The statistical distribution of incurred losses and its evolution over time III: dynamic models Greg Taylor November 2000 Casualty Actuarial Society i Table of Contents 1. Introduction .............................................................................................................. 1 2. The parametric framework ..................................................................................... 3 3. Kalman filter............................................................................................................. 7 4. Evolutionary model with unknown second moments ........................................... 9 5. Estimation of second moments .............................................................................. 11 6. Prediction and prediction error ............................................................................ 17 7. Numerical example................................................................................................. 19 8. Acknowledgements ................................................................................................. 35 9. References ............................................................................................................... 36 Appendices A Covariance of prediction errors B Covariance of squared prediction errors d:\219548251.doc 26/07/2016 5:19 AM Casualty Actuarial Society 1. 1 Introduction This paper is written at the request of, and is partly funded by, the Casualty Actuarial Society’s Committee on Theory of Risk. It is the third of a trio of papers whose purpose is to answer the following question, posed by the Committee: Assume you know the aggregate loss distribution at policy inception and you have expected patterns of claims reporting, losses emerging and losses paid and other pertinent information, how do you modify the distribution as the policy matures and more information becomes available? Actuaries have historically dealt with the problem of modifying the expectation conditional on emerged information. This expands the problem to continuously modifying the whole distribution from inception until it decays to a point. One might expect that there are at least two separate states that are important. There is the exposure state. It is during this period that claims can attach to the policy. Once this period is over no new claims can attach. The second state is the discovery or development state. In this state claims that already attached to the policy can become known and their value can begin developing. These two states may have to be treated separately. In general terms, this brief requires the extension of conventional point estimation of incurred losses to their companion distributions. Specifically, the evolution of this distribution over time is required as the relevant period of origin matures. Expressed in this way, the problem takes on a natural Bayesian form. For any particular year of origin (the generic name for an accident year, underwriting year, etc), one begins with a prior distribution of incurred losses, which applies in advance of data collection. As the period of origin develops, loss data accumulate, and may be used for progressive Bayesian revision of the prior. When the period of origin is fully mature, the amount of incurred losses is known with certainty. The Bayesian revision of the prior is then a single point distribution. The present paper addresses the question of how the Bayesian revision of the prior evolves over time from the prior itself to the final degenerate distribution. This evolution can take two distinct forms. On the one hand, one may impose no restrictions on the posterior distributions arising from the Bayesian revisions. These posterior distributions will depend on the empirical distributions of certain observations. Such models are non-parametric. Alternatively, the posterior distributions may be assumed to come from some defined family. For example, it may be assumed that the posterior-to-data distribution of incurred losses, as assessed at a particular point of development of the period of origin, is log normal. Any estimation questions must relate to the parameters which define the distribution within the chosen family. d:\219548251.doc 26/07/2016 5:19 AM Casualty Actuarial Society 2 These are parametric models. They are, in certain respects, more flexible than non-parametric, but lead to quite different estimation procedures. The first paper (Taylor 1999a) dealt with non-parametric models only. The second (Taylor 1999b) dealt with parametric models. The present paper addresses the case of dynamic models, in which parameters are allowed to evolve from one period of origin to the next. Familiarity with the earlier papers will be assumed here. In particular, the Bayesian background introduced and described there will be assumed. As far as possible, the notation used here will be common with the earlier papers. d:\219548251.doc 26-07-16 5:19 AM Casualty Actuarial Society 3 2. The parametric framework 2.1 Basic framework Let X(i, j) denote some real valued stochastic variable that is indexed by year of origin i and development year j, i 0, 0 j J for fixed J > 0. Note that i + j labels a particular year of calendar time (experience year), and the data for the year k = i + j constitute the vector: X k , 0 , X k 1,1 ,..., X 0, k , T (2.1) which will be denoted X(k). For brevity, the whole discussion here is formulated in terms of years. However, any other period, consistently replacing years, would be equally satisfactory. Let X h denote the data triangle: X h X i, j : i 0,0 j J ,0 i j h h X k . (2.2) k 0 Generally, the use of the prime, as in (2.2), will indicate the incorporation of all past experience years in the associated quantity. Equation (2.2) shows that the data triangle grows over time by the addition of diagonals. Denote i, j E X i , j , (2.3) and suppose the X i, j | i, j form a mutually stochastically independent set. In this set-up, X i, j corresponds to one component of the vector Y i, j , and i, j to one component of the vector i, j , in the second of the earlier papers. Just as the X i, j were represented in diagonals (see (2.1)), so may the i, j be represented. Thus k k , 0 , k 1,1 ,..., 0, k . T d:\219548251.doc 26-07-16 5:19 AM (2.4) Casualty Actuarial Society 2.2 4 Parameters linking development years Section 8 of the paper on parametric models represented parameters j ( depended only j there) in terms of basis functions, weighted by a smaller set of underlying parameters, as follows: Q j qq j , (2.5) q 1 where q were the pre-defined basis functions, and the q constants requiring estimation. More precisely, j in the earlier paper was a vector, each component having the representation (2.5). This representation is extended in the present paper to the i, j , which depend on both i and j: Q i, j q i q j . (2.6) q 1 Note that the basis functions have not been changed, and still depend only on j. However, their coefficients now vary with i, creating variation in with i. It is convenient to express (2.6) and related formulas in matrix form: i, j U T j 1x Q i (2.7) Q x1 where matrix and vector dimensions are optionally written below their associated symbols, and U T j 1 j ,..., Q j (2.8) T i 1 i ,..., Q i . (2.9) It is now possible to represent the vector E X k in the form: k E X k C k k , k 1 x k 1Q k 1Q x1 where d:\219548251.doc 26-07-16 5:19 AM (2.10) Casualty Actuarial Society 5 C k diag U T 0 ,U T 1 ,...U T k U T 0 1x Q U T 1 1x Q T U k 1x Q k T k , T k 1 ,..., T 0 . T 2.3 (2.11) (2.12) Evolution of parameters In the previous two papers, all parameters such as i have been assumed constant over time. For the dynamic models that form the subject of the present paper, these parameters are assumed to evolve from one year of origin to the next, as follows: i G i i 1 v i , (2.13) where G i is a deterministic Q x Q matrix and v i is a stochastic Q-vector with E v i 0 (2.14) V v i V i . (2.15) From (2.12) and (2.13), k evolves over k as follows: k G k k 1Q x1 k 1 v k k 1Q x kQ kQ x1 k 1Q x1 (2.16) with G k 1 1 G k , 1 (2.17) each submatrix here of order Q x Q and v k vT k , 0 . T d:\219548251.doc 26-07-16 5:19 AM (2.18) Casualty Actuarial Society 6 Substitution of (2.14) and (2.15) into (2.18) yields E v k 0 (2.19) V k 0 V v k , 0 0 (2.20) denoted V k . Now recall (2.10), but expressed in the form: X k C k k 1 x1 k 1 x k 1Q k w k k 1Q x1 k 1 x1 (2.21) with E w k 0. (2.22) In addition, denote W k V w k V X k | k . (2.23) The v i and w k are assumed mutually stochastically independent. The structure described by (2.16) and (2.21) may be recognised as the Kalman filter structure (Kalman, 1960). d:\219548251.doc 26-07-16 5:19 AM Casualty Actuarial Society 3. 7 Kalman filter Consider the forecast of a new diagonal X k 1 from data X k . Let Xˆ k 1 denote the forecast, and suppose that it must satisfy two conditions: (i) (ii) it must be linear in the data; and it must be least squares in the sense that 2 E Xˆ k 1 X k 1 is a minimum within the admissible forecasts, where the expectation is unconditional. These two conditions correspond to (4.8) and (4.9) in the previous paper (Taylor 1999b). The forecasts Xˆ k 1 , k = 0, 1, 2, etc may be calculated according to the Kalman filter recursion (Kalman, 1960), as follows: ˆ h 1| h G h 1 ˆ h | h (3.1) h 1| h V h 1 G h 1 h | h GT h 1 (3.2) Xˆ h 1| h C h 1 ˆ h 1| h (3.3) L h 1| h W h 1 C h 1 h 1| h CT h 1 (3.4) K h 1 h 1| h CT h 1 L1 h 1| h (3.5) ˆ h 1| h 1 ˆ h 1| h K h 1 X h 1 Xˆ h 1| h (3.6) h 1| h 1 1 K h 1 C h 1 h 1| h . (3.7) The recursion is initiated at h = -1 in (3.3) and (3.4) with given values ˆ 0 | 1 and 0 | 1 , which are the prior-to-data estimates of 0 and its uncertainty V v 0 . The recursion then proceeds through (3.3) – (3.7), and then cycles through (3.1) – (3.7) with increasing h. Throughout this recursive scheme, a symbol of the form Q h2 | h1 represents an estimate of quantity Q h2 at time h2 on the basis of data up to and including time h1 . Thus, (3.3) with h = k is the estimator sought in the present case, and (3.4) its covariance matrix. d:\219548251.doc 26-07-16 5:19 AM Casualty Actuarial Society 8 Equation (3.6) indicates how the parameter estimate ˆ is affected by new data X. It is seen that the previous estimate ˆ is adjusted by a multiple (in fact, a matrix multiple) of its associated prediction error. Thus, as data emerge and reveal errors in earlier predictions, the filter corrects for them in its subsequent predictions. The matrix K is called the Kalman gain matrix. A very useful dissertation on the Kalman filter is given by Neuhaus (1989), where it is noted that L h 1| h V X h 1 Xˆ h 1| h (3.8) h2 | h1 V h2 ˆ h2 | h1 , (3.9) for h2 h1 or h1 1 . Note also that, by (3.1), E ˆ h 1| h G h 1 E ˆ h | h G h 1 h (3.10) if ˆ h | h is an unbiased estimator of h . Then, by (2.14) and (2.16), E ˆ h 1| h E h 1 . (3.11) Thus, unbiasedness of ˆ h | h as an estimator of h implies unbiasedness of ˆ h 1| h as an estimator of h 1 . Similarly, by (3.3), one can show that unbiasedness of ˆ h 1| h implies unbiasedness of Xˆ h 1| h as an estimator of X h 1 . Induction on h leads to the following result. Proposition 3.1 Suppose that ˆ 0 | 1 is an unbiased estimator of 0 . Then, for each h = 0, 1, etc, ˆ h 1| h is an unbiased estimator of h 1 Xˆ h 1| h is an unbiased estimator of X h 1 ˆ h 1| h 1 is an unbiased estimator of h 1 . d:\219548251.doc 26-07-16 5:19 AM Casualty Actuarial Society 4. 9 Evolutionary model with unknown second moments Section 2.3 described a model which incorporated parameter evolution. introduced the two sets of second order quantities V(i) and W(k). It These were regarded as known quantities. Consider, however, the case where they are unknown. In the simplest such case, they will involve just one unknown parameter, thus: V i V * i (4.1) QxQ W k W * k , (4.2) k 1 x k 1 where is the unknown scalar parameter, and V * i and W * k are known matrices. Generally, a starred symbol will represent the corresponding unstarred symbol after removal of the multiplier . Suppose in addition that the initial value 0 of the Kalman filter (Section 3) is subject to the uncertainty: 0 | 1 * 0 | 1 , (4.3) where * 0 | 1 is a known matrix, independent of . QxQ Proposition 4.1 When (4.1) – (4.3) hold, the quantities h2 | h1 , h2 h1 or h1 1, and L h 1| h in the Kalman filter are proportional to . Moreover, the Kalman gain matrices K(h) are independent of . This result is simply proved by reference to (3.2), (3.4), (3.5) and (3.7), and induction on h. As a consequence of the proposition, one may write h2 | h1 * h2 | h1 , h2 h1 or h1 1 L h 1| h L * h 1| h , (4.4) (4.5) where the starred quantities here may be obtained from a “starred recursion” corresponding to (3.1) – (3.7), but with (3.2), (3.4) and (3.7) replaced as follows: d:\219548251.doc 26-07-16 5:19 AM Casualty Actuarial Society 10 * h 1| h V * h 1 G h 1 * h | h GT h 1 (3.2a) L * h 1| h W * h 1 C h 1 * h 1| h CT h 1 (3.4a) * h 1| h 1 1 K h 1 C h 1 * h 1| h (3.7a) where V * h 0 V * h . 0 h 1Q x h 1Q 0 (2.20a) This recursion is initiated with given values of ˆ 0 | 1 and * 0 | 1 . By (3.8) and (4.5), V X h 1 Xˆ h 1| h L * h 1| h , (4.6) where L * h 1| h is a known matrix given by (3.4a). Write (4.6) as V h 1| h L * h 1| h (4.7) with h 1| h denoting the prediction error h 1| h X h 1 Xˆ h 1| h . (4.8) Then TrV h 1| h Tr L * h 1| h . (4.9) Recall from Proposition 3.1 that E h 1| h 0. (4.10) Hence T is an unbiased estimator of V . Then, by (4.9), an unbiased estimator of is ˆ h 1 Tr h 1| h T h 1| h / Tr L * h 1| h T h 1| h h 1| h / Tr L * h 1| h . d:\219548251.doc 26-07-16 5:19 AM (4.11) Casualty Actuarial Society 11 5. Estimation of second moments 5.1 Unbiased estimation When data X h 1 are available, (4.11) provides h + 2 unbiased estimators of , viz ˆ 0 , ˆ 1 ,..., ˆ h 1 . Then any convex combination of these estimators is itself an unbiased estimator. Proposition 5.1. Let ˆ h 1 ˆ 0 ,..., ˆ h 1 T (5.1) and R h 1 V ˆ h 1 . (5.2) Consider estimators of of the form ˆ h 1 aT h 1 ˆ h 1 , (5.3) where a(h + 1) is a non-stochastic (h + 2)-vector. The MVU estimator is given by a h 1 R 1 h 11/ 1T R 1 h 11 , (5.4) where 1 denotes a vector with all entries equal to unity. Moreover, for this a ( h + 1), ˆ h 1 1T R 1 h 11 1 . V (5.5) Proof The proof is an elementary and well-known exercise in constrained optimisation. Application of (5.3) and (5.4) requires a knowledge of R(h + 1). One requires quantities of the form Cov ˆ f 1 , ˆ g 1 Cov T f 1| f f 1| f , T g 1| g g 1| g / Tr L * f 1| f Tr L * g 1| g . (5.6) This last quantity involves covariances of second moments, i.e. involves fourth moments, of the observations. A practical estimate requires parametric assumptions, which enable the expression of fourth moments in terms of second. d:\219548251.doc 26-07-16 5:19 AM Casualty Actuarial Society 12 Appendices A and B calculate the covariance in (5.6) on the assumption that the observations X(i, j) are normally distributed. The relevant results obtained from there are as follows: Cov T f 1| f f 1| f , T g 1| g g 1| g 2 2 Tr M * f 1, g 1 M *T f 1, g 1 [from (B.18)] (5.7) where, by (A.25) and the comment at the end of Appendix A, M * h, g C h N * h, g CT g C h Q * h, g hgW * h (5.8) and N * h, g and Q * h, g are calculated by means of the following recursions (see (A.20) and (A.14)): N * h, g P h 1 N * h 1, g gh V h 1 G h K h 1W h 1 K T h 1 GT h for h g Q * h, g P h 1 Q * h 1, g for h g 1 (5.9) (5.10) with P h G h 1 1 K h C h [by (A.11)]. (5.11) The recursion for Q is initiated (see A.18)) by: Q * g 1, g G g 1 K g W * g . (5.12) Also Q * g , g 0. (5.13) The recursion for N* is initiated by N * g , g 1 , which is itself obtained from another recursion (see A.22) – (A.24)): N *T g , g 1 P g P g 1 N * g 1, g V * g 1 G g K g 1W * g 1 K T g 1 GT g (5.14) N * 0,1 * 0 | 1 PT 0 . (5.15) N * 0,0 * 0 | 1 [by (A.30)]. (5.16) By definition of M(f,g) in Appendix B, d:\219548251.doc 26-07-16 5:19 AM Casualty Actuarial Society 13 L f 1| f M f 1, f 1 and so L * f 1| f M * f 1, f 1 . (5.17) Substitute (5.7) and (5.17) into (5.6): Cov ˆ f , ˆ g 22Tr M * f , g M *T f , g / Tr M * f , f Tr M * g , g (5.18) for f, g = 0, 1, 2, …, h + 1. By definition (5.2), R(h + 1) has elements given by (5.18). They each involve the unknown factor 2 2 , but note that this cancels in (5.4). Therefore, (5.4) is equivalent to: 1 1 a h 1 R * h 1 1/ 1T R * h 1 1 (5.19) with R * h 1 having (f,g) element Tr M * f , g M *T f , g / Tr M * f , f Tr M * g , g . (5.20) ˆ h 1 is defined by (5.3) with a (h + 1) given by (5.19). Then the estimator By (5.5), (5.18) and the definition of R * h 1 , 1 ˆ h 1 22 1T R * h 1 1 1 . V 5.2 (5.21) Credibility estimation Now assume that the parameter is a latent parameter, i.e. it is a sampling from some prior distribution with d.f. F , mean and variance 2 . According to the credibility of the earlier papers, specifically Taylor (1999b, ˆ h is Section 4), the least squares estimate of that is linear in ˆ h h 1 z h z h (5.22) with z h 1 S h 1 ˆ h | / V E ˆ S h E V h | . d:\219548251.doc 26-07-16 5:19 AM (5.23) (5.24) Casualty Actuarial Society 14 By (5.21), ˆ h | 2 E 2 1T R * h 1 1 E V 1 1 1 2 2 2 1T R * h 1 . (5.25) ˆ h is an unbiased estimator of , Since ˆ h | V 2 . V E (5.26) Substitute (5.25) and (5.26) in (5.24): 1 1 S h 2 1 2 / 2 1T R * h 1 . (5.27) In the case h = -1 (no data), h is given by its prior: 1 . 5.3 (5.28) Summary of algorithm The complete algorithm incorporating the Kalman filter of Section 3, as modified by Section 4, and the present section’s estimation of second moments, is as follows. ˆ h 1| h G h 1 ˆ h | h (3.1) * h 1| h V * h 1 G h 1 * h | h GT h 1 (3.2a) h 1| h h * h 1| h (4.4) Xˆ h 1| h C h 1 ˆ h 1| h (3.3) L * h 1| h W * h 1 C h 1 * h 1| h CT h 1 (3.4a) ˆ h 1 X h 1 Xˆ h 1| h X h 1 Xˆ h 1| h / Tr L * h 1| h (4.11) T At this point, there follows an inner recursion to calculate the h 2 x h 2 matrix R(h + 1) (see below) 1 1 a h 1 R * h 1 1/ 1T R * h 1 1 d:\219548251.doc 26-07-16 5:19 AM (5.19) Casualty Actuarial Society 15 ˆ h 1 ˆ 0 ,..., ˆ h 1 T (5.1) ˆ h 1 aT h 1 ˆ h 1 1 S h 1 2 1 2 / 2 1T R * h 1 1 z h 1 1 S h 1 (5.3) 1 (5.27) 1 (5.23) ˆ h 1 h 1 1 z h 1 z h 1 (5.22) L h 1| h h 1 L * h 1| h K h 1 * h 1| h C T h 1 L * h 1| h (4.5) 1 ˆ h 1| h 1 ˆ h 1| h K h 1 X h 1 Xˆ h 1| h * h 1| h 1 1 K h 1 C h 1 * h 1| h h 1| h 1 h 1 * h 1| h 1 . (3.5) (3.6) (3.7a) (4.4) The recursion is initiated, as in Section 4, at h = -1 with given values of ˆ 0 | 1 and * 0 | 1 and with 1 . (5.28) It begins at (3.3), runs through to (4.4) with h = -1, then cycles through (3.1) – (4.4) with h = 0, 1, etc. The inner recursion, between steps (4.11) and (5.19), is as follows, where throughout P h G h 1 1 K h C h . (5.11) For each value of h in the outer recursion, calculate: Q * h 1, g P h Q * h, g g 0,1,..., h 1 (5.10) Q * h 1, h G h 1 K h W * h (5.12) Q * h 1, h 1 0 (5.13) d:\219548251.doc 26-07-16 5:19 AM Casualty Actuarial Society 16 N * h 1, g P h N * h, g h1, g V h G h 1 K h W h K T h GT h 1 g 0,1,..., h 1, h 0 (5.9) where, in the case g = h + 1, N * h, h 1 , is given by N *T h, h 1 P h P h 1 N * h, h 1 V * h 1 T G h K h 1W * h 1 K T h 1 GT h (5.14) M * h 1, g C h 1 N * h 1, g C T g C h 1 Q * h 1, g h 1, gW * h 1 g = 0, 1, …, h + 1 (5.8) Calculate R* (h + 1) as the symmetric matrix with (f, g) element Tr M * f , g M *T f , g / Tr M * f , f Tr M * g , g . This inner recursion calculates values of (5.20) Q * h 1, g , N * h 1, g , g 0,1,..., h 1 in terms of Q * h, g , N * h, g , g 0,1,..., h , all of which are calculated at previous iterations of the outer recursion. The first loop of the outer recursion, h = -1, requires the value of R(0), hence N * 0,0 and Q * 0,0 . These are given by Q * 0,0 0 (5.13) N * 0,0 * 0 | 1 . (5.16) The second loop of the outer recursion, h = 0, requires the value of R(1), hence N * 1,0 . This is given by N * 1,0 N *T 0,1 [by (A.6) and (A.28)] P 0 0 | 1 , (5.29) by (5.15). Note that the inner recursion calculating N * h 1, g and Q * h 1, g for g = 0, 1, …, h + 1 calls on just N * h, g and Q * h, g for g = 0, 1, …, h. Once the N * h 1, g and Q * h 1, g have been calculated, and are ready for use in the next iteration of recursion, the N * h, g and Q * h, g may be discarded. Note also that, at each iteration of the outer recursion, R(h + 1) is constructed by the augmentation of R(h) with an additional row and column. d:\219548251.doc 26-07-16 5:19 AM Casualty Actuarial Society 17 6. Prediction and prediction error 6.1 Prediction Predictors are given by Neuhaus (1989, Section 2.3). Define ˆ h | k G h ˆ h 1| k (6.1) whence ˆ h | k G h, k 2 ˆ k 1| k for h k 2 (6.2) with G h, k 2 G h G h 1 ...G k 2 . (6.3) Also define Xˆ h | k C h ˆ h | k . (6.4) Then Xˆ h | k is the Kalman filter’s unbiased estimate of X(h) based on data up to and including experience year k. 6.2 Prediction error The same section of Neuhaus (1989) gives: h 1| k V h 1 G h 1 h | k GT h 1 (6.5) where h | k denotes MSEP ˆ h | k . This provides a recursion by which k 2 | k , k 3| k , etc can be calculated starting from k 1| k given by (4.4). Also L h | k W h C h h | k CT h (6.6) where L h | k denotes MSEP Xˆ h | k . Equation (6.6) gives MSEP for each future experience year h. It is also possible to obtain prediction covariances across different future years from Neuhaus (1989, Section 2.2). Define d:\219548251.doc 26-07-16 5:19 AM Casualty Actuarial Society h1 , h2 | k E h1 ˆ h1 | k h2 ˆ h2 | k 18 T (6.7) L h1 , h2 | k E X h1 Xˆ h1 | k X h2 Xˆ h2 | k . T (6.8) Note that h, h | k h | k (6.9) L h, h | k L h | k . (6.10) From Neuhaus, h1 , h2 | k G h1 , h2 1 h2 | k (6.11) L h1 , h2 | k C h1 h1 , h2 | k C T h2 (6.12) for h1 h2 k . Note that h1 , h2 | k and L h1 , h2 | k are given for the case h2 h1 k by h1 , h2 | k T h2 , h1 | k (6.13) L h1 , h2 | k LT h2 , h1 | k . (6.14) d:\219548251.doc 26-07-16 5:19 AM Casualty Actuarial Society 7. 19 Numerical example The present section will illustrate the results of Section 5 by reference to the same real data set as used in the earlier papers. The data appeared in the form of incurred losses, adjusted to constant dollar values for inflation, in Table 7.1 of Paper II. They were converted to logged age-to-age factors in Table 7.2 of the same paper. These tables are repeated as Tables 7.1 and 7.2 below. d:\219548251.doc 26-07-16 5:19 AM Casualty Actuarial Society Table 7.1 20 Incurred Losses Period Incurred losses to end of development year n= of origin 0 $000 1 $000 2 $000 3 $000 4 $000 5 $000 6 $000 7 $000 8 $000 9 $000 10 $000 11 $000 12 $000 13 $000 14 $000 15 $000 16 $000 17 $000 1978 9,268 18,263 20,182 22,383 22,782 26,348 26,172 26,184 25,455 25,740 25,711 25,452 25,460 25,422 25,386 25,520 25,646 25,469 1979 9,848 16,123 17,099 18,544 20,534 21,554 23,219 22,381 21,584 21,408 20,857 21,163 20,482 19,971 19,958 19,947 19,991 1980 13,990 22,484 24,950 33,255 33,295 34,308 34,022 34,023 33,842 33,933 33,570 31,881 32,203 32,345 32,250 32,168 1981 16,550 28,056 39,995 42,459 42,797 42,755 42,435 42,302 42,095 41,606 40,440 40,432 40,326 40,337 40,096 1982 11,100 31,620 40,852 38,831 39,516 39,870 40,358 40,355 40,116 39,888 39,898 40,147 39,827 40,200 1983 15,677 33,074 35,592 35,721 38,652 39,418 39,223 39,696 37,769 37,894 37,369 37,345 37,075 1984 20,375 33,555 41,756 45,125 47,284 51,710 52,147 51,187 51,950 50,967 51,461 51,382 1985 9,800 1986 11,380 26,843 34,931 37,805 41,277 44,901 45,867 45,404 45,347 44,383 1987 10,226 20,511 26,882 32,326 35,257 40,557 43,753 44,609 44,196 1988 8,170 1989 10,433 19,484 32,103 38,936 45,851 45,133 45,501 1990 9,661 1991 14,275 25,551 33,754 38,674 41,132 1992 13,245 29,206 36,987 44,075 1993 14,711 27,082 34,230 1994 12,476 23,126 1995 9,715 d:\219548251.doc 24,663 36,061 37,927 40,042 40,562 40,362 40,884 40,597 41,304 42,378 18,567 26,472 33,002 36,321 37,047 39,675 40,398 23,808 32,966 42,907 46,930 49,300 26/07/2016 5:19 AM Casualty Actuarial Society Table 7.2 21 Logged incurred loss age to age factors Period of origin 0 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 0.678 0.493 0.474 0.528 1.047 0.747 0.499 0.923 0.858 0.696 0.821 0.625 0.902 0.582 0.791 0.610 0.617 1 0.100 0.059 0.104 0.355 0.256 0.073 0.219 0.380 0.263 0.270 0.355 0.499 0.325 0.278 0.236 0.234 2 0.104 0.081 0.287 0.060 -0.051 0.004 0.078 0.050 0.079 0.184 0.220 0.193 0.264 0.136 0.175 Logged age to age factor from development year n to n+1 development year n= 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 3 0.018 0.102 0.001 0.008 0.017 0.079 0.047 0.054 0.088 0.087 0.096 0.163 0.090 0.062 0.145 0.048 0.030 -0.001 0.009 0.020 0.089 0.013 0.084 0.140 0.020 -0.016 0.049 -0.007 0.074 -0.008 -0.008 0.012 -0.005 0.008 -0.005 0.021 0.076 0.069 0.008 0.000 -0.037 0.000 -0.003 -0.000 0.012 -0.019 0.013 -0.010 0.019 0.018 -0.028 -0.036 -0.005 -0.005 -0.006 -0.050 0.015 -0.007 -0.001 -0.009 0.011 -0.008 0.003 -0.012 -0.006 0.003 -0.019 0.017 -0.022 -0.001 -0.026 -0.011 -0.028 0.000 -0.014 0.010 0.026 -0.010 0.015 -0.052 -0.000 0.006 -0.001 -0.002 0.000 -0.033 0.010 -0.003 -0.008 -0.007 12 -0.001 -0.025 0.004 0.000 0.009 13 14 15 16 -0.001 0.005 0.005 -0.007 -0.001 -0.001 0.002 -0.003 -0.003 -0.006 Average 0.699 0.250 0.124 0.065 0.049 0.020 -0.001 -0.013 -0.004 -0.006 -0.006 -0.007 -0.003 -0.003 0.001 0.004 -0.007 Standard deviation 0.169 0.121 0.095 0.045 0.052 0.033 0.017 0.004 0.002 d:\219548251.doc 26-07-16 5:19 AM 0.019 0.013 0.018 0.021 0.014 0.013 0.002 Casualty Actuarial Society 22 As in the example of Section 8.3 of Paper II (see (8.38)), it is assumed that (2.6) takes the form: i, j 1 i j 1 2 i j 1 2 3 (7.1) ie in (2.11), 2 3 U T j j 1 , j 1 . (7.2) Consistently with (8.39) in Paper II, it is assumed that V X i, j | i x 0.8 2j (7.3) ie in (2.23) 2 2k W k diag 1, 0.8 ,..., 0.8 (7.4) ie 2 2k W * k diag 1, 0.8 ,..., 0.8 . (7.5) The evolution of parameters (see (2.13), (2.16) and (2.20)) will be assumed subject to the following G i 1 (7.6) 2x 2 V i 12 1 (7.7) 2x 2 i.e. V * i 1 2 1. (7.8) 2x 2 The following parameters are assumed for : 0.5 x 0.19 , 2 2 0.01 . 2 (7.9) These parameters, together with (6.4), set the prior for W(k) as representing half the parameter variances assumed in the example of Paper II (see just after (8.55)). This allows for the parameter variance of the earlier paper to be only partly attributable to uncertainty in in the present case, and also partly attributable to evolutionary variation. In common with the same example in the earlier paper, the Kalman filter is initiated with d:\219548251.doc 26/07/2016 5:19 AM Casualty Actuarial Society 23 0.97 0 | 1 . 0.37 (7.10) It is assumed that * 0 | 1 1 . (7.11) 2x 2 Table 7.3 gives estimates Xˆ h 1| h from (3.3). These are used to develop estimates Xˆ h | k , h > k, from (6.4). Table 7.4 gives the associated standard 2 errors L jj h 1| h , where the subscript indicates the element of the covariance matrix. 1 d:\219548251.doc 26-07-16 5:19 AM Casualty Actuarial Society 24 Table 7.3 Filtered logged age to age factors Period of Origin 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 d:\219548251.doc 0 1 2 3 4 0.60000 0.65215 0.54568 0.49364 0.50990 0.85428 0.78785 0.59788 0.79870 0.84538 0.75509 0.79913 0.70136 0.84473 0.68892 0.75663 0.66637 0.63755 0.20603 0.18491 0.17317 0.17419 0.24854 0.23444 0.18884 0.21997 0.23262 0.21308 0.22108 0.21059 0.24790 0.22840 0.24864 0.22985 0.22212 0.09327 0.08576 0.08302 0.10139 0.11281 0.09710 0.09156 0.10559 0.10268 0.09980 0.10450 0.11139 0.11775 0.11679 0.11569 0.10953 0.05341 0.04960 0.05477 0.05784 0.05977 0.05438 0.05423 0.05866 0.05867 0.05960 0.06487 0.06727 0.07192 0.06715 0.06673 0.03453 0.03503 0.03530 0.03542 0.03725 0.03586 0.03433 0.03775 0.03932 0.04069 0.04417 0.04578 0.04633 0.04325 26/07/2016 5:19 AM Logged age to age factor from development year n to n+1, filtered on data up to preceding experience year, for n = 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 0.02552 0.02444 0.02375 0.02383 0.02625 0.02454 0.02393 0.02714 0.02843 0.02993 0.03197 0.03175 0.03199 0.01877 0.01760 0.01689 0.01769 0.01898 0.01792 0.01813 0.02032 0.02182 0.02271 0.02340 0.02302 0.01417 0.01308 0.01300 0.01332 0.01437 0.01401 0.01391 0.01611 0.01702 0.01724 0.01759 0.01096 0.01034 0.01011 0.01038 0.01149 0.01090 0.01133 0.01285 0.01328 0.01329 0.00889 0.00826 0.00806 0.00848 0.00907 0.00901 0.00920 0.01026 0.01045 0.00728 0.00670 0.00670 0.00674 0.00758 0.00743 0.00746 0.00824 0.00604 0.00567 0.00536 0.00569 0.00635 0.00610 0.00605 0.00516 0.00462 0.00456 0.00482 0.00528 0.00500 13 0.00433 0.00392 0.00391 0.00405 0.00438 14 15 0.00374 0.00328 0.00340 0.00294 0.00333 0.00279 0.00337 16 17 0.00288 0.00248 0.00250 Casualty Actuarial Society 25 Table 7.4 Standard errors of filtered logged age to age factors Period of Origin 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 0 1 2 3 0.22159 0.20329 0.19124 0.17740 0.25712 0.23260 0.24359 0.24657 0.23627 0.22825 0.21964 0.21787 0.22633 0.22605 0.22224 0.21743 0.21162 0.21162 0.10199 0.09691 0.09022 0.13110 0.11886 0.12473 0.12647 0.12136 0.11739 0.11307 0.11226 0.11669 0.11661 0.11469 0.11224 0.10927 0.10929 0.07608 0.07074 0.10269 0.09301 0.09752 0.09881 0.09476 0.09160 0.08820 0.08753 0.09096 0.09088 0.08937 0.08745 0.08512 0.08513 0.05635 0.08174 0.07401 0.07756 0.07856 0.07531 0.07279 0.07007 0.06952 0.07224 0.07217 0.07096 0.06943 0.06758 0.06759 d:\219548251.doc 26-07-16 5:19 AM Standard error of filtered logged age to age factor from development year n to n+1, filtered on data up to preceding experience year 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 0.06527 0.05908 0.06190 0.06269 0.06009 0.05807 0.05590 0.05546 0.05762 0.05756 0.05660 0.05538 0.05390 0.05390 0.04721 0.04947 0.05009 0.04801 0.04640 0.04466 0.04431 0.04603 0.04598 0.04521 0.04424 0.04306 0.04306 0.03955 0.04004 0.03838 0.03709 0.03570 0.03542 0.03680 0.03676 0.03614 0.03536 0.03442 0.03442 0.03202 0.03069 0.02966 0.02855 0.02832 0.02943 0.02939 0.02890 0.02828 0.02752 0.02752 0.02454 0.02372 0.02283 0.02265 0.02353 0.02351 0.02312 0.02262 0.02201 0.02201 0.01897 0.01826 0.01812 0.01882 0.01880 0.01849 0.01809 0.01761 0.01761 0.01460 0.01449 0.01506 0.01504 0.01479 0.01447 0.01409 0.01409 0.01159 0.01205 0.01203 0.01183 0.01158 0.01127 0.01127 0.00963 0.00963 0.00947 0.00926 0.00902 0.00902 13 0.00770 0.00757 0.00741 0.00722 0.00722 14 15 16 17 0.00606 0.00474 0.00593 0.00462 0.00577 0.00462 0.00578 0.00370 0.00370 0.00296 Casualty Actuarial Society 26 Figure 7.1 illustrates the credibility smoothing of estimated , displaying the raw estimates from (5.3) and their smoothed versions according to (5.22). Figure 7.1 Credibility smoothing of theta 0.08 0.07 0.06 0.05 Theta 0.04 0.03 0.02 0.01 0.00 -5 0 5 10 15 20 Experience year Unsmoothed Smoothed Let Y(i) denote the vector of quantities X(i, j) relating to accident year i, ie Y T i X i, 0 , X i,1 ,..., X i, J . (7.12) Define an unbiased estimator Yˆ i | k of Y i based on data X k : Xˆ 0 i | i Xˆ 1 i 1| i 1 Yˆ i | k Xˆ k i k | k Xˆ k i 1 k 1| k Xˆ i J | k J (7.13) where Xˆ j h | k denotes the j-th component of vector Xˆ h | k , j = 0, 1, etc. Note that in (7.13) the first k – i + 2 components are obtained from the Kalman filter, whereas the last J – k + i – 1 are obtained from (6.2) and (6.4). The first k i 1 components are not used in the following. Adopt the convention in (7.13) that d:\219548251.doc 26/07/2016 5:19 AM Casualty Actuarial Society 27 Xˆ 0 i | i 1 ˆ i 1| i 1 X 1 Yˆ i | i 1 . Xˆ i J | i 1 Write i, k for the (J + 1)-vector: 1,...,1 0,..., 0, T i, k k i 1 terms J k i terms (7.14) and define R i | k T i, k Yˆ i | k . (7.15) In the present example, this is the logged age-to-ultimate factor for accident year i when data are available up to and including experience year k. The values of R(i|k) are displayed in Table 7.5. d:\219548251.doc 26-07-16 5:19 AM Casualty Actuarial Society 28 Table 7.5 Filtered logged age to ultimate factors Period of Origin 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 d:\219548251.doc 0 1 2 3 4 1.09826 1.11100 0.99314 0.96688 1.08274 1.38609 1.26782 1.14576 1.36463 1.39586 1.33365 1.37866 1.33344 1.44233 1.30705 1.34438 1.25411 1.20673 0.51657 0.47102 0.44436 0.44450 0.61052 0.57923 0.47346 0.53236 0.56284 0.51918 0.53572 0.52152 0.61032 0.57903 0.62910 0.58775 0.56918 0.29701 0.27516 0.26663 0.32224 0.35335 0.30508 0.28672 0.32759 0.31830 0.31014 0.32678 0.35062 0.37271 0.37340 0.36949 0.35129 0.20026 0.18680 0.20632 0.21654 0.22097 0.20090 0.20114 0.21573 0.21567 0.22054 0.24068 0.25138 0.26897 0.25240 0.25041 0.14528 0.14799 0.14904 0.14857 0.15467 0.14940 0.14318 0.15650 0.16346 0.16991 0.18496 0.19243 0.19451 0.18218 26/07/2016 5:19 AM Filtered logged age to ultimate factor from development year n, filtered on data up to that experience year, for 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 0.11636 0.11171 0.10835 0.10816 0.11847 0.11089 0.10827 0.12248 0.12851 0.13585 0.14534 0.14450 0.14544 0.09004 0.08452 0.08100 0.08457 0.09025 0.08532 0.08652 0.09676 0.10414 0.10864 0.11197 0.11021 0.06973 0.06441 0.06401 0.06537 0.07023 0.06863 0.06823 0.07892 0.08351 0.08469 0.08635 0.05407 0.05105 0.04990 0.05111 0.05643 0.05361 0.05579 0.06323 0.06538 0.06546 0.04300 0.03996 0.03901 0.04095 0.04373 0.04347 0.04446 0.04950 0.05043 0.03369 0.03102 0.03102 0.03113 0.03497 0.03432 0.03451 0.03803 0.02599 0.02441 0.02306 0.02446 0.02728 0.02623 0.02602 12 13 14 15 16 17 0.01997 0.01786 0.01763 0.01865 0.02038 0.01931 0.01438 0.01304 0.01300 0.01345 0.01454 0.00994 0.00906 0.00885 0.00898 0.00619 0.00554 0.00527 0.00288 0.00250 0.00000 Casualty Actuarial Society 29 The MSEP of the R(i|k) may also be estimated. By (7.15), MSEP R i | k T i, k MSEP Yˆ i | k i, k . (7.16) Because of the positioning of the zeros in i, k , only the bottom right J k i x J k i sub-matrix of MSEP Yˆ i | k is required. A typical element of this sub-matrix is E X i, h1 i Xˆ h1 i h1 | k X i, h2 i Xˆ h2 i h2 | k , h1 , h2 k 1, k 2,..., i J (7.17) which is equal to the h1 i, h2 i element of L h1 , h2 | k from (6.8). That is, MSEPh1 i ,h2 i Yˆ i | k Lh1 i ,h2 i h1 , h2 | k (7.18) for h1 , h2 = k + 1, …, i + J. Equivalently, MSEPj1 j2 Yˆ i | k L j1 j2 i j1 , i j2 | k (7.19) for j1 , j2 k i 1, k i 2,..., J . After substitution of (7.19), equation (7.16) generates a triangle of quantities MSEP R i | k , whose square roots are set out in Table 7.6. d:\219548251.doc 26/07/2016 5:19 AM Casualty Actuarial Society 30 Table 7.6 MSEP of filtered logged age to ultimate factors Period of Origin 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 d:\219548251.doc 0 1 2 3 4 0.06855 0.09930 0.09608 0.09559 0.12478 0.13698 0.13364 0.13698 0.13197 0.12425 0.11816 0.11534 0.11803 0.11971 0.11710 0.11322 0.10926 0.10750 0.03226 0.03355 0.03683 0.04421 0.04529 0.04537 0.04547 0.04385 0.04206 0.04091 0.04071 0.04134 0.04133 0.04038 0.03926 0.03834 0.03802 0.02027 0.02241 0.02695 0.02661 0.02688 0.02666 0.02553 0.02451 0.02389 0.02387 0.02424 0.02407 0.02346 0.02281 0.02232 0.02220 0.01407 0.01695 0.01646 0.01668 0.01647 0.01571 0.01510 0.01472 0.01473 0.01496 0.01481 0.01442 0.01402 0.01372 0.01367 0.01074 0.01033 0.01050 0.01034 0.00985 0.00946 0.00923 0.00925 0.00939 0.00928 0.00903 0.00878 0.00860 0.00857 26/07/2016 5:19 AM MSEP of filtered logged age to ultimate factor from devleopment year n, filtered on data up to that experience year, for 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 0.00652 0.00664 0.00653 0.00621 0.00597 0.00583 0.00584 0.00594 0.00586 0.00570 0.00554 0.00543 0.00541 0.00421 0.00413 0.00393 0.00378 0.00369 0.00370 0.00376 0.00371 0.00361 0.00351 0.00344 0.00343 0.00262 0.00249 0.00239 0.00234 0.00235 0.00239 0.00235 0.00229 0.00223 0.00218 0.00218 0.00157 0.00151 0.00148 0.00149 0.00151 0.00149 0.00145 0.00141 0.00138 0.00138 0.00095 0.00093 0.00094 0.00096 0.00094 0.00092 0.00089 0.00087 0.00087 0.00058 0.00059 0.00060 0.00059 0.00057 0.00056 0.00055 0.00055 0.00037 0.00037 0.00037 0.00036 0.00035 0.00034 0.00034 12 13 14 15 0.00023 0.00022 0.00022 0.00021 0.00021 0.00021 0.00013 0.00013 0.00013 0.00012 0.00012 0.00007 0.00007 0.00007 0.00007 0.00004 0.00004 0.00004 16 17 0.00001 0.00000 0.00001 Casualty Actuarial Society 31 Tables 7.5 and 7.6 lead to estimates of (unlogged) ultimate incurred losses through the log normal formula: incurred losses of accident year i as at end of experience year k x exp R i | k 12 MSEP R i | k . These estimates appear in Table 7.7. d:\219548251.doc 26/07/2016 5:19 AM (7.20) Casualty Actuarial Society 32 Table 7.7 Estimates of ultimate claims incurred Period of Origin 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 d:\219548251.doc 0 1 2 3 4 28,765 31,435 39,629 45,654 34,886 67,141 77,396 33,003 47,581 43,943 32,890 43,872 38,883 64,118 51,894 59,716 46,182 34,265 31,111 26,259 35,716 44,738 59,559 60,380 55,112 42,931 48,128 35,185 32,378 33,508 44,747 46,520 55,875 49,688 41,643 27,438 22,768 33,015 55,941 58,953 48,936 56,335 50,657 48,599 37,097 37,151 46,137 48,420 49,596 54,120 49,179 27,539 22,543 41,213 53,166 48,834 44,014 55,596 47,407 47,251 40,605 42,294 50,426 56,543 50,120 57,005 26,486 23,933 38,850 49,909 46,354 45,093 54,815 47,043 48,835 41,981 43,898 55,824 57,253 49,563 26/07/2016 5:19 AM Ultimate incurred claims, as estimated at end of development year n, filtered on data up to that experience year, for n= 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 29,697 24,182 38,359 47,787 45,019 44,169 57,791 45,984 51,208 46,591 42,961 52,291 57,173 28,698 25,320 36,965 46,267 44,251 42,796 56,967 44,545 50,993 48,859 44,452 50,890 28,112 23,900 36,316 45,212 43,342 42,567 54,866 44,292 49,414 48,604 44,090 26,890 22,731 35,600 44,335 42,477 39,878 54,970 43,278 48,444 47,218 26,884 22,291 35,299 43,365 41,690 39,595 53,308 43,419 46,699 26,599 21,521 34,638 41,731 41,330 38,684 53,283 44,033 26,127 21,690 32,631 41,440 41,264 38,343 52,746 12 13 14 15 16 17 25,977 20,853 32,779 41,090 40,651 37,801 25,792 20,234 32,771 40,886 40,791 25,640 20,141 32,538 40,459 25,679 20,058 32,338 25,720 20,041 25,469 Casualty Actuarial Society 33 Figure 7.2 gives a plot of the evolving distribution of estimated ultimate incurred losses for accident year 1980. The illustrated distributions are based on the parameters in Tables 7.5 and 7.6. The figure corresponds to Tables 7.1 and 8.1 in Taylor (1999b). Figure 7.2 Fig 7.2 Accident year 1980 Probability density 10 8 At At At At At 6 4 2 end end end end end 1980 1981 1983 1988 1995 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 Incurred losses ($000) Thousands The different distributions can be identified by their increasing concentration (and therefore increasing peak height) with increasing development. Thus, the distribution at the end of 1995, with only two years of development remaining, is highly concentrated. Figure 7.2 differs little visually from Figure 8.1 of the previous paper. However, Figure 7.3 provides a little more detail of the comparison of results derived from the Kalman filter (present paper) and from the credibility approach (previous paper). Figure 7.3 Acc yr 1980 (previous) $60,000 $55,000 Acc yr 1986 (previous) $50,000 Acc yr 1990 (previous) $45,000 $40,000 Acc yr 1980 (present) $35,000 Acc yr 1986 (present) Development year d:\219548251.doc 26/07/2016 5:19 AM 14 12 10 8 6 4 2 $30,000 0 Predicted ultimate incurred ('000) Comparison of development with previous paper Acc yr 1990 (present) Casualty Actuarial Society 34 The graph provides comparisons in respect of accident years 1980, 1986 and 1990. In the earliest of these years, the two approaches produce very similar results, the Kalman filter being slightly lower at early development but slightly higher at late development. By accident year 1986, the Kalman filter is producing materially higher results. By accident year 1990, the gap has widened further. These differences result from the dynamic nature of the filter. It is seen from Table 7.2 that age-to-age factors at all development years up to say 9 show an increasing trend over most of the experience periods. While the experience rating nature of the credibility method in the previous paper causes it to follow the trend, the model is static in its parameters. The Kalman filter, on the other hand, contains dynamic parameters, and therefore adapts more rapidly to the changing claims experience. The Kalman filter is also somewhat tighter in its predictions, as Table 7.8 indicates. Here the coefficients of variation of the final diagonal of incurred losses (Table 7.7) are calculated from Table 7.6 and compared with the corresponding c.v.’s from Table 8.4 of the previous paper. By the log normal assumption in use here, the c.v. associated with any forecast is estimated as: c.v. exp MSEP 1 2 . 1 (7.21) Table 7.8 Predictive coefficients of variation Accident year 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 1984 1985 1986 1987 1988 1989 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 d:\219548251.doc 26-07-16 5:19 AM Estimated predictive coefficient of variation of ultimate incurred losses Kalman filter Credibility % % 0 0 0.3 0.4 0.6 0.7 0.8 1.0 1.1 1.3 1.4 1.7 1.8 2.2 2.3 2.8 3.0 3.6 3.7 4.5 4.7 5.6 5.9 7.0 7.4 8.8 9.3 11.0 11.7 13.9 18.4 17.4 19.7 33.7 Casualty Actuarial Society 8. 35 Acknowledgements I am grateful to my colleagues Steven Lim and Graham Taylor, who programmed calculations for the numerical example in Section 7. d:\219548251.doc 26-07-16 5:19 AM Casualty Actuarial Society 9. 36 References Kalman, R.E. (1960). A new approach to linear filtering and prediction problems. Journal of Basic Engineering, 82, 340-345. Neuhaus, W. (1989). Dynamic linear models and the discrete Kalman filter. Statistical Memoir No. 1/89 from the University of Oslo. Taylor, G.C. (1999a). The statistical distribution of incurred losses and its evolution over time I: non-parametric models. Research Paper No. 72, Centre for Actuarial Studies, University of Melbourne. Taylor, G.C. (1999b). The statistical distribution of incurred losses and its evolution over time II: parametric models. Research Paper No. 73, Centre for Actuarial Studies, University of Melbourne. d:\219548251.doc 26-07-16 5:19 AM