PUBLIC HIGHER EDUCATION SPENDING AND ECONOMIC GROWTH: THE ROLE OF THE PRIVATE MARKET FOR HIGHER EDUCATION AND THE MEDIATING EFFECT OF EDUCATIONAL ATTAINMENT A Thesis Presented to the faculty of the Department of Economics California State University, Sacramento Submitted in partial satisfaction of the requirements for the degree of MASTER OF ARTS in Economics by Cary Garcia Jr. FALL 2013 PUBLIC HIGHER EDUCATION SPENDING AND ECONOMIC GROWTH: THE ROLE OF THE PRIVATE MARKET FOR HIGHER EDUCATION AND THE MEDIATING EFFECT OF EDUCATIONAL ATTAINMENT A Thesis by Cary Garcia Jr. Approved by __________________________________, Committee Chair Suzanne O’Keefe, Ph.D. __________________________________, Second Reader Kristin Kiesel, Ph.D. ___________________________ Date ii Student: Cary Garcia Jr. I certify that this student has met the requirements for format contained in the University format manual, and that this thesis is suitable for shelving in the Library and credit is to be awarded for the thesis. __________________________, Graduate Coordinator ___________________ Kristin Kiesel, Ph.D. Date Department of Economics iii Abstract of PUBLIC HIGHER EDUCATION SPENDING AND ECONOMIC GROWTH: THE ROLE OF THE PRIVATE MARKET FOR HIGHER EDUCATION AND THE MEDIATING EFFECT OF EDUCATIONAL ATTAINMENT by Cary Garcia Jr. This thesis revisits the effect of public higher education spending on economic growth. The data used covers all 50 U.S. States over the time period from 1989-2006. Unlike previous studies, we have included the variation in the composition of the market for higher education from state to state. In addition, a 2SLS model was specified, where public higher education spending had an indirect effect on economic growth through educational attainment. The results suggest that the relationship between public higher education spending and economic growth is only positive in those states with the smallest markets for private higher education. Also, results indicated that public higher education spending has a negative relationship with educational attainment. However, this negative effect decreases in states with larger markets for private higher education. _______________________, Committee Chair Suzanne O’Keefe, Ph.D. _______________________ Date iv ACKNOWLEDGEMENTS I would first like to thank my parents, my family and friends who have supported me in all my endeavors. I also want to thank my partner, Katherine Valenzuela, for her patience and encouragement. Lastly I want to thank the professors who have guided and assisted me in writing this thesis, Suzanne O’Keefe and Kristin Kiesel. v TABLE OF CONTENTS Page Acknowledgements ............................................................................................................. v List of Tables ................................................................................................................... viii List of Figures .................................................................................................................... ix Chapter 1. INTRODUCTION ............................................................................................... 1 2. LITERATURE REVIEW .................................................................................... 4 2.1 Human Capital Theory ......................................................................................... 4 2.2 Public Higher Education Spending and Economic Growth ................................. 5 2.3 The Market for Higher Education ........................................................................ 7 2.4 Educational Attainment ........................................................................................ 9 3. EMPIRICAL MODEL AND DATA ................................................................. 12 3.1 Empirical Model ................................................................................................. 12 3.2 Data .................................................................................................................... 16 3.3 Summary Statistics and Time Trends................................................................. 18 4. ESTIMATION ISSUES AND RESULTS ......................................................... 24 4.1 Estimation Issues ................................................................................................ 24 4.2 Initial Results...................................................................................................... 25 vi 4.3 Interaction Variable Results ............................................................................... 27 4.4 2SLS Results ...................................................................................................... 32 5. CONCLUSION .................................................................................................. 38 5.1 Summary of Findings ......................................................................................... 38 5.2 Future Research .................................................................................................. 42 References ......................................................................................................................... 44 vii LIST OF TABLES Table Page Table 3.1 Variable Definitions and Sources ..................................................................... 18 Table 3.2 Summary Statistics ........................................................................................... 19 Table 4.1 Initial Estimates ................................................................................................ 27 Table 4.2 Interaction Variable Estimates .......................................................................... 29 Table 4.3 Higher Education Attainment Estimates (First Stage of 2SLS) ....................... 33 Table 4.4 Final 2SLS Estimates ........................................................................................ 36 viii LIST OF FIGURES Figure Page Figure 3.1 State Average Income Per Capita and Public Higher Education Appropriations Per Capita ........................................................................................................ 21 Figure 3.2 State Average Income Per Capita and Higher Education Attainment ............. 22 Figure 3.3 State Average Public Higher Education Appropriations Per Capita and Higher Education Attainment ..................................................................................... 23 Figure 4.1 Average Appropriations Per Capita and Average Share of Total Students Attending Public Institutions for 50 States ..................................................... 32 ix 1 1. INTRODUCTION According to recent figures from National Center for Education Statistics, tuition for public higher education institutions rose by 30% from 1980 to 1990. It then increased by another 22% from 1990 to 2000. Finally in the most recent decade from 2000 to 2010 it increased by 42%. Although the amount of expenditure or spending on public higher education by states has increased in the past decades, the National Association of State Budget Officers points out that tuition has continued to rise and percentage of state spending on public higher education as a percentage of total state budgets has decreased from 13.1% in 1998 to 10.1% in 2011. It seems that state governments are reducing their investments in public higher education and are placing that burden more on students and their families. The role of the government is important in the financing of higher education. Without government intervention the role of financing higher education would be left mostly to students and families. In a scenario with no public option for higher education, a financially constrained family may be unable to access education in the private market. Families unable to afford post-secondary education would then lag behind their more wealthy counterparts who would be increasing their earning power and becoming more wealthy with advanced skills and education. This inevitably leads to greater social inequality. Therefore the government then has the role to either provide or subsidize education for the public to reduce inequality (Becker, 1981; Bräuninger & Vidal, 2000). With spending on public higher education being reduced relative to state government budgets, it is important that those investments are efficient and therefore 2 provide the most benefit to the public. Many studies have investigated the relationship between higher education spending by government and the impact it has on the economy. The basis for these investigations has often been the work of Becker (1962) and Schultz (1963).They proposed that spending on higher education is an investment in human capital that positively impacts economic growth in a similar manner as physical capital investments. There are many studies that have investigated the relationship between government investments in human capital through higher education spending across countries, but there is no common understanding of what effect state government spending on higher education has on economic growth. Furthermore, the link between the products of those investments, an educated workforce, has not been clearly presented in such a way that links all three parts; the investment, the human capital and the economic impact of that investment. Consequently the purpose of this thesis is to conduct an empirical analysis that would illustrate the positive causal link between each part. This analysis is unique for two reasons. First it is one of the few studies that have taken into account the private market for higher education in an analysis of public higher education spending and economic growth. Second it may be the only study that has tested the role of the private market for higher education in an analysis of public higher education spending and educational attainment. This thesis first begins with a review of the literature to provide a theoretical and methodological foundation for the analysis. Next, we provide the empirical model and summarize the data used. Here is where the general functional form of the statistical 3 models will be presented along with descriptions of the variables and corresponding expectations. And finally, the results will be summarized and suggestions for future research will be presented. 4 2. LITERATURE REVIEW Still very little has been done in terms of understanding the effects of higher education spending specifically as a component of human capital theory and there is no consensus on what effect this spending has on growth. It seems though that significant and positive results may be found in models that take into account the composition of the market for higher education. By including these differences along with the possible mediating effect of educational attainment, we may be able to better examine how education spending affects states’ economic growth. Although the theoretical background exists to support the hypothesis that public higher education spending positively influences economic growth and empirical evidence exists in cross national studies, when tested empirically on the United States the results are often mixed. This literature review begins with a section discussing human capital theory and its importance to the analysis of public higher education spending’s effect on economic growth. Then we will focus on empirical analyses that investigate the role of the market for higher education and the mediating effect of educational attainment. 2.1 Human Capital Theory Most studies that attempt to understand the relationship between education and economic growth are dependent on the human capital theory pioneered by Becker (1962) and Schultz (1963). Becker (1962) explains that by focusing on intangible characteristics across countries, such as knowledge possessed, rather than differences in physical capital, we can arrive at a better explanation of differences in income among people and across 5 countries.1 Since investments in human capital are closely tied with these intangible characteristics it would seem that examining changes in human capital investments would provide an explanation of differences in growth across countries. Furthermore, if the primary benefits of human capital investments are to increase the physical and mental abilities of the population so as to increase real income, then it is through this process that investments in education improve the mental abilities of the workforce and in turn increase economic growth (Barro, 2001; Becker, 1962; Lucas Jr, 1988). 2.2 Public Higher Education Spending and Economic Growth If investments in education are a key component of economic growth then where do these investments come from when looking at the United States? Bräuninger & Vidal (2000) in their study of private versus public financing of education and inequality, call education “the crossing of three institutions, the Market, the Family and the State.” Using human capital theory as a basis for their analysis, Bräuninger & Vidal (2000) propose that parents are largely responsible for the decision of whether or not to educate their children. The decision to educate is then based on three factors: the parents’ wage rate, degree of intergenerational altruism, and the private cost of education. In the presence of a borrowing constraint, the market is not a viable option for the financing of education, thus the family and the state become the primary financiers of education (Becker, 1981). If families were to finance education on their own, then those families with the greatest wage rates would be more able to afford education for their children while less wealthy 1 The knowledge possessed by the workforce is often explained to increase either by learning by doing (onthe-job training) or through formal schooling (Becker, 1962; Lucas Jr, 1988) 6 families would forgo the decision to educate holding the other two factors equal. Thus the State then has the role of financing education through loans and subsidization to lower the financial burned placed upon families and reduce inequality (Bräuninger & Vidal, 2000). In contrast with Bräuninger & Vidal’s hypothesis, some economists have found that the effect of public higher education spending on economic growth is nil if not negative. Wang and Davis (2005) studied the U.S. states excluding Alaska and Hawaii over a 20 year period from 1980 to 2000 using a fixed effects panel analysis. Looking at the major areas of government expenditure and the varying effects on economic growth, they found that changes in public education expenditures, combining elementary, secondary and higher education expenditures, did not have any positive effects on growth. They agree that investments in education can improve the workforce and increase income, but they blame the inefficiency of state governments’ use of funds for the negative results of their analysis. Furthermore, Wang and Davis (2005) suggest that ineffective state expenditure on education is crowding out private sector spending, thus leading to low levels of growth. Vedder (2004) too believes in this crowding out theory when it comes to public higher education investments. Using state-level data for the United States including the District of Columbia from 1977 to 2002, he measured total spending by state and local institutions on higher education. He found that it was negatively related with growth in real income per capita. Furthermore he found no significantly positive relationship between higher education expenditure and enrollments. Vedder explains that his results 7 do not support the existence of positive externalities and equality and even suggests that there may be negative externalities from spending on higher education i.e the crowding out of private market spending. Moreover he argues that higher education institutions may simply be screening devices for employers that lower information costs. A key issue with the findings of Vedder’s analysis is that the results do not include state fixed effects or time effects and therefor do not address across state variation or time trends. It is possible that with 50 diverse states , there may be unexplained variation from state to state that may distort results if using model without state fixed effects. The same may be true for not accounting for any unexplained variation over time as there may be large scale economic trends that vary over time and affect the country as a whole. 2.3 The Market for Higher Education Another part of this thesis focuses on the role the market for higher education plays in the relationship between public higher education spending and economic growth. In studies that have found positive effects from an increase in public higher education spending by states, the research has generally focused on the non-homogeneity of states such as the economic, polticial and demographic differences. Returning to the work of Bräuninger & Vidal (2000), they constructed an endogenous growth model to see what effect an increase in public or private funding on higher education would have on economic growth. With their model they showed that a mixed system of public and private financing of education would lead to lower economic growth, whereas a system that financed exclusively by either public or private means 8 would experience greater growth. Furthermore they found that the greatest levels of long term growth would be achieved in a system where education was completely subsidized by the government. Bräuninger & Vidal continue to further the thought that the effect of state spending on higher education on growth is not homogenous across the country. They found that in a system that was dominated by the public market, an increase in subsidization from an already high level, would increase growth. On the other hand, in a system that was dominated by the private market for education and therefore had a low level of subsidization, an increase in the public subsidy had the opposite effect. In observing the 50 U.S. states from 1970-2005 Curs, Bhandari, and Steiger (2011) found that public education expenditure increased income growth per capita. Their investigation was based on a state fixed effects and time fixed effects model that included the interaction between the percentage of college students attending public institutions and the public higher education expenditure. The percentage of college students attending public institutions was used as a proxy measurement of the size of the private market for higher education. For example, when comparing two states, a state with a smaller share of students attending public institutions would suggest a larger market private market for higher education within that state. They believed that omission of the market for higher education in an analysis of public higher education expenditure’s effect on economic growth would lead to negative omitted variable bias. In agreement with Bräuninger and Vidal (2000) they discovered that spending on higher education had different effects on growth based on composition of the market for 9 higher education in each state. Their results showed that states which had a larger market for private higher education and thus a smaller percentage of college students attending public institutions would see a smaller or even negative effect from public higher education expenditure on economic growth. On the other hand, a state which had a comparatively smaller private market for higher education would experience a more positive impact from higher education expenditure by the government. Specifically they found that percentage exceeding about 70% would produce positive effects. Although using the share of students attending public institutions as a measure of the private market for higher education does not give a complete picture of the true market size it seemed to provide a good proxy measurement. 2.4 Educational Attainment Some studies have hypothesized that increases in state public higher education expenditure would increase higher education graduation rates and therefore educational attainment of the population. Zhang (2008) examined this topic, focusing on institutionallevel graduation rates. Using a 6-year cohort survey of graduation rates for 2004 from the Integrated Postsecondary Education System, Zhang developed a panel model controlling for institution differences and time trends with the addition of institutional fixed effects and time fixed effects. Zhang explains that although some studies have found a positive link between instructional expenditure only and graduation rates, the results of his analysis suggest that at a broader level, state public higher education expenditure overall is the primary determinant of graduation rates. Specifically he found that an increase in public higher 10 education expenditure of 10% per Full Time Equivalent student at 4-year public institutions would increase the graduation rate about 0.64%. He argues that this is the result of resource dependence, which states that internal organizational activities are influenced primarily by the actions of external resource providers, i.e. state spending budgets and public higher education systems. Furthermore, this would mean that a decline in public higher education appropriations would lead to reduced instructional expenditures for public higher education institutions and therefore a reduction in the graduation rate. Baldwin, Borrelli, and New (2011) took a different approach with their analysis and developed a model that attempted to inlcude both the direct effect of public higher education expenditure and the effect mediated by educational attainment. Using a path analysis controlling for time trends for the 48 states from 1988-2005, they found that college attainment levels was one of the most consistent predictors of GSP per capita growth. Furthermore, they theorized that by using the path analysis they would find that higher education can impact economic growth on two fronts: the direct impact of increasing the funding of colleges and universities and what they consider an indirect impact, increasing educational attainment of the population.2 Although Baldwin et al. found that public higher education expenditure had a positive direct effect on economic growth, they also discovered a negative mediating effect from educational attainment. 2 The direct effect of expenditure on higher education may be due to the current trend in higher education institutions demonstrating that they are regionally focused institutions that provide more than educated graduates by also providing research and development as well as technical services to nearby businesses or government institutions and other economic development activities (Storm & Feiock, 1999). 11 The results of Baldwin et al. do not agree with Becker (1962), Schultz (1963) Lucas Jr (1988) and human capitol theory. One possibility though, is that the omission of the private market for higher education may also negatively bias public higher education expenditure’s effect on educational attainment in similar way that was suggested by Curs et al. (2011) when studying the direct effects of public higher education spending on economic growth. Baldwin et al. also bring up this likelihood in the discussion of their results. 12 3. 3.1 EMPIRICAL MODEL AND DATA Empirical Model In line with previous research, this paper will use a growth model where economic growth is a function of state government spending on higher education. The basic form of the model will be the following: %βπΌππΆπππΈππΆππ‘ = πΌπΈπ·ππΈπππΆππ‘ + πΏπ‘ + ππ + πππ‘ (1) Specifically %βπΌππΆπππΈππΆππ‘ is the growth rate of real income per capita and πΈπ·ππΈπππΆππ‘ is per capita dollars expended on state public higher education. πΏπ‘ and ππ are included as time fixed effects and state fixed effects respectively. The time fixed effects will control for omitted variables that may change over time but do not vary from state to state while the state fixed effects will control for omitted variables that may change from state to state but do not vary with time. Lastly πππ‘ is the idiosyncratic error term. Based on human capital theory we would expect the coefficient for state higher education would be positive, but as explained in the review of literature and the various studies with both positive and negative results the expected sign is somewhat ambiguous. If we accept the findings of Curs et al. (2011), where the omission of the private market for higher education negatively biases the effect of higher education spending, then we must develop the above model further. It will thus take the form: %ΔπΌππΆπππΈππΆππ‘ = πΌπΈπ·ππΈπππΆππ‘ + π½πππ΅πΏπΌπΆππ»π΄π πΈππ‘ + ππΈπ·ππΈπππΆππ‘ × πππ΅πΏπΌπΆππ»π΄π πΈππ‘ +πΏπ‘ + ππ + πππ‘ (2) In this equation we have included our proxy for the composition of the market for education, the share of college students enrolled in public institutions, 13 as πππ΅πΏπΌπΆππ»π΄π πΈππ‘ . Also we have the interaction between public higher education spending and the public share in the market education. Goldin and Katz (1998) explained that across time the shares of public to private enrollments are stable within each state. Therefore, it cannot be expected that small changes in enrollments will have any significant effects on economic growth. By using the interaction between enrollments and spending we will be allowing the effects of states’ spending to vary across different state enrollment patterns and thus different markets for higher education (Curs et al., 2011). It is expected that because of the lack of variation in the composition of the market for higher education within states over time, we will not find any significant results for the share of students attending public higher education institutions. On the other hand, we expect that the interaction between public higher education spending and the percentage of students enrolled in public institutions will yield positive results. This would then suggest that there is a difference in the impact of public higher education spending which is dependent on the composition of the market for higher education in each state. Specifically we should find that in comparison to states with larger private markets for higher education, states that have a greater dependence on public institutions for higher education would see a more positive effect from public higher education spending per capita. Along with explanatory variables focused on education, we will also include some economic control variables. Our first variable will be the growth rate of the population for each state, which may have a negative impact on income growth per capita if population growth exceeds growth in income. Then we include total government 14 spending per capita, to control for other state spending. The result for this variable may be ambiguous based on previous studies that did not find significant results for government spending as a whole (Devarajan, Swaroop, & Zou, 1996; Hsieh & Lai, 1994). Finally, we have variables for agriculture, manufacturing, mining, and the finance, insurance, and real estate industries measured as a percentage of GSP. Agriculture we would expect to be positive but may have a marginal impact on growth and may slow growth for states largely dependent on agriculture output due to the fact that agriculture output growth for the United States was just above one percent from 1990 to 2004 (United States Department of Agriculture, 2013). We expect a similar result with the mining industry as the average growth rate across the nation was less than one percent over the same time period (Bureau of Economic Analysis, 2013). The next model will be treating educational attainment as a function of public higher education per capita. This will take the following form: π΅π΄25ππ‘ = πΌπΈπ·ππΈπππΆππ‘ + π½πππ΅πΏπΌπΆππ»π΄π πΈππ‘ + ππΈπ·ππΈπππΆππ‘ × πππ΅πΏπΌπΆππ»π΄π πΈππ‘ + πΏπ‘ +ππ + πππ‘ (3) Here our measure of educational attainment is π΅π΄25ππ‘ . This variable is measured as the percentage of the population 25 years old and older that has achieved at least a bachelor’s degree. Then we have simply included public higher education spending, the percentage of students attending public institutions, the interaction term from the previous equation as well state fixed effects and time fixed effects. Since Baldwin et al. found a negative relationship between public higher education spending and educational 15 attainment we expect that the inclusion of the proxy measurement for the size of private higher education market would remove negative omitted variable bias similar to expectations for the second model presented. The third model used in the two-stage least squares (2SLS) analysis, where the model of educational attainment will become the first stage of the estimation and educational attainment will be treated as an endogenous variable that will be instrumented using the independent variables from the second equation that was presented. If we are treating higher education spending as an investment in human capital, it is reasonable that we should include the product of that investment in our analysis. If it is expected that an educated workforce leads to economic growth, then higher education spending and educational attainment are two parts of one process (Barro, 2001; Becker, 1962, 1993; Lucas Jr, 1988). As discussed in the review of the literature, Baldwin, Borrelli, and New (2011) used a path analysis to examine the direct effect of higher education expenditure itself and the indirect effects via educational attainment levels. Specifically when tested they found that public higher education spending had a significant negative effect on educational attainment. They proposed that this was likely due to not including the market for private education in their model. We test this hypothesis by using the third model as the first stage for the 2SLS model. We will essentially be examining the indirect effects of public higher education spending on economic growth through the mediating effect of educational attainment like Baldwin, et al. Specifically, we will be using public higher education spending, the share of students attending public institutions and the 16 interaction between these two variables as the primary instruments for predicting educational attainment. 3.2 Data As mentioned previously, the data for this analysis covers the 50 United States for 18 years from 1989-2006. Table 3.1 lists definitions and sources for the key variables. All dollars values used in this analysis are in real 2005 dollars. The Grapevine surveys of financial officers of public higher education institutions produced by Illinois State University’s Center for the Study of Education Policy provided state-level data for state appropriations for public higher education including grants and financial aid for all degree granting institutions, which will serve as our measure of public higher education spending. The annual Digest of Education Statistics produced by the National Center for Education Statistics (NCES) contained data for public and private enrollments, of which the share of total college students attending public institutions was calculated. Data for the last education related variable, higher education attainment of the population 25 years old or older, was gathered from U.S. Census Bureau’s annual data tables from their Current Population Survey. The data for measuring income per capita growth rates and the size of agricultural, manufacturing, mining and finance, insurance and real estate industries was gathered from the Bureau of Economic Analysis’s interactive data tables. The data for total government expenditure was gathered from annual volumes of the U.S. Census Bureau’s Statistical Abstract of the United States. The BEA’s interactive data tables were used to gather population data produced by the U.S. Census Bureau. This data was used 17 to derive the per capita measurements of income growth, higher education expenditure, total government expenditure as well as the annual population growth rates for each state. It is expected that since higher education expenditure is an investment over time, it will have a delayed effect on economic growth. Therefore, a lagged three-year moving average centered on t-5 will be used in the models tested. Data from the 2000/2001 Baccalaureate and Beyond Longitudinal Study by the NCES showed that among students surveyed, the average time to graduation for students seeking 4-year degrees at public institutions was 57.2 months or just under five years. Also, of those surveyed over 33 percent took six years or more to graduate (National Center for Education Statistics, 2003). 3 3 The variable for the share of college students attending public higher education institutions and total expenditures per capita will also be used as lagged three-year moving average centered on t-5. 18 Table 3.1 Variable Definitions and Sources Variables Dependent %ΔINCOMEPC Definitions and Sources Annual percentage change in real income per capita (BEA) Explanatory EDUEXPC State higher education appropriations per capita ( BEA, Grapevine) PUBLICSHARE The percentage of total college students enrolled in public institutions (NCES) BA25 The percentage of the population over 25 years old who has attained a bachelor’s degree or more (U.S. Census Bureau) %ΔPOP Annual percentage growth in population ( BEA) TEXPPC Total government expenditure per capita (U.S. Census Bureau) AG The size of the agricultural industry as a percentage of GSP (BEA) MAN The size of the manufacturing industry as a percentage of GSP (BEA) MIN The size of the mining industry as a percentage of GSP (BEA) FIRE The size of the finance, insurance and real estate industries as a percentage of GSP (BEA) 3.3 Summary Statistics and Time Trends Table 3.2 provides summary statistics for the variables used in this analysis. Wyoming, the Dakotas and Louisiana had the top average growth rates for income per capita above 2.5%, with Wyoming experiencing an average growth rate of 3.6%.Alaska and Michigan have the lowest growth rates of income per capita at 1.2% and 1.3% respectively. 19 Table 3.2 Summary Statistics Variables Dependent Mean Std. Dev. Max Min 0.0204246 0.0203195 0.0989778 -0.0371158 EDUEXPC 184.6575 51.08501 337.479 64.04503 PUBLICSHARE 0.7946073 0.1210606 0.9935223 0.4251673 BA25 0.2366244 0.0501337 0.404 0.111 %ΔPOP 0.0112213 0.0098133 0.0732498 -0.0598613 TEXPPC 425.71 1487.04 13305.61 1585.72 AG 0.0199968 0.02052 0.1260822 0.0015239 MAN 0.15238 0.0657023 0.3146684 0.0185499 MIN 0.0244665 0.0534322 0.3760898 0.0001301 FIRE 0.179982 0.0555591 0.4653468 0.0739304 %ΔINCOMEPC Explanatory When looking at public higher education appropriations per capita from 19892006, Wyoming, Alaska and Hawaii have the highest annual average of over $300. The next three highest states are New Mexico, North Dakota and North Carolina spending $296, $268 and $265 per capita respectively. New Hampshire spends the least averaging $77 dollars annually. The majority of the schools that spend the least per capita are in the North Eastern region of the United States except for Missouri which spends less than $145 per capita. The average across the country is about $184 per capita annually. Total state government spending per capita, seems to have the highest values in states with smaller populations. Alaska and Hawaii have averages of $11,367 and $6,036 per capita respectively. New York is an exception with total state government spending 20 per capita of $5,588. The states with the least amount of state government spending per capita are all in the South. Missouri, Tennessee, Florida and Texas all have an average below $3,200 per capita. Turning to share of students attending public institutions, we find that only one state, Massachusetts, has a majority of students attending private institutions. Over half the states have at least 80% of college students attending public institutions. Five states have over 90% of college students attending public institutions including Wyoming and Nevada at average rates of 96%. Along with the North Eastern region of the country spending less public funds they also expectedly have a greater reliance on private institutions for higher education than the rest of the country. As for educational attainment levels, the Southern region has the lowest levels of higher education attainment. West Virginia has the lowest level of higher education attainment at 14% of the population 25 years old and older achieving a bachelor’s degree or more. The exceptions are Texas and Georgia. They averaged levels of 23%, close to the national average. Colorado, Massachusetts, Connecticut and Maryland lead the country with average college attainment levels over 30%. Since the central focus of this thesis is the effect of higher education spending on economic growth, we consider real income per capita for the 50 United States from 19892006. As Figure 3.1 shows, average income per capita grows fairly consistently at rate of about 2% until 2000, after which growth averages 3% per year. 21 Figure 3.1 State Average Income Per Capita and Public Higher Education Appropriations Per Capita $40,000 $290 $270 $35,000 $230 $30,000 $210 2005 Dollars 2005 Dollars $250 $190 $25,000 $170 $20,000 $150 Income Per Capita Appropriations Per Capita Figure 3.1 also illustrates the growth of higher education appropriations per capita over the same time period. Appropriations grow at about the same rate as income per capita, about two to three percent per year. This trend appears to change beginning in the 2003-2004 period as appropriations grow seven and eight percent for the next two years while income per capita sees less dramatic growth. Overall this graph is unable to show a clear picture of the lagged effect of higher education spending on the economy. Examining the trends of income per capita and higher education attainment in Figure 3.2, it appears that attainment grows at a similar rate as income per capita. You may notice that a slight inverse relationship appears to emerge. In 1990 we see attainment grow by seven percent while income decreases by one percent, while in 2000 we see that 22 attainment grows by only one percent and income increases by five percent. It is entirely possible that during bad economic times more of the population returns to school and obtains a degree to increase personal income which would explain this relationship. If we expect educational attainment to have a positive impact on income growth per capita, the trend of the graph suggests that we may not find a positive relationship in our analysis. In addition, if we look at Figure 3.3 we can see that there is also no clear relationship between educational attainment and higher education appropriations per capita. Figure 3.2 State Average Income Per Capita and Higher Education Attainment 30% $35,000 2005 Dollars 25% $30,000 20% $25,000 $20,000 15% Income Per Capita Attainment Percentage of Populations > 25 Years Old $40,000 23 Figure 3.3 State Average Public Higher Education Appropriations Per Capita and Higher Education Attainment $270 2005 Dollars $250 25% $230 $210 20% $190 $170 $150 15% Appropriations Per Capita Attainment Percentage of Populations > 25 Years Old 30% $290 24 4. ESTIMATION ISSUES AND RESULTS For comparative purposes we began our estimation first testing no effects, state fixed effects only, time fixed effects only and combined state fixed effects and time fixed effects models for best fit. Next we present the estimation results for the addition of the interaction between the share of total college students attending public higher education institutions and public higher education spending per capita. Finally we will estimate the 2SLS model using public higher education spending per capita and the interaction term as an instrument for educational attainment. 4.1 Estimation Issues Before discussing the results of the estimation, there are several issues that need to be addressed. First, the inclusion of state fixed effects may become an issue because as mentioned previously, there is little within state variation when observing the share of students attending public higher education institutions. Beck (2001) explains that with variables that change slowly over time the use of fixed effects will make it difficult to derive any meaningful or significant estimates. Therefore the addition of the interaction term will let us measure public higher education spending’s effect in each state’s particular mix of public and private college enrollments. Another issue that is usually addressed in models that estimate the effect of any type of government spending and economic growth is that government spending may be endogenous. In this case it is possible that the growth of the economy may influence the amount of funds spent on public higher education. Lags are often used to address such issues. Since we are using a lagged three-year moving average centered on the t-5, based 25 on the findings from the National Center for Education Statistics (2003) discussed earlier, we have alleviated this problem. 4.2 Initial Results The results of our baseline (Model 1), fixed effects only (Model 2), time effects only (Model 3) and the state fixed and time effects (Model 4) models are shown in Table 4.1. Table 4.2 contains models 5-7 which show estimates with the addition of the interaction between public higher education spending and the share of college students attending public institutions. Looking at the results of our initial estimates, we can clearly see that there are some differences across models using state fixed effects and time effects. It is important to note the distinction in how coefficients are identified between the models with and without the state fixed effects. In a model without state fixed effects the variation across states is what determines the effect of the coefficients, whereas a model with state fixed effects, the variation within states determines the effect. Looking first at goodness of fit the model the two models with the lowest Rsquared values are the baseline model and the state fixed effects only model with Rsquared values of .073 and .215 respectively. The highest R-squared of 0.572 is the combined state fixed effects and time effects with the time effects only model not far behind with an R-squared of 0.486. Since it is likely that there are variations across states as well as variations over time that we are not able to capture with the variables we have specified in our analysis, we will use a combination of state fixed effects and time effects to control for such unexplained variation. F-tests confirm that the state fixed effects and 26 time effects are justifiable in our specification, therefore the additional estimates after the initial estimation are reported including both fixed effects. Also the discussion of the initial estimates will focus on the inclusion of both fixed effects results unless otherwise noted. First looking at control variables, we find the population growth variable is not statistically significant. Then we have the total expenditure per capita model which was also a lagged three year moving average like the public higher education expenditure per capita. This variable produces an insignificant negative coefficient. Finally we have the industry size variables, agriculture, mining, manufacturing and the finance, insurance and real estate industries as a percentage of GSP. All of these variables have positive coefficients but only agriculture, mining, and manufacturing produce statistically significant values. This suggests that increases in the size of any of these industries will positively impact income growth per capita. In terms of magnitude an increase in agriculture as a share of GSP has the biggest positive impact. Now looking at higher education expenditure per capita, which was measured as lagged three-year moving average of t-4, t-5 and t-6, we find negative coefficients in all models including our preferred model, although the model with both fixed effects does not produce a significant estimate. This is not surprising as we discussed the likelihood of getting insignificant or even negative results for this particular variable without the inclusion of the interaction between the share of students attending public higher education institutions and higher education spending per capita. 27 Table 4.1 Initial Estimates VARIABLES EDUEXPC(t−4 ,t−5,t−6) %ΔPOP TEXPPC(t−4 ,t−5,t−6) AG MIN MAN FIRE Constant State Fixed Effects Time Fixed Effects Observations R-squared (1) (2) %ΔINCOMEPC %ΔINCOMEPC (3) (4) %ΔINCOMEPC %ΔINCOMEPC -7.72e-05*** (1.87e-05) 0.105 (0.124) -5.88e-07 (8.23e-07) 0.213*** (0.0694) 0.0955*** (0.0289) 0.0284* (0.0162) 0.0215 (0.0190) 0.0246*** (0.00712) -0.000197*** (4.18e-05) -0.0861 (0.297) 1.24e-05*** (2.32e-06) 0.827*** (0.168) 0.111 (0.0832) 0.295*** (0.0607) -0.00893 (0.0981) -0.0436 (0.0280) -3.57e-05** (1.63e-05) -0.0102 (0.104) -1.68e-06** (7.58e-07) 0.156** (0.0629) 0.0872*** (0.0282) 0.00604 (0.0138) 0.0319** (0.0149) 0.0237*** (0.00577) -6.64e-05 (4.19e-05) 0.0252 (0.256) -2.06e-06 (2.90e-06) 1.038*** (0.159) 0.141* (0.0786) 0.248*** (0.0536) 0.0793 (0.0930) -0.0480* (0.0256) No No Yes No No Yes Yes Yes 650 0.073 650 0.215 650 0.486 650 0.572 Robust standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 4.3 Interaction Variable Results In Table 4.2 we have estimated Model 4, the two-way fixed effects model with the inclusion of the interaction between the share of total students attending public higher education institutions and the public higher education spending per capita. We include Model 5 and Model 6 which present the introduction of the share of total students attending public higher education institutions and then the interaction term. First looking at Model 5, we find that including the share of students attending public institutions produces a positive but insignificant coefficient of 0.0269. Next we 28 find that public higher education spending per capita is still negative but is now statistically significant. The control variables then remain close to the same along with the R-squared. Looking at Model 6, we have now included the interaction between the share of students attending public institutions and public higher education spending per capita. First we can see that again the control variables remain the same and there is small improvement in fit. Then we have the share of students attending public institutions variable change signs but remain insignificant. But now we find that the interaction term produces a positive and significant coefficient of 0.000771. In addition public higher education spending itself produces a negative and significant coefficient of -0.000722. These results agree with the findings of Curs et al. (2011). Although we measured public higher education spending as a percentage of GSP, we obtained similar results with a different specification using per capita measurements for public higher education spending and income growth. This result implies that variation in the share of students attending public higher education across states has a significant effect on the relationship between public higher education spending and economic growth. We will simulate marginal effects of the interaction by testing the mean, maximum and minimum of the share of students attending public higher education students to make these findings more clear. 29 Table 4.2 Interaction Variable Estimates VARIABLES EDUEXPC(t−4 ,t−5,t−6) (4) %ΔINCOMEPC (5) %ΔINCOMEPC (6) %ΔINCOMEPC -6.64e-05 (4.19e-05) -7.04e-05* (4.21e-05) 0.0269 (0.0532) 0.0252 (0.256) -2.06e-06 (2.90e-06) 1.038*** (0.159) 0.141* (0.0786) 0.248*** (0.0536) 0.0793 (0.0930) -0.0480* (0.0256) 0.0232 (0.255) -2.32e-06 (2.88e-06) 1.042*** (0.159) 0.141* (0.0785) 0.247*** (0.0538) 0.0717 (0.0933) -0.0697 (0.0515) -0.000722*** (0.000233) -0.103 (0.0747) 0.000771*** (0.000270) 0.0355 (0.257) -3.26e-06 (2.99e-06) 1.042*** (0.161) 0.118 (0.0771) 0.231*** (0.0530) 0.0720 (0.0937) 0.0439 (0.0678) -0.0001095** (0.0000439) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes 650 0.572 650 0.572 650 0.578 PUBLICSHARE(t−4 ,t−5,t−6) EDUEXPC x PUBLICSHARE(t−4 ,t−5,t−6) %ΔPOP TEXPPC(t−4 ,t−5,t−6) AG MIN MAN FIRE Constant Combined Effect4 State Fixed Effects Time Fixed Effects Observations R-squared Robust standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 Going back to the summary statistics presented in Table 3.2, we find a mean value of .79, a maximum of .99 and a minimum of .43 for the share of students attending public institutions. If we hold higher education spending at a constant value we could see how that effect changes based on the different values for the share of students. First let us 4 Combined marginal effect of EDUEXPC and EDUEXPC x PUBLICSHARE is shown at the mean value for PUBLICSHARE. Combined marginal effects were also calculated at the maximum and minimum values. 30 assume a $1 increase in public higher education per capita for each state. If we then assume the mean value of .79 for the share of students attending public institutions we can calculate marginal effects. First the $1 increase in spending alone would have a negative effect of -0.000722 based on the coefficient for public higher education spending. Then looking at the interaction term we arrive at a positive value of 0.000609, which is based on the $1 increase in spending multiplied by the mean value for the share of students attending public higher education institutions. Combining the effect of the interaction term and public higher education spending per capita we arrive at the combined effect of -0.0001095. Based on our assumptions, this would suggest that for a state where 79% of students were enrolled in public institutions the $1 increase in state public higher education spending per capita would decrease growth of income per capita by 0.01%. Now if we look at the maximum and minimum values of the share of students attending public higher education institutions we are basically looking at what occurs when a state is heavily dependent on public higher education institutions to educate or when a state is heavily dependent on the private market. Looking at the maximum share of students attending public institutions, which is .99 and the same $1 increase in public higher education spending per capita we find a positive combined effect of 0.0000439. This indicates that the $1 increase in public higher education spending per capita would increase income growth per capita by 0.004%. Using the minimum value of .43 then gives a negative combined effect of -0.000394, which then suggests an opposite effect. In 31 this case the $1 increase in spending per capita would now reduce income growth per capita by 0.04%. These results agree with the endogenous growth model proposed by Bräuninger and Vidal (2000) that suggested a higher education market dominated by the public sector would see greater long run growth than a mixed system or one dependent on the private market. As mentioned in the review of literature, they found that an increase in higher education subsidy has a non-monotonic effect therefore an increase in the subsidy from a low-level, such as with a state that is more dependent on the private market, would have a negative effect on economic growth. On the other hand a state that already had a high subsidy level and therefore may be more dependent on the public market would see an increase in economic growth from an increase in the education subsidy. If we look at Figure 4.1 we can see that states with a smaller share of students attending public higher education institutions appear to spend less on public higher education. So states at the left of this spectrum up to about .93 or 93% public share, based on the results in Table 4.2, would see negative effects from increases in public higher education spending, but those to the right would see positive effects. Looking at the most recent year of data collected for the share of students attending public higher education institutions which is 2006, only eight states are near 93%.5 Curs found that this breakeven point at a lower level of about 72%, but the relationship remains the same. 5 These states are Alabama, Alaska, Arkansas, Mississippi, Montana, Nevada, New Mexico and Wyoming. The only states to exceed 93% of students attending public institutions are Alaska and Wyoming. 32 Figure 4.1 Average Appropriations Per Capita and Average Share of Total Students Attending Public Institutions for 50 States $350 Appropriations Per Capita $300 $250 $200 $150 $100 $50 0.35 4.4 0.45 0.55 0.65 0.75 Public Share 0.85 0.95 2SLS Results Before we discuss the results of the 2SLS estimates, we will first regress educational attainment on public higher education spending per capita and the interaction between public higher education spending per capita and the share of students attending public institutions. This will be the first stage of our 2SLS model. Table 4.3 presents the results of the higher education estimates. In Model 8 we have a baseline estimate. We then include Model 9 which includes the share of students attending public institutions. And finally, Model 10 has the inclusion of the interaction term. 33 Table 4.3 Higher Education Attainment Estimates (First Stage of 2SLS) VARIABLES EDUEXPC(t−4 ,t−5,t−6) (8) BA25 (9) BA25 (10) BA25 -0.000103** (4.85e-05) -9.12e-05* (4.87e-05) -0.0791 (0.0591) -0.111 (0.165) -7.23e-06** (2.93e-06) -0.0175 (0.123) 0.0717 (0.0750) -0.0290 (0.0453) 0.0894 (0.0651) 0.203*** (0.0219) -0.105 (0.163) -6.47e-06** (2.97e-06) -0.0284 (0.123) 0.0701 (0.0737) -0.0252 (0.0454) 0.112 (0.0705) 0.266*** (0.0521) 0.000588** (0.000264) 0.0565 (0.0820) -0.000803*** (0.000309) -0.118 (0.162) -5.49e-06* (2.96e-06) -0.0287 (0.125) 0.0946 (0.0723) -0.00874 (0.0449) 0.111 (0.0696) 0.148** (0.0712) -0.0000505 (0.00005) Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes Yes 650 0.920 650 0.921 650 0.922 PUBLICSHARE(t−4 ,t−5,t−6) EDUEXPC x PUBLICSHARE(t−4 ,t−5,t−6) %ΔPOP TEXPPC(t−4 ,t−5,t−6) AG MIN MAN FIRE Constant Combined Effect6 State Fixed Effects Time Fixed Effects Observations R-squared Robust standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 First looking at Model 8, we find a statistically significant negative coefficient for the effects of public higher education. This significant negative effect is similar to the results of Baldwin et al. (2011) using the path analysis model discussed earlier. 6 Combined marginal effect of EDUEXPC and EDUEXPC x PUBLICSHARE is shown at the mean value for PUBLICSHARE. Combined marginal effects were also calculated at the maximum and minimum values. 34 In the second column (Model 9), we add the variable for the share of students attending public higher education institutions. We find that the negative effect of public higher education spending is reduced somewhat but the result is still negative and significant. The coefficient for the share of students attending public higher education institutions is negative but insignificant. Looking at Model 10, where we have added the interaction term, we expected a similar result as when used in the models focusing on economic growth. We find that is not the case. In this model we find that the interaction term has a negative and significant coefficient of -0.000803 and public higher education expenditure per capita then has a positive and significant coefficient of 0.000588. This then suggests that holding other variables constant, that an increase in the share of students attending public higher education institutions would lead to decreased attainment levels. We will now look at marginal effects of changes in the share of students attending public higher education institutions at the mean, maximum and minimum as we have done in the previous section. As we have found, the mean, maximum and minimum values of the share of students attending public higher education institutions are .79, .99 and .43 respectively. Once again we will assume a $1 increase in public higher education spending per capita. Looking first at mean share value, we find that a $1 increase in public higher education spending per capita alone would increase educational attainment by 0.059%, but then looking at the effect of the interaction term we find that the $1 increase in public higher education spending per capita when the share of students attending public higher 35 education institutions is at the mean of 79%, would decrease educational attainment by 0.06%. The coefficient for the total marginal effect at the mean is then -0.0000505. This means that a $1 increase in spending would reduce educational attainment is reduced by about 0.01%. Now we look at the effect of increasing public higher education spending per capita by $1, at the maximum share of students attending public institutions based on the data collected. In this scenario we still have a positive increase in educational attainment of 0.06% but now the interaction term increases in magnitude, reducing attainment by 0.08%. The coefficient for the total marginal effect is -0.0002103. This then gives us a reduction in attainment of about 0.021 %. Moving to the other end of the spectrum we find that at the minimum share value of 43% we end up instead with a total marginal effect coefficient of 0.0002463. This suggests a net increase in attainment of about 0.025%. The breakeven point for the share of students attending public institutions, where public higher education spending has neither a negative effect nor a positive effect on educational attainment, is at about 73%. The results of Model 10 suggest that states that have a larger markets for private higher education will see increases in educational attainment when public higher education spending per capita increases whereas the states that have smaller markets will see a decrease in educational attainment. This result will be discussed further in the summary of findings. Now moving on to Table 4.4 we have our 2SLS estimates, where we have instrumented educational attainment using public higher education spending and the 36 interaction between higher education spending and the percentage of students attending public higher education institutions. The first-stage estimate for educational attainment, BA25, is based on results of Model 10. Table 4.4 Final 2SLS Estimates VARIABLES BA25 (first-stage estimate) TEXPPC(t−4 ,t−5,t−6) %ΔPOP AG MIN MAN FIRE Constant State Fixed Effects Time Fixed Effects Observations R-squared (11) %ΔINCOMEPC -0.290 (0.237) -4.25e-06 (3.36e-06) 0.0554 (0.223) 1.046*** (0.151) 0.147** (0.0699) 0.238*** (0.0514) 0.104 (0.0956) -0.00857 (0.0473) Yes Yes 650 0.534 Robust standard errors in parentheses *** p<0.01, ** p<0.05, * p<0.1 In this model we have made the assumption that public higher education spending per capita affects income growth per capita through educational attainment. We have included estimated educational attainment explained by public higher education spending and the interaction between public higher education per capita and the share of students attending public higher education institutions as primary instruments. We find similar estimates for the effects of the control variables as we found in the initial estimates 37 focusing on growth of income per capita. Now looking at educational attainment we find a statistically insignificant coefficient of -0.290. 38 5. 5.1 CONCLUSION Summary of Findings The primary focus of this thesis is to investigate the relationship between public higher education spending and economic growth, while a secondary analysis focused on the role of educational attainment mediating the effect of that spending. We used the interaction between spending and the share of students attending public higher education institutions to control for variation in the size of the private market for higher education in both analyses. In the first part of this analysis we tested for consistency with previous research. In the second part we attempted to apply a new method of analysis using the interaction proposed by Curs et al., in the investigation of the effect of public higher education spending on educational attainment. We begin by first looking at the results of the initial estimates and the results when we included the interaction between public higher education spending and the share of students attending public higher education institutions. In the initial two-way fixed effects model we found an insignificant negative correlation between public higher education spending and income growth per capita. Based on the results of Curs et al. (2011) we expected that the addition of share of students attending public higher education, which acted as a proxy for the size of the market for private education, would remove negative bias associated with its omission. When we included the interaction between public higher education spending per capita and the share of students attending public higher education institutions and thus began controlling for variation in this share across states, we arrived at a similar result. In contrast with the finding of Curs et al. the 39 point at which an increase in public higher education spending per capita was at a significantly higher level of 93%. These results suggested that in states with more than 93% of students attending public higher education institutions and thus smaller markets for private higher education, an increase in public higher education spending per capita would increase economic growth. In states with shares of students attending public higher education institutions below this level, the same increase in public higher education spending per capita would have a negative effect. It appears that increasing public higher education spending in a majority of states except for the most heavily dependent on public systems, would not lead to the expected improvements in economic growth. One possibility for this result is that the private market for higher education may be providing a superior option in states that are not completely dominated by public institutions. In comparison with the findings of Curs et al the results in this study are more dire because only two states in this analysis would see positive effects from increases in spending on higher education. It may be the case that public institutions are inefficient or perhaps do not provide the same quality of education that a private institution may provide. In addition private institutions may be targeting a different pool of applicants and have a higher level of funding compared to public systems. In the second part of this thesis we examined public higher education spending as one part of a two part process. We said that public higher education spending per capita should positively influence educational attainment and therefore increase economic 40 growth. The attempt at modeling this causal relationship was based on the human capital theory proposed by Becker (1962).and Schultz (1963). In their path analysis Baldwin et al. (2011) discovered a negative relationship between public higher education spending and educational attainment. Therefore the indirect effect of public higher education spending on economic growth mediated by educational attainment was negative. It was expected that as with the investigation of the direct relationship between public higher education spending and economic growth, we would find that the omission of the size of the market for private education would negatively bias the results. Therefore the inclusion of the proxy variable for private market size, the share of students attending public higher education institutions, would show that public higher education spending’s effect on educational attainment was dependent on variation in that share across states. We would then find that public higher education spending per capita would increase attainment but only in those states that had the smallest amount of students attending private institutions and therefore smaller private markets for higher education. The results of the analysis suggested otherwise. Instead we found that the states with the larger markets for private higher education would see an increase in attainment if there was an increase in public higher education spending. On the other hand a state dominated by the public institutions would then see a decrease in attainment levels for the same increase in spending. Specifically this negative effect on educational attainment would be found in states that had over 73% percent of college students attending public institutions. 41 It is not clear why increased spending on public higher education in a state with a large market for higher education would increase attainment, whereas a state with little to no market for higher education would see a decrease in attainment for that same increase in spending. First we would think that immigration is playing a role here but it is not likely that this is related to the immigration of college graduates. A special report by the U.S. Census Bureau published in 2003, focused on the migration of single college educated people between the ages of 25 and 39 from 1995-2000 (Franklin, 2003). Comparing their findings to the one here, we find some consistency because the states that show the highest percentages of net out of state migration of single college educated young people occur in states that have large shares of students attending public institutions. At the same time though states like Nevada and California that have larger public higher education systems also show net into state migration. So the results of the analysis do not present a clear picture. In the last part of our analysis we conducted a 2SLS analysis in an attempt to connect public higher education spending per capita, to educational attainment and then to income growth per capita and address potential endogeneity. The basis of the 2SLS model was that public higher education spending should increase educational attainment and therefore add more skilled labor to the workforce. This increase in skilled labor should then positively impact economic growth. The results from the 2SLS model resulted in a statistically insignificant coefficient for educational attainment. In future research it would be desirable to find stronger instruments for educational attainment. The insignificant impact of attainment 42 on growth result may be due to migration that has not been accounted for in the model. Potentially other important variables are also omitted, such as socio-demographics and student achievement characteristics prior to entering college. Generally cross national studies have shown a positive relationship between investments in human capital and economic growth. One issue though is that many of these investigations have focused on differences between developing countries and developed countries. Although in the United States, individual states may differ significantly, they are all generally well off economically in comparison to developing and even other developed nations. Explaining differences across states may require a different approach than simply applying models based on country-level theory and analysis to the United States. 5.2 Future Research There are several possibilities for future research that may make the relationship between public higher education spending, educational attainment and economic growth more clear. First controlling for migration would be useful. The 2003 Special Census report shows significant movement of college graduates across states, so data on college graduation migration could be gathered. For the purposes of this study, this data was not available on an annual basis. Second we could alter the structure of 2SLS model. Public higher education spending and the interaction between spending and the share of students attending public institutions showed signs of being weak instruments for linking educational attainment and economic growth. It seems that the relationship between public higher education and 43 educational attainment is the most complex and additional variables should be considered here as well. Finally to generate a better link between attainment and economic growth, we may want to conduct a microeconomic analysis that focused on the relationship between public higher education spending and graduation rates in those institutions. This would give us a better understanding of how state funding may affect student success at public institutions. Also it may provide a better idea of what effects budget constraints have on public institutions and how they may affect student progress towards degree completion. 44 REFERENCES Baldwin, J. N., Borrelli, S. A., & New, M. J. (2011). State Educational Investments and Economic Growth in the United States: A Path Analysis*. Social Science Quarterly, 92(1), 226-245. doi: 10.1111/j.1540-6237.2011.00765.x Barro, R. J. (2001). Human Capital and Growth. [10.1257/aer.91.2.12]. American Economic Review, 91(2), 12-17. Beck, N. (2001). TIME-SERIES–CROSS-SECTION DATA: What Have We Learned in the Past Few Years? Annual Review of Political Science, 4(1), 271-293. doi: doi:10.1146/annurev.polisci.4.1.271 Becker, G. S. (1962). Investment in Human Capital: A Theoretical Analysis. Journal of Political Economy, 70(5), 9-49. Becker, G. S. (1981). A treatise on the family. Cambridge, Mass.: Harvard University Press. Becker, G. S. (1993). Human capital : a theoretical and empirical analysis, with special reference to education. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Bräuninger, M., & Vidal, J.-P. (2000). Private versus Public Financing of Education and Endogenous Growth. Journal of Population Economics, 13(3), 387-401. Bureau of Economic Analysis. (2013). Regional Economic Accounts Retrieved July, 2013, from http://www.bea.gov/regional/index.htm Curs, B. R., Bhandari, B., & Steiger, C. (2011). The Roles of Public Higher Education Expenditure and the Privatization of the Higher Education on U.S. States Economic Growth. Journal of Education Finance, 36(4), 424-441. Devarajan, S., Swaroop, V., & Zou, H.-f. (1996). The composition of public expenditure and economic growth. Journal of Monetary Economics, 37(2), 313-344. doi: http://dx.doi.org/10.1016/S0304-3932(96)90039-2 Franklin, R. S. (2003). Migration of the Young, Single, and College Educated, 19952000: US Department of Commerce, Economics and Statistics Administration, US Census Bureau. Goldin, C., & Katz, L. F. (1998). The Origins of State-Level Differences in the Public Provision of Higher Education: 1890-1940. The American Economic Review, 88(2), 303-308. doi: 10.2307/116938 45 Hsieh, E., & Lai, K. (1994). Government spending and economic growth. Applied Economics, 26(1), 83-94. Lucas Jr, R. E. (1988). On the mechanics of economic development. Journal of Monetary Economics, 22(1), 3-42. doi: 10.1016/0304-3932(88)90168-7 National Center for Education Statistics. (2003). Baccalaureate and Beyond Longitudinal Study Retrieved July, 2013, from http://nces.ed.gov/surveys/b%26b/ Schultz, T. W. (1963). The economic value of education. New York: Columbia University. Storm, R., & Feiock, R. C. (1999). Economic Development Consequences of State Support for Higher Education. State & Local Government Review, 31(2), 97-105. United States Department of Agriculture. (2013). Agricultural Productivity in the United States Retrieved July, 2013, from http://www.ers.usda.gov/dataproducts/agricultural-productivity-in-the-us.aspx#28270 Vedder, R. (2004). Private vs Social Returns to Higher Education: Some New CrossSectional Evidence. Journal of Labor Research, 25(4), 677. Wang, L., & Davis, O. A. (2005). The Composition of State and Local Government Expenditures and Economic Growth. Working Paper. Department of Social and Decision Sciences. Carnegie Mellon University. Zhang, L. (2008). Does State Funding Affect Graduation Rates at Public Four-Year Colleges and Universities? Educational Policy. doi: 10.1177/0895904808321270