CARLO BERNINI CARRI Trade liberalization, growth and food security. Introduction. Almost 800 million people in the developing world do not have enough to eat, and another 34 million people in the industrialised countries and countries in transition also suffer from chronic food insecurity (Fao, 1999). In 1996, the World Food Summit set as a target a reduction by half in the number of undernourished people in the world by 2015. This aim is confirmed inside the Millenium Development Goals. Attention was also drawn to this issue in the Ministerial Declaration of the WTO Doha Conference, held in November 2001, which launched a new round of multilateral trade negotiations. In particular, with respect to agriculture, Ministers agreed that special and differential treatment for developing countries should be an integral part of the negotiations and embodied in concessions and commitments as well as in the rules and disciplines to be negotiated, “so as to enable developing countries to effectively take account of their development needs, including food security” (Fao, 2004). Food security is a multi-faceted concept, variously defined and interpreted. At one end of the spectrum food security implies the availability of adequate supplies at a global and national level; at the other end, the concern is with adequate nutrition and well-being. There are two broad options for achieving food security at national level: food self-sufficiency or food self-reliance. Food self-sufficiency means the satisfying needs primarily through domestic supplies. Food self-reliance implies maintaining a level of domestic production plus a capacity to import in order to meet the food needs of the population (Fao, 2004). The benefits and risks of relying on international trade to ensure food security are at the heart of the debate between these alternative strategies. Considering the strict connections and assimilation between poverty and undernutrition problems 1 the free trade can be seen, in broader terms, in its impacts on poverty issue. Despite the net economic and social benefits of reducing most government subsidies and opening economies to trade, almost every national government intervenes in markets for goods and services in ways that distort international commerce. Those distortionary policies harm most the economies imposing them, but the worst of them (in agriculture and clothing) are particularly harmful to the world’s poorest people. This challenge in its modern form has been with us for about 75 years. The latter part of the nineteenth century saw a strong movement towards laissez faire, but that development was reversed following the first world war in ways that led to the Great Depression of the early 1930s and the conflict that followed (Kindleberger 1989). It was during the second world war, in 1944, that a conference at Bretton Woods proposed an International Trade Organization. The GATT during its 47-year history (before it was absorbed into the World Trade Organisation, WTO, on 1 January 1995) oversaw the gradual lowering of many tariffs on imports of manufactured goods by governments of developed countries. Manufacturing tariffs remained high in developing countries, however, and distortionary subsidies and trade policies affecting agricultural and services markets of both rich and poor countries continued to hamper efficient resource allocation, economic growth and poverty alleviation. 1 Food insecurity and poverty are closely interlinked but distinct phenomena. While food insecurity is often a result of poverty, it is also a leading cause of poverty. Hunger and malnutrition can permanently stunt the developmental capacity of children, making it more difficult for them to grow and learn. Hunger has longer-term economic implications because it reduces people’s capacity to work and fight disease (Fao, 2005, p. 10). The Uruguay Round of multilateral trade negotiations led to agreements signed in 1994 that have seen some trade liberalization over the subsequent ten years. But even when those agreements are fully implemented by end-2004, and despite additional unilateral trade liberalizations since the 1980s by a number of countries (particularly developing and transition economies), many subsidies and trade distortions will remain. They include not just trade taxes-cum-subsidies but also contingent protection measures such as anti-dumping, regulatory standards that can be technical barriers to trade, and domestic production subsidies. The extent and the depth of trade liberalization reflect the wide and long involvement of most least developing countries (LDCs) with structural adjustment programmes. As a result, most of the LDCs now have more open trade regimes than other developing countries and as open trade regimes as high-income OECD countries 2 . The gains from trade: theoretical approaches Long-term international trade flows in a wide range of commodities have steadily increased over hundreds of years and they have accelerated spectacularly since the Second World War. This is surely not just because transport and communications facilities have dramatically improved, but it must also be because benefits are derived from trade. Economists have put forward a number of arguments in favour of trade; some are rather obvious and common sense, others are less evident. These arguments can be classified into three groups according to whether they emphasize (i) the increase that trade can bring to the total amount of goods and services available to the national population (increased consumption argument), (ii) the diversity of goods and services made available through trade to this population (diversification argument), or (iii) the stability in the supply and prices of goods and services brought about by trade (stability argument) (Fao, 2000). We can consider three main theoretical approaches on trade-development relationships: I°) An “optimistic” vision: trade with positive effects extensible to all the partners thanks to more growth rates, higher demand, more efficient allocation in resources, economies of scale, economies of agglomeration, and so on. The consequence can be more resources devoted to the poverty fight and to face food insecurity. The arguments for trade liberalization are strong, and typically inform policy advice to governments from international institutions. These arguments are premised on Ricardian “conventional” or “neoclassical” trade theory, and in particular the theory of comparative advantage. One reason why the amount of goods and services available to a country at a point in time can increase through trade is because it allows the country to buy goods and services from sources where it costs comparatively less to produce them. Local resources tied up in the production of these goods in the absence of trade are hence liberated so that comparatively more of other goods can be produced. The theoretical reference is the comparative advantages (costs) theory, both in its static and dynamic version. The classical comparative cost theory of the gains from trade, also known as 2 The depth and extent of trade liberalization in the LDCs can be gauged by using the IMF index of trade restrictiveness, which classifies countries according to their average tariff rate and also the extent of non-tariff barriers. From these data is apparent that very few LDCs have restrictive trade regimes now. In 2002, on the basis of this evidence: -the average tariff rate of 42 out of 46 LDCs for which data are available was less than 25 per cent; - the average tariff rate of 36 of these 46 LDCs was less than 20 per cent; - the average tariff rate of 23 of these 46 LDCs was less than 15 per cent; -in 29 of these 46 LDCs, non-tariff barriers were absent or minor in the sense that less than 1 per cent of production and trade is subject to non-tariff barriers; -twenty-eight of these 46 LDCs had no or minor non-tariff barriers coupled with average tariff rates of below 25 per cent (Unctad, 2004). comparative advantage theory, originally was stated by Davide Ricardo in the early part of the 19th century. It deals with resource allocation in the whole economy under the stylised conditions of perfect competition. The theory argues that differences in productivity and opportunity costs of production between countries form the underlying reasons why it is advantageous for countries to engage in trade. Many reasons explain why such differences occur. Climate is of obvious importance for agriculture as is the availability of extensive arable land and abundant water supply. The availability of other natural resources, such as large and easily accessible mineral deposits, and differential access to productive technologies give rise to varying labour productivities. The Heckscher-Ohlin (H-O) theorem provides the most widely accepted explanation of the pattern of trade, based on countries’ differing factor endowments and the factor requirements of different kinds of goods. This version states that trade occurs because the cost of labour relative to that of capital is lower in the labour-abundant country, which means that the price ratio of labour-intensive goods to capital-intensive goods is lower in the labour abundant country than in the capitalabundant country. The basis for comparative advantage is that each country exports commodities that use the relatively abundant factors and imports those that use scarce factors more intensively. This model is sometimes referred to as the factor proportions or factor endowment model. A logical consequence of trade, therefore, is a process of eventual factor price equalization leading, for example, to real wages (as well as other factor prices) becoming the same across trading countries. The static gains arise from countries producing more of the goods and services they can provide most efficiently and less of what others can produce more efficiently. Each country will maximize the values of its output of good and services After trading, each individual country will be better off than in a world without trade. The smaller the economy, the greater the static gains from trade tend to be as a share of national output. Additionally, dynamic gains result as increased trade fuels economic growth. Typically, freeing up imports of intermediates and capital goods encourages entrepreneurs to make greater investments in production capacity. The free trade approach also argues that, under competitive free market conditions, trade maximizes potential economic welfare internationally, by creating a situation where no country can be made better off without another being made worse off. It is a situation where those that gain from trade could fully compensate those that lose and still be better off: the total gain will be greater than the total loss. With free trade a point would be reached where more of each traded good is produced, such that everyone will gain if suitable redistribution is made. A general higher growth produces more resources devoted to the poverty and food insecurity fights. In this context we can distinguish two interpretations around the role of trade in the growth and development process: the first emphasizing the role of the trade as an engine for growth; the second as a fuel for growth. Some qualifications of the theory are: first, gains arise from the existence of different domestic exchange ratios of the two goods in the two countries. These exchange ratios are associated with different production conditions of the two goods in the two countries; second, the amount of resources needed to produce both commodities may be higher in one of the countries, and trade can still be advantageous to both parties. The concept of comparative advantage has to be distinguished from that of absolute advantage, which indicates that the country in question uses in absolute terms fewer resources in the production of the given commodity. The gains from trade arise from the existence of a comparative cost advantage and not of an absolute cost advantage; third, the theory is static. It explains trade and trade gains on the basis of comparative advantage at a certain point in time. There are a number of important qualifications to these predictions of the model, however, that must be held in mind. First, the consequences described are dependent on the assumption of competitive markets. In the absence of these, countries may be better off intervening to restrict free trade. Second, countries will not necessarily gain equally from trade: the relative gains will depend on the terms of trade 3 . Thirdly, there are no mechanisms in place to ensure that losers in the world market will be compensated by those that benefit, so the gains remain potential. Fourthly, the issue of redistribution also applies within countries, where there will also be gainers and losers from trade. Finally, any comparative static solution described by the conventional theory assumes that all external costs are internalized, including environmental externalities. Although this theory is the basis of modern “orthodox” trade economics, this does not mean that it is accepted without questioning. Nevertheless, this theory remains the dominant framework of analysis for the policy decisions of governments and international organizations 4 . The theoretical approach outlined above underpins the policy advice concerning trade liberalization given to governments by international institutions, as well as the approach adopted by the WTO Agreement on Agriculture. Taking advantage both by the different technologies available (Ricardo-Torrens model) or by the different endowment in resources (Heckescher-Ohlin model) a specialization path leads all the partners toward an income increase also if with possible different degree among them. While this view, labelled as “mainstream economics”, has much to say on the benefits deriving from trade and the welfare implications of protectionist policies and regional trade agreements, it does not offer much by way of prediction with respect to the intercountry distribution of trade gains. Under the comparative cost theory the distribution of benefits is inversely related to the closeness of the international terms of trade to the domestic price ratio. In more modern forms of the theory, the terms of trade continue to depend on the relative strength of the respective demands. Taylor (1999) identifies several channels through which openness to trade can affect an economy’s growth rate. They include the scale of the market when knowledge is embodied in the products traded, the degree of redundant knowledge creation that is avoided through openness (Romer 1994), and the effect of knowledge spillovers. More importantly from a policy maker’s viewpoint, 3 The commodity terms of trade can be defined as the purchasing capacity of one good in terms of another. The evolution of the terms of trade between agricultural commodities and manufactured products provides information on the capacity for agricultural commodities to be exchanged favourably with manufactured products, i.e. how much can be imported of manufactured products by exporting one unit of agricultural commodity (Fao, 2000). 4 An important question emerges from this theoretical review, however. If free trade could potentially raise economic welfare in the world as a whole and even in all trading nations, why are border intervention policies so commonly used by governments to restrict free trade? Trade theory literature provides three main explanations for this apparent anomaly. First, the case of the “optimum tariff” shows that in certain circumstances a country can gain more from imposing a tariff than from free trade (assuming other countries do not retaliate). Such gains are at the expense of losses by trading partners (a zero-sum game, in other words). A more interesting reason for protection is the infant industry perspective. Where an industry has large economies of scale, firms may need protection to allow them time to grow before competing head-on with more established firms overseas. It may concern the food and agriculture sector where the argument can be applied to primary processing industries, in the context of a development strategy involving an export shift from raw-materials to processed products. Another explanation concerns political imperatives, including the influence of groups which gain from protection, and the importance of revenue from border measures for developing country governments, where other tax bases are not strong. The importance of non-trade concerns such as food security and rural viability are often put forward as powerful imperatives for protecting domestic agriculture. the available empirical evidence strongly supports the view that open economies grow faster (see the survey by USITC 1997) 5 . II°) A “pessimistic” vision: trade with asymmetric impacts and also as a possible source of worsening for some countries or segments of population, generally the poorest ones. This approach is based on the ‘immisering trade theory”: strong asymmetries in the market power and in the competitive degree; declining terms of trade for primary commodities and, consequently, for countries with more inclination in these productions that are, generally, the developing countries, and so on. This position was particularly present in ‘60s and ‘70s decades, constituting the base for “inward looking” and “import substitution” strategies (ISI) in the development literature (particularly: Latin America school: Prebisch, Singer, etc.). In the 1950s and 1960s, the distribution of trade gains between developed countries (the “centre” of the world economy) and less developed countries (the “periphery”) became an issue of intense debate, due in no small part to the intellectual influence of Raul Prebisch (1950; 1959), one of the fathers of the Latin American structuralist school. Structuralists argue that the periphery is disadvantaged relative to core countries. The argument is based on the assumption of trade specialization between centre and periphery, with the centre specializing in exporting manufactured industrial products and the periphery primary commodities. After observing (and measuring) a secular decline in the terms of trade of primary commodities vis-à-vis manufactured goods, the structuralists view the decline not as a transitory phenomenon due to a specific set of circumstances but as something embedded in the structural features of central and peripheral economies and in the nature of the development process. The declining trend in the terms of trade for countries in the periphery was explained by three reasons:1) the income elasticity of the demand for imports is lower at the centre than in the periphery due to different type of the goods imported by both sets of countries – primary commodities in one case, industrial product in the other. The consequence is that the process of growth, and hence of income expansion, raises import demand more in the periphery than at the centre pushing up the prices of periphery imports vis-à-vis those of exports and thus lowering the terms of trade; 2) asymmetries are postulated in the impact of technological change at the centre and in the periphery. In central countries, it is argued that technological progress tends to decrease the demand for periphery country exports (many of which are substituted by synthetic products). On the contrary, technological progress in the periphery increases the demand for capital goods and inputs produced at the centre. This also lowers the terms of trade; 3) product and factor markets are argued to be less competitive at the centre than in the periphery, with prices (particularly wage rates) showing more downward rigidity in the centre. As a consequence, cost savings from technical progress are passed on to export prices more in the periphery than in the centre, where a significant portion of these savings goes to improve wages. Also, during the downturn of the business cycle the prices of export products fall proportionally more in the periphery than at the centre. A natural policy corollary of the structuralist view was the emphasis on industrialization as a vehicle for development, for it the diagnosis of the long-term evolution of the terms of trade was right, the development process could not rely on export-led growth based on primary products (import-substitution strategy). Theorists subscribing to the so-called “unequal exchange” view have also insisted on the uneven distribution of trade gains between the centre and the periphery. A key difference with the structuralists is that, while the latter focus on the trend over time of an observable variable, the terms of trade, the former have a more normative approach, focussing on the “unfairness” of trade 5 Evidence gathered during the second half of the twentieth century shows that countries which have liberalised their trade have enjoyed an average 1.5% increase in annual GDP growth compared with the pre-reform rate. between the two sets of countries at any given point in time. “Unequal exchange” refers to the terms on which different commodities entering trade between the centre and the periphery are exchanged. Exchange is said to be unequal (in the normative sense of “unfair”) because production conditions in the periphery lead to exporting goods at cheaper prices than if the conditions had been those of the centre. At any point in time, production conditions at the centre lead to high prices of the commodities exported, whereas production conditions in the periphery lead to cheap prices of exports. For the authors belonging to the under-development and dependency schools, inequalities in trade are seen in connection to inequalities in development. These in turn are seen as a consequence of the way in which the capitalist system has expanded over time and has come into contact with other modes of production, central countries subordinating periphery ones to their own advantage (for example: Frank). Moreover, in more recent times, this position has emphasized significant controversial elements in the trade liberalization-food security relationships: a) trade reform can be a damage for food security with its benefits only for the bigger farms, ‘export-oriented’ and the push toward the marginality of little farmers with a consequent result of more unemployment and poverty; b) agricultural system has got a special role in an underdeveloped context, not only as an economic activity but also as a social protection (safety nets, income and labour integration) for the poorest families and so on. Consequently it needs to reserve a special treatment for this sector and not to abandon it to the uncontrollable forces in the world market; c) a particular support and protection is needed also for the institutional lacks and scarcity of capital in the poor countries; d) a growing domestic agricultural production is a necessity to improve food security and to reduce rural poverty; e) low-income producers in developing countries are very vulnerable to the fluctuations in the international prices because of a limited capacity in the supply adjustment. Also for the strong asymmetry in the public support for agriculture between developed (higher) and underdeveloped countries (lower) a special protection can be justified for the primary sector in poor countries; f) finally there is the political question concerning the ‘food sovereignty’ and the protection of the biodiversity, threatened by the liberalization and globalization processes. III°) An “intermediate” or more “neutral” vision: trade with global net benefits but also with possible consistent asymmetric spread effects. (Unctad, 2002; 2004). The standard theory shows that countries as a whole gain from trade but makes no reference to whether and how different groups within each country benefit or lose from trade. Trade can have important impacts on income distribution and this adds a social dimension to the trade issue. Two issues can be distinguished on trade and equity relationship: one is the impact of trade on different economic or social groups within a country, the other is whether the gains from trade are fairly distributed between trading countries. The standard theory is silent about the impact of trade on income distribution within a country. It is obvious that workers, entrepreneurs, investors and owners of natural resources (i.e. the owners of productive factors) engaged in export industries stand to win from increased trade since their activities develop if exports expand. Contrariwise, the owners of factors engaged in industries which have to compete with products imported from abroad, i. e. of import-competing industries, stand to lose from increased trade. The distribution of the gains and losses arising from trade among the owners of productive factors will depend on the situation in the respective markets. In general, however, factors which are intensively used in an industry, for instance labour in textile industries or land in extensive farming, will stand to gain or lose more than those not intensively used. Similarly, owners of factors that are rather specific to the industry and hence relatively immobile, for instance workers skilled in some agricultural operations (e.g. pruning) or the owners of lands particularly suited to the production of specific crops, will gain or lose more than the owners of more undifferentiated and mobile factors. Since, in comparison with other industries, factor mobility and product differentiation are rather limited in agriculture, the farming sector is particularly vulnerable to the impact of trade. Thus, it is difficult for agricultural land to change its use to urban or recreational use in response to import competition, or for agricultural labour to find another type of employment since this normally requires reskilling and will often imply migration. It is possible for farmers to change crops to adjust to international competition, but weather, soils, technical know-how and other factors that may restrict or jeopardize possible changes will often come into play. Shifting from plantation or livestock farming to other type of agriculture will be particularly expensive and take a long time. These rigidities, typical of the farm sector, are one of the reasons why governments have traditionally tended to protect farmers from the effects of international competition. The comparative advantages can change and can be acquired over time through, inter alia, policy action. In that case, having a comparative advantage in one good would not necessarily imply that a country should specialize in the production of that good at the expense of other lines of production. New industries (so-called infant industries) may not have a comparative advantage when they are being established and may need to be protected until they achieve the size required to benefit from economies of scale. Countries may also lose comparative advantage in certain types of production as technology evolves abroad (the so-called sunset industries issue). In addition, world prices change over time, impacting on a country’s comparative advantage; Moreover, trade may itself be a source of price instability. Thus, if a country is highly specialized in the production of some export commodities and depends largely on imports of other commodities, it will be very exposed to international price fluctuations. These fluctuations are also felt in tradable goods which are only marginally exported or imported, in the absence of policy instruments designed to isolate domestic prices from world price fluctuations. Agriculture has traditionally been the main sector where these instruments have been applied, with varying effects. This is not surprising in view of the characteristic instability of international agricultural prices and the importance attached by governments to the stabilization of food prices and farmers’ incomes. Growth and trade opening relationship. The arguments that openness to trade contributes to economic growth and that this can, in turn, be beneficial for poverty reduction and food security, are well grounded in conventional economic theory and have been supported by a number of empirical studies. No country has experimented successfully fast and stable growth in a context of lack in the trade opening and integration process. But not all the countries improving the opening and integration degree have experimented successfully economic growth. According Unctad (2004), in the relationships between consumption per caput increase and trade (exports) increase, the total of cases characterized by ambiguous effects (no clear trend) and immisering effects (consumption decrease together with exports increase) overtook the total of cases characterized by virtuous effects (consumption increase at the same time with exports increase) in 1990-1995 and 1995-2000 comparison 6 . A recent World Bank report (2000/2001; also 2002) reviews the evidence as to whether globalization supports poverty reduction and concludes that whilst a category of “new globalizers” are benefiting from greater integration into the world economy, a significant group are becoming more marginalized. International trade is vital for poverty reduction in all developing countries. But the links between trade expansion and poverty reduction are neither simple nor automatic. These findings suggest that positive export growth rates are a necessary condition for poverty reduction. But export expansion is no guarantee of poverty reduction. 6 Using a very conservative threshold growth rate of average private consumption per capita (+1 per cent per annum and –1 per cent per annum) to distinguish between situations where there is a virtuous trade effect, an ambiguous trade effect or an immisering trade effect, during both 1990-1995 and 1995-2000, the Report shows that the potential role of trade in poverty reduction is not working as expected: -the immisering trade effect is present in 18 of the 51 cases; - the ambiguous trade effect and the immisering trade effect, which together account for 29 of the 51 cases, occur more frequently than the virtuous trade effect; - the virtuous trade effect is present in only 22 of the 51 cases (Unctad 2004). For LDCs exporting agricultural commodities, there is a mixed picture which reflects differences in export performance and also differences in the inclusiveness of the export growth process, which is related to the organization of production (plantations versus smallholders), access by farmers to production inputs (credit, land and labour), trends in productivity and prices, the bargaining power of farmers in relation to traders and processors, and the relationship between export crop expansion and food prices. The infrequency of export expansion with poverty reduction in the LDCs may have two causes. First, export growth may not be facilitating sustained economic growth at levels sufficient to lead to substantial poverty reduction. Second, economic growth may not be of an inclusive form that increases average household incomes and consumption 7 . Moreover, also if cross-country and time-series analysis show a positive correlation between trade and economic growth, there is a relevant question: what is the actual direction of the relationship. “Simultaneity problem”, as it is known in statistics: is trade influencing positively growth or is growth influencing trade? Also with reference to food security question, several cross-country analysis show an inverse correlation between food insecurity incidence and trade increase: trade increase is the determinant factor of the food insecurity quota decrease or is there another element (income per-capita growth) explaining the trend evolution of the two variables? Export growth can play a number of different roles in supporting economic growth. These include: (a) static efficiency gains which arise through specialization according to current comparative advantage; (b) increased capacity utilization which arises if external demand enables the employment of previously idle labour and land resources which previously were not utilized (“vent for surplus” theory); (c) increased physical and human capital investment owing to improved returns to investment which can arise either through the identification of new opportunities associated with external demand or through the improved profitability of investment; (d) productivity growth which can arise through the transfer of technology or increased efficiency owing to the pressure of exposure to international trade competition; (e) export-accelerated industrialization, involving a labour re-allocation from agriculture into manufacturing; and (f) relaxation of the balance of payments constraint on sustained economic growth. Another reason why trade can increase efficiency is because it allows an expansion of the market for a certain industry beyond the limits of the domestic economy. Through exports, the output of the industry can expand and, if there are economies of scale, the average cost of the industry’s product will fall. The relative importance and the mix of these roles vary between countries. In particular for most LDCs, the primary sector, specifically agriculture, dominates production and employment in the economy, and productive capacities are weakly developed. In this situation, the key role of exports is that they enable the acquisition, through importation, of goods which are necessary for economic growth and poverty reduction, but which are not produced domestically. These include food, manufactured consumer goods, fuel and raw materials, machinery and equipment and means of transport, and intermediate inputs and spare parts. The income elasticity of demand for imports is likely to be high in the early stages of development. Exports must thus grow sufficiently fast, and in a sufficiently stable way, to meet growing import demand. If not, and in the absence of capital inflows in the form of grants and compensatory financing facilities to cope with temporary shocks to export earnings, the sustainability of economic growth will be threatened by the build-up of an unsustainable external debt (Unctad, p. 107). 7 The Unctad Report considers three possible factors related to the form of economic growth that may be contributing to trade expansion without poverty reduction and to immiserizing trade. They are the following: the level of income inequality; the demand-side sources of economic growth; and the scale of domestic resource mobilization efforts (Unctad, 2002). In conditions of mass poverty, poverty reduction requires sustained economic growth of a type that substantially increases average household incomes and consumption. International trade can play a powerful role in poverty reduction. It is important because exports and imports facilitate a process of sustained economic growth, the development of productive capacities and expansion of employment opportunities and sustainable livelihoods. Although international trade can play a powerful role in poverty reduction in the LDCs, in practice the positive role of trade in poverty reduction is actually being realized in very few LDCs. The first and obvious reason for this is that there has been a lack of export dynamism in many LDCs. This is closely related to export structure, and in particular commodity dependence. The non-oil-commodity-exporting underdeveloped countries generally depend on a narrow range of low-productivity, low-value-added and weakly competitive primary commodities serving declining or sluggish international markets. International trade cannot work for poverty reduction if export performance is weak. But even when the underdeveloped countries have increased their overall export growth rate, better export performance rarely translate into sustained and substantial poverty reduction. The relationship between trade and poverty is thus asymmetrical. Although LDCs with declining exports are almost certain to have a rising incidence of poverty, increasing exports do not necessarily lead to poverty reduction. The usual view of the relationship between trade liberalization and poverty is that trade liberalization is likely to have adverse effects in the short run, particularly as social groups which formerly benefited from a protectionist tariff regime are exposed to international competition, but that in the long run the effects will be favourable because trade liberalization will increase the growth potential of the economy. In according to Unctad Report the findings are the opposite, however. Poverty trends during and immediately after trade liberalization in the LDCs are very mixed, and not invariably negative as some claim. But there are many grounds for concern about the long-term effects in terms of both the sustainability of economic growth and its inclusiveness. The short-term effects to the process of trade liberalization on poverty vary considerably between the countries, with some groups benefiting and other losing. This pattern is related to export specialization as much as to trade liberalization, and also to differences in the speed of trade liberalization in Asian and African LDCs. African LDCs have undertaken deeper and faster trade liberalization than Asian LDCs. But it is the latter that have generally had a better performance in terms of poverty reduction and also have been more successful in developing more market-dynamic manufactures exports, partly through regional trade and investment linkages (see: Unctad 2002; 2004). According to Unctad, there has been a tendency for the countries that have opened more gradually and less deeply to have a better trade-poverty relationship than those that have opened further and fastest, and better also than those which have been restrictive Whatever the short-term trends, however, the central issue is whether the new policy environment is likely to facilitate substantial and sustained poverty reduction in the long run. In this regard, there are some positive elements and some negative elements. For the underdeveloped countries which have undertaken deep trade liberalization, comparisons of economic trends before and after trade liberalization indicate that GDP growth rates, export growth rates and investment growth rates are all higher in the post-liberal economic environment. But, given high population growth rates, the rates of economic growth that are being achieved are in many cases not sufficient to yield GDP per capita growth rates that will make a major dent in poverty. The composition of trade is as important for the nature of the trade-poverty relationship as the level of trade. This applies both to exports and imports. Ignoring the form of a country’s integration with the rest of the world through trade can lead to major fallacies. For exports, there is a particularly sharp distinction between commodities and manufactures. Commodity exports are subject to short-term price and demand fluctuations, as well as having episodes of medium- to long-term terms-of-trade decline. Commodities are also subject to intense price competition, as a result of which productivity gains are normally passed to the consumers rather than benefiting the producers. Because of the involvement of fixed factors of production, such as land and reserves in mines, they can be also subject to diminishing returns. In contrast, manufacturing is subject to substantial static and dynamic economies of scale. There is often higher income elasticity of demand for manufactures exports than for commodity exports. The composition of imports also matters. In very low-income economies which depend on a narrow range of low-value-added primary commodities and have deep mass poverty, there is a strong tendency for the domestic vicious circles of economic stagnation and persistent poverty to be reinforced by external trade and financial relationships. In this situation trade can be part of an international poverty trap in which low and unstable commodity prices interact with unsustainable external debts and an aid/debt service system (Unctad, 2002). The inclusiveness of the post-liberal growth process also gives cause for concern. A form of economic growth in which expansion is localized within a small geographical and sectoral enclave is becoming a problem in some LDCs whose major exports are manufactures and mining. With this form of economic growth, there are weak links between the rapidly growing export enclave and the agricultural sector where the majority of the population and the majority of the poor have their livelihoods. In this circumstances, it is possible to have very high rates of export growth but no change in the incidence of poverty. What is required is not simply a process of export expansion, but also the promotion of development linkages between growing export activities and the rest of the economy. For an inclusive process of economic growth, it is particularly important that the development complementarities between agriculture and non-agricultural activities be strengthened. Although there are some exceptions, agriculture is the main source of livelihood in the LDCs 8 . There are some large-scale capitalist farms (plantations, estates and agribusiness). However, agricultural production is mainly organized on a household basis with the unity of production and consumption overlapping and part of total household production not entering the market system but being consumed within the household. Both agribusinesses and smallholders are engaged in export production. But, in general, exports constitute only a small fraction of total output 9 . The ratio of agricultural exports to agricultural value-added is a certainly not a perfect measure of the extent to which agricultural livelihoods are export-oriented. But it suggests that direct involvement of people working in agricultural activities in LDCs in exports is rather limited, with a few notable exceptions, including Guinea-Bissau, Malawi and the West African LDCs which export cotton. Given this structure of production, enterprise and employment (also for mining, industry and services), there is no guarantee that export expansion will lead to a form of economic growth which is inclusive. Indeed, there is a great likelihood that export expansion will be associated with “enclave-led growth”. This is a form of economic growth which is concentrated in a small part of the economy, both geographically and sectorally. Enclave-led growth offers a short-term solution to the many binding constraints on economic growth which are characteristic of a low-income trap of underdevelopment and generalized poverty (Unctad 2004) 10 . 8 In 2000, 71 per cent of the population of working age was employed in agriculture in the LDCs as a group, and the proportion engaged in agriculture was more than 50 per cent in all except seven LDCs. 9 Agricultural exports were equivalent to less than 10 per cent of agricultural value-added in more than half of the LDCs for which data were available (Unctad 2004). 10 Basic features of the export structure of the LDCs are: -The total merchandise exports of the LDCs are divided more or less equally between oil exports, non-oil commodity exports and manufactures exports. So, trade liberalization is a necessary but not sufficient factor for sustained growth (Pronk) 11 . Evidence presented by Dollar and Kraay (2002), Sala-I-Martin (2002) among others suggests aggregate economic growth differences have been largely responsible for the differences in poverty alleviation across regions. Initiatives that boost economic growth are therefore likely to be helpful in the fight against poverty, and trade liberalization is such an initiative. But cuts to subsidies and trade barriers also alter relative product prices domestically and in international markets, which in turn affect factor prices. Hence the net effect on poverty depends also on the way those price changes affect poor households’ expenditure and their earnings net of remittances. If the consumer and producer price changes (whether due to own-country reforms and/or those of other countries) are pro-poor, then they will tend to reinforce any positive growth effects of trade reform on the poor. The effects of trade reform on global poverty can be thought of at two levels: on the income gap between developed and developing countries, and on poor households within developing countries. How poor households within developing countries are affected is more difficult to say (Winters 2002; McCulloch, Winters and Cirera 2001). The agricultural policies of developed countries provide a major source of developing country gains from reform, and lowering barriers to textiles and clothing trade also is important. Both would boost the demand for unskilled labour and for farm products produced in poor countries. Since two-thirds of the world’s poor live in rural areas and, in least-developed countries, the proportion is as high as 90 per cent (OECD, 2003a),and since most poor rural households are net sellers of farm labour and/or food, one would expect such reforms to reduce the number in absolute poverty (Anderson 2004; Cline 2004) (Hertel, Ivanic, Perckel and Cranfield, 2003). Making international trade a more effective mechanism of poverty reduction in the LDCs requires a development approach in which three pillars work together coherently and synergistically: better national development strategies which integrate trade objectives as a central component; improvements in the international trade regime, including issues which go beyond the scope of the WTO, to reduce international constraints on development in the LDCs; increased and effective international financial and technical assistance for developing production and trade capacities. -On the basis of a classification in the late 1990s, primary commodities are the major source of export earnings in 31 out the 49 LDCs. Four countries are oil exporters; seven countries are predominantly mineral exporters; and 20 countries are predominantly agricultural exporters. -Whatever their main exports, the export structure of most LDCs is concentrated on a narrow range of products. For the group as a whole, the three leading export products constituted 76 per cent of total merchandise exports in 1997-1999. -The non-oil primary-commodity-exporting LDCs have a low-productivity, low-value-added and weakly competitive commodity sector that is generally concentrated on a narrow range of products serving declining or sluggish international markets. In 1997-1999, 84 per cent of total primary commodity exports of this group of countries were unprocessed before export. -Manufactures exports also tend to be narrowly concentrated on a few low-skill lines of manufacture with competition on the basis of cost, and industries have often been built up on the basis of market access preferences granted by developed countries, including especially the EU and the USA, as well as market access preferences granted by multilateral agreements, namely the Multifibre Arrangement (Unctad 2004). 11 Winters argues that although he believes that trade liberalization aids economic growth, it “may have some adverse consequences for some – including some poor people – that should be avoided or ameliorated to the greatest extent possible”. He suggests that rather than using this as a reason for resisting reform, it should “stimulate the search for complementary policies to minimize adverse consequences and reduce the hurt that they cause”. Trade liberalization and food security. The agricultural trade policy reform involves a combination of: a) domestic support measures; b) export subsidies; c) tariffs. In each case, there are complications that must be taken into account. For example, the removal of domestic price support on, say, wheat, will lower output of wheat and raise its price in the world markets. Wheat-exporting developing countries will benefit and wheat-importing countries that continue to be importers after the removal of the support will lose and those that switch from being importers to exports may benefit or lose. In the same vein, a reduction in tariffs by the developed importing countries will increase the world price of the product, benefiting exporters, hurting importers and leading to an ambiguous effect on those turning from importers to exporters. But this standard analysis is complicated by the presence of trade preferences. The reduction in export subsidies raises the world price of the product, benefiting developing country exporters, hurting importers and yielding ambiguous effect on those turning from being importers to exporters. Again, if the export subsidies were being countervailed, the net impact of the two measures is likely to be a transfer of the export subsidy from the exporting country government to the importing country government in the form of duty, without a significant effect on prices and output. The removal of the export subsidy will also result in the removal of the countervailing duty and the world supply will be unchanged. This is the case with export subsidies in general, although with the removal of targeted export subsidies the affect may be less predictable (Unctad, 2004). The trade barrier removals in developed countries supply increasing opportunities of access for the underdeveloped countries exports; this process can supply more resources to finance more food imports. Nevertheless, if the export increase in developing countries happen through a shift process to detriment of domestic production, for example shifting the resources devoted to it to exports, or triggering off “enclave” systems, the net benefits for poor and for small rural and urban producers could be, at best, insignificant. The subsidies removal for developed countries exports could damage, in the other hand, the poorest countries net food importers in consequence of higher import prices. Besides, the tariff reduction or removal can determine a stronger competition among developing countries in consequence of the changes in trade preferential treatment systems. Nevertheless, according to some authors all these negative effects could have a short period of life, followed by higher positive effects coming out by better incentives for domestic producers and by domestic production increase. Trade liberalization in food and agricultural goods, with the reduction in the protectionist level especially in developed countries, would imply a food international price increase. If this increase will be passed on domestic markets, according to some authors, most of the poor could benefit from in accordance with their dependence by the rural economy and net food suppliers. This is because the poor are found predominantly in farm households and are net sellers of food. Also in the case that most of the poor are net food buyers net benefits could derive by increased labour demand for them. Nevertheless, this presupposes the existence of potential conditions for the agricultural growth (resources, technology, education availability) and a limited number of urban poor or rural landless 12 . 12 If the consequence of an export subsidies removal for a commodity is to increase its international price, the scale of the change could be variable. It depends on the incidence of subsidied exports compared to the total trade volume, to the cross-commodity effects, to the demand reaction and so on. A recent OECD analysis (Oecd, 2002; 2003), based on Aglink model, simulates, for example for wheat, very limited effects on its price, proving previous studies, in consequence of a full liberalization in the agricultural policies in OECD countries, with a bigger impact on the quantities rather than prices. If rich countries subsidize food exports, the presumption should be that this is good for consumers in food importing countries. The poor in particular can benefit from lower food prices. One needs to assess carefully if imports actually represent unfair competition with domestic producers. Often, independently of the price of imports, domestic production is insufficient to meet demand. Furthermore, the commodities imported are often not directly competing with local production (there is market segmentation), so an increase in (cheap) imports does not necessarily pose a threat to local farmers. In any case, for countries characterized by a strong vulnerability in weakness and food insecurity conditions also a limited increase in the international price level could have harmful consequences. What about in developing countries where multilateral agricultural trade liberalization means lower domestic prices for agricultural products because such countries had kept domestic food prices above international levels via import restrictions? It is true that removing those distortions will reduce farm incomes in those countries, and urban households will benefit from lower food prices. However, food self-sufficiency will fall; and it is the fall in both farm earnings and food selfsufficiency that focuses the attention of those who argue that agricultural trade liberalization is bad for poor households. Focusing on just the direct effects of agricultural trade policy reform can be misleading, however, not least because it does not take account of the fact that such reform would be undertaken in the context of multilateral, economy-wide liberalization. Being multilateral means that other countries’ farm protection cuts raise international food prices. If the subsidies reduction or removal could increase agricultural international prices, the tariff reduction or removal in OECD countries, particularly in EU, could decrease domestic prices. Many poor countries, especially African countries, sell European Union commodities, obviously for domestic prices. Consequently, an increased export quantity could involve lower earning for unity of export and limited positive (or negative) effects on real incomes and on poverty and food security. Hunger and under-nutrition can be eased by trade not only in goods but also in agricultural technologies, in particular newly bred varieties of staple crops (Runge et al.2003). Anyway, more recent quantitative simulations, based on econometric and statistical models, support the common judgment according to which the tariff and agricultural subsidies are the most important obstacle for the development of the poor countries and, consequently, for the fight against poverty and food insecurity (Fao, 2003). At the same time, however, the potential gains from trade liberalization are not guaranteed and will not necessarily be reflected in improved food security status of all groups within society. In particular, there are likely to be significant differences between the impacts on small scale and commercial farmers, rural non-farm producers and urban consumers both within and across countries. These need to be considered in identifying the food security implications of trade liberalization. Trade policy will have implications for food security through the link with incomes and expenditures. Any change in the trade regime will have a direct effect on both rural and urban incomes, and employment, and through these on income distribution. In addition, there will be an effect on government revenues through, for example, a change in the level of revenue from import levies. Trade liberalization implies also a change in the relative prices of traded and nontraded goods and factors in a previously protected sector or economy. The change in relative prices will induce changes in the allocation of resources to different activities and hence changes in both subsectoral and aggregate levels of production. In turn, changes in income levels (which are expected to increase in aggregate as resources are used more efficiently) have the potential both to reduce poverty levels and in doing so, to improve the food security status by increasing the access of the poor to food. The strategy employed by individual countries to improve their food security status is one of the key factors in understanding the relationship between trade liberalization and food security. The two broad options followed by countries attempting to achieve adequate levels of food security are, as said, food self-sufficiency and food self-reliance. While food self-sufficiency approach implies the provision of sufficient domestic production to meet a substantial part of consumption requirements, it does not necessarily imply that all households in the country have access to all the food they require. In a number of countries which are net food exporters, substantial numbers of households are suffering from malnutrition. A strategy of food self-reliance reflects a set of policies where the sources of food are determined by international trade patterns and the benefits and risks associated with it. This strategy has become more common as global trade has become more liberal. The success of these broad options will depend, inter alia, on the ability of producers to react to price incentives, or of countries to use income gains for improved efficiency of resource allocation in order to procure food on the international market (Fao, 2003). Accepting food self-reliance as the means to achieve food security, it is possible to ask how the liberalization of trade in agriculture will impact on developing countries. It is necessary to distinguish between importers and exporters of the products and between liberalization in the developed and developing countries 13 . If the object is to study the impact on the poor, much finer analysis is required since the effects must be decomposed at the national level into effects on the poor and non-poor. It is clear that the effect of liberalization by the developed countries is bound to be quite uneven on developing countries. As said before, net importers of both food and agriculture are likely to be hurt by the developed country liberalization, which must raise agricultural prices 14 . On the other hand, the bulk of the benefits will accrue to the relatively well-to-do developing countries in Latin America and Asia and the United States. Countries that are net exporters or naturally self-sufficient can expect to benefit from trade liberalization. Countries that are inherently food insecure will need some assistance, and will face increased import costs if multilateral liberalization leads to higher food prices. Trade theory tells us that developing countries, since they tend to be endowed with land, labour and natural resources (rather than with capital and technology), should have a comparative advantage in agriculture. At the same time, the conventional view among trade economists at least, has been that the policy bias against agriculture in developing countries has often been severe. Trade policies, by protecting manufacturing and taxing (implicitly or explicitly) agriculture, have contributed to this distortion. Misguided agricultural, fiscal and investment policies have also contributed to the bias. Consequently, it is argued, trade reforms alone will be insufficient to remove this bias against agriculture; so also agriculture sector reform will be necessary. In many developing countries, according to this view, protection has encouraged excess resources into inefficient manufacturing and insufficient resources into potentially efficient agriculture. This bias is exacerbated by policies 13 Using Fao and World Bank data, Valdés and McCalla classify 148 developing countries according to a variety of criteria, among others: a) classification according to income (the World Bank divides these countries into Low Income Countries, Lower Middle Income Countries and Lower Middle Income Countries; b) classification according to net trade status in food and agriculture (countries are divided into Net Food Importing and Net Food Exporting; Net Agricultural Importing and Net Agricultural Exporting). This classification shows that of the 148 developing countries, 63 are Low Income Countries , 52 Lower Middle Income Countries and 33 Lower Middle Income Countries. As many as 48 out of 63 Low Income Countries are net importers of food. Even among the Lower Middle Income Countries, 35 out of 52 are net food importers. 14 Strictly speaking, it is only in respect of such countries that the issue of an active food security policy arises. A costly option is to provide subsidies to farmers, and this may not be viable. A number of countries are likely to remain dependent on food aid, or aid that can be used to finance food imports. that tax and discriminate against agriculture. Furthermore, protection reduces the quantity and variety of imports and increases the price of importables, therefore reducing consumer welfare. Tariffs and non-tariff barriers also encourage unproductive activities (rent-seeking), tax avoidance and evasion. These also contribute to inefficiency in the economy. Agriculture sector reforms are intended to increase productivity. In general, these will increase farm incomes or profit margins, and allow prices (especially of foods) to be reduced (at least in real terms). In this sense, agriculture sector reforms confer widespread benefits (Fao, 2003). Trade reform has mixed benefits. Import liberalization (easier access at lower prices) benefits those using imported inputs. This may include producers –farmers using imported fertilizer – or consumers (e.g. lower prices for food). However, it increases competition against those competing with imports, and this may include food producers. Commercial farmers, for example, may benefit from cheaper imported inputs but face increased competition from cheaper food. Measures that favour exporters are generally beneficial, but from the self-sufficiency perspective a problem arises if farmers substitute from food to cash crops. However, if the cash crops earn the revenue to import food, it is consistent with self-reliance. Anyway, the claim that the removal of agricultural protection and export subsidies in the OECD countries, also if with net benefits on efficiency grounds, will bring net gains to the least developed countries as a whole is at best questionable and at worst outright wrong. Developing countries face a number of risks associated with trade. Perhaps the best known is declining terms of trade, as the world prices of the primary commodities they export tend to fall over time relative to the price of the manufactures they import. A related problem is the volatility of world prices for the primary (especially agricultural) commodities they export. Furthermore, these prices are determined in markets beyond the influence of individual poor countries and typically affected by factors beyond their control. Related to this are supply side risks, especially the sensitivity of output to climatic variability. A new type of risk is emerging in the face of increasingly integrated global markets. Trade in agricultural commodities is dominated by large, typically multinational, companies that are present in all or critical stages of the commodity chain. The risk arises because small producers, and even some large producers in small countries, are the weakest link in the chain. In addition, most developing countries are price-takers in the majority of international markets in which their nationals trade, but their activities are concentrated in a small number of markets. They cannot influence world market prices (mainly because of the small relative size of their market contribution), but at the same time are severely affected by changes in world market prices. A related issue here is the increasing tendency for large multi-national companies to capture the benefits of comparative advantage by virtue of their monopsony position (Fao, 2003). We have to consider another possible effect of trade liberalization: will commodity price volatility in the international market increase or decrease? According to many authors we can expect a bigger price volatility. In this case the impact on food security for poor countries could be more remarkable in negative sense rather than a limited increase in the price. The price increase presumably can be a short period phenomenon, intended to be counterbalanced by the declining trend of the agricultural commodities international prices (Ayouz et al.). Assuming volatility in agricultural prices to be due to the lack of price responsiveness in demand, coupled with the fact that short run supplies are volatile and largely pre-determined, some authors have documented the positive relationship between freer trade and lower market instability (for example: Bale and Lutz, 1979, Tyers and Anderson, 1992 and Vanzetti, 1998). Negative macro consequences of agricultural price instability was demonstrated by Timmer (2001) and Dawe (2001) for developing Asia, where stabilisation schemes –although imperfect- enabled farmers to invest, increase labour productivity and food supply, which in turn reduces consumer prices, poverty and inflation. A huge body of literature isolates agricultural price-induced terms of trade volatility as a significant factor reducing growth, through its effect either on investment and saving instability (for recent findings and survey, see Turnovsky and Chattopadhyay, 2003). Trade may also serve to smooth out transitory excess demand or excess supply situations in domestic markets, thus avoiding or reducing price fluctuations and eventual supply shortages. Agricultural products may benefit especially in this respect from foreign trade, since agricultural markets tend to be particularly unstable as a consequence of supply rigidities (it takes time for agricultural production to respond to market signals), exogenous factors affecting production (such as weather and pest conditions) and the fact that the demand for food tends to vary little when prices go up or down (it is inelastic). A country largely self-sufficient in food and agricultural products may have agricultural surpluses in good years, which will place strong downward pressure on farm prices. The international market may serve to dispose of these surpluses with minimum disruption of domestic prices and incomes. The opposite will happen in poor agricultural years. A number of steps are necessary to evaluate the link between trade policy and food security, and such an evaluation needs to be specific to the country. An identical policy change in two different contexts, whether within a country at two discrete points in time, or across a set of countries, can result in quite different outcomes, because of modifying factors. Any attempt to assess the impact of trade reform on levels of food security must therefore take into account the existing policy and institutional environment, the agro-climatic constraints, and the level of physical and human capital which will all influence the extent to which reform will cause a change in the intermediate indicators, which in turn determine the final outcome in terms of changes in food security status. In addition, even if increases in aggregate agricultural production and net incomes do result from such reforms, it does not necessarily follow that the level of food security of the insecure will rise, especially if the distribution of the benefits associated with increased agricultural production is not in their favour, or the potential impacts of changes in agricultural production levels are offset by changes elsewhere in the economy. High-income countries must also open their markets to low-income countries, particularly for highvalue crops. They must also ensure that farm income transfers do not depress world prices. In conclusion, there is a strong correlation between export expansion and economic growth but the challenge is whether small farmers can participate effectively in international specialization. Such participation is only possible if farmers’ productivity can increase and the costs and risks of engaging in trade are reduced. As producer prices rise and farm input costs are reduced, farmers are able to invest and commercialize their production activities, leading to structural transformation. Estimating the potential effects of trade liberalization. The potential effects of post U-R trade liberalization on developed and developing countries have been assessed using computable general equilibrium (CGE) models in a number of recent studies (for an overview see Unctad, 2003a). The models estimate the static gains from multilateral trade liberalization based on product-specific elasticities of supply and demand which relate output and demand changes to changes in prices associated with the reduction of tariff barriers, and also dynamic gains which incorporate assumptions about induced capital formation and productivity growth following trade liberalization. None of the studies include the least developed countries as a sub-group of developing countries. Moreover, in interpreting the estimated gains it is important to recognize that the models incorporate certain assumptions that diverge from real-world conditions, notably that factors of production are fully utilized and industries are perfectly competitive and there are constant returns to scale and constant elasticities of substitution. However, the studies provide a basis for assessing the possible order of magnitude of the impact of multilateral trade liberalization on the LDCs (Unctad). The results of the studies suggest that the least developed countries cannot be expected to gain much from further multilateral liberalization unless improvements are made to their productive capacities to enable them to benefit from any subsequent global growth in trade. There are two reasons for coming to this conclusion: firstly, the overall magnitude of gains from multilateral trade liberalization; and secondly, the extent to which the LDCs can be expected to share in these gains. What this static and dynamic gains imply in terms of poverty reduction depends on assumptions about the relationship between the income gains and poverty. The World Bank (2003) estimates that the dynamic gains from a “realistic” multilateral trade liberalization would be real income gains of $518 billion for the world as a whole and $349 billion for low- and middle-income countries in 2015 in 1997 dollars. Without such trade liberalization the number of people living on less than $1/day in the low- and middle- income countries as a whole would be expected to fall from 1.1 billion in 2000 to 734 million in 2015 and the number of people living on less than $2/day would be expected to fall from 2.7 billion to 2.1 billion over the same period. With such trade liberalization the number of people living in extreme poverty in the low- and middle-income countries would fall by an extra 61 million (8 per cent of the projected 2015 level) by 2015, and the number of people living on less $2/day would fall by an extra 144 million (7 per cent of the projected 2015 level) by 2015. How the least developed countries would benefit in terms of welfare gains and poverty reduction depends on whether the LDCs are affected in exactly the same way as other developing countries. If one assumes that the poverty reduction associated with the income gains is exactly proportional to LDCs’ population share on total population of low- and middle-income countries, about 8 million of the extra 61 million people estimated lifted out of extreme poverty through multilateral trade liberalization would be inhabitants of the LDCs. This would clearly be an important achievement. However, as the group of least developed countries is predicated to see an increase of poverty, if the trends of the 1990s persist, multilateral trade liberalization would slow down the rate of increase of the number of extremely poor people in the LDCs. Moreover, it is likely that (World Bank and others) estimates of the impact of multilateral trade liberalization on poverty in the LDCs are optimistic. One basic reason is that many of the least developed countries have already undertaken extensive unilateral trade liberalization, and thus the gains from multilateral trade liberalization through further opening of their own markets are likely to be smaller. This is significant as most of the models suggest that the greatest gains from multilateral trade liberalization to developing countries come from liberalization of their own markets. In addition, because preferential market access has been a major international support measure for the LDCs in the past, multilateral trade liberalization will be associated with the erosion of preferences. Finally, multilateral trade liberalization will only have the povertyreducing effects if there is an export supply to the opportunities that result from multilateral trade liberalization. The problem here is that the ability of the LDCs to increase their exports is highly constrained by weak production capacities (Unctad, 2002; 2004). An area of multilateral trade liberalization that is likely to have a strongly positive poverty-reducing impact in the LDCs in the long run is the phasing-out of agricultural support measures in advanced countries in a way that ends the distorting effects of this support on international trade. This issue is vital for the LDCs because agriculture plays such an important role in their economies, contributing 35 per cent of GDP, employing 69 per cent of the total economically active population, and contributing 24 per cent of total exports in 1999-2001. The key mechanism through which the phasing-out of agricultural support measures can help to reduce poverty in the LDCs is the way in which it will stop low prices and cheap imports undermining the incentives for investment and productivity growth in domestic agriculture. The effects of the phasing-out of OECD agricultural support measures in the LDCs will, nevertheless, be complex. They depend on what the LDCs produce, export and import now, and also what they potentially can produce, export and import in the future. The LDCs have become increasingly dependent on food imports. This implies, as seen, that in the short run, phasing out will mean higher food prices and also considerable pressure on the balance of payments of many LDCs. Proposals for a food financing facility have been put forward to address these adverse effects (Unctad, 2003b). Models which estimate the effects of a phasing-out of OECD agricultural support provide a mixed picture, with Hoekman et al. indicating welfare gains for the LDCs and Peters indicating welfare losses 15 . The models are likely to underestimate the benefits of the phasing-out of OECD agricultural support to the LDCs for at least three reasons. They assume that factors of production are fully employed. They concentrate on the products that receive agricultural support rather than both those products and potential substitutes for them. Their starting-point is the current pattern of agricultural production and trade, which is itself a product of the agricultural support measures, rather than a pattern of agricultural production and trade that reflects comparative advantage. In the long run, those LDCs that have a comparative advantage in agricultural production should benefit from the phasing-out of agricultural support measures. According to Cline (2004), although many LDCs are net food importers, more than half of them have a comparative advantage in food production. The phasing-out of agricultural support measures is important for the LDCs because substantial and sustained poverty reduction depends in many of the LDCs on improvements in agricultural productivity and also beneficial complementarities between the agricultural sector and the nonagricultural sector. Without such complementarities, there is likely to be an enclave-based pattern of development. The harmful effects of agricultural support lie precisely in its encouraging this disarticulation in the domestic economy, which then prevents agrarian commercialisation and development of national markets. The efforts to remove distortions in the domestic agricultural sector within the LDCs is being subverted by distortions in the domestic agricultural sector in other countries. In order to encourage agricultural production in developing countries effectively the process might start by focusing on strategic agricultural goods that are of particular importance to the poorest developing countries. Finally, it should be noted that the greatest benefits of the phasing-out of agricultural support will accrue if the phasing-out is linked to increasing international financial and technical assistance to agriculture in the LDCs to promote agricultural productivity growth and commercialisation (Unctad, 2004). 1.6 Conclusion: some key questions Achieving food security means ensuring that sufficient food is available, that supplies are relatively stable and that everyone can obtain food. At least at the household level, if not at the national level, food security can be interpreted as being determined, inter alia, by purchasing power. Changes in the latter, in turn, are conditional on economic growth and the distribution of income and resources. Over the next two or three decades at least, the world could produce enough food to feed the population. The problem is not one of redistribution of scarce resources. Food security is a political problem, requiring political solutions at national and international level. International cooperation should also mean building a trade system that allows countries to have access to world resources without endangering the lives and livelihoods of their people. However, imports generally account for under 10% of food supplies in the countries most affected by hunger, so the solution depends on increasing agricultural productivity. This in turn means improving health and education services for small farmers, and notably for women, who are responsible for much of the work. Redistribution could also make a significant contribution 16 . 15 Although export subsidies are a potent symbol of the rich world’s iniquitous farm policies, they have little impact on global commerce. According to the World Bank, their abolition would yield only 2% of the theoretical gains from free trade in agriculture. The European Union is the biggest user, subsiding its exports, mainly of dairy products and sugar, to the tune of 2,8 billion euro a year. Reform of the EU’s Common Agricultural Policy will reduce these subsidies sharply. 16 The US Department of Agriculture points out that malnutrition could be eliminated in the 40 poorest nations of the world if only 3% of their available food supply was redistributed to the poorest segments of the population. The relationships between free trade and development, and specifically between trade and poverty, trade and food security is a very complex matter. In literature, in fact, there is room for different theoretical positions, not completely clarified by the analytical, quantitative simulations based on a large range of econometric and statistical tools. There is a predominant approach that considers as strategic a freer trade for the prevalence of net benefits over the costs. But this assertion has to match with the awareness of possible asymmetries in the distribution of the net benefits and also with the prevalence of social and economic costs for some countries. There are many reasons behind these more prudential approaches: asymmetric market power, incomplete market, different positions of the underdeveloped countries as net agricultural exporters or net agricultural importers, different conditions in their productive capacity, agricultural market instability and so on. Besides, free trade does not seem a sufficient source to fight poverty and food security, because it can not reach the poorer segments of a population. According to Unctad (Unctad, 2004) an increased integration into international market could be considered as a necessary condition for developing countries in order to grow and to fight against poverty and malnutrition. At least at a national level, as no country experimented in the last decades positive trends in the economic growth without improving own opening degree. But, at the same time, the judgment that the persistent mass poverty and the widespread food insecurity in the less developed countries are the outcome of an integration lack and inadequate trade liberalization rather than the outcome of underdevelopment can be groundless. The integration of economies in the international market mustn’t to neglect the policies aimed to reduce poverty and food insecurity. Other than the ‘pro-poor’ strategies the integration form is as important as the integration level and degree. Some econometric simulations show stronger positive effects for the developed and more protectionist countries and for the medium income, net exporters countries compared to the poorest and net importers countries linked to trade liberalization. So, trade as a necessary but not also a sufficient condition to increase income and welfare; consequently, a gradual strategy in the market opening could be pursued. The effect of multilateral liberalization on developing country exports will vary considerably according to the product and the market. The broad effect is that a reduction of import tariffs by developed or developing countries should increase their demand for imports, including those from developing countries. But how this affects particular developing countries depends both upon the current trade regime for the products they export and their capacity to alter supply in response to increased demand. We can identify at least two strategic paths to link more strictly the trade reforms to the alleviation of poverty and food insecurity for the least developed countries. One of them concerns more appropriate and specific researches aimed to describe pools of countries characterized by different position on the international market, on the productive capacity and so on and, consequently, by unhomogeneous exposure in terms of social benefits and costs deriving by a free trade. Some works are already oriented in this direction, with interesting and stimulating contributions overcoming the limits inherent in too aggregate analysis (for example: Valdes-McCalla; Diaz-Bonilla et al.; Sassi). Another path concerns the capacity, both at a domestic and international levels, to connect trade reform processes with pro-poor policies and to perform WTO discipline improving global welfare and putting the needs of the least developed countries as a priority in its agenda. Special international support measures have an important role to play in making international trade a more effective mechanism for poverty reduction in the least developed countries. Trade reform and trade liberalization have to become part of a global development approach and not considered as the only and the most strategic factor to face poverty and food insecurity. Also agricultural reforms that improve factor mobility and productivity (such as improved access to credit and functioning markets for land) can play an important role. The role of the agriculture sector in reducing levels of food insecurity goes far beyond simply increasing the amount of available food. It is therefore important to understand how agriculture can make its contribution. An emerging consensus view is that in many rural economies, agriculture has greater potential than other activities to stimulate initial growth and improvements in income (Mellor). Increases in agricultural productivity have the potential to increase incomes as rural households specialize and intensify production. Supply response will also be affected by many other factors, such as access to assets, skills and credit. Globalization can greatly enhance the role of agriculture as an engine of growth in low-income countries by making it possible for agriculture to grow considerably faster than domestic consumption. It also increases the potential for agriculture to increase food security through enlarged multipliers to the massive, employment-intensive, nontradable rural non-farm sector (Fao, 2003). A major element in ensuring food security is increased incomes of poor people. The marginal propensity of the poor to spend on food is high. Low-income people increase their incomes and hence their food security through increased employment. It is agricultural growth that reduces poverty. The great majority of persons below the poverty line work in the rural non-farm sector. The rural non-farm sector uses very little capital and hence is highly employment-intensive. It produces goods and services that are dominantly non-tradable, that is they are dependent on local sources of demand. Agricultural growth is the underlying source of that demand growth. The agricultural demand shows strong growth multipliers since the rural non-farm sector also tends to spend substantially on itself. Low-income countries need to invest far more than at present in agricultural research and technology dissemination. Without such investment, opening markets will do little good for agriculture and hence for poverty reduction and food security. Bibliography. Anderson K., (2004), «Subsidies and Trade Barriers», Copenhagen Consensus Challenge Paper, Copenhagen. Ayouz M., Chabe-Ferret S., Gerard F. and Voituriez T. (2004), Are Bhagwati’s Arguments Against Free Trade Restricted to Capital Flows?, “Paper presented to the 85th Seminar of European Association of Agricultural Economics”, Florence. Bale M., Lutz E. (1979), The Effect of Trade Intervention on International Price Instability, “American Journal of Agricultural Economics”, 61: 512-516. Cline W. R. (2004), Trade Policy and Global Poverty,, Center for Global Development, Washington. Dawe D. (2001), How Far Down the Path to Free Trade? The Importance of Rice Price Stabilization in Developing Asia, “Food Policy”, 26. Diaz-Bonilla E., Thomas M., Robinson S., Cattaneo A. (2000), Food Security and Trade Negotiations in the World Trade Organization: a Cluster Analysis of Country Groups, “TMD Discussion Paper n. 59” International Food Policy Research Institute, , December . Diaz-Bonilla E., Thomas M., Robinson S. (2002), On Boxes, Contents, and Users: Food Security and the WTO Negotiations, “TMD Discussion Paper n. 82”, International Food Policy Research Institute, January. Diaz-Bonilla E., Thomas M., Robinson S. (2002), Trade Liberalization, WTO, and Food Security, “Trade and Macroeconomic Discussion Paper 82”, Washington D.C., International Food Policy Research Institute. Dollar D. and Kraay A. (2002), Institutions, Trade and Growth, “Journal of Monetary Economics,, n. 50. Fao (1999), Agricultural Trade and Food Security, Fao, Rome. Fao (2000), Multilateral Trade Negotiations on Agriculture. Agreement on Agriculture, Fao, Roma. Fao (2003), Trade Reforms and Food Security: Conceptualizing the Linkages, Fao, Rome. Fao (2005), The State of Food and Agriculture, Fao, Rome. Frank A. (1974), Dependence and Underdevelopment: Latin America’s Political Economy, Doubleday, N.Y. Hertel T. W., Ivanic M., Prectual P. V., Cranfield J. A. (2003), Trade Liberalization and the Structure of Poverty in Developing Countries, “Paper to the Conference on Globalization, Agricultural Development and Rural Livelihoods”, Cornell University, Ithaca, 11-12 April. Hoekman B.M., Michalopoulos C., Schiff M. and Tarr D. (2001), Trade Policy Reform and Poverty Alleviation, “Policy Research Working Paper 2733”, The World Bank. Hoekman B.M., Ng F. and Olarreaga M. (2002), Eliminating Excess Tariffs on Exports of Least Developed Countries, “World Bank Economic Review”, 16. Hoekman B.M., Ng F. and Olarreaga M. (2004), Agricultural Tariffs versus Subsidies: What’s More Important for Developing Countries?, “World Bank Economic Review”, 18. Kindleberger C. P. (1989), Commercial Policy between the Wars’, in Mathias P. and Pollard S. (eds.), The Cambridge Economic History of Europe, vol. 8, Cambridge, Cambridge University Press. McCulloch N., Winters L. A., Cirera X. (2001), Trade Liberalization and Poverty: a Handbook, Centre for Economic Policy Research, London. Mellor J. W. (2000), Faster More Equitable Growth: the Relation between Growth in Agriculture and Poverty Reduction, “CAER Project Office”, Harward Institute for International Development, Cambridge MA. Mellor J. W. (2002), The Impacts of Globalization on the Role of Agriculture, “Paper presented at the export consultation on trade and food security”, July, Rome. Oecd (2002), The Medium Term Impacts of Trade Liberalization in OECD Countries on the Food Security of Non-Member Economies, Oecd, Parigi. Oecd (2003), Agricultural Trade and Poverty: Making Policy Analysis Count, Oecd, Paris. Peters R. (2004), Roadblock to Reform: the Persistence of Agricultural Export Subsidies, “mimeo”. Prebisch R. (1950), The Economic Development of Latin America and its Principal Problems, United Nations, New York. Prebisch R. (1959), Commercial Policy in the Underdeveloped Countries, “American Economic Review”, n. 49. Pronk J., (2004), Subsidies and Trade Barriers: a Comment, “Copenhagen Consensus Challenge Paper”, Copenhagen. Romer P. (1994). New Goods, Old Theory, and the Welfare Costs of Trade Restrictions, “Journal of Development Economics, 43. Runge C.F., Senauer B., Pardey P.G. and Rosegrant M.W. (2003), Ending Hunger in Our Lifetime: Food Security and Globalization, London, J. Hopkins University Press. Sala-i-Martin X. (2002), The World Distribution of Income, “NBER Working Paper 8933, Cambridge MA. Sassi M. (2004b), Riforma del Commercio Agricolo e Sicurezza Alimentare nei PVS, “Paper for XLI SIDEA Conference,16-18 sept., Roma. Taylor M. S. (1999), Trade and Trade Policy in Endogenous Growth Models, in Piggott J. and Woodland A., International Trade Policy and the Pacific Rim, London, MacMillan. Timmer P. (2000), Agriculture and Economic Development, in Gardner B.L. and Rausser G.C. (eds.), Handbook of Agricultural Economics, London, Elsevier Science. Turnovsky S.J., Chattopadhyay P. (2003), Volatility and Growth in Developing Economies: Some Numerical Results and Empirical Evidence, “Journal of International Economics” 59. Tyers R. and Anderson K. (1992), Disarray in World Food Markets: A Quantitative Assessment, Cambridge University Press. Unctad (2002), The Least developed Countries, Report 2002,, U. N., Geneva, 2002 Unctad (2003a), Trade and Development Report, 2003.U.N., Geneva Unctad (2003b), Back to Basic, U. N., Geneva Unctad (2004), The Least Developed Countries, Report 2004,, U. N., Geneva, 2004. USITC (1997), The Dynamic Effects of Trade Liberalization: an Empirical Analysis, “Publication 3069”, Washington D.C.: United states International Trade Commission. Valdes A., McCalla A. (1999), Issues, Interests and Options of Developing Countries, “IBRD”, Washington. Vanzetti D. (1998), Global Stocks, Price Stability and Food Security. “Report n. 95”, Danish Institute for Agriculture an fisheries Economics, Copenhagen. Winters L. A. (2000), Trade, Trade Policy, and Poverty: What Are the Links?, “CEPR Research Paper n. 2382”, Center of Economic Policy Research, London. Winters L. A., (2001) Trade Policies for Poverty Alleviation in Developing Countries, in Hoekman B., English P. and Mattoo A. (eds.), Trade Policy, Economic Development and Multilateral Negotiations: a Sourcebook, Washington, World Bank. Winters L. A., (2002), «Trade Liberalization and Poverty: What Are the Links?», The World Economy 25(9): 1339-68, September. World Bank (2000/2001), World Development Report, Attacking Poverty, Washington, D.C. World Bank (2002), Globalization, Growth and Poverty: Building an Inclusive World Economy, Oxford University Press. World Bank (2000), Trade Policy, Food Security and Adjustments to Liberalization, “Draft for discussion”. World Bank (2002a), Development, Trade, and the WTO. A handbook, The World Bank, Washington. World Bank (2002b), Global Economic Prospects and the Developing Countries: Making Trade Work for the Poor, The World Bank, Washington. World Bank (2003), Agriculture, Trade and WTO. Creating a Trading Environment for Development, The World Bank, Washington. WTO (2000), Special Agricultural Safeguard. “Background Paper by Secretariat for the Committee on Agriculture”. WTO (2000), Agricultural Trade Performance by Developing Countries 1990-1998, Geneva.