Prepared by:
Kevin Richter, Douglas College
Charlene Richter,
British Columbia Institute of Technology
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
1
Introduction
Monopoly is a market structure in which a single firm makes up the entire market.
Monopolies exist because of barriers to entry into a market that prevent competition.
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
2
Introduction
Legal barriers , such as patents, prevent others from entering the market.
Sociological barriers – entry is prevented by custom or tradition.
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
3
Introduction
Natural barriers – the firm has a unique ability to produce what other firms can’t duplicate.
Technological barriers – the size of the market can support only one firm.
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
4
Differences Between a Monopolist and a Perfect Competitor
A competitive firm is too small to affect the price.
The monopolist takes into account the fact that its production decision can affect price.
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
5
Differences Between a Monopolist and a Perfect Competitor
A competitive firm's marginal revenue is the market price.
A monopolistic firm’s marginal revenue is not its price – it takes into account that in order to sell more it has to decrease the price of its product.
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
6
Differences Between a Monopolist and a Perfect Competitor
Monopolist as the only supplier faces the entire market demand curve.
Therefore, monopoly demand is downward sloping, and to increase output the firm must decrease its price.
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
7
Model of Monopoly
How much should the monopolistic firm choose to produce if it wants to maximize profit?
The monopolist employs a two-step profit maximizing process; it chooses quantity and price.
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
8
Monopolist’s Price and Output
Numerically
The first thing to remember is that marginal revenue is the change in total revenue that occurs as a firm changes its output.
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
9
Monopolist’s Price and Output
Numerically
When a monopolist increases output, it lowers the price on all previous units.
As a result, a monopolist’s marginal revenue is always below its price.
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
10
Monopolist’s Price and Output
Numerically
In order to maximize profit, a monopolist produces the output level at which marginal cost equals marginal revenue.
Producing at an output level where MR >
MC or where MR < MC will yield lower profits.
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
11
Profit Maximization for a Monopolist
Output Price TR
2
3
0
1
4
5
8
9
6
7
36
33
30
27
24
21
18
15
12
9
0
33
60
81
96
105
108
105
96
81
MR
—
33
27
21
15
9
3
–3
–9
–15
TC
47
48
50
54
62
78
102
142
196
278
MC
—
1
2
4
8
16
24
40
56
80
ATC Profit
48.00 –15
25.00
18.00
15.50
15.60
17.00
–47
10
27
34
27
6
20.29 –37
24.75 –102
30.89 –197
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
12
Monopolist’s Price and Output
Graphically
The marginal revenue curve is a graphical measure of the change in revenue that occurs in response to a change in price.
It tells us the additional revenue the firm will get from an additional unit of output.
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
13
Maximizing Output
If MR > MC , the monopolist gains profit by increasing output.
If MR < MC , the monopolist gains profit by decreasing output.
If MC = MR , the monopolist is maximizing profit.
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
14
Price a Monopolist Charges
The MR = MC condition determines the quantity a monopolist produces.
The monopolist will charge the maximum price consumers are willing to pay for that quantity.
That price is found on the demand curve.
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
15
Price a Monopolist Charges
To determine the profit-maximizing price
(where MC = MR), first find the profit maximizing output.
That quantity determines the price the monopolist will charge.
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
16
Determine Monopoly Price and Output
Price
$36
30
24
18
12
6
0
6
12
Monopolist price
MC
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
MR
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
D
17
Comparing Monopoly and Perfect
Competition
Equilibrium output for both the monopolist and the competitor is determined by the MC
= MR condition.
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
18
Comparing Monopoly and Perfect
Competition
Because the monopolist’s marginal revenue is below its price, price and quantity will not be the same as it is under perfect competition.
The monopolist’s equilibrium output is less than, and its price is higher than, for a firm in a competitive market.
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
19
Comparing Monopoly and Perfect
Competition
MC
Price
$36
30
24
18
12
6
0
6
12
Monopolist price
Competitive price
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10
MR
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
D
20
Profits and Monopoly
Draw the firm's marginal revenue curve.
Determine the output the monopolist will produce by the intersection of the MC and
MR curves.
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
21
Find Monopoly Price and Output
Price
MC
D
MR
Quantity
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
22
Profits and Monopoly
Determine the price the monopolist will charge for that output.
Determine the average cost at that level of output.
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
23
Find Monopoly Price and Output
Price
MC
P
M
MR
Q
M
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
D
Quantity
24
Profits and Monopoly
Determine the monopolist's profit (loss) by subtracting average total cost from average revenue ( P ) at that level of output and multiply by the chosen output.
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
25
Profits and Monopoly
The monopolist will make a profit if price exceeds average total cost.
The monopolist will make a normal return if price equal average total cost.
The monopolist will incur a loss if price is less than average total cost.
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
26
Monopolist Making a Profit
A monopolist can make a profit.
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
27
Monopolist Making a Profit
Price
MC
0
ATC
P
M
C
M
Profit
A
B
MR
Q
M
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
D
Quantity
28
Monopolist Breaking Even
A monopolist can break even.
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
29
Monopolist Breaking Even
Price
P
M
MC
ATC
0
MR
Q
M
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
D
Quantity
30
Monopolist Making a Loss
A monopolist can make a loss.
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
31
Monopolist Making a Loss
Price
C
M
P
M
Loss
B
A
MC
ATC
0
MR
Q
M
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
D
Quantity
32
Welfare Loss from Monopoly
People’s purchase decisions don’t reflect the true cost to society because monopolies charge a price higher than marginal cost.
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
33
Welfare Loss from Monopoly
The marginal cost of increasing output is lower than the marginal benefit of increasing output.
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
34
Welfare Loss from Monopoly
A single price monopoly creates welfare losses.
Welfare losses can be illustrated by the area of consumer and producer surplus that is lost due to smaller output produced, compared to output produced in perfect competition.
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
35
Welfare Loss from Monopoly
Compare the normal monopolist's equilibrium to the equilibrium of a perfect competitor.
Equilibrium in both market structures is determined by the MC = MR condition.
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
36
Welfare Loss from Monopoly
But the monopolist's MR is below its price, thus its equilibrium output is different from a competitive market.
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
37
Welfare Loss from Monopoly
The welfare loss of a monopolist is represented by the triangles B and D .
The welfare loss is often called the deadweight loss or welfare loss triangle .
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
38
Welfare Loss from Monopoly
Price
MC
P
M
P
C
0
C
D
B
A
MR
Q
M
Q
C
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
D
Quantity
39
Price-Discriminating Monopolist
Price discrimination is the ability to charge different prices to different individuals or groups of individuals.
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
40
Price-Discriminating Monopolist
In order to price discriminate, a monopolist must be able to:
Identify groups of customers who have different elasticities of demand;
Separate them in some way; and
Limit their ability to resell its product between groups.
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
41
Price-Discriminating Monopolist
A price-discriminating monopolist can increase both output and profit.
It can charge customers with more inelastic demands a higher price.
It can charge customers with more elastic demands a lower price.
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
42
Price Discrimination Occurs in the
Real World
Movie theaters give senior citizens and child discounts.
Airline seat sales usually require Saturday night stopovers.
Automobiles are seldom sold at their sticker price.
Theaters have midweek special rates.
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
43
Price-Discriminating Monopolist
A perfect price discriminating monopoly will stop expanding its output when MR = MC, which corresponds to the perfectly competitive output.
The deadweight loss is therefore eliminated under perfect price discrimination.
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
44
Perfect Price Discrimination
Price
4
3
6
5
10
9
8
7
2
1
MC
D=MR
1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11
MR
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All
Quantity (number of consumers) rights reserved.
45
Barriers to Entry and Monopoly
What prevents other firms from entering the monopolist’s market in response to profits the monopolist earns?
Monopolies exist because of barriers to entry .
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
46
Barriers to Entry and Monopoly
Barrier to entry – a social, political, or economic impediment that prevents firms from entering the market.
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
47
Barriers to Entry and Monopoly
In the absence of barriers to entry, the monopoly would face competition from other firms, which would erode its monopoly position .
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
48
Barriers to Entry and Monopoly
Economies of scale:
When production is characterized by increasing returns to scale, the larger the firm becomes, the lower its per unit costs become.
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
49
Economies of Scale
If significant economies of scale are possible, it is inefficient to have two producers.
If each produced half of the output, neither could take advantage of economies of scale.
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
50
Economies of Scale
A natural monopoly is an industry in which one firm can produce at a lower cost than can two or more firms.
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
51
Barriers to Entry and Monopoly
Economies of scale:
In cases of natural monopoly, technology is such that minimum efficient scale is so large that average total costs decrease over the range of potential output.
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
52
Natural Monopoly
C
3
C
2
C
1
0
ATC
Q
⅓
Q
½
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
Q
1
Quantity
53
Economies of Scale
There is no welfare loss in the natural monopoly situation.
There can actually be a welfare gain because a single firm is so much more efficient than several firms producing the good.
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
54
Natural Monopoly
P
M
C
M
Profit
C
C
P
C
0
Loss
MR
Q
M
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
Q
C
ATC
MC
D
Quantity
55
Barriers to Entry and Monopoly
Set-up costs:
In many industries high set-up costs characterize production.
The industry may be highly capital-intensive, requiring a large investment in expensive but highly specialized capital.
Examples are an oil refinery or a diamond mine.
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
56
Barriers to Entry and Monopoly
Set-up costs:
In some industries a lot of money may be spent on advertising.
Heavy advertising creates a barrier to entry in those cases, such as in the perfume industry or the automobile industry.
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
57
Barriers to Entry and Monopoly
Legislation:
Monopolies can also exist as a result of government charter.
Patents are another way in which government can grant a company a monopoly.
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
58
Barriers to Entry and Monopoly
Legislation:
A patent is a legal protection of technical innovation that gives the inventor a monopoly on using the invention.
To encourage research and development of new products, government gives out patents for a wide variety of innovations.
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
59
Barriers to Entry and Monopoly
Other barriers to entry:
Sometimes one company can gain ownership of some essential aspect of the production process, a unique input, or control over a resource.
An example is DeBeers. By controlling the worldwide distribution network for diamonds, the company enjoys a monopoly in the diamond industry.
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
60
Normative Views of Monopoly
The public generally views monopolies the way the Classical economists did – they consider them unfair and wrong.
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
61
Normative Views of Monopoly
Some normative arguments against monopoly include:
Income distributional effects associated with monopoly.
Rent-seeking activities in which people spend resources to lobby government for the monopoly power.
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
62
Normative Views of Monopoly
The public does not like the distributional effects of monopoly.
They believe that it transfers income from
“deserving” consumers to “undeserving” monopolists.
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
63
Normative Views of Monopoly
It is possible for the well-financed and the well-connected to garner government favours.
The public prefers that firms do productive things rather than lobby for government favours.
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
64
Government Policy and Monopoly:
AIDS Drugs
The patents for AIDS drugs are owned by a small group of pharmaceutical companies.
They can charge a very high price for a drug whose marginal cost is very low.
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
65
Government Policy and Monopoly:
AIDS Drugs
What, if anything, should the government do?
Government could force the producer to charge a price equal to its marginal cost.
Society would be better off but this would create a significant disincentive for drug companies to do further research on other life-threatening diseases.
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
66
Government Policy and Monopoly:
AIDS Drugs
Another alternative is for the government to buy the patents and allow anyone to produce the drugs.
Payment would come from increased taxes and would be quite expensive.
The cost of regulation would decrease, but it would raise the question as to which patents the government should buy.
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
67
End of Chapter 11
© 2006 McGraw-Hill Ryerson Limited. All rights reserved.
68