Mixed SUE behaviour under traveller information provision services with heterogeneous multi-class multi-criteria decision making Xiaoqing Jaber Centre for Transport Research and Innovation for People (TRIP) Department of Civil, Structural and Environmental Engineering Trinity College Dublin, Dublin 2, Ireland Email: lixq@tcd.ie Margaret O’Mahony Centre for Transport Research and Innovation for People (TRIP) Department of Civil, Structural and Environmental Engineering Trinity College Dublin, Dublin 2, Ireland Email: margaret.omahony@tcd.ie Abstract- This paper studies travellers’ mixed stochastic user equilibrium (SUE) behaviour under traveller information provision services with heterogeneous multi-class multi-criteria decision making. A multi-class, multi-criteria mixed SUE assignment model under traveller information provision services is proposed and modelled as a nonlinear complementary problem (NCP). The model considers heterogeneous road travellers who are assumed to be multi-criteria decision makers. The route choice behaviour of equipped and unequipped travellers under traveller information provision services is then formulated as an optimisation program, in which the net economic benefit is maximised and the total generated emissions are constrained. The optimisation model has an interpretation from economic, behavioural 1 and environmental viewpoints. The solution of this program satisfies the logit-based SUE assignment. By deriving first-order optimality conditions from this program, the marginal cost pricing policy is obtained. This pricing is not only class-dependent but also link-dependent. Index Terms—traveller information provision services, mixed SUE assignment, nonlinear complementarity problem, multi-class multi-criteria decision making INTRODUCTION Over the last two decades, there has been a considerable interest in the transportation area on the analysis of the effects of providing traveller information. Much research work has been undertaken to evaluate the impact of traveller information provision in terms of welfare economic considerations (e.g. Arnott et al., 1991; Verhoef et al., 1995; Emmerink et al., 1998), potential travel time savings (e.g. Abdel-Aty and Abdalla, 2004; Adler, 2001; Adler et al., 2005; Jou et al., 2005; Mahmassani and Liu, 1999; Toledo and Beinhaker, 2006), driver behaviour (e.g. Dell’Orco and Teodorovic, 2009; Emmerink et al., 1996; Iida et al., 1992; Khattak et al., 1995; Mannering et al., 1994; Tsirimpa et al., 2007; Yang et al., 1993), safety implications (e.g. Srinivasan et al., 1995; Al-Deek et al., 1998), and the efficiency of road usage (e.g. Al-Deek and Kanafani, 1993; Emmerink et al., 1995a,b; Mahmassani and Jayakrishnan, 1991), and so on. Only very few studies were focused on studying the environmental impact of traveller information provision, particularly from increased vehicular emissions. For example, Al-Deek et al. (1995) proposed an analytical method for evaluating the impact of Advanced Traveller Information System (ATIS) on air quality in a simple network where traffic experienced incident congestion. Kanninen (1996) discussed congestion 2 relief and the environmental impact expected of Intelligent Transportation Systems (ITS). It was mentioned that ITS might induce latent travel demand which would probably increase vehicular emissions. The impact of traveller information on vehicular emissions requires more evaluation, because any underestimation or overestimation of the environmental impact of traveller information provision could lead to an unexpected outcome. Conventionally, it is intended that providing travellers with the dissemination of traffic information would allow equipped vehicles to spread from the congested to the less congested areas. Hence the travel times of both equipped drivers and the total system travel time (TSTT) would be reduced. However, diverted traffic may impose extra environmental externalities, such as air pollution, noise pollution, and accidents, on existing drivers and residents living in the neighbourhood. The increased pollution is hazardous to human health, so in this case, the aim of implementing traveller information provision is not only to enhance the mobility of a transportation system but also to maintain the system which is sustainable in an environmentally-friendly way. Szeto et al. (2008) found out paradoxical phenomena present with the provision of traveller information services, in which the provision of traveller information cannot reduce TSTT and vehicular emissions simultaneously. With the above considerations, more analysis is required to evaluate the impact of traveller information provision services on these two issues simultaneously. Traditionally, the travellers consider two criteria when making route choices, which are travel times and travel costs. For those who choose to use information provision services, they make their decisions based on the obtained information of travel times and costs on a network. For those who do not use the services, they make route choices based on their experience or their 3 knowledge of the network. Nagurney et al. (2002) pointed out that it is not unreasonable to assume that certain classes of travellers factor an environmental criterion into their decision making process with the increasing concern of the degradation of the environment. Also with the growing interests in studying Intelligent Transportation Systems, it is expected that the emissions can be broadcast to the travellers as well as travel times and costs (Nagurney et al., 2002). The consideration of the environmental criterion regarding emissions may cause travellers to change their previous choices which they would have made when emissions were not taken into account. Additionally, the weights of travellers’ multiple criteria of travel times, costs and emissions will have direct impacts on their route choices as well, and consequently TSTT and emissions. Therefore, it would be very meaningful to consider incorporating the environmental criterion into the travellers’ decision making process when analysing the impact of traveller information provision services. However, no one has attempted this in the transportation literature to date. In this paper, we proposed a multi-class multi-criteria mixed stochastic user equilibrium (SUE) assignment model under the traveller information provision services with heterogeneous road travellers. Traveller heterogeneity is considered by assuming a discrete set of value of times (VOTs) for several traveller classes. The travellers of each class having the same VOT are further divided into different groups with different travel cost perception variations. It is assumed that equipped travellers have lower perception variation due to provided traveller information and unequipped travellers have higher perception variation due to the lack of current traffic information. The route choice behaviour of the equipped and unequipped travellers is modelled to follow a mixed SUE assignment. In addition, the route choice behaviour of equipped and unequipped travellers is formulated as an optimisation model, in which the net economic benefit is maximised and the total generated emissions are 4 constrained. The proposed model has an interpretation from economic, behavioural and environmental viewpoints. The solution of this model satisfies the logit-based SUE assignment. The marginal cost pricing was then derived from the proposed model. This marginal cost pricing is not only class-dependent but also link-dependent. The rest of the paper is organised as follows: The next section describes NCP formulation and performance measures. A system optimised pricing policy in a mix SUE assignment comes after that followed by illustrative examples, concluding remarks, acknowledgement, and references. NCP FORMULATION AND PERFORMANCE MEASURES In this paper, a multi-class multi-criteria mixed SUE assignment model is developed under traveller information provision services based on Szeto (2007), where user heterogeneity and multi-criteria decision making are not considered. The travellers’ multi-criteria decision making process is incorporated into the proposed model in which there is an explicit environmental criterion. The multi-class multi-criteria mixed SUE assignment model is different from those proposed in Yang and Zhang (2002), Huang and Li (2007), Yang and Zhang (2008), and Zhang et al. (2008), as the latter models do not consider the environmental criterion. This multi-class multi-criteria mixed SUE assignment problem with driver heterogeneity is modelled as a nonlinear complementary problem (NCP). The model then can be solved by any existing optimisation program. In this study, the model is solved using the Generalised Reduced Gradient (GRG) method (Abadie and Carpentier, 1969). 5 NCP Formulation of the Heterogeneous Multi-class Mixed SUE Assignment Problem with an Environmental Criterion The multi-class route choice behaviour of equipped and unequipped travellers is modelled to follow the principle of SUE by only varying travel cost perception variation as in Lo and Szeto (2002), which implies that all the equipped travellers have a lower travel cost perception variation and all the unequipped travellers have a higher travel cost perception variation. It is assumed there are N information service providers (ISP) who provide traffic information service over the entire road network for the corresponding N equipped driver groups, who only pay for the information from one service provider. There is an unequipped driver group who does not pay for any information service. Therefore, this problem has N 1 driver groups in each class having their own VOT. Each driver is assumed to be a multicriteria decision maker, who considers travel times, travel costs and generated emissions when making route choices. Let M denote the number of driver classes in the network and let m be a typical driver class, m 1, 2,..., M . The problem has M classes of drivers. For the drivers in any class m , they all follow N 1 sets of SUE conditions with all groups of equipped drivers having lower perception variations than those of unequipped drivers. Using the logit model, the SUE conditions are formulated as follows: f rs p ,i , m exp i prs,i ,m exp rs k ,i , m i qirs,m 0, rs, p, i, m , (1) k w rs p ,i , m exp i prs,i ,m exp i rs k ,i , m , rs, p, i, m , (2) k where f prs,i ,m , wrsp,i ,m , and prs,i ,m represent respectively the route flows, the proportion, and the generalised travel cost or the disutility of group i drivers in class m on route p between 6 origin-destination (OD) pair rs ; i represents the travel cost perception variation of group i drivers; qirs,m stands for the demand of group i drivers in class m between OD pair rs . In (1), the route flows are calculated according to the proportion defined by the logit model (2). The generalised route travel cost or the disutility prs,i ,m in (2) is a weighted average of three criteria: travel times, travel costs and emission costs, which in turn are functions of the link flow va . The link flow va can be determined by summing up all the route flows on that link: va mM pP rs iN 1 f prs,i ,m ap , a , (3) where ap is the link-route incidence indicator - ap 1 if link a is on route p ; ap 0 otherwise, and P rs is the set of paths between OD pair rs . The Bureau of Public Roads (BPR) type performance function is applied in this study and shown as follows to calculate the link travel time t a : va ta t 1 0 , a , ca 0 a (4) where t a0 , va and ca0 are the link free flow travel time, link flow and capacity, and 0.15, 4 . The route travel cost can be computed as follows: prs,i ,m CISP ,i Bmta a ap , rs, p, i, m, (5) a where C ISP ,i is the information service charge for group i drivers; Bm is the value of time of 7 class m drivers; a is the toll on link a . The sum of the travel time cost Bm ta and its toll a is the travel cost on link a . The route travel cost is composed of the service charge and the sum of the travel costs of the links on that route. According to Nagurney et al. (2002), the environmental costs associated with travelling on link a can be expressed as follows: ea ea (va ), a. (6) If a single pollutant is simply considered, ea (va ) can be assumed to be the average emissions of this single pollutant generated by the travellers on link a , for example, carbon monoxide. Although speed and grade variations are essential considerations in estimating vehicular emissions, they are not modelled in macroscopic traffic assignment models (Benedek and Rilett, 1998). Once the travel time, travel cost and emission costs are clearly defined, one can obtain the following generalised route cost: prs,i ,m tat ,a ,m ap prs,i ,m (c ,a ,m ap ) eae,a ,m ap , rs, p, i, m , a a (7) a where prs,i ,m is the generalised travel cost or the disutility of group i drivers in class m on route p between origin-destination (OD) pair rs ; t ,a,m , c,a,m and e,a,m denote the nonnegative weights associated with traveller’s travel time, cost and emissions on link a respectively. The weights t ,a,m , c,a,m and e,a,m are not only class-dependent but also linkdependent. Equation (7) implies that each group i drivers in class m has their own perception of the trade-offs among travel time, travel cost, and emissions generated when they travel on route p between origin-destination (OD) pair rs . The trade-offs are represented by these 8 weights associated with each criterion. The link-dependent weights allow us to incorporate some link-dependent factors as safety, comfort, view, sociability factors, as well as sensitivity to pollution (Nagurney et al., 2002). The total travel demand in the network q rs can be calculated as follows: q rs i ,m m q rs , rs, i, m, (8) i where qirs,m is the demand of group i drivers in class m between OD pair rs , which is fixed in this study. It can also be modelled through the newly proposed multinomial logit elastic market penetration model shown in Szeto et al. (2008), which captures the elasticity of the demand for the services measured by market penetration. The NCP formulation is obtained by adding the non-negativity conditions and multiplying route flows by the SUE conditions (1) as follows: f prs,i ,m f prs,i ,m wrsp ,i ,m qirs,m 0 f prs,i ,m 0 , rs, p, i, m . rs rs rs f p ,i ,m wp ,i ,m qi ,m 0 If f prs,i ,m 0 in (9), the term f rs p ,i , m (9) wrsp ,i ,m qirs,m must be zero to satisfy NCP. It means (1) must be satisfied. If f prs,i ,m 0 , the last constraint in (9) is satisfied, i.e. f prs,i ,m wrsp,i ,m qirs,m 0 . Put everything together and let y represents a strategic interaction of decisions makers as follows: 9 i , i 1,..., N C , i 1,..., N ISP ,i a , a 1,..., A , y t ,a ,m , a 1,..., A, m 1,..., M c ,a ,m , a 1,..., A, m 1,..., M e ,a ,m , a 1,..., A, m 1,..., M (10) x y f prs,i ,m , rs, p, i, m , and (11) F x f prs,i ,m wrsp ,i ,m qirs,m , rs, p, i, m , (12) the NCP (9) can then be expressed as finding x* 0 such that: F x* 0, x* y F x* 0 , T (13) where i and C ISP ,i are the strategy of information providers; a is the strategy of a toll operator; and the weights t ,a,m , c,a,m and e,a,m are respectively travellers’ own perception of the trade-offs among travel time, travel cost, and emissions; and wrsp,i ,m is defined by (2). Performance Measures of the Total System Travel Time (TSTT) and Vehicular Emissions The total system travel time (TSTT) is calculated to measure system performance regarding congestion and it is the sum of the travel times of all drivers on all links, expressed as: TSTT vata . (14) a According to (14), TSTT is a function of link flows, and hence is a function of route flows based on (3). 10 In terms of vehicular emissions, there are two types of vehicular emissions: link and network (or overall). The link vehicular emission is defined through the link emission factor approach. The key of estimating vehicular emissions is the relationship that volume of emissions is equal to the product of an emission factor and link load (DeCorla-Souza et al., 1995). This emission factor obtained using MOBILE model proposed by the Environmental Protection Agency (EPA) is based on the federal test procedure (FTP), typical driving conditions for an urban vehicle trip (DeCorla-Souza et al., 1995). This link emission factor approach adopted by Nagurney et al. (1998) and others can be expressed as follows: Qa ha va , a, (15) where Qa is the vehicular emissions on link a ; va represents the hourly traffic flow on link a ; ha is the emission factor on link a , which is assumed to be given for all links. The factors affecting the value of ha are discussed in Nagurney (2000). The overall vehicular emissions can be calculated as follows: Q Qa . (16) a According to (15), the vehicular emissions on a particular link are the product of the link flows and the corresponding emission factor. And the overall vehicular emissions can be obtained as in (16) by summing of the vehicular emissions on each link. A SYSTEM OPTIMISED PRICING POLICY IN A MIXED SUE ASSIGNMENT PROBLEM Traveller Information Services with Net Economic Benefit Maximisation 11 According to the trip consumer approach in Oppenheim (1995), an individual traveller considered as a consumer of urban trips maximises direct utility through an optimal choice of the aggregate demand. The direct utility of a representative group i traveller f prs,i ,m with a level of travel cost perception variation i in class m corresponding to the aggregate demand qirs,m can be defined as follows: U i ,m 1 i rs pP f prs,i ,m ln f prs,i ,m rs 1 i q rs i ,m ln qirs,m . (17) rs Then the gross direct utility of representative consumers in class m with various levels of travel cost perception variations (various i ) can be expressed as follows: U i ,m i ( i 1 i rs pP rs f prs,i ,m ln f prs,i ,m ) ( i 1 i q rs i ,m ln qirs,m ). (18) rs According to Yang and Huang (2005), net economic benefit of all the travellers is the difference between their gross direct utility and total travel cost. Therefore, the net economic benefit (NEB) of class m consumers is the difference between the gross direct utility of travellers in class m , U i ,m , and the total travel cost in class m , i i f prs,i ,m prs,i ,m , and rs pP rs can be expressed as follows: NEBm ( i 1 i rs pP f rs f prs,i ,m ln f prs,i ,m ) ( i rs p ,i , m rs p ,i , m 1 i q rs i ,m ln qirs,m ) rs (19) . rs pP rs i One then can obtain the net economic benefit of all consumers from all classes as follows: 1 NEB ( m i i i rs pP rs rs pP rs f rs p ,i , m f prs,i ,m ln f prs,i ,m ) ( i rs p ,i , m . 12 1 i q rs i ,m rs ln qirs,m ) (20) The maximisation of the net economic benefit is equivalent to the minimisation of the negative net economic benefit. In this model, the negative net economic benefit is minimised so that a convex minimisation program can be formulated and the strict convexity of F (f ) in the following Model 1 with respect to flow variable, f prs,i ,m over the feasible region can be proved. minF (f ) ( f Model 1: m i i i subject to 1 i rs pP f pP rs i rs p ,i , m 1 i q rs i ,m rs ln qirs,m (21) ) f prs,i ,m qirs,m q rs , rs, p, i, m, m a m rs rs p ,i , m h a f prs,i ,m ln f prs,i ,m rs pP rs m i rs pP (22) i f prs,i ,m ap Q, a, rs, p, i, m (23) rs f prs,i ,m 0, rs, p, i, m, (24) where i is the parameter representing the travel cost perception variation of group i drivers; f prs,i ,m and prs,i ,m are respectively the route flows and the route travel cost of group i drivers in class m on route p between origin-destination (OD) pair rs ; qirs,m is the demand of group i drivers in class m between OD pair rs ; q rs is the total travel demand between OD pair rs ; ha is the emission factor on link a ; Q is the maximum allowable vehicular emissions in the transportation system. qirs,m , q rs and Q are exogenously decided. Equation (22) guarantees that the path flow pattern satisfies the travel demands. Constraint (23) guarantees that the path flow pattern does not exceed the maximum allowable vehicular emissions. Constraint (24) is to ensure route flows are non-negative. It is observed that conditions (22)-(24) correspond to Linear System 4.1 in Nagurney (2000), the existence of a solution to this linear system of 13 equations and inequalities guarantees that the demand associated with OD pairs can be satisfied by a path flow pattern, which also satisfies the maximum allowable vehicular emissions simultaneously. This means that the solution guarantees viability of a transportation system with given OD pairs and travel demands. Nagurney (2000) has pointed out that there may be more than one such flow pattern to Linear System 4.1. It is proved in Jaber (2009) that the solution f prs,i ,m to the minimisation problem is a strict local minimum of F (f ) and then that is the unique minimum of F (f ) over the feasible region defined by conditions (22)-(24). The Equivalent Logit-Based SUE Assignment Conditions and a System Optimised Toll The solution of Model 1 can be derived to have the form of the logit-based Stochastic User Equilibrium assignment conditions. This is demonstrated by proving that the first-order conditions of Model 1 are equivalent to the logit-based SUE assignment conditions. The Lagrangian for the minimisation Model 1 can be formulated as: L(f , λ , μ) F (f ) rs ( qirs,m rs m ( ha a i i m f i pP rs f prs,i ,m ) (25) Q), rs p p ,i , m a rs pP rs where rs and are Lagrange multipliers associated with constraints (22) and (23) respectively. Equating the partial derivatives of L(f , λ , μ) with respect to the flow variables f prs,i ,m to zero will lead to the conditions that a stationary point of F (f ) subject to constraints (22)-(24) must satisfy. It is important to note that L does not exist when f prs,i*,m 0 , rs f p ,i ,m because of the singularity at f prs,i*,m 0 in the logarithmic function in the objective function F (f ) , a solution to the stationary point conditions will only be valid if all components of 14 f prs,i ,m are strictly positive. The first-order conditions obtained by calculating the partial derivatives of L(f , λ , μ) with respect to the flow variables f prs,i ,m are expressed as follows: f rs p ,i , m where f prs,i ,m L(f , λ, μ) F (f ) 1 i F (f ) rs ha ap 0, rs, p, i, m, f prs,i ,m (ln f rs* p ,i , m (26) a 1) rs p ,i , m f m rs* p ,i , m i d prs,i ,m df prs,i ,m , rs, p, i, m . Therefore f prs,i ,m L(f , λ , μ) 1 i rs* p ,i , m (ln f 1) rs p ,i , m f m i rs* p ,i , m d prs,i ,m df prs,i ,m rs (27) ha ap 0, rs, p, i, m. a Equation (27) can be modified as follows: 1 i (ln f rs* p ,i , m 1) rs p ,i , m f m i rs* p ,i , m d prs,i ,m df rs p ,i , m ha ap rs , rs, p, i, m. (28) a It is observed that the left-hand side of (28) consists of the sum of four items. The first of which is the derivative of the first item in the objective function F (f ) , which has the form of an entropy function defined on the path flow. The second is route travel cost, which is defined in (5). The third is congestion externality, which is the additional travel time burden that an additional traveller inflicts on each one of the travellers already using path p (Sheffi, 1985). The fourth is the marginal contribution of the total cost on path p due to vehicular emissions generated by travelling on path p (Nagurney, 2000). The Lagrange multiplier associated with vehicular emission constraint (23) is interpreted as being the marginal cost of emission abatement. The sum of the second, third and fourth items on the left-hand side of (28) can be interpreted as the marginal cost of group i drivers in class m travelling on path p between OD pair rs , prs,i ,m , associated with the congestion and emission externalities that the additional traveller imposes on others: 15 rs p ,i , m rs p ,i , m f m i rs* p ,i , m d prs,i ,m df rs p ,i , m ha ap , rs, p, i, m. (29) a Then (28) becomes: 1 i (ln f prs,i*,m 1) prs,i ,m rs , rs, p, i, m. (30) Combine (22) and (30), carrying out some manipulations, there is: f prs,i*,m qirs,m exp(i prs,i ,m ) exp( kK rs i k ,i , m ) , p. (31) Observing that (31) obtained from the first-order optimality conditions of Model 1 has the form of the logit-based SUE assignment conditions. The differences between the above SUE condition and the ones derived in Sheffi (1985) and Yang (1999) are the usage of the route cost function. Here, the route cost function is (29), where prs,i ,m is the marginal cost of group i drivers in class m travelling on path p between OD pair rs associated with the congestion and emission externalities. However, the one in Sheffi (1985) uses the usual travel cost function without considering the congestion and emission externalities. The one derived in Yang (1999) only incorporates the congestion externality in the travel cost function not considering the emission externality. The solution of Model 1 satisfying the logit-based SUE assignment not only maximises the net economic benefit of all the travellers but also ensures that total emissions does not violate its constraint. This means, at equilibrium, the flow pattern is system optimised, but travellers still behave in a manner following the mixed SUE. To achieve such an optimal equilibrium point in any network where equipped and unequipped travellers follow the mixed SUE assignment, it is required that the congestion and emission externalities should be simultaneously incorporated into the travel cost function. This can be obtained by charging travellers a toll equal to the congestion and emission externalities, which is the difference between the marginal travel cost and generalised travel cost as follows: 16 rs p ,i , m rs p ,i , m f rs p ,i , m m where f m i rs* p ,i , m d prs,i ,m df df i and ha ap rs p ,i , m d prs,i ,m rs* p ,i , m rs p ,i , m ha ap , rs, p, i, m, (32) a are respectively the congestion and emission a externalities. Karush-Kuhn-Tucker (K-K-T) Optimality Conditions Since the objective function (21) is to maximise the net economic benefit, Karush-KuhnTucker (K-K-T) optimality conditions can be derived for the system-optimised problem given by (21)-(24). K-K-T conditions for Model 1 can be stated as follows: 1 i (ln f rs* p ,i , m 1) rs p ,i , m f m i rs* p ,i , m d prs,i ,m df prs,i*,m (33) rs* * ha ap 0, rs, p, i, m, a 1 d prs,i ,m rs* rs rs* (ln f p ,i ,m 1) p ,i ,m f p ,i ,m rs* df p ,i ,m m i i T rs* * ha ap f prs,i*,m 0, rs, p, i, m, a * ( ha a m i f prs,i*,m ap Q) 0, rs, p, i, m, m i pP rs (35) rs pP rs * 0, (34) f prs,i*,m qirs,m 0, rs, p, i, m, m (36) (37) i f prs,i*,m 0. 17 (38) Because of the singularity at f prs,i* 0 in the logarithmic function in the objective function F (f ) , it is required that all f prs,i* are strictly positive. Therefore, (33) must hold as equality, which has been proved to be the conditions equivalent to the logit-based SUE conditions. This implies that at equilibrium the system optimised flow pattern follows the logit-based SUE. In conditions (35) and (36), the positive marginal cost of emission abatement * is to ensure the vehicular emissions not to exceed the maximum allowable vehicular emissions. When the vehicular emissions are smaller than its maximum allowable value, the marginal cost of emission abatement is zero. Conditions (37) and (38) are respectively the flow conservation and non-negativity constraints. Weights in a Bicriteria Model: Relation to the Optimal Toll If it is assumed that the travellers in the network are environmentally conscious and consider travel costs and generated emissions in their route choice decision making, there is the following generalised route cost function, which incorporates two criteria that travellers consider: prs,i ,m prs,i ,m e, p ,m ea ap , rs, p, i.m, (39) a where e , p , m is the weight associated with emissions generated on path p for class m drivers. Obviously, the weight associated with travel cost is assumed to be 1. It is assumed as in Nagurney et al. (2002) that the emissions function ea on link a is equal to the emission factor on the link, which represents emissions generated by a single traveller travelling on that link. Then the above generalised route cost function can be rewritten as follows: 18 prs,i ,m prs,i ,m e, p ,m ha ap , rs, p, i.m. (40) a To achieve the optimal equilibrium solution in Model 1, a toll should be charged and equal to: prs,i ,m prs,i ,m prs,i ,m f rs* p ,i , m f rs* p ,i , m m m i i d prs,i ,m df rs p ,i , m d prs,i ,m df rs p ,i , m ha ap e, p ,m ha ap a (41) a ( e, p ,m ) ha ap . a The above equation represents the optimal toll which guarantees a SUE flow pattern is system optimised. When the weight associated with generated emissions is equal to lagrange multiplier , traveller only needs to pay a toll equal to the congestion externality. When the traveller is not aware of the generated emissions, he needs to pay a toll equal to the congestion and emission externalities. When the traveller has very high awareness of generated emissions (i.e., e , p ,m ), he pays a toll less than the congestion externality. This implies that the weight that the traveller place on emissions is directly related to the charged optimal toll under the assumption mentioned before. The higher the awareness of generated emissions is, the lower the optimal toll is. ILLUSTRATIVE EXAMPLES Here, two examples are given for an illustrative purpose to analyse the effectiveness of derived marginal cost pricing. The proposed NCP formulation is used as an analysis methodology, route flow patterns of equipped travellers and unequipped travellers can be solved and next system performance can be evaluated. It is assumed that there are two classes of travellers with different VOTs. Each class is further divided into two groups, equipped and 19 unequipped travellers. The scenario example used here is broadly based upon an existing section of the road network in Ireland between North of Balbriggan and Dundalk in Co. Louth, which consists of two links, two nodes and one OD pair shown in Figure 1 below. 1 3 1 2 Figure 1 The example network. 13 The parameters adopted in the first example are as follows: a) demand parameters: q1,1 150 13 13 vph; q13 2,1 700 vph; q1,2 800 vph; q2,2 2600 vph; b) route choice parameters: value of time B1 = € 15/ hr; B2 = € 10/ hr; travel cost perception variation parameter: unequipped drivers 1 = 0.15 €-1; equipped drivers 2 =2 €-1; c) toll operation parameter: toll 1 2 € 0 d) information service parameter: service charge CISP = € 0.5; e) vehicular emission parameter: link emission factors h1 =0.9 litre/veh; h2 =1.3 litre/veh; maximum allowable vehicular emissions: Q =4310 litre; f) Network parameters: c10 2500 vph; c20 2000 vph; t10 21 mins; t20 29 mins. Table 1 demonstrates system performance before and after implementation of marginal cost pricing. Before setting a maximum allowable vehicular emission constraint in the network, no marginal toll is needed. Travellers are bircriteria decision makers but only concerned with travel costs in their decision making process, which means c =1, e =0. The generalised route cost function in (39) substituting into (2) in NCP formulation is reduced to (5). The calculated TSTT and total emissions are respectively 118363.66 minutes and 4351.86 litres. To limit the total emissions not to exceed 4310 litres, a marginal toll as expressed in (32) is implemented, 20 which reduces the total emissions to be 4310 litres but increases TSTT to 120513.73 minutes whether or not travellers are concerned with generated emissions in their decision making. In this case, the marginal cost pricing under the logit-based SUE does not necessarily diminish TSTT. This point has been indicated in Yang (1999), although Yang’s marginal cost pricing only considers congestion externality. Table 1 System performance before and after the marginal cost pricing under SUE. Total Emissions Maximum Allowable (litre) Vehicular Emissions (litre) TSTT (min) Before Marginal c =1, e =0 118363.66 4351.86 None c =1, e =0 120513.73 4310.00 4310 c =1, e =5 120513.73 4310.00 4310 Cost Pricing After Marginal Cost Pricing Table 2 shows the optimal tolls under various emission weights when the same maximum allowable vehicular emissions are required. It is revealed that congestion tolls are classdependent. Class 1 drivers face higher congestion tolls than class 2 drivers when they traverse the same link. It is observed that emission tolls are not class-dependent like congestion tolls, but are link-dependent. Emission tolls are related to the emission factors on links. The higher the emission factor, the higher the emission toll, and vice versa. When travellers are more environmentally conscious (higher e ), the marginal cost of emission abatement is less. Therefore, emission tolls are less. However, congestion tolls remain. It is observed that the difference between optimal marginal costs of abatement is 5, which is exactly the same as the 21 weight travellers place on generated emissions in their decision making. This coincides with the relationship derived in (41). Table 2 The optimal tolls under different emission weights with the same total emission constraint. Class 1 Drivers Class 2 Drivers the Marginal Maximum (B1=15 €/hr) (B2=10 €/hr) Cost of Emission Allowable Abatement μ Vehicular Link 1 Link 2 Link 1 Link 2 Emissions (litre) Congestion 6.86 c =1, Toll (€) e =0 Emission 0.59 4.58 0.39 11.54 16.66 11.54 16.66 6.86 0.59 4.58 0.39 12.82 4310 7.82 4310 Toll (€) Congestion c =1, Toll (€) e =5 Emission 7.04 10.16 7.04 10.16 Toll (€) In the second example, the same network and parameters are adopted as in the first example with the exception of the following: link emission factors h1 =1.3 litre/veh; h2 =0.9 litre/veh; maximum allowable vehicular emissions: Q =4950 litre and 4840 litre. Table 3 illustrates how the system performance changes before and after implementing the marginal cost pricing with various levels of total emission constraints. It shows that the marginal cost pricing decreases both TSTT and total emissions, which are 118363.66 minutes and 4998.14 litres originally. To lower total emissions such that they are less than 4950 litres, the marginal cost pricing used in the network is where the traveller has no environmental consciousness. Surprisingly, 22 total emissions, which are 4851.37 litres, are less than the maximum permitted level, which is 4950 litres. Table 3 System performance before and after the marginal cost pricing under SUE. TSTT (min) Total Emissions Maximum Allowable (litre) Vehicular Emissions (litre) Before Marginal c =1, e =0 118363.66 4998.14 None c =1, e =0 115374.94 4851.37 4950 c =1, e =0 115437.87 4840.00 4840 c =1, e =0.3 115437.87 4840.00 4840 Cost Pricing After Marginal Cost Pricing It is shown in Table 4 that with this emission constraint there are only congestion tolls. If the maximum allowable vehicular emissions are further lowered to be 4840 litres, it can be seen in Table 3 that total emissions are further reduced to the maximum allowable level. However, in this case, congestion tolls alone are not enough. As shown in Table 4, there are emission tolls on all links, which is 0.96 euro on link 1 and 0.67 euro on link 2. As discussed in the last example, emission tolls are link-dependent. Link 1 has a higher emission toll since link 1 has a higher emission factor. If the travellers are assumed to be environmentally conscious ( e =0.3) in the same network with the same maximum allowable emissions, which are 4840 litres, emission tolls are reduced but congestion tolls remain the same. Observing that, before and after travellers place some weights on emissions, the difference between optimal marginal costs of emission abatement is 0.3, which is exactly equal to the weight the traveller puts on 23 generated emissions. This implies that there is a strong relationship between weights associated with emissions and the marginal cost pricing, more specifically the marginal cost of emission pricing. It is found that an increased weight associated with emissions results in less optimal tolls. It is also observed in Table 3 that TSTT is pushed up from 115374.94 minutes to 115437.87 minutes when a tighter emission constraint is adopted. This means that there is a trade-off between TSTT and total emissions. When one tries to lower total emissions, TSTT is worsened. As appeared in the last example, the marginal cost pricing cannot lower TSTT and total emission simultaneously. This does not mean that the system is not optimised. The phenomenon that the marginal cost pricing under SUE cannot necessarily decrease TSTT is not a paradox but a pseudo paradox. This is rooted in the stochastic nature of the mixed equilibrium model, which is the randomness of the perceived travel times (Sheffi, 1985). With traveller information provision services, equipped travellers still have perception variation of travel times, which is only less than that of unequipped travellers. Therefore, in the mixed stochastic network loading model, travellers’ perceived travel times are minimised. An improved system does not necessarily mean a reduction in TSTT. An optimised system here is referred to as an optimal situation with a given emission bound. Whether the marginal cost pricing under the logit-based SUE can reduce TSTT and total emissions simultaneously or not depends on the topology, characteristics and the emission bound of a network. Table 4 The optimal tolls under different emission constraints with various emission weights. Class 1 drivers Class 2 drivers the Marginal Maximum (B1=15 €/hr) (B2=10 €/hr) Cost of Allowable 24 Link 1 c =1, e =0 Link 2 Link 1 Emission Vehicular Abatement μ Emissions (litre) 0 4950 0.74 4840 0.44 4840 Link 2 Congestion 3.50 2.19 2.33 1.46 Toll (€) Emission 0.00 0.00 0.00 0.00 3.34 2.34 2.23 1.56 Toll (€) c =1, e =0 Congestion Toll (€) Emission 0.96 0.67 0.96 0.67 3.34 2.34 2.23 1.56 Toll (€) c =1, e =0.3 Congestion Toll (€) Emission 0.57 0.40 0.57 0.40 Toll (€) CONCLUDING REMARKS In this paper, a multi-class multi-criteria mixed SUE assignment model is presented under the traveller information provision services incorporating traveller heterogeneity. The novelty of this study is to incorporate the travellers’ multi-criteria decision making process into the proposed mixed SUE model in which there is an explicit environmental criterion, which has not been attempted in the transportation literature to date. An optimisation model is proposed to derive the marginal cost pricing, which was demonstrated to be applicable in the network under the logit-based mixed SUE. 25 It is noteworthy that the marginal cost pricing derived is not only class-dependent but also link-dependent. Gomez-Ibanez and Small (1994) provided a brief review of congestion pricing schemes and technologies available for implementing them. They discussed that the practical possibilities of implementing complex pricing schemes are changing rapidly with new developments in automated vehicle identification and charging. The implementation of more sophisticated congestion pricing schemes more depend on automated charging technologies. Three tasks involved in every such system are: to recognize the identities of valid users; to detect and classify vehicles for the purpose of enforcement; and to manage the financial transactions. With the application of such technologies such as in-vehicle units, it is possible to implement the proposed class-dependent and link-dependent marginal cost pricing in practice. Niskanen and Nash (2008) provided a comprehensive review of experiences of road pricing in Europe and elsewhere, both in research and practice. They mentioned an approach, which is now often referred to as marginal cost-based pricing, in which prices remain based on marginal cost and various second-best rules may be derived to indentify the optimal adjustments from marginal cost pricing. Verhoef et al. (2008) discussed the implementation paths (IPs) for marginal cost-based pricing in urban transport, proposed a structural economic approach to the design and evaluation of such IPs and applied such approach to analyse IPs in the context of urban transport. Even though the practical possibilities of implementing marginal cost pricing are increasing, Niskanen and Nash (2008) pointed out that the importance of institutional implementation issues including political acceptability have been given too little attention both in research and in actual attempts to implement road pricing measures. Both the analysis of theoretical approaches and the feasibility of practical applications of marginal cost pricing, therefore, require more investigation. 26 This paper opens up a number of research directions. The total travel demand is assumed to be fixed. Kanninen (1996) pointed out that ITS may induce potential travel demand. Ignoring latent travel demand may overestimate the benefits of information provision services. It is thus interesting to study the effect of information provision in a network with an elastic travel demand. The proposed models are static. It would be meaningful to model mixed SUE behaviour under endogenous market penetration of traveller information services in a dynamic traffic assignment framework. This type of dynamic model considering traveller information services was previously proposed by Lo and Szeto (2004), which allowed the study of the impact of traveller information provision services to capture the changes in departure times and the impact of traveller information provision services under non-recurrent network congestion. As it is not the focus of this study, we leave the dynamic analysis of marginal cost pricing for future studies. Also, it would be very meaningful to calibrate the parameters of perception variations i , which represent travel uncertainty, once the survey data is available. The method proposed by Huang (1995) can be employed for this purpose. Moreover, our proposed NCP formulation allows the analysis of strategic interactions among information providers, toll road operators, and travellers’ multicriteria decision making. It would be interesting to analyse how each strategy of these decision makers affects the marginal cost pricing and the concerns of other parties. In addition, extending the existing model to incorporate travel time, cost and network uncertainties would be another challenging research direction. ACKNOWLEDGEMENT 27 This research is funded under the Programme for Research in Third-Level Institutions (PRTLI), administered by the Irish Higher Education Authority. REFERENCES Abadie, J. and Carpentier, J. (1969). Generalization of the Wolfe Reduced Gradient Method to the Case of Nonlinear Constraints. In R. Fletcher (ed.), Optimization, New York: Academic Press, 37-47. Abdel-Aty, M. and Abdalla, P.E.F. (2004). Modelling drivers diversion from normal routes under information provision using generalized estimating equations and binomial probit link function. Transportation, 31(3), 327-348. Adler, J. L., Satapathy, G., Manikonda, V., Bowles, B. and Blue, V. J. (2005). A multi-agent approach to cooperative traffic management and route guidance. Transportation Research Part B, 39(4), 297-318. Adler, J.L. (2001). Investigating the learning effects of route guidance and traffic advisories on route choice behaviour. Transportation Research Part C, 9, 1-14. Al-Deek, H. M., Ishak, S. S. and Radwan, A. E. (1998). Impact of traffic diversion with ATIS on travellers' safety. Computers & Industrial Engineering, 34(2), 547-558. Al-Deek, H., Wayson, R. and Radwan, A.E. (1995). Methodology for evaluating ATIS impacts on air quality. Journal of Transportation Engineering, 121(4), 376-384. Arnott, R., de Palma, A. and Lindsey, R. (1991). Does providing information to drivers reduce traffic congestion? Transportation Research Part A, 25(5), 309-318. Benedek, C.M. and Rilett, L.R. (1998). Equitable Traffic Assignment with Environmental Cost Functions. Journal of Transportation Engineering, 124(1), 16-22. 28 Dafermos, S. (1981). A Multicriteria Route-Mode Choice Traffic Equilibrium Model. Lefschetz Center for Dynamical Systems, Brown University, Providence, Rhode Island. DeCorla-Souza, P., Everett, J., Cosby, J. and Lim, P. (1995). Trip-based approach to estimate emissions with environmental protection agency's MOBILE model. Transportation Research Record, 1444, 118-125. Dell'Orco, M. and Teodorovic, D. (2009). Data fusion for updating information in modelling drivers' choice behaviour. Transportmetrica, 5(2), 107-123. Emmerink, R. H. M., Verhoef, E. T., Nijkamp, P. and Rietveld, P. (1998). Information policy in road transport with elastic demand: Some welfare economic considerations. European Economic Review, 42(1), 71-95. Emmerink, R.H.M., Axhausen, K.W., Nijkamp, P. and Rietveld, P. (1995a). The potential of information provision in a simulated road transport network with non-recurrent congestion. Transportation Research Part C, 3(5), 293-309. Emmerink, R.H.M., Axhausen, K.W., Nijkamp, P. and Rietveld, P. (1995b). Effects of information in road transport networks with recurrent congestion. Transportation, 22 (1), 21-53. Emmerink, R.H.M., Nijkamp, P., Rietveld, P. and Van Ommeren, J.N. (1996). Variable message signs and radio traffic information: an integrated empirical analysis of drivers' route choice behaviour. Transportation Research Part A, 30(2), 135-153. Gomez-Ibanez, J.A. and Small, K.A. eds. (1994). Road Pricing for Congestion Management: A Survey of International Practice. Transport Research Board, National Academic Press, Washington, DC. 29 Huang, H.J. and Li, Z. (2007). A multiclass, multicriteria logit-based traffic equilibrium assignment model under ATIS. European Journal of Operational Research, 176, 1464-1477. Huang, H.J. (1995). A combined algorithm for solving and calibrating the stochastic traffic assignment model. Journal of the Operational Research Society, 46, 977-987. Iida, Y., Akiyama, T. and Uchida, T. (1992). Experimental analysis of dynamic route choice behaviour. Transportation Research Part B, 26(1), 17-32. Jaber, X.Q. (2009). Analytical approaches to evaluating sustainable transportation strategies. Ph.D. thesis, Trinity College Dublin, Ireland. Jou, R.C., Lam, S.H., Liu, Y.H. and Chen, K.H. (2005). Route switching behaviour on freeways with the provision of different types of real-time traffic information. Transportation Research Part A, 39(5), 445-461. Kanninen, B. J. (1996). Intelligent transportation systems: An economic and environmental policy assessment. Transportation Research Part A, 30(1), 1-10. Khattak, A.J., Schofer, J.L. and Koppleman, F.S. (1995). Effect of traffic information on commuter's propensity to change route and departure time. Journal of Advanced Transportation, 29(2), 193-212. Lo, H. and Szeto, W.Y. (2002). A methodology for sustainable traveler information services. Transportation Research Part B, 36, 13-130. Lo, H. and Szeto, W.Y. (2004). Modeling advanced traveler information services: static versus dynamic paradigms. Transportation Research Part B, 38, 495-515. Mahmassani, H.S. and Jayakrishnan, R. (1991). System performance and user response under real-time information in a congested traffic corridor. Transportation Research Part A, 25(5), 293-308. 30 Mahmassani, H.S. and Liu, Y.H. (1999). Dynamics of commuting decision behaviour under advanced traveller information systems. Transportation Research Part C, 7, 91-107. Mannering, F., Kim, S.G., Barfield, W. and Ng, L. (1994). Statistical analysis of commuters' route, mode and departure time flexibility. Transportation Research Part C, 2(1), 3547. Nagurney, A. (2000). Sustainable Transport Networks. Edward Elgar Publishers, UK. Nagurney, A., Dong, J. and Mokhtarian, P. L. (2002). Traffic network equilibrium and the environment: a multicriteria decision-making perspective. In E. Kontoghiorges, B. Rustem, and S. Siokos, (Eds), Computational Methods in Decision-Making, Economics and Finance, Kluwer Academic Publishers, 501-523. Nagurney, A., Ramanujam, P. and Dhanda, K.K. (1998). A multimodal traffic network equilibrium model with emission pollution permits: compliance versus noncompliance. Transportation Research Part D, 3, 349-374. Niskanen, E.O. and Nash, C.A. (2008). Road pricing in Europe - a review of research in practice, In: C. Jensen-Butler, B. Sloth, M.M. Larsen, B. Madsen & O.A. Nielsen (Eds.), Road Pricing, the Economy and the Environment, Springer, Berlin, 5-28. Oppenheim. N. (1995). Urban Travel Demand Modelling: From Individual Choice to General Equilibrium. John Wiley & Sons, USA. Sheffi, Y. (1985). Urban Transportation Networks–Equilibrium Analysis with Mathematical Programming Methods, Prentice-Hall, Englewood Cliffs, NJ. Srinivasan, R., Kowshik, R., Vaughn, K., Srinivasan, K., Gard, J., Jovanis, P.P., and Kitamura, R. (1995). Advanced traveller information systems: opportunities and risks. Proceedings of the Transportation Congress, 1, 369-381 31 Szeto, W. Y., Jaber, X.Q. and O'Mahony, M. (2008). Paradoxes with the traveler information provision services. Proceedings of the 9th Intelligent Transport Systems Asia-Pacific Forum & Exhibition, Singapore, CD-ROM. Szeto, W.Y. (2007). Competition between information service providers and toll road operators: modeling frameworks. Journal of Intelligent Transportation Systems, 11(1), 41-56. Toledo, T. and Beinhaker, R. (2006). Evaluation of the potential benefits of advanced traveler information systems. Journal of Intelligent Transportation Systems, 10(4), 173-183. Tsirimpa, A., Polydoropoulou, A. and Antoniou, C. (2007). Development of a mixed multinomial logit model to capture the impact of information systems on travelers' switching behaviour. Journal of Intelligent Transportation Systems, 11(2), 79-89. Verhoef, E.T., Lindsey, C.R., Niskanen, E., De Palma, A., Moilanen, P., Proost, S. and Vold, A. (2008). Implementation paths for marginal-cost-based pricing in urban transport: Theoretical considerations and case study results, In: C. Jensen-Butler, B. Sloth, M.M. Larsen, B. Madsen & O.A. Nielsen (Eds.), Road Pricing, the Economy and the Environment, Springer, Berlin, 49-78. Verhoef, E.T., Nijkamp, P. and Rietveld, P. (1995). Second-best regulation of road transport externalities. Journal of Transport Economics and Policy, 29(2), 147-167. Yang, H. (1999). System optimum, stochastic user equilibrium and optimal link tolls. Transportation Science, 33(4), 354-360. Yang, H. and Huang, H.J. (2005). Mathematical and Economic Theory of Road Pricing. Amsterdam: Elsevier. Yang, H. and Zhang, X. (2002). Modelling competitive transit and road traffic information services with heterogeneous endogenous demand. Transportation Research Record, 1783, 7-16. 32 Yang, H. and Zhang, X.N. (2008). Existence of anonymous link tolls for system optimum on networks with mixed equilibrium behaviors. Transportation Research Part B, 42(2), 99-112. Yang, H., Kitamura, R., Jovanis, P.P., Vaughn, K.M. and Abdel-Aty, A. (1993). Exploration of route choice behavior with advanced traveler information using neural network concepts. Transportation, 20, 199-223. Zhang, X., Yang, H. and Huang, H.J. (2008). Multiclass multicriteria mixed equilibrium on networks and uniform link tolls for system optimum. European Journal of Operational Research, 189(1), 146-158. 33