PARSING DR CULLEN: FROM NEW PUBLIC MANAGEMENT IN TERTIARY EDUCATION TO WHERE? Dr Jonathan Barrett, School of Business and Computer Technology, Nelson Marlborough Institute of Technology Abstract The effects of New Public Management (NPM) doctrines on tertiary education in New Zealand during the 1990s have been well documented. However, the relevant policies of centre-left government in the new millennium have been subject to less thorough analysis. Recent proposals by Dr Cullen, Tertiary Education Minister, for a new tertiary education model enhance opportunities for such analysis. This paper critically analyses the proposed ‘Cullen model’ of tertiary education in New Zealand, specifically considering business education in the polytechnic sector. Comparing key principles and rhetorical features of NPM with Dr Cullen’s statements, it identifies underpinning policy information to predict practical consequences. At a fundamental level, the Cullen model is criticised for seeking to instrumentalise education, diminishing the autonomy of participants in tertiary education in a way comparable to neoliberalism. It is concluded, inter alia, that NPM’s deleterious effects on institutional autonomy make a new pervasive bureaucracy likely. Under these conditions, excellence in teaching will continue to be challenged by government prescriptions, whilst remaining principally dependant on autonomous professionalism in the classroom. 1. Introduction During the period 1984-1996, the New Zealand public sector was transformed by neoliberal ideology and the doctrines of new public management (NPM) (see, for example, Norman, 2003). The ideas underpinning NPM – neoliberal economics, agency theory, transaction-cost, and managerialism (Boston et al., 1996, pp. 1728) – imposed a market model on government, requiring it to be re-imagined in corporate terms, as an agency performing only certain minimal functions, and those more efficiently than it had done in the past (McKinnon, 2003, p. 363). Generally, tertiary education institutes (TEIs) were expected to become autonomous, competitive, market-responsive, and principally funded by student fees (see Olssen, 2002). However, the project of commercialising education, which could have led to full student fees and still greater competition (see Ministry of Education, 1998, for proposed reforms), was interrupted by the election of a centre-left coalition in 1999. The Labour-led government (eventually) reassumed some of the economic risk of education that had been shifted on to students via its forgiveness of interest on student loans, but did not radically restructure the system. Notably, the equivalent full-time students (EFTS) funding scheme, which financed TEIs on the basis of the number of students they could register, was retained. In April 2006, Dr Cullen, Tertiary Education Minister, announced plans to restructure the tertiary education system (see Cullen, 2006a). At the time of writing, the details of his proposed model are not clear, and, given the triennial electoral cycle, there is no guarantee that the proposed reforms will be effectuated. Nevertheless, this paper seeks to critically analyse the principles underpinning the ‘Cullen model’ for tertiary education, and speculates on the possible consequences of the proposals for institutes of technology and polytechnics (ITPs), with particular consideration of business education. 2. The market model of tertiary education The market model for public institutions is broadly predicated on the following premise: by minimising government intervention, the ‘invisible hand of the market’ can efficiently allocate scarce resources in a way that best satisfies consumers’ desires. Since, the consumer is ‘sovereign’, ‘the consumer’s choice must be accepted’ (Baker, 1979, p. 233). Students’ consumption choices – education being conceived as a commodity to be consumed – should principally determine which TEIs and which courses will exist and flourish. On the supply side, TEIs should be autonomous and competitive: for example, ITPs should face competition from private training enterprises (PTEs) – and, in turn, ITPs may compete with universities. In terms of this model, outputs are the key measure of performance. EFTS represents an appropriate output for measuring TEI performance, since TEIs are funded to the extent that they meet consumer demand. Following the report of the Advisory Group (2001), the main drivers of public management in New Zealand have been reformulated to: focus on results; strengthen the integration of structures and processes; and demonstrate greater citizen and community orientation (Commonwealth Secretariat, 2003, p. 28). These changes indicate an emphasis on outcomes rather than outputs; fostering of co-operation, rather than competition within the public sector; and privileging democratic participation over purely technocratic decision-making (Norman, 2003, p. 214). These developments in public management, the ‘pushing back of the pendulum’ (Cullen, 2006a), are reflected in Dr Cullen’s proposals, but a tectonic ideological shift away from the market is also intended. 3. The Cullen model 3.1 Aims The essential goal of the Cullen model lies in ‘producing the quality graduates we need to drive economic transformation’. This goal is broadly supported. For example, Kerr (2006), representing a doctrinaire laissez faire viewpoint, observes that ‘It is hard to disagree with the objectives of the government’s announced changes. We all want a tertiary education system that is of a high quality, is flexible, and delivers skills that are relevant’. The difference between the two ideologies lies in how the goal should be achieved. 3.2 Underpinning ideology The Cullen model is founded on a communitarian conception of society, which is sceptical of individuals’ independent existence (Mulhall & Swift, 1995, p. 10). It seeks to reverse the individualist consumerism of neoliberalism. Thus, if neoliberalism constitutes a distribution mechanism, for which a common goal is D:\219552926.doc 2 absent (Barrett, 2006), the security state that the current government promotes is a distributive mechanism with a particular shared goal (Foucault, 1996, p. 100). The purpose lies in replacing the unplanned outcomes of the market with community agreed goals; a strategy to achieve ‘broad goals that are based on where we want our economy to develop, what social and cultural issues are emerging, and what is important for our sense of national identity’ (Cullen, 2006b). In theory, the community as a whole will decide which courses, and at which TEIs, potential students ought to study in order to promote the common good, rather the students themselves. Although Cullen (2006b) proposes ‘aiming for a better balance between the subjective choices of students and the priorities that emerge out of an objective analysis of where our economy and our society are heading’, it is evident that the ‘better balance’ is one in which the student is no longer considered the sovereign consumer. Indeed, given that ‘The needs of New Zealand industry, in terms of a more skilled workforce with the broader competencies that allow ongoing improvements in productivity, are a central concern in the reform process’ (Cullen, 2006c), it seems that the balance has radically shifted to the needs of the economy as identified by government. 4. Position of ITPs 4.1 Functions Cullen (2006d) advises that ITPs will have three roles, specifically: • To act as a regional facilitator; • To provide skills for employment and productivity; and • To provide foundation education - education rated levels 1 to 3 on the National Qualifications Framework (Ministry of Education, 2005). It is not obvious to what extent this represents a restatement of the status quo or a radical change. For example, regional ITPs are already deeply embedded in their communities and are bound by their charters to meet the needs of their particular communities (see, for example, NMIT, 2005). Although Cullen (2006d) includes questions and answers on what the proposals will mean for universities, wānanga, PTEs and industry training organisations, no similar guidance is given in respect of ITPs. 4.2 Funding TEIs ‘will be funded on the basis of three year plans outlining how they will meet the education and training needs of students, employers and communities’ (Cullen, 2006d). ITP managers are likely to embrace the concept of three-year funding plans but face considerable uncertainty about funding levels (Nielsen, 2006). 4.3 Courses Cullen (2006b) contends that one of the features of the ‘dark underbelly’ of the market model is that ‘record numbers of graduates with middling degrees in law, business and communication’ are being produced. Despite the likelihood that any such surplus of graduates in certain fields is attributable to a policy of preferring D:\219552926.doc 3 greater participation to elitist entry requirements, the statement implies a lack of confidence in certain degrees currently being offered by ITPs. It seems unlikely that ITPs will be denied the authority to confer degrees, but their degrees may no longer be considered equal to a university-conferred degree. The question posed in Cullen (2006d): “What about the idea of separating research from teaching?” and its answer, “Officials have been asked to provide advice on what needs to underpin high quality undergraduate degrees, offered by institutions other than universities” indicate that it is envisaged that teachers on ITP degrees will not be subject to similar research requirements as their peers teaching in universities. This may indicate that a national body, such as the New Zealand Qualifications Authority, will extend its quality assurance functions to a national bachelor of commerce, as an extension to the New Zealand Diploma in Business. It may also imply that ITPs will not be required or funded to conduct research. This would be highly detrimental for regional economies. 5. Critical analysis 5.1 High road or low road Adopting the ‘high road/low road’ model proposed by Sunter (1996), it is submitted that the tertiary education system that could eventuate from the proposals include a ‘high road’, which is broadly in line with Habermasian democratic discourse (see Habermas, 1996), and a ‘low road’, which may lead to sclerotic neo-Muldoonism (see Brash, 1996; Kerr, 2006). Under the high road scenario, government would act as an honest broker between various interest groups (students, TEIs, local communities, employers, as so forth), providing institutional and financial resources to encourage what Habermas (1987) identifies as ‘communicative action’. Each group would have a voice; interests, rights and reasonable expectations would be respected; and consensus goals arrived at through empathetic and rational argumentation. Consequently, students would participate in courses of study that further consensus goals. Government would facilitate communication amongst interested community members. Of course, it would also be the principal source of funding; provide expert information to help decisionmaking; and ensure quality assurance. On the low road, government would replace the student as the ‘sovereign consumer’ whose choices must be satisfied by TEIs. In this schema, as the principal source of funding for TEIs, government would behave as a monopsonist, using its market power to shape the courses TEIs provide. In this regard, Cullen (2006d) advises that TEIs ‘will not be funded’ unless certain conditions are met, and ‘where agreement cannot be reached over the plan the TEC will have the final say over the level of funding’. Community participation in formulating goals would be superficial. While all those involved in tertiary education will hope that the proposals will lead to the high road, there are reasons to be concerned that the reforms will lead toward the low road. D:\219552926.doc 4 5.2 The position of students The market model for tertiary education has been subject to trenchant criticism from pedagogical commentators. According to Brookfield (2005, p. 25) education has become commodified, and changed from being thought of as a ‘transformative adult learning experience’ to being viewed ‘as the pursuit of a qualification that can be exchanged for higher salary and status’. Olssen (2002, p. 67) argues that the market has detrimentally ‘colonised’ TEIs, and that neoliberalism ‘effects an increase in control’, engendering docility rather than autonomy. Generally, the market model is problematic when applied to teaching, and may lead to ‘unconscionable bargains’ being made with students, particularly international students (Barrett, 2006). In this light, a model for tertiary education that moves away from the market may be expected to be preferable from a pedagogical perspective. But, whereas the market model focuses on the exchange, rather than the use value of education (Brookfield, 2005, p. 24), the Cullen model comparably seeks to instrumentalise tertiary education. The experience and ontological growth inherent in education is not considered an end in itself; rather education is only valuable when it clearly leads to an economically productive result. From a classical pedagogical perspective, a model that conceives of education as a mere instrument may be as equally undesirable as one that imagines education as a commodity. Contemplating tertiary education under the conditions of neoliberalism, Clear (2002, p. 19) observes that ‘Generating docile labour units to participate in today’s jobs…will do little to address the broader needs of society.’ This observation may equally apply to instrumental education under the Cullen model. In sum, whereas the role of neoliberalism in education may be characterised as moulding students as uncritical entrepreneurs (Fitzsimons, 2002), the Cullen model may be viewed as conceiving students as future factors of production. And both systems may usurp the possibility of self-discovery and growth toward autonomy that is traditionally expected of learning at a tertiary level (see Hinchcliff, 1997, pp. 183 – 186 on the purposes of learning). For TEIs, which will be funded in part on the basis of student success, students may become seen as ‘cases’, analogous to subjects of health and correctional services, rather than participants in their own development as autonomous citizens. Many TEIs have relied on the contribution of international students to maintain financial viability and, indeed, cultural richness. But engagement with international students, which has been ethically fraught under the conditions of commercialised tertiary education (Barrett, 2004), may become more problematic still under the Cullen model. Under the market model, the essential difference between domestic and international students was the source of funding i.e. all students could be considered equal but some were subsidised by the New Zealand government. Commercialised TEIs tend to be open and outward looking, consonant with an individualist, globalised worldview. Conversely, communitarianism is inherently inward looking and exclusionary (Waltzer, 1984, p. 200). Consequently, the apparent absence of consideration of international students in the formulation of the communitarian Cullen model is disturbing. D:\219552926.doc 5 5.3 Potential for institutional resistance While outcomes seem preferable to outputs as a subject of audit, they are difficult to measure. Indeed, it is arguable that an outcome is simply an aggregate of outputs requiring multiple measurements. It seems most likely that the Cullen model will result in an expansion of the audit culture and compliance obligations. In this regard, it is crucial to recognise that the structure of audits is not objective; audits only measure what technical experts consider worthy of measurement (Power & Laughlin, 1996). LaRocque (2006) notes the particular potential for ideological bias in quality assurance under the Cullen model. Furthermore, the structure of an audit establishes the terms for avoidance as much as it does the grounds for compliance. If TEIs are funded, in part, on the basis of the number of students they retain, the obvious response is to ensure that more students pass courses by lowering standards. Of course, quality assurance will seek to ensure this does not happen, but it is extremely difficult to prevent, say, coaching for assessments. Generally, the forms of recalcitrance and resistance to neoliberalism in education that Fitzsimons (2002) identifies, may apply mutatis mutandis to instrumental education. Autonomous responsibility in institutional management and teaching lies greatly beyond practicable audit yet is the key ingredient of educational excellence. 6. Conclusion It is trite that a modern tertiary education system must aspire to an efficient allocation of scarce resources; be subject to the quality assurance performed by trusted agencies; and meet society’s needs. Inevitably, government must play a significant role but the characteristics of the role are ideologically determined. Contemplating a pre-commercialised education system, Habermas (1987, p. 371) observed, ‘a judicialization and bureaucratization that penetrates deep into the teaching and learning process’. Theoretically, commercialisation could have liberated tertiary education from such bureaucratic control. But, as Olssen (2002) has shown, neoliberal influence on tertiary education has been synonymous with conformity and docility, rather than autonomy. Conversely, it is plausible to predict that the Cullen model may lead from NPM to NPB – a new pervasive bureaucracy. Perhaps when a future review of tertiary education is proposed it will be informed by the goal of fostering the autonomous responsibility of all participants, not the commodification or instrumentalisation of education. In the meantime, as LaRocque (2006) observes, those involved in tertiary education ‘need more autonomy, not more form filling or centralised plans and strategies’. D:\219552926.doc 6 References Advisory Group. (2001). Report of the Advisory Group on the review of the Centre. Wellington: State Services Commission. Baker, C.E. (1979). The ideology of the economic analysis of law. In A.T. Kronman & R.A. Posner (Eds.) The economics of contract law (pp. 233–239). Barrett, J. (2004). Respecting human dignity, rejecting “New Orientalism”. Paper presented at the 13th annual conference of the Australia New Zealand Education Law Association, Wellington. Barrett, J. (2006). Does neoliberal contractualism in tertiary education compromise professional ethics and personal integrity? Paper presented at the conference of the International Society for Legal Ethics, Auckland. Boston, J., Martin, J., Pallot, J., & Walsh, P. (Eds.). (1996). Public management: the New Zealand model. Auckland: Oxford University Press. Brash, D. (1996). New Zealand's remarkable reforms. The Fifth Hayek Memorial Lecture, Institute of International Affairs, London, June 4, 1996. Retrieved: December 20, 2005 from http://www.donbrash.com/Speeches/NZs_remarkable_reform.htm Brookfield, S.D. (2005). The power of critical theory for adult learning and teaching. Maidenhead: Open University Press. Clear, T. (2002). E-learning: A vehicle for e-transformation or Trojan horse for enterprise? International Journal on E-learning. October-December 2002. Commonwealth Secretariat. (2003). A profile of the public service of New Zealand: Current good practices and new developments in public service management. London: Commonwealth Secretariat. Cullen, M. (2006a). Ensuring quality and relevance in tertiary education. Press release. April 4, 2006. Cullen, M. (2006b). Speech to chancellors/Tertiary Advisory Monitoring Unit workshop. April 11, 2006. Cullen, M. (2006c). Speech to UCOL Faculty of Health, Science and Technology graduation ceremony. April 21, 2006. Cullen, M. (2006d). Key decisions to improve tertiary performance. Press release. July 27, 2006. Fitzsimons, P. (2002). Neoliberalism and education: the autonomous chooser. Radical pedagogy (4) Retrieved: October 16, 2005 from http://radicalpedagogy.icaap.org/content/issue4_2/04_fitzsimons.html Foucault, M. (1991). Governmentality. In G. Burchell, C. Gordon & P. Miller (Eds.) The Foucault effect: Studies in governmentality: with two lectures and an interview with Michel Foucault (pp. 87–104). Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Habermas, J. (1987). The theory of communicative action, volume two, lifeworld and system: Critique of functionalist reason. Boston, MA: Beacon Press. Habermas, J. (1996). Between facts and norms: Contributions to a discourse theory of law and democracy. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Hinchcliff, J. (1997). Values integrating education: an exploration of learning in New Zealand. Pukekohe: Mirilea Press. LaRocque, N. (2006, August 9). Bums on seats approach flawed. Dominion Post, p. B7. McKinnon, M. (2003). Treasury: the New Zealand Treasury 1840–2000. Auckland: Auckland University Press. Kerr, R. (2006). Tertiary education: Who knows best? OpEd 99 May 2006. Retrieved: July 31, 2006 from http://www.educationforum.org.nz/documents/articles/issue99.pdf Ministry of Education. (1998). A future tertiary education policy for New Zealand: Tertiary education review green paper. Retrieved: July 31, 2006 from http://www.minedu.govt.nz/index.cfm?layout=document&documentid=4710&CFID=24521 58&CFTOKEN=29197376 D:\219552926.doc 7 Ministry of Education. (2005). Profiles and trends 2004: New Zealand’s tertiary education sector. Wellington: Tertiary Sector Performance Analysis and Reporting, Ministry of Education. Mulhall, S., & Swift, A. (1995). Liberals and communitarians. Oxford: Blackwell. Nelson Marlborough Institute of Technology (NMIT). (2005). NMIT charter and profile 2003-2006, reviewed 2005. Nelson: Nelson Marlborough Institute of Technology. Nielsen, D. (2006, August 2). Funding reforms put NMIT under pressure. Nelson Mail. Norman, R. (2003). Obedient public servants? Management freedoms and accountabilities in the New Zealand public sector. Wellington: Victoria University Press. Olssen, M. (2002). The restructuring of tertiary education in New Zealand: Governmentality, neo-liberalism, democracy. McGill Journal of Education 37 (1), 57–87. Power, M., & Laughlin, R. (1996). Habermas, law and accounting. Accounting Organizations and Society 21 (5), 441–465. Sunter, C. 1996. The high road: Where are we now? Cape Town: Tafelberg. Waltzer, M. (1984). Welfare, membership and need. In M.J. Sandel (Ed.) Liberalism and its critics (pp. 200–218). Oxford: Basil Blackwell. D:\219552926.doc 8