of surface access, the Commission indicated that its resources and remit meant that it was not the appropriate body to reach a view on many of the schemes proposed for improving access to regional airports. It recommended that the Government work with local authorities and Local Enterprise Partnerships (LEPs) to “ensure that proper consideration is given to 522 ibid., paras 6.47-52 ibid., paras 6.56-6.57 524 ibid., paras 6.24-6.46 525 Airports Commission press notice, “Airports Commission announces inner Thames estuary decision”, 2 September 2014; and full decision: Inner Thames estuary airport: summary and decision 526 op cit., Airports Commission: Interim Report, chapter 4 523 137 Transport 2015 the needs of airport users when prioritising local transport investment”.527 In terms of specific regional proposals, the Commission received two long term proposals for airport expansion that would have had a significant impact on Bristol Airport and Cardiff Airport – it dismissed them both in the first sift. They were: MSP Solutions suggested the construction of an airport in the Severn estuary to replace Bristol and Cardiff airports. The Commission said that the scale of the contribution of a new airport in the Severn Estuary as presented in this proposal to UK airport capacity was “not clear and would not appear to offer additional capacity where the assessment of need identified the demand (the South East)”. Given that Cardiff and Bristol airports would close, any additional capacity benefit may be small compared to the proposed cost; and Severn24 proposed a new two-runway airport on a reclaimed island in the Severn Estuary with road and rail links to the M4 and the Great Western Main Line near Newport. The Commission said that whilst the proposal would provide capacity to serve the South West of England and the south of Wales, it was “not clear that this proposal would add significantly to overall national capacity, given the almost certain operational and commercial need for Cardiff and Bristol airports to close, therefore the additional benefit may be small against the proposed cost”.528 A third proposal affecting Cardiff – from Western Gateway Group – was dismissed in the second sift. The Commission said that the proposal had a high cost due to its high speed requirements and did not deliver any significant additional capacity. Furthermore the “very limited additional capacity it does deliver is in a region of the country where it is not clear that unfulfilled demand exists. Therefore does not meet the requirements identified in the assessment of need”.529 The Commission received one long-term proposal for expansion at Birmingham – it was dismissed in the second sift. The Commission said that significant distance from the key catchment area of London makes it unlikely that Birmingham Airport would cater as well as more proximate options. It would offer the largest catchment of people within two hours of the airport of all options, but this is largely dependent on the journey time assumptions of HS2, which also makes the London airport system easier to access for passengers from Birmingham’s core aviation market. It would also have significant noise impacts. The Commission concluded that the “current demand profile favours other airports”.530 The Commission also made recommendations about making best use of existing capacity, including airport collaborative decision 527 ibid., p161; for more information on local transport planning and funding see HC Library note SN5735 528 ibid., Appendix 2, pp16-17 529 ibid., p22 530 ibid., Appendix 2, p22 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 138 making; airspace changes supporting performance based navigation; enhanced en-route traffic management; and time based separation.531 When will it report? The Commission’s final report is expected in Summer 2015. In evidence to the Transport Committee in March 2015 the Secretary of State for Transport, Patrick McLoughlin, said that he would “expect the report to be with the Secretary of State for Transport in July or August—around that sort of time”.532 7.3 Will the recommendations of the Airports Commission be implemented? This is the big question and ultimately it will come down to the airports themselves to take the initiative and put in a Development Consent application for any expansion proposal. The Secretary of State for Transport is likely to have the ultimate say, as set out below. Political parties not committed Perhaps unsurprisingly, before the 2015 General Election no political party committed to implementing the Airports Commission’s recommendations, whatever those might be. As indicated in section 2, above, the Conservatives said that they would “respond to the Airports Commission’s final report”.533 Sir Howard Davies has repeatedly indicated his frustration with the ‘political’ aspects of his inquiry, and particularly the idea that after two and a half years of detailed work, the Government of the day might not heed his recommendations. In an interview with The Observer, shortly after he was appointed, Sir Howard acknowledged that “he ‘can't be convinced’ that when he reports in 2015 the politicians will actually listen”.534 More recently in December 2014 the media reported on Sir Howard’s comments at an aviation conference where one audience member suggested to him that the new Government after May 2015 might not reach a decision on expanding either Gatwick or Heathrow, “however thorough your recommendations will be”. He replied: Well, hey, what do you want me to say? Do you want me to stand here and say, ‘hey guys, I’ve been wasting my f-----g time for the last two-and-a-half years?’ If you start saying, ‘the Government has looked at this for 40 years, they’ve never decided before, and they’re not going to decide next time, then you will get what you wish for.535 The reasons for this uncertainty are ultimately the same as those behind the decision to appoint an independent commission in the first 531 ibid., pp12-13; full details in chapter 5 Transport Committee, Oral evidence: Work of the Department for Transport, HC 1109, 9 March 2015, Q24 533 op cit., Strong Leadership, A Clear Economic Plan, A Brighter More Secure Future: The Conservative Party Manifesto 2015, p14 534 “Under pressure: the man who must rule on next UK airport”, The Observer, 3 November 2012 535 “City Diary: Government guru lets off steam over airports saga”, Daily Telegraph, 10 December 2014 532 139 Transport 2015 place: there are critical constituencies in the South East of England where support for airport expansion is an electoral liability; similarly there are others where significant numbers of people depend on Heathrow or Gatwick for employment and opposition to expansion is a liability. While this may have had an impact on how some decided to vote in May 2015, as indicated below, ultimately no local MP will have to vote for or against a new or extended runway at either airport. Parliament has a limited role One of the important things to note about this whole process is that it is not a Parliamentary one. There will be no Parliamentary Bill, no opportunity for MPs to vote a proposal through or vote it down, or to amend the proposal in Parliament. However, Parliament will have the opportunity to approve the Government’s National Policy Statement on Aviation, which in all likelihood will have to be ‘designated’ before a decision could be taken on any Development Consent application put forward by Heathrow or Gatwick (see below). There will naturally be extra-Parliamentary opportunities for MPs to exert influence and express their views on any specific proposal. Onus is on the airports to put in application for a DCO Expansion at either Heathrow or Gatwick would be considered a Nationally Significant Infrastructure Project (NSIP). The Planning Act 2008 introduced a new Development Consent process for NSIPs. NSIPs are usually large scale developments (relating to energy, transport, water, or waste) which require a type of consent known as ‘Development Consent’. An extension of the regime in 2013 now allows certain business and commercial projects to opt into this process. A Development Consent Order (DCO) automatically removes the need to obtain several separate consents, including planning permission, and is designed to be a much quicker process than applying for these separately. The DCO process starts when an application is formally accepted by the National Infrastructure Planning Unit and lasts approximately 12-15 months. The final decision on granting a DCO rests with the Secretary of State for that field, based on advice from planning inspectors – known as the ‘examining authority’. Applications for DCOs are decided in accordance with National Policy Statements (NPSs), which after a process of consultation and Parliamentary scrutiny are formally ‘designated’ by Government.536 Local opposition As we saw in 2007-09 when Heathrow was given approval for a third runway, there is likely to be considerable local opposition to any 536 more detailed information on NSIPs and the DCO process can be found in HC Library briefing paper SN6881 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 140 airport expansion at Gatwick or Heathrow. Local campaign groups are well organised and supported by prominent individuals.537 Due to the new planning process for this sort of development (see above) it is unlikely that campaigners will be able to delay the planning process in a way that has been possible in the past.538 However, there may be more ‘direct action’ such as was seen in 2013 over plans to test drill for shale gas at Balcombe in West Sussex and back in the late 1990s over Manchester’s second runway.539 Shortly after the granting of planning permission for the second runway at Manchester in 1997 environmental campaigners built 25 tree houses in two camps to establish their presence before the contractors secured the site.540 They were also claiming to have built two tunnels. A Judge in the High Court in Manchester refused the protesters a stay of execution on 10 May pending their appeal against possession orders granted to the airport and developers at an earlier hearing.541 There were also reports that bailiffs had admitted that there were substantial obstacles in clearing the protesters from the runway site. Several protesters who had previously been evicted had set up camps on airport land nearby and five were hiding in a network of underground tunnels, some as deep as 70ft.542 The additional cost of policing the protests was put at over £270,000 in May 1997. Protests renewed at various stages of construction, particularly in 1999 when Cedar’s Wood and Arthur’s Wood were cleared. 7.4 What else has happened since 2010? LHR had a plan ready to go in 2010 and withdrew it Before the 2010 General Election both the Conservative and Liberal Democrat parties had indicated that they were opposed to a third runway and a sixth terminal at Heathrow and had long campaigned against it. When the then Labour Government announced in January 2009 its intention to invite BAA to put forward a planning application for a third runway and a sixth terminal,543 the then Shadow Transport Secretary, Theresa Villiers, said that the Conservatives would “fight them every step of the way”.544 Subsequently, the Conservative Party Manifesto for the 2010 election stated: “Our goal is to make Heathrow airport better, not bigger. We will stop the third runway and instead see, e.g. AirportWatch, HACAN, and GACC; on the ‘celebrity angle’, see e.g. “Celebrities buy Heathrow land to delay third runway”, The Guardian, 13 January 2009 538 e.g. the planning public inquiry into Heathrow Terminal 5 took almost four years, making it the longest in UK planning history; for further information see section 7 of HC Library briefing paper SN1136 539 for more information on shale gas and fracking see HC Library briefing paper SN6073 540 "Protesters dig in as runway deal awarded", Financial Times, 11 February 1997 541 "Protesters lose eviction battle", Financial Times, 11 May 1997 542 "Bailiffs admit serious obstacles in runway battles", Financial Times, 28 May 1997; the most famous of whom was ‘Swampy’ 543 HC Deb 15 January 2009, cc357-358; the documentation published alongside the Secretary of State’s statement, including a report on the consultation responses, is available on the DfT archive website 544 HC Deb 15 January 2009, c360 537 141 Transport 2015 link Heathrow directly to our high speed rail network, providing an alternative to thousands of flights”.545 Following the election and the formation of the Conservative-Liberal Democrat Coalition Government, the Coalition Agreement stated: “We will cancel the third runway at Heathrow”.546 In May 2010, following the election of the Coalition Government, BAA (now Heathrow Airport Holdings Limited), the owners of Heathrow, announced that they would abandon their plans for a third runway and a sixth terminal at the airport.547 However, there followed concerted lobbying by the airport itself, the main airlines that use it and by business to persuade the Government to look again at its policy on Heathrow. This was a contributory factor to the appointment of the Airports Commission. Air Passenger Duty Over the course of the 2010 Parliament there was a long-running campaign to reform or abolish Air Passenger Duty (APD). Since the Scottish Independence referendum in September 2014 there have also been concerned expressed about the possible impact of devolution of APD. APD is essentially a departure tax on all passenger flights from UK airports. The rate of tax varies according to passenger destination and the class of passenger travel. The tax is estimated to raise £3.2 billion in 2014-15.548 Some commentators have argued that APD should be charged on planes rather than passengers, to provide better incentives for passengers and airlines to cut carbon emissions from aviation. In January 2008 the Labour Government launched a consultation on just such a change, but in November that year the then Chancellor Alistair Darling announced that instead of a per-plane duty, APD would be restructured: the tax would be based on four geographical bands set at intervals of 2,000 miles, so that travellers flying farther would pay a higher rate of duty.549 The new structure took effect from 1 November 2009, despite concerns about the impact of the new system for passengers making long-haul flights, particularly those making journeys to the Caribbean.550 During the 2010 election campaign both the Conservatives and the Liberal Democrats argued for reforming APD, and alongside the 2011 Budget the Government published a consultation paper setting out options for simplifying the rate structure as well as proposals to extend the scope of the tax to flights on business.551 In December 2011 the Government announced that it would proceed with 545 Conservative Party, Invitation to join the government of Britain: General Election Manifesto 2010, April 2010, p23 546 HMG, The Coalition: Our Programme for Government, May 2010, p16 547 BAA Heathrow press notice, “Heathrow updates local residents”, 24 May 2010 548 OBR, Economic and fiscal outlook, Cm 9024, March 2015, para 4.94, p121 549 HC Deb 24 November 2008, c499 550 for more details see HC Library briefing papers SN6426 and SN413 551 HMT, Reform of Air Passenger Duty: a consultation, March 2011, para 1.4 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 142 extending the tax to business aviation, with effect from 1 April 2013, but that it would retain the current banding structure.552 Generally the Government has opposed cutting tax rates or abolishing the tax on grounds of cost.553 However in his 2014 Budget the Chancellor, George Osborne, announced that from April 2015 the four-band structure of the tax would be replaced with two bands, with all long-haul flights charged the same rate of tax.554 Since 1 May 2015, children under the age of 12 years on the date of the flight, travelling in economy, have been exempt from APD.555 Children under the age of 16 will be exempt form 1 March 2016.556 As to the potential impacts of devolution, there have been concerns expressed about the cross-border impacts of any devolved – and presumably lower – rate of APD in Scotland, particularly as it might affect competing English regional airports such as Newcastle, Durham Tees Valley, Liverpool and Manchester. Northern Ireland provides an interesting example: in 2011 the Northern Ireland Affairs Committee published a report on APD in which it recommended that the tax should be abolished for flights both to and from airports in Northern Ireland, because of competition from airports in the Republic and the threat this posed to one particular transatlantic route.557 In September 2011 the Chancellor announced that to maintain this route, the Government would cut the rate of APD on long haul flights using airports in Northern Ireland as “a response to the unique challenge facing Northern Ireland and is designed to ensure local airports remain competitive”.558 When the House debated the annual changes to APD rates at Committee stage of the Finance Bill on 18 April 2013 there was discussion of new clauses put down by the SNP and Plaid Cymru for the devolution of APD to the Scottish and Welsh governments respectively.559 As indicated in section 3, above, in November 2014 the Smith Commission report was published. This recommended that APD be devolved to the Scottish Parliament, along with the power for the Scottish Government to ‘make its own arrangements’ with regard to the design and collection of any replacement tax.560 In terms of the possible regional impacts of this change, there has been some pressure to look at devolving APD entirely, so that it could be set on a regional basis. This may emerge more strongly in the next year or so, depending on how the debate about English devolution 552 HMT, Reform of Air Passenger Duty: response to consultation, December 2011 HC Deb 23 October 2013, c403 554 HMT, Budget 2014, HC 1104, March 2014, paras 2.160-1 555 HMRC, Excise Notice 550: Air Passenger Duty, 27 February 2015, section 3.1.2 556 HMT, Autumn Statement 2014, Cm 8961, December 2014, para 1.223 557 NIA Committee, Air Passenger Duty: implications for Northern Ireland (Second report of 2010-12), HC 1227, 8 July 2011, paras 5, 18-19 558 HC Deb 19 October 2011, c964W and HM Treasury press notice, “Chancellor announces overhaul of Northern Ireland flight tax”, 107/11, 27 September 2011 559 HC Deb 18 April 2013, cc601-2; in the event both new clauses were negatived on division 560 op cit., Report of the Smith Commission for further devolution of powers to the Scottish Parliament, p24 553 143 Transport 2015 progresses. There was some debate on this issue in 2011/12 and in its December 2013 interim report the Airports Commission (see above) stated that: “Regional variations in APD could potentially give rise to perverse incentives, for example to not use spare capacity in London and the South East, as currently exists at Stansted and Luton”. Indeed on devolution to Scotland and Wales it said: “Devolving APD would do little to incentivise better use of existing capacity at regional airports in England, and could potentially distort competition between proximate airports on either side of a border, such as Bristol and Cardiff, or Newcastle and Edinburgh”.561 Most recently, the Transport Committee called on the Government to avoid any further devolution of APD to, for example, north-east England or Wales that might ultimately “serve to extend a patchwork of APD-derived market distortions across the UK and drive a race to the bottom on regional APD rates”. Instead, the Committee recommended that the Government “act strategically and in the national interest” to address APD.562 Airspace change Throughout Europe there is a move to simplify and harmonise the way airspace and air traffic control is used through the Single European Sky (SES) project. Processes are underway at a European level to make modernisation a legal requirement for the UK and other European states by 2020. The UK intends to address this through its Future Airspace Strategy (FAS), which sets out a plan to modernise airspace by 2020. Any development of runways arising from the report from the Airports Commission (see above) will eventually require further changes to the airspace system. However, the development of runways does not happen quickly; the report to be provided by the Commission in Summer 2015 and any recommendation made will only be the start. Adoption of any recommendations, design, assessment, planning application and construction processes all take time; if/when a decision is finally taken to progress new runway development it is probably reasonable to assume that no new runway will be operational before 2025. A change to the use or classification of airspace in the UK can take many forms and may be simple and straightforward to implement with little noticeable operational or environmental impact. Conversely, a change may be complex and involve significant alterations to existing airspace arrangements and impact upon the various airspace user groups and the general public. Changes to the use or classification of airspace in the UK are managed in accordance with the Airspace Charter and under the Airspace Change Process.563 561 op cit., Airports Commission: Interim Report, p119 Transport Committee, Smaller Airports (ninth report of session 2014-15), HC 713, 13 March 2015, para 18 563 further information on airspace change can be found on the website of the aviation regulator, the Civil Aviation Authority (CAA) [accessed 29 April 2015] 562 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 144 Under its licence from the Civil Aviation Authority (CAA), National Air Traffic Services (NATS) is required to make sure the UK airspace system operates safely and efficiently. With that in mind it conducts a rolling programme of airspace development. NATS follows the airspace change process set out in the Airspace Charter. As part of this process it consults with both airspace users and environmental stakeholders who might be affected by the proposed changes.564 Over the 2010 Parliament the most noteworthy – and contentious – airspace change proposal was that for what NATS calls ‘London airspace’. This is something of a misnomer as it only refers to arrival routes for Gatwick and London City airports above 4,000ft; some departure routes at these airports to complement the changes to arrivals above 4,000ft; all routes below 4,000ft in the immediate vicinity of Gatwick (but not at London City); and changes to some routes for traffic to/from London Biggin Hill and London Southend airports that share some of the same airspace as London City Airport. It does not include changes to the airspace around Heathrow.565 The changes relating to Gatwick caused the most concern. The NATS consultation was followed by a second consultation published by Gatwick Airport in May 2014.566 Gatwick was the first major airport to consult on all levels of its airspace and all other airports will be required to follow suit. Gatwick’s consultation was focused on changes in noise contours; changes to or new noise preferential routes; and rotating respite options. The Gatwick Area Conservation Campaign (GACC) has been campaigning against not only the content of these proposals but how the consultations were conducted.567 Following this consultation Gatwick and NATS announced in September 2014 their intention to “defer submitting any proposals to change local airspace until more detailed work is done to better understand the available options and next steps”. This does not affect the wider duty to submit a proposal for implementation in 2020.568 Since then NATS and Gatwick have been developing detailed designs taking into account the consultation responses. This work led them to split the London Airspace Consultation project into two parts: the first part focusing on changes designed to improve the efficiency of London City flight paths; the second part on changes in the vicinity of Gatwick.569 There were also a number of airspace trials at London airports over the 2010 Parliament intended to improve operating efficiency. The most notable were: 564 a list of recent consultations can be found on the NATS website [accessed 29 April 2015] 565 NATS, London Airspace Consultation, October 2013, Part A, para 1.4 566 LGW, London Airspace Change – Gatwick Local Area Consultation, May 2014 567 see, e.g. GACC, London Airspace Change Gatwick Local Area Consultation, August 2014 568 LGW press notice, “Gatwick to delay changes to local airspace”, 30 September 2014 569 NATS London Airspace website [accessed 29 April 2015] 145 Transport 2015 A trial of extended simultaneous runway use and other ‘operational freedoms’ at Heathrow between November 2011 and February 2013. The airport and the CAA disagreed on the outcome of the trial. Heathrow concluded that the trial “delivered useful operational performance improvements in limited areas” and that as a consequence three operational freedoms should be integrated into standard procedures as soon as practically possible.570 The CAA thought that the data from the trial was ‘inconclusive’ and that the benefits claimed by Heathrow in their report had “not been statistically proven”; further, the operational benefits of operational freedoms were offset by some redistribution of aircraft noise among local communities, and preliminary work had suggested some detrimental impact.571 A trial of a departure route called ‘ADNID’ at Gatwick for six months between February and August 2014. The route, which was trialled on westerly departures from Gatwick, was tested to gather data as part of wider work looking at how to use UK airspace more effectively and efficiently, as well as how to make the most of Gatwick’s single runway capacity (as part of FAS). Gatwick intends to use the findings from the trial and consultation to re-visit its airspace change proposal and route designs in 2015.572 Press reports indicated that there was an uptick in noise over some areas during the course of the trial. Gatwick argued that this was not a direct result of the trial but because of generally increased activity, which is partly seasonal and partly to do with renewed economic growth.573 Airport failures, closures and nationalisations Over the 2010 Parliament a number of smaller, regional airports experienced difficulties, in some but not all cases as a consequence of the earlier recession. Other factors to consider might be competition between airlines and with rail and car, video conferencing affecting business travel, and airspace closures caused by the 2010 Eyjafjallajökull eruption and consequent volcanic ash clouds. For example, Plymouth City Airport was closed at the end of 2011 due to lack of business;574 Cardiff Airport was nationalised in March 2013 when it was sold to the Welsh Assembly Government for £52 million;575 and Glasgow Prestwick was nationalised in November 2013 when it was sold to the Scottish Government for a nominal fee.576 Blackpool Airport closed to in October 2014, reopened on a 570 HAHL, Operational Freedoms Trial: Final Report, October 2013, pp2-3 CAA, Heathrow Airport Operational Freedoms Trial, CAP 1117, October 2013, p9 572 LGW press notice, “Gatwick completes departure route trial and asks for feedback in the final week of its airspace consultation”, 8 August 2014 573 “Gatwick Airport's potential new departure route trial ends amid complaints of increase in noise in West Kent”, Sevenoaks Chronicle, 11 August 2014 574 “Plymouth airport closure a sign of things to come”, The Independent, 29 April 2011 575 “Cardiff Airport is sold to the Welsh government for £52m”, BBC News Online, 27 March 2013 576 “Prestwick Airport sold to Scottish government for £1”, BBC News Online, 24 November 2013 571 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 146 small scale in December 2014 and started serving commercial passengers again in April 2015.577 However, by far the most contentious was the closure of Manston Airport in Kent in May 2014.578 Campaigners have been trying to get the airport site sold and reopened since its closure and there have been various accusations levelled against the former owner and the responsible council. The Transport Select Committee used Manston as a ‘case study’ in their March 2015 report on smaller airports, detailing the twisting tale of the airport’s closure, and calling for more clarity and transparency by the parties involved.579 In the May 2015 local elections UKIP took control of Thanet District Council and indicated their intention to compulsorily purchase Manston with a view to reopening it as an airport.580 7.5 Issues for the 2015 Parliament What is the role of the National Policy Statement for aviation? As indicated in section 7.3 above, in order for the Development Consent (planning) permission for any airport expansion to go ahead, a National Policy Statement (NPS) for aviation must be approved by Parliament and designated by the Government. The Aviation Policy Framework, published in March 2013 presumably stands in lieu of the NPS until such a time as it is designated. It is unclear when this would be. The APF states that the Government expects the final recommendations of the Airports Commission to feed into the NPS process.581 The lack of an NPS might lead to delays in any decision as it is not clear whether a decision could be taken in its absence. It would likely depend on whether the Secretary of State at the time were inclined to wait for the NPS or not – there are powers for them to take the decision in the absence of the NPS and there are also powers for him/her to delay the decision. Section 105 of the Planning Act 2008, as amended, gives the Secretary of State the power to take the decision on a DCO in the absence of an NPS. Section 107 of the 2008 Act and section 23 of the Infrastructure Planning (Examination Procedure) Rules 2010 (SI 2010/103) (the ‘procedure rules’) allows for further time to be taken in the decision making process. Under section 107 any extension to the statutory timetable would require the Secretary of State to make a statement to Parliament and would not be a decision which “would be “Blackpool Airport: Daily passenger flights to resume”, BBC News Online, 21 March 2015 578 “Kent's Manston Airport to close on 15 May”, BBC News Online, 6 May 2014 579 op cit., Smaller Airports, section 3, pp16-22 580 “Manston airport: Thanet council Ukip leader Chris Wells says council will try to buy the site with compulsory purchase order”, Kent Online, 11 May 2015 581 DfT, Aviation Policy Framework, Cm 8584, March 2013, p74 577 147 Transport 2015 taken lightly”.582 Government guidance states that the Secretary of State: … is required under the Procedure Rules to notify all interested parties if he is inclined to disagree with the Examining Authority’s recommendation because he differs from the Examining Authority on any matter of fact mentioned in, or appearing to be material to, a conclusion reached by the Examining Authority, or because the Secretary of State proposes to take into consideration any new evidence or any new matter of fact. The Secretary of State will set out the reasons for disagreement with the Examining Authority and will give interested parties the opportunity to make representations in writing, in respect of any new evidence or new matter of fact, by an appropriate deadline.583 How much is a new runway in the South East likely to cost the taxpayer? The promoters of the three shortlisted schemes for Heathrow and Gatwick insist that the cost to the taxpayer will be nil. As Heathrow and Gatwick are both privately owned it will be for them to raise the money to fund any expansion proposal. The Airports Commission concluded that the costs of the three shortlisted schemes at these airports “could credibly be financed” but that for all options under consideration “some level of Government involvement may be required to secure financing at an attractive rate”.584 Government guarantees aside, there is one other area where the taxpayer might have some liability and that is in the provision or improvement of surface access for any new or enhanced runway and the extra traffic (in terms of public and private transport) it would be expected to generate. There is a general principle for this sort of scheme that ‘user pays’. For example, the London Underground Piccadilly line extension to Heathrow Terminal 5 was wholly funded by the airport owner.585 It is also worth noting that any sort of public sector contribution would be affected and likely limited by European State Aid rules.586 In November 2014 the Commission published surface access analyses by Jacobs Consultancy of the three shortlisted options for expansion. In summary, these stated as follows:587 582 Gatwick Airport Second Runway: Funding would need to be secured for the uncommitted BML [Brighton Main Line] rail CLG, Planning Act 2008: Guidance for the examination of applications for development consent, March 2015, para 108 583 ibid., paras 117-118 [emphasis added] 584 op cit., Airports Commission: Interim Report, p196 585 TfL press notice, “First Piccadilly line passengers travel to Heathrow Terminal 5”, 27 March 2008 [see ‘notes to editors] 586 for example, the December 2012 Leipzig Halle judgement of the ECJ held that the construction of infrastructure with a view to its subsequent commercial use, is an economic activity “and shall be prima facie aid to the operator”, for more, see: DCLG, State Aid and Infrastructure – Leipzig Halle Guidance (ERDF-GN-1-010), February 2013 587 Airports Commission, Additional airport capacity: surface access analysis, 11 November 2014 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 148 infrastructure to provide sufficient capacity to accommodate background demand in 2030. The airport has allocated £50 million in their second runway cost plan for enhancements to the airport station if additional works are required. The schemes associated with the airport’s road proposal in the vicinity of the airport were priced independently by Jacobs based on a QS assessment and out-turn costs from comparable recently completed schemes, and an initial estimate of £510 million was derived for all the identified schemes (£734 million with optimism bias). Heathrow Airport North West Runway: The total capital expenditure costs were estimated at between £1.43 billion and £2.72 billion. The range relates to the criteria that were applied to define the requirement for strategic road widening and rail infrastructure. If optimism bias is included this cost range rises to between £2.16 billion and £4.03 billion. Heathrow Airport extended northern runway: The total capital expenditure costs were estimated at between £1.76 billion and £3.09 billion. The range relates to the criteria that were applied to define the requirement for strategic road widening and rail infrastructure. If optimism bias is included the cost range rises to between £2.64 billion and £4.56 billion. It is as yet unclear whether the taxpayer would be asked to contribute to these costs. Is new runway capacity compatible with environmental commitments? As indicated above, both the Labour and Liberal Democrat parties went into the 2015 election with a manifesto commitment to consider the environmental impacts of aviation expansion before taking any decision on new capacity. The question of whether a new or extended runway with the attendant implied increases in air travel is compatible with tackling climate change, limiting air pollution and minimising local noise impacts is a complex one. Particularly on climate change, the UK has signed up to international and legislated for its own goals to reduce greenhouse gas (GHG) emissions.588 Globally, aviation accounts for around 1% to 2% of GHG emissions, but is expected to make up a growing proportion of the total as other sectors decarbonise. Aviation is harder to decarbonise than other sectors because of the lack of an obvious low-carbon alternative to aviation fuel (kerosene). In addition, the long service life of aircraft compared to most other vehicles means that it takes longer for new technologies to penetrate the aircraft fleet than, for example, surface vehicle fleets.589 The Airports Commission stated that industry-driven fuel-efficiency improvements and biofuels use “will not be sufficient to tackle the climate effects of aviation”, making further measures necessary to address the remaining emissions gap “ideally through a global framework to control aviation emissions” Establishing such a 588 this section assumes that the Government will retain the current legal commitments ‘as is’ 589 op cit., Airports Commission: Interim Report, pp44-5 149 Transport 2015 framework “has, however, proved challenging”.590 However, the industry has stated that aviation emissions can be carbon-traded to other sectors that are more easily ‘greened’ and that new technology can significantly reduce noise and emissions.591 The Climate Change Act 2008 set out a legally binding target to reduce overall UK emissions by at least 80% below 1990 levels by 2050 and a system of five-year carbon budgets. Separate from the statutory framework, in the context of its 2009 decision to allow an expansion of Heathrow airport, the then-Government adopted a target that gross CO2 emissions from UK aviation in 2050 should not exceed 2005 levels. Analysis undertaken by the Committee on Climate Change (CCC) at that time suggested that aviation demand growth of around 60% between 2005 and 2050 was compatible with that target, given prudent assumptions around aircraft fuel efficiency and biofuels use.592 The Commission’s interim report concluded that expansion can be accommodated, even where aviation emissions are capped at a level consistent with current plans to meet UK climate targets. In this scenario passenger demand at UK airports is still forecast to increase from 217 mppa (million passengers per annum) in 2011 to 295 mppa in 2030 and 389 mppa by 2050. This is an average increase of 1.4% a year, compared to historic growth of 4% a year and forecast growth of 1.5% a year without a carbon cap.593 The CCC wrote to the Commission in February 2015 clarifying its position, specifically that: … the 2050 target to reduce greenhouse gas emissions by 80% compared to 1990 levels, set in the Climate Change Act … could be achieved with aviation emissions at 2005 levels in 2050, and by reducing other sectors by 85%. Aviation emissions at 2005 levels could be achieved with fuel and operational efficiency improvements, use of sustainable biofuels and by limiting demand growth to around 60% by 2050 compared to 2005. Higher aviation emissions than 2005 levels in 2050 should not be planned for, since this would imply greater than 85% cuts in other sectors; there is limited confidence about the scope for this.594 In light of this the CCC recommended that the need to limit aviation demand growth should be reflected in its economic analysis of infrastructure investments and that “it would be appropriate to assess whether investments still make sense if overall demand growth were to be limited to around 60% by 2050 on 2005 levels”.595 The Aviation Environment Federation (AEF) stated that constraining demand growth in this way would be difficult and that limiting 590 ibid., p46 for more information see the Sustainable Aviation website [accessed 6 May 2015] 592 HC Deb 15 January 2009, c360; see also: DfT, Adding capacity at Heathrow airport - Consultation document, 22 November 2007 593 op cit., Airports Commission: Interim Report, p110 594 CCC, Letter to Sir Howard Davies, 3 February 2015 595 ibid. 591 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 150 emissions to the level recommended by CCC could require politically unpalatable and practically difficult actions such as: The introduction of a carbon tax, rising with time to between £329 and £1316 by 2050 according to the Commission’s own analysis, The introduction of planning caps on activity at regional airports Requirement of sectors other than aviation to make cuts in emissions beyond the level currently deemed feasible by the Committee on Climate Change, to allow for further leniency for aviation596 In addition to greenhouse gas production, aviation also impacts on air quality in the areas surrounding airports. Section 7.2, above contains information on how the proposed expansions at Heathrow and Gatwick might affect these more local concerns, particularly as regards the numbers likely to be affected by noise. It may also be worth noting that newer aircraft are quieter and cleaner than older aircraft, and technological development is likely to continue in this direction. This makes it more difficult to determine in particular noise effects and depends to some extent on modelling of changes to fleets.597 How do we support regional connectivity? Domestic air travel has seen a decline since 2008.598 An increased focus on tackling emissions under previous Labour and Coalition governments has led policymakers to focus on providing reliable public transport alternatives to short haul domestic flights – such as high speed rail. However, there are indisputably some areas of the country (e.g. to the far north of Scotland and the South West of England) where access to ‘lifeline’ flights is critical. Government can provide subsidy for such flights via a Public Service Obligation (PSO), where companies bid to run a required service on a monopoly basis with a subsidy attached. PSOs are used in cases where there is insufficient revenue for routes to be profitable in a free market, but where it is socially, economically and/or politically desirable to maintain the transport link. PSOs are a form of state aid and as such are governed by the relevant EU rules.599 The Coalition Government introduced a policy to promote the use of PSOs to maintain routes from smaller airports to London which might otherwise be lost. As the Transport Select Committee explained in its March 2015 report on smaller airports: The funding stream for that policy is known as the Regional Air Connectivity Fund. In June 2014, the Government announced support from the Regional Air Connectivity Fund to maintain the air link between Dundee airport and London Stansted until 2016 596 AEF, Climate change committee: is airport expansion viable when emissions are capped?, 19 February 2015 597 for more information see the Sustainable Aviation website [accessed 6 May 2015] 598 CAA, UK Airport Statistics 2014: Table 02.3, February 2015 599 EC press notice, “State aid: Commission adopts new guidelines on state aid to airports and airlines (Aviation Guidelines)”, 20 February 2014 151 Transport 2015 through a PSO agreed with Dundee City Council. In October 2014, the Government announced a second new PSO to maintain the Newquay to London Gatwick air link, which was agreed with Cornwall County Council. 600 In January 2015 the Government published guidance explaining how airlines and airports with fewer than five million passengers per annum could apply for start-up aid for new routes; those with between three and five million would require clearance from the European Commission. In March 2015 the Government published a list of those who had applied for start-up aid: the routes were from 11 separate airports across England, Scotland and Northern Ireland.601 600 601 op cit., Smaller Airports, para 23, p11 DfT, Airports with fewer than 5 million passengers per year: start-up aid, 22 January 2015; and Start-up aid for airports: applications received, 27 March 2015 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 152 8. Statistical Appendix: transport trends since 2010 While there have been relatively few fundamental changes in the patterns of travel in the UK over the course of the past five years, there are some interesting trends to consider. This appendix provides an analysis and discussion of some of the key statistical points with regard to transport over the 2010 Parliament. As much statistical data with regard to transport is produced on an annual, rather than monthly or quarterly, basis the latest data for many indicators is for 2013. In the majority of cases, particularly where there have been no dramatic changes in trends over the period 2010 to 2013, one would not expect the 2014 data to show a pronounced change. The purpose of this appendix is not to provide a comprehensive analysis of every statistical table and chart which could be produced. Rather, it is to provide an overview of some of the more interesting and policy-relevant areas, which may be of interest to Members of Parliament, and their staff. In general, only GB or England-wide measures are presented, rather than providing lists of data at local authority and constituency level. Such data is, in many cases, available. Full sets of statistical data are available from numerous sources, the most significant of which are outlined in HC Library briefing paper Sources of Statistics: Transport (SN3853). Overall Modal share The modal share of selected modes of transport is given below – rail usage has increased noticably, while other modes have remained more or less constant. Car usage, however has declined by roughly 3% over the period, but remains by far the most prevalent mode of transport, at in excess of 5,000 miles per person per year. It should be noted that the per person averages presented in the chart are subject to very considerable variations – many people will, for example, very rarely or never use a motorbike, whereas for others, it will be their major means of transport. 153 Transport 2015 Distance travelled by mode, England, 2009 - 2013 Miles per person per year 600 500 400 300 200 100 0 2009 Walk 2010 Cycle 2011 Motorcycle 2012 Bus Rail 2013 Taxi / Minicab Source: National Travel Survey, Table NTS0302 Transport Expenditure As an ‘unprotected’ area of public spending, transport - in line with many areas - saw significant reductions in expenditure over the 2010 Parliament. These reductions totalled almost 20% in nominal terms, and over 25% in real terms. Expenditure on All Services was roughly flat in nominal terms over the course of the 2010 Parliament, leading to significant reductions in real terms. Index: 2009-10 = 100 Public Expenditure, Transport & All Services, 2009 - 2014 140 120 100 80 60 2009-10 2010-11 2011-12 Total general public services 2012-13 2013-14 Transport Source: HMT, Public Expenditure Statistical Analysis 2014, Table 5.2 Aviation Both domestic and international aviation hit a trough in 2010, as a result of the economic crisis causing a downturn in both business and leisure travel. Recovery has been steady but provisional 2014 data indicates that overall passenger numbers are still somewhat below the pre-crisis peak in 2007. The number of flights has increased by less than the number of passengers, as concerns over emissions and noise has led to larger aircraft, with a higher number of passengers per flight. Terminal Passengers, UK Airports, 1990 - 2014 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 154 Source: CAA Aviation Trends 2014 Commercial Passenger flights, UK airports, 1990 - 2014 Source: CAA Aviation Trends 2014 As outlined in the main paper, the key policy decisions with regard to aviation are those around airport expansion, with the Airports Commission due to make recommendations later in 2015. Road Traffic After years of steady increases, the total vehicle mileage on British roads fell during and after the 2008-10 recession, but has recently started increasing again. The total distance travelled on British roads was 310 billion miles in 2014 – more than 3,000 times the distance between the Earth and the Sun. 155 Transport 2015 Road vehicle miles, GB, 1993 - 2014 320 Road vehicle miles (bn) 310 300 290 280 270 260 2014 2013 2012 2011 2010 2009 2008 2007 2006 2005 2004 2003 2002 2001 2000 1999 1998 1997 1996 1995 1994 1993 250 Source: DfT Table TRA0101 The roads that this mileage is being accumulated on are the subject of concerns with regard to maintenance and repair, with potholes being a particular concern. The amount of money spent on repairs and maintenance of roads declined in real terms over the course of the 2010 Parliament, with the 2013/14 figure being 23.5% lower than that of 2009/10. Expenditure on road maintenance, England 6,000 £m, 2013/14 prices 5,000 4,000 3,000 2,000 1,000 0 2009/10 2010/11 Trunk Roads 2011/12 2012/13 2013/14 Local Authority roads Source: DfT Table RDC0310 The reliability of journey times on major roads is subject to seasonal variation, but there is little overall trend change. The exceptionally snowy weather in late 2010 led to only two-thirds of journeys on trunk roads being completed in line with expected times, but the non-winter average shows roughly 4 in every 5 journeys being completed ‘on time’ (in line with the historical expected time for a given stretch of road). This suggests, given the increase in overall vehicle miles mentioned previously, that road users are selecting less busy times, or less congested roads to use, rather than continuing to increase congestion-related delays on the busiest roads at peak hours. Number 7177, 13 May 2015 156 90.0 85.0 80.0 75.0 70.0 65.0 60.0 55.0 50.0 April 2010 June 2010 August 2010 October 2010 December 2010 February 2011 April 2011 3 June 2011 August 2011 October 2011 December 2011 February 2012 April 2012 3 June 2012 August 2012 October 2012 December 2012 February 2013 April 2013 June 2013 August 2013 October 2013 December 2013 February 2014 April 2014 June 2014 August 2014 October 2014 December 2014 p Percentage of journeys completed in line with historical prevailing time Reliability of journeys on Highways Agency roads, England Source: DfT Table CGN 0104 Data on the speed of vehicles from automated monitoring points on motorways reveal that, when traffic is free-flowing, nearly half of most types of vehicle exceed the speed limit. This trend has not changed over recent years. Percentage of free-flowing vehicles recorded as exceeding speed limit on motorways 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 2010 Car 2011 Motorcycle 2012 Light Goods Vehicle 2013 Heavy Goods Vehicle Source: DfT Table SPE0105 Heavy goods vehicles are shown as being more observant of the speed limit than other vehicles, but this is likely due to the speed regulator devices which have been mandatory on these types of vehicles for over a decade. It should be noted that the data refer to a strict interpretation of the 70 mph speed limit. 157 Transport 2015 Vehicle registrations Percentage of all registered cars Recent changes to the Vehicle Excise duty (VED) system to encourage the use of vehicles with lower levels of carbon emissions appear to be having the desired effect, although the direct causality between any policy change and changed behaviour is difficult to determine. The chart below shows the proportion of registered vehicles in the two highest, and two lowest emission categories. Percentage of registered cars, by emission band (selected), GB 2009 - 2014 6 5 4 3 2 1 0 2009 1 - 100 g/km 2010 2011 101 - 110 g/km 2012 226 - 255 g/km 2013 2014 Over 255 g/km Source: DfT Table VEH0206 Vehicles registered in the lowest emissions groups pay a zero rate of VED in their first year, and low rates after this, in comparison with the highest emitting vehicles, which are charged at a rate of £1,100 at first registration, and £505 per year thereafter. In addition, vehicles which emit high levels of CO2 will also tend to be those which have lower fuel efficiency, meaning that users of these vehicles will also incur higher amounts of fuel duty. Diesel fuelled cars tend to have lower CO2 emissions than equivalent petrol models, but concerns have been raised with regard to the air quality implications of having a large number of diesel vehicles on the road. This may be an issue for the 2015 Parliament. Driving Licences Roughly three-quarters of the adult (17+) population holds a full driving licence but there are significant variations between genders and age groups. Fewer than half of women aged 70+ hold a driving licence, compared to 4 out of 5 men this age. The proportion of older women qualified to drive a car is increasing slowly but, particularly as it is unusual for people of this age to learn to drive for the first time, it will likely be several decades before the numbers begin to equalise. Social structures in the mid-to-late 20th century meant that women were less likely to learn to drive than men, and this trend continues to show up in the data for older driving licence holders. Number 7177, 13 May 2015 158 Percentage of population holding full driving licence by age and gender 85 80 75 70 65 60 55 50 45 40 2010 Men (all ages) 2011 2012 2013 Men 70+ Women (all ages) Women 70+ Source: DfT Table NTS 0201 Concessionary Travel Older and disabled people throughout the UK have a statutory entitlement to concessionary travel on buses (the ‘bus pass’), and some local travel authorities provide enhanced service by also funding travel on other means of transport. Within London (where the concessionary ‘Freedom Pass’ includes travel on London Underground rail and trams, as well as buses) takeup of passes is at a high rate (98% of eligible older people have taken up their entitlement), while in non-metropolitan areas of England the take-up rate is 3 in 4. While it is unrealistic to expect a 100% take-up rate, the significant disparities among areas may be a cause for further investigation. Take-up of concessionary travel passes among older people 100 Percentage 80 60 40 20 0 London English English nonmetropolitan areas metropolitan areas 2010/11 2011/12 2012/13 England 2013/14 Source: DfT Table BUS 0820 Road Accidents British roads are continuing to get safer, both in terms of the number of accidents, and the number of people injured or killed in accidents. 159 Transport 2015 In terms of casualties per mile travelled, British roads are among the safest in the developed world. Road accident fatalities by user type, GB, 2009 2013 2,500 2,000 1,500 1,000 500 0 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 Pedestrians Pedal Cyclists Motorcycle users Car occupants Bus & Coach occupants Goods vehicle occupants Source: DfT Table RAS 30001 The position of pedal cyclists has been of particular concern – partially owing to the high-profile clustering of fatal accidents in London in 2013. Such a clustering of events, while tragic, is not indicative of an overall increase in the number of fatal accidents. While the overall number of cycling fatalities has remained roughly constant over recent years, this appears to be a function of increased levels of cycling overall - the rate of fatalities per mile of cycling has been on a downward trend. Fatalities per billion vehicle miles Fatality rates by type of road user, GB, 2003 2013 250 200 150 100 50 0 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 Pedal cyclists Motor Cyclists Car drivers Source: DfT Table 30013 Both accidents and fatalities involving drink-driving have remained roughly steady over the period since 2010, but are at roughly half the level seen in 2000. It may be the case that, after the social change seen with regard to drink driving since the 1970s, less attention has been paid to this issue in recent years, or it may be the case that Number 7177, 13 May 2015 160 drink-driving has reached something of an irreducible minimum, and that it is unrealistic to expect 100% of drinkers to make the correct and responsible decision not to drive after the consumption of significant amounts of alcohol. Road accidents, and fatalities involving drinkdriving, GB, 2000 - 2013 Index 2000 = 100 120 100 80 60 40 20 0 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 2006 2007 2008 2009 2010 2011 2012 2013 Fatalities Accidents Source: DfT Table RAS 51001 Trams and Light Rail While there have been no significant tram or light rail systems opening since 2010, those systems in use have continued to grow, both in size and in usage. The number of passenger journeys on these systems exceeded 200 million for the first time in 2011/12, and the overall number of journeys was up by 22% on the final year of the previous Parliament. Total passenger journeys 240 (millions) 220 Passenger journeys on light rail and tram systems, England, 1983 - 2014 Nottingham Express Transit Croydon Tramlink 200 180 Midland Metro 160 Sheffield Supertram 140 120 Manchester Metrolink 100 Docklands Light Railway 80 60 Tyne and Wear Metro 40 20 0 1983/84 Blackpool Tramway 1988/89 1993/94 Source: DfT Table LRT 0101 1998/99 2003/04 2008/09 2013/14 161 Transport 2015 Rail Performance (all data Source: Office of Rail Regulation) The performance of train companies in running trains on time has come under significant scrutiny ever since privatisation in the mid1990s. While long distance operators have improved performance significantly over the past decade (albeit from a much worse position) overall performance of train companies has remained static and, in the most recent periods for which data are available, has seen a small increase in delays and cancellations. Percentage of trains cancelled or significantly late, GB, 2003 - 2014 12.0% 10.0% 8.0% 6.0% 4.0% 2.0% 0.0% 2003-04 2004-05 2005-06 2006-07 2007-08 2008-09 2009-10 2010-11 2011-12 2012-13 2013-14 Long-distance operators London & South East operators Regional and Scotand operators All franchised operators Over the same period, the number of passenger complaints with regard to rail services has declined significantly. In 2002, one complaint was made for every 782 passenger journeys – by 2013 this had declined to one complaint for every 3,440 journeys. Passenger complaints per 100,000 rail journeys, GB, 2002 - 2014 140.0 120.0 100.0 80.0 60.0 40.0 20.0 0.0 Number 7177, 13 May 2015 162 While the numbers of passenger journeys have been going up in all areas, the majority of rail usage still takes place in the South East of England. In 2013/14, 70% of all journeys on franchised operators were those operating in London and the South East. This is undoubtedly a function of the density of rail lines, particularly the wellused commuter lines into and out of London, but may raise questions with regard to finding an equitable distribution of expenditure among the regions and nations of the UK. Journeys made (millions) Passenger journeys on rail services, 2003 - 2014 1,800 1,600 1,400 1,200 1,000 800 600 400 200 0 Franchised regional operators Franchised London and South East operators Franchised long distance operators While some Train Operating Companies (TOCs) continue to receive subsidies as a part of their franchise agreement, in order for them to provide socially necessary but non-commercial services, the majority of TOCs pay a franchise fee (negative subsidy) to the Government. Over the four years of the 2010 Parliament for which data are available, the Government received a net total of £1.05 billion in franchise fees/subsidies from all active TOCs. Conclusions While there were some interesting changes in patterns of transport usage and behaviour over the 2010 Parliament, and the past decade, these do not amount to fundamental shifts in how people in Great Britain travel. While major policy and infrastructure decisions, including HS2, the future development of automated cars, and choices about potential airport expansion in London will fall to be made by the 2015 Parliament, the lead time on these types of large infrastructure projects means that any changes to transport usage as a result of them will be felt beyond the lifetime of this Parliament. Changes within the next five years are likely to continue to be incremental – it seems likely that the trend towards lower emitting vehicles will continue, and that the number of passengers on trams and light railway systems will continue to expand. Where previous trends have slowed or ceased, as with the reduction in drink-driving incidents or the punctuality performance of trains, it may be the case 163 Transport 2015 that a significant lead from Government and Parliament will be necessary in order to continue improvements. The House of Commons Library research service provides MPs and their staff with the impartial briefing and evidence base they need to do their work in scrutinising Government, proposing legislation, and supporting constituents. As well as providing MPs with a confidential service we publish open briefing papers, which are available on the Parliament website. Every effort is made to ensure that the information contained in these publically available research briefings is correct at the time of publication. Readers should be aware however that briefings are not necessarily updated or otherwise amended to reflect subsequent changes. If you have any comments on our briefings please email papers@parliament.uk. Authors are available to discuss the content of this briefing only with Members and their staff. If you have any general questions about the work of the House of Commons you can email hcinfo@parliament.uk. Disclaimer - This information is provided to Members of Parliament in support of their parliamentary duties. It is a general briefing only and should not be relied on as a substitute for specific advice. The House of Commons or the author(s) shall not be liable for any errors or omissions, or for any loss or damage of any kind arising from its use, and may remove, vary or amend any information at any time without prior notice. BRIEFING PAPER Number XXX, 13 May 2015 The House of Commons accepts no responsibility for any references or links to, or the content of, information maintained by third parties. This information is provided subject to the conditions of the Open Parliament Licence.