A State-Dependent Production Function: An Economist’s Apology Charles B. Moss Food and Resource Economics Department 1 Introduction In this paper, I am using apology in a classical sense: 2 Apology comes from a Greek word apologia which means to speak in defense of. Some years ago, I read a book by G.S. Hardy titled A Mathematician’s Apology in which the author tried to defend or explain the way mathematicians view the world. In this presentation, I want to defend or explain the way that economists use production functions and to renew the conversation on the estimation and use of production functions. 7/17/2016 Food and Resource Economics Department What is the Role of Economics? Returning to the work of the Austrian Economist Ludwig von Mises, economics is a science of human action. Specifically, economics is the science of human action regarding the allocation of goods and services. In this historical approach, the most basic datum is the market transaction – the quantity of any good purchased at a specific price. 3 This market price is determined in part by what consumers are willing to pay for any given quantity of goods and services – the demand. The other half of the scissors is the quantity that producers are willing to supply a given quantity of goods and services – the supply. Production economics is primarily interested in the supply of output. 7/17/2016 Food and Resource Economics Department Two Approaches to Production Economics Primal Approach Specification dates back to Wicksteed’s definition of the production function. Steps: Estimate a production function using input-output data. Given these estimated function, firm level supply function and demand for each input can be derived. Dual Approach Early work in the area dates back to Hotelling, but its recent popularity started with the work of Shephard, Diewert, and McFadden. Steps: 4 7/17/2016 Assume that agents are making optimizing decisions based on a production technology they know. Estimate the optimizing relationships directly (i.e., the supply and derived demand functions). Food and Resource Economics Department Typical Primal Estimation Gather production data This table comes from the USDA Chemical Use Survey. Data and the economic question is a significant opportunity for collaboration. Specify the production function. Statistical estimation of the function. 5 7/17/2016 Nit Phos Pot Corn 127.0 60.0 90.0 140.0 202.0 104.0 120.0 110.0 88.0 24.0 90.0 61.0 150.0 69.0 120.0 138.0 200.0 0.0 0.0 150.0 153.3 52.6 126.6 102.0 139.0 35.0 90.0 160.0 150.0 60.0 120.0 115.0 160.0 40.0 50.0 165.0 180.0 37.0 120.0 140.0 160.0 30.0 60.0 135.0 182.7 76.8 127.7 160.0 Food and Resource Economics Department Specifying the Production Function Using the Cobb-Douglas Production Function y Ax1 x2 x3 ln y ln A ln x1 ln x2 ln x3 Estimating the coefficients using ordinary least squares ln y 0 1 ln x1 2 ln x2 3 ln x3 Solve for the economic relationships max pY x1 x2 w1 x1 w2 x2 Y pY w1 0 x1 x1 Y pY w2 0 x2 x2 6 7/17/2016 Food and Resource Economics Department Deriving the Implication of the Primal Economic results Factor Demands 1 * 1 x * 2 x pY , w1 , w2 p 1 1 Y pY , w1 , w2 p 1 1 Y w1 1 Output Supply Y * pY , w1 , w2 pY 7 w1 1 7/17/2016 1 w1 w2 w2 1 1 1 1 w2 1 Food and Resource Economics Department Economic/Policy Questions Asked Both the primal and the dual approach can be used to answer questions such as: What is the supply response to a change in input or output prices? The dual approach requires the assumption that the researcher can observe people making optimal decisions. Hence, it is difficult to address the impact of new technologies (ex ante). The approach may also obfuscate the impact of risk and uncertainty on production. 8 7/17/2016 Food and Resource Economics Department Production Function My program in production economics focuses on how individuals decide to employ factors of production (land, labor and capital) in an effort to create production which is offered to the market. The essence of this question is again one of constraint. If we envision a N x M space where there are N inputs and M outputs there must be an constraint (or envelope) which limits the combination of inputs and outputs which are feasible. 9 It may be possible for the producer to use 250 pounds of fertilizer per acre to produce one bale of cotton; However, it is impossible for that producer to choose to produce 5 bales of cotton per acre with the same 250 pounds of fertilizer. 7/17/2016 Food and Resource Economics Department Graphical Definition of Production Function Cotton 5 Feasible 1 250 10 7/17/2016 Nitrogen Food and Resource Economics Department The Technology Set In general terms the production technology is mathematically depicted as x, y T Economics theory suggests a set or conditions on this technology which make the economic question interesting. Economics requires the technology be defined so that the individual can optimize some objective function (usually profit). 11 : x RN , y RM The technology should be bounded (so that an infinite amount of output cannot be produced from a finite bundle of inputs), Concave (so that a unique optimal exists), Inputs should be weakly essential (so that a positive quantity of a least one input is required), and Continuous. 7/17/2016 Food and Resource Economics Department The Production Mapping Given that the production technology meets these criteria a production map (or production function) can be defined which depicts the level of outputs resulting from the application of any fixed set of inputs f x, y : R R N 12 M This formulation is consistent with the objection that production scientists have levied against simplified economic applications. Life is complicated so reducing the input space could negate the economic implications of the production function. May 27, 2009 Food and Resource Economics Department To address some of these shortcomings this analysis starts with a production function where combinations of controllable inputs (pounds of nitrogen applied to each acre) are combined with uncontrollable inputs (such as rainfall, which I will use as a stochastic variable such as rainfall) to produce output. This transformation can be written as f : X R 1 13 7/17/2016 Food and Resource Economics Department Approximating this production function with a secondorder Taylor series expansion: f x, f x0 , 0 x x x0 f x0 , 0 0 1 x x0 2 x 2 0 x x0 f x0 , 0 0 O 2 x0 , 0 14 7/17/2016 Food and Resource Economics Department f x, g x, h x, 1 x x0 Axx x0 , 0 x x0 2 h x, x0 , 0 0 x x0 A x x0 , 0 0 g x, 0 x x0 , 0 x x0 1 0 A x0 , 0 0 O 2 x0 , 0 2 1 x0 , 0 x x0 A x x0 , 0 0 A x0 , 0 0 2 O 2 x0 , 0 15 7/17/2016 Food and Resource Economics Department As a starting point, we formulate a quadratic production function where production is a function of two controllable inputs and one uncontrollable input. 0.15 x1 x1 0.001 0.0005 0.002 x1 1 f x1 , x2 , 1.5 0.25 x2 x2 0.0005 0.0015 0.001 x2 0.10 2 0.002 0.001 0.009 16 7/17/2016 Food and Resource Economics Department 0.1163 x1 1 x1 0.001 0.0005 x1 f x1 , x2 , 16.83 1.4582 x x x 0.2332 0.0005 0.0015 2 2 2 2 0.15 x1 1 x1 0.001 0.0005 x1 f x1 , x2 , 0.00 1.50 x x x 0.25 0.0005 0.0015 2 2 2 2 0.1837 x1 1 x1 0.001 0.0005 x1 f x1 , x2 , 16.83 1.9083 x x 0.2668 2 2 2 0.0005 0.0015 x2 17 7/17/2016 Food and Resource Economics Department To estimate the state-dependent production function, I use a quantile regression approach: P Yi y F y xi where P(Yi < y) denotes the probability of the observed variable (Yi) less than some target value (y), F(.) is a known cumulative probability density function, xi are observed independent variables, and is a vector of estimated coefficients. 18 7/17/2016 Food and Resource Economics Department Koenker and Bassett demonstrate that the regression relationship at the th quantile can be estimated by solving mink yi xi 1 yi xi R ii: yi xi ii: yi xi 19 7/17/2016 Food and Resource Economics Department To examine the possibility of this specification, I formulated a stochastic production function consistent with the general specification above 0.15 x1 x1 0.001 0.0005 0.002 x1 1 f x1 , x2 , 1.5 0.25 x2 x2 0.0005 0.0015 0.001 x2 0.10 2 0.002 0.001 0.009 Next, I generate a dataset assuming that the stochastic factor of production () is distributed normally with mean of zero and a variance of 400. 20 7/17/2016 Food and Resource Economics Department In addition, I also considered a negative exponential error term z exp , ,0 Finally, I applied the specification to wheat production on the Great Plains 21 7/17/2016 Food and Resource Economics Department Results for Great Plains 22 0.20 Quantile 0.50 Quantile 0.80 Quantile Intercept 19.713 9.647 32.906 Nitrogen 0.278 0.325 0.484 Phosphorous -0.544 0.975 -1.217 Nitrogen2 -0.0057 -0.0059 -0.0039 Phosphorous2 -0.0048 -0.0131 -0.0089 Nit*Phos 0.0151 0.0149 0.0066 Missouri 7.727 8.028 9.106 Nebraska 10.241 10.665 11.181 Kansas 13.504 11.486 13.233 7/17/2016 Food and Resource Economics Department Wheat bushels acre 35 30 25 20 15 Nitrogen pounds acre 10 23 20 30 7/17/2016 40 50 Food and Resource Economics Department