Competition and Innovation: An Inverted U Relationship Presentation to HM Treasury May 2004 Philippe Aghion (Harvard & UCL) Nick Bloom (CEP, LSE) Richard Blundell (IFS & UCL) Rachel Griffith (IFS & UCL) Peter Howitt (Brown) Contact Details: n.bloom@lse.ac.uk; 020 7955 7286 1 Evidence from conventional wisdom, theory and empirics on the impact of competition appears contradictory • Conventional wisdom provides mixed views “Schumpeterian effect” – the carrot: “....anti-trust discourages innovation.......” (Bill Gates and lawyers, frequently) “Competition effect” – the stick: “... from Adam Smith to Richard Caves: the belief that competition is good, rests on the idea that competition exerts downward pressure on costs, reduces slack and provides incentives for efficient production...” (Nickell, 1996) • Economic theory often supports the Schumpeterian effect • But the empirical evidence in mixed – Early studies in 1940s/50s found a negative “Schumpeterian” relationship – Scherer (1965) found a mixed relationship with an inverted-U form – Recent work focusing on linear effects find a positive relationship: Geroski (1995), Nickell (1996) and Blundell, Griffith and Van Reenen (1999) 2 Empirical results Model Policy implications 3 Basic Relationship Appears to be an Inverted-U • Using UK data (details to come) we estimate a flexible Kernel estimator (a local ‘moving average’) and find an inverted-U in the raw data • Firms are quite evenly distributed across the up, flat and down parts of the curve, so linear estimation would beregression, misleadingbw = .025, k = 6 Kernel x=(1-Lerner), y=CW Patents Peak occurs around high 10 0.85 – i.e. 15% price cost mark-up 8 Patents 6 4 2 low .83 low .85 .87 .91 .89 Grid points .93 Kernel with Gaussian weights Competition .95 high 4 Measure innovation using patents from US PTO • UK firm level accounting data 1968-94 cover all stock market firms • Measure innovation by matching to US Patent Office data – Choose US data as easily available electronically from 1968-1999 and PTO where all major international inventions are patented – Hand matched patents to UK firms so includes overseas subsidiaries – Weighted patents by citations received to measure innovation “quality” – Also confirm results using an alternative R&D measure of innovation • Final Data set has – 330 firms, 4500 observations, 60,000 patents, 200,000 citations • Bloom and Van Reenen (2001, EJ) use this data set and demonstrated patents play a powerful role determining market value and productivity of UK firms 5 Measure Competition Using Lerner “Profit Index” • Traditional measures based on market share – But problem defining the product & location market, particularly in open economies – For the UK international markets important – i.e. Glaxo has 10% UK NHS market but 70% “market” defined by sales of UK listed firms • So we use the Lerner Index and assume MC AC P MC P Q TC P AC P PQ P • Mean of value of the Lerner is around 0.1, minimum is 0.21 and maximum is 0.02 6 Confirm this inverted-U shape is robust by re-estimating quadratic model with industry and time controls • Kernel moving average data descriptive but can not control for different industry and time effects • So use an exponential `Poisson style’ model because patent counts are skewed with many zeros, taking a quadratic form and control for industry and time effects • Again find strong inverted U-relationship which is significantly different from a linear specification 7 Exponential quadratic with year and industry dummies Peak occurs around 0.88 – i.e. 12% price cost mark-up, and in middle of the data high Each point is an industry year observation, indicating most industries are clustered around the peak innovation level Patents Estimating a straight line predicts a positive impact in line with Nickell Outer feint lines provide the point-wise 95% confidence interval low low high Competition 8 Finally need to check cause and effect • Competition drives innovation but the reverse is also true, typically higher innovation acts to reduce competition, i.e. • Innovative firms obtain patents and reduce competition • Firstly, we include time and industry dummies to remove much of the spurious correlation between competition and innovation • Secondly, we instrument changes in competition using the large number of competition changes that have occurred in the UK since 1970: • The 1992 EU single market program • Thatcher and Major era privatisations • Remedies imposed on industries by MMC • Policy instruments have a significant negative impact on our Lerner measure 9 After identifying causal impact still find inverted-U shape, but shifted rightwards as would expect Controlling for cause and effect shifts the peak to around 0.95 – i.e. 5% price cost mark-up, and at the upper end of the data high Patents low low high Competition 10 Empirical results Model Policy implications 11 In the paper we model competition and Schumpeterian effects, which together generate an inverted-U shape • In our model: – At low levels of competition the “competition effect” dominates leading to a positive relationship – At high levels of competition the “Schumpeterian effect” dominates leading to a negative effect – Overall obtain a balanced inverted U-shape high Innovation low low high Competition 12 There are other potential explanations for the inverted-U • For example, managerial effort versus cash-flow – At low level of competition the principal-agent problem of motivating managers is paramount so higher competition helps innovation – At high level of competition managers work harder but as competition increases further firms lack finance for innovation high Positive management effort effects dominate Negative cash flow effects dominate Innovation low low Competition high 13 Empirical results Model Policy implications 14 Competition has other positive welfare effects (2) Competition may also improves productivity by forcing more rapid adoption of innovations – the “McKinsey” hypothesis Welfare high (3) Higher competition also reduces monopoly pricing deadweight loss, directly improving consumer welfare (1) Baseline relationship between competition and innovation low low high Competition 15 So overall higher Competition likely to be positive, particularly in low-competition industries • In industries with low or moderate levels of competition increasing competition is unambiguously good • U-shape suggests greatest gain from focusing on industries with lowest levels of competition • At higher levels of competition policy less obvious – results suggests reducing competition may promote innovation – But competition has other positive effects and so probably always beneficial • Low or moderate competition could indicated by high average industry price-cost mark-ups 16