CHAPTER 9 WORKERS ARE HETEROGENEOUS I. Two Skill Markets: One of outcomes of the model to this point is that lifetime incomes are the same for all workers. Different skill-markets have different levels of income when observed at any specific time, but summed over all periods from t=0,n , those incomes are equal in Long-Run equilibrium. In fact it’s even stronger: the actual definition of Long-Run equilibrium, which has no net entry into, or exit from, any skill-market, is that lifetime incomes are equal. If they are not, both net entry and net exit will occur. This is the result of free entry. As in the model of pure competition for firms, where free entry causes zero excess profits, here free entry causes zero “rents” to choosing to acquire a skill. Yet this is not what we observe in the economy. There we observe lifetime income differentials, very substantial (and, currently, growing fast) lifetime income differentials. To develop a model in which lifetime income differentials exist, we must assume that workers are different from one another, or heterogenous. And ultimately, in Chapters 10 and 11, we must assume that one of these differences – differences in ability – lead to restriction in entry to some skills. This isn’t hard to believe: how many of your fellow high school students would you want operating on your brain, for example? Or teaching you economics. Or, perhaps, wiring your house for electricity? To keep things simple, I develop most of the rest of the analysis for only two skill-markets: A and B. We have already seen that the extension to three and more skill-markets just to repeat the analysis for A vs B, but one time period later, with B vs C substituted for A vs B. So the analysis of two skill-markets generalizes, with no new insights, to three or more skill-markets in a hierarchy. All of the exogenous variables currently in the model are candidates for introducing differences between workers. Let's consider, first, that workers obviously differ in their values of n, the time remaining in their working life. The way this model is currently constructed, variations in n don't matter mcuh because, in Long-Run equilibrium, the wage differential is small enough that only workers in the initial period will have any incentive to choose B. Differences in n will matter once heterogeneity is introduced via other exogenous variables, however. To do that requires an analysis with at least two types of heterogeneity: differences in n and differences in one other variable. That comes later. A. Differences in Discount Rates: A second variable that obviously varies between individuals is , the rate of discounting the future. To denote that this now varies between individuals, I subscript the deltas with i, for individual: i . This means that the discount operator also varies between individuals, with each i mapping to a unique discount operator: Dni . Varying discount rates are shown on Figure 9-1. For simplicity this is represented as a uniform, or rectangular, distribution of the i's. The smallest value of a delta in that distribution is i = 0, and the largest value is i = “max”. Since the Dnis are inversely related to the is , the largest value of Dni is determined by i = 0, and the smallest value of Dni is determined by i = “max”. Each individual entering the initial period chooses A or B according to how he or she discounts the future, that is, based on his or her value, i . Since the wage differential between B and A occurs in the future, the value of any given wage differential is higher to individuals who discount the future the least – that is, for individuals with the lowest is and, therefore, the highest Dnis. Allen: labour economics, Chapter 9 page 2 Once again, consider equation (8-4), which has the return to choosing B on the LHS and the costs of B on the RHS. We now slightly rewrite it as an inequation, adding subscripts for individuals: (9-1) Dni•h•(wB– wA) >< OCB + DCB . Individuals choose B when the LHS is greater than the RHS. Note that with the “all other things equal” condition, we assume all costs to be the same for all individuals. Given a long-run equilibrium wage differential, (wB– wA), individuals with the lowest values of i (the highest values of Dni) are the first to choose B. For them the value of the LHS of inequation (9-1) are highest. And individuals with the highest values of i (the lowest values of Dni) are the first to choose A. For them the value of the LHS of inequation (9-1) are lowest. [Note: look back at the numbers of Exercise 8-A, Problem 3, a) and b). From these and inequation (9-1) you can see that facing a wage differential (wB – wA) = $1.10, individuals with i =0 D5i = 5, will choose B; individuals with i D5i = 4 will choose A.] Figure 9-1 Number Of Workers i(1) i(2) i(E) Cohort-B i = 0 i increasing i(99) i(100) Cohort-A E i = max Equilibrium is still stasis: the number of new entrants to A is equal to exits from A, and the number of new entrants to B equals exits from B. So there is an equilibrium proportion of the new entrants choosing A, and an equilibrium number choosing B. Denote the total number of new entrants in any period, the cohort, as EN; ENA is the cohort entering the A-market and ENB is the cohort entering the B-market: EN = ENA + ENB. E is the value of i which splits the cohort, EN, into its equilibrium proportions: ENA/EN and ENB/EN. And E DnE , which in turn sets the LHS equal to the RHS of equation (9-1): Long-Run equilibrium is now: (9-2) DnE•h•(wBE – wAE) = OCB + DCB . Long-Run equilibrium is now a double equilibrium. Long-Run equilibrium simultaneously determines both the equilibrium wage differential (or, really, the wage relation, wBE = XwAE + Z), and the equilibrium value of the “cutting” discount rate: E DnE . To illustrate, assume the cohort is 100 individuals entering the work force each period. Order these individuals on the basis of their values of i , and denote them as i(1), i(2), i(3), … , i(98), i(99), i(100). Individual i(1)’s i = zero, individual i(2)’s 1 = (zero plus a small number), etc; individual i(100)’s i = “max”, individual i(99)’s i = (“max” minus a small number), etc. If skills A and B exist, then some must choose A and some must choose B. The first to choose B will be i(1), since for her the return to choosing B – that is, the value of the LHS of inequation (9-1) – is the highest. The next to choose B is i(2), the next i(3), … . Meanwhile, the first to choose A will be Allen: labour economics, Chapter 9 page 3 i(100), since for her the return to choosing B – that is the value of the LHS of inequation (9-1) – is the lowest. (Remember that A exists, so some workers must choose A) The next to choose A will be i(99), the next i(98), … . This self-selection process continues until, somewhere in the middle of the rectangle on Figure 9-1, one individual is indifferent. This individual’s value of i is such that the LHS of inequation (9-1) equals the RHS. (Since she must make a decision, we will have her choose B.) Her value of i is the equilibrium E DnE, where DnE sets the LHS of inequation (12) equal to the RHS. Given long-run wage differential (wBE– wAE), this is individual i(E), with a value E , on Figure 9-1. Individual i(E) is the “cut” individual – the individual who divides the group of all new entrants into those who choose A, Cohort-A on Figure 9-1, and those who choose B, Cohort-B on Figure 9-1. Reaching equilibrium is now a two-stage process analytically. To describe this, we will consider an exogenous change: an increase in productivity in the B-sector that increases demand for the B-skill and increases the wage at B in the Short Run. (This is the process described on pages 7 and 8 of Chapter 8.) Its effects on equilibrium discount rates are shown on Figure 9-2. We begin with Long-Run equilibrium, E1, shown on Figure 9-2. The increase in the wage at B causes the wage differential to increase in the Short-Run. More new entrants choose B. Some of these new entrants will have higher discount rates, i , than the first cut, E1. So the “cut” increases in the initial Short-Run, to SR . This will cause an increase in Cohort-B, from B1 to BSR, and simultaneously a decrease in Cohort-A from A1 to ASR. Figure 9-2 Number Of Workers i(E1) Cohort-A1 Cohort-B1 BSR i = 0 i(E2) Cohort-A2 Cohort-B2 i increasing ASR E1 2 SR i = max SR to LRE2 This increase in new entrants to B causes NB to increase and wages at B to decrease. Simultaneously the decrease in new entrants to A causes NA to decrease and wages at A to increase. (See the graph and description on pages 7 and 8 of Chapter 8.) These dual changes reduce the wage differential between B and A, which causes the i of the “cut” individual to fall. The process continues until the new Long-Run equilibrium is reached. This will be characterized by Long-Run wage differential, (wBE2 – wAE2) and a new “cut” individual, i(E2), whose i is E2. This process is illustrated on Figure 9-2. Three things must be true of the new Long-Run equilibrium. Look back at the long-run equilbrium condition, equation (9-2). The initial change is that the wage at B, wB, rises from the productivity increase in sector B. In the Short-Run, the equation no longer holds. The RHS remains constant, so to get back to equality, to Long-Run equilibrium, the LHS must fall. That fall, the movement to Long-Run equilibrium, must be caused by a greater supply of labour to the B-market, NB, which means a lesser supply of labour to the A-market, NA. These in turn reduce the B-wage, increase the A-wage, and reduce the wage differential. And as the size of the Allen: labour economics, Chapter 9 page 4 B-sector increases, DnE must fall. The approach from the Short-Run to the new Long-Run equilibirum is a simultaneous reduction of DnE and a reduction of the wage differential, as a greater proportion of workers choose B. So the first thing that is true of the new Long-Run equilibrium is that it must be characterized by a greater NB and a smaller NA than the initial Long-Run equilibrium. This is shown on pages 7 and 8 of Chapter 8, and is shown on Figure 9-2, where Cohort-B2 is larger than Cohort-B1, and Cohort-A2 is smaller than Cohort-A1. Figure 9-2 also makes it clear that this first effect strictly implies the second – that the value of the discount rate of the “cut” individual must have risen. This too is shown on Figure 9-2. There individual i(E2) is further along the continuum of individuals ordered by their discount rates than is individual i(E1). So 2 is greater than E1, and, since 2 > E1 , DnE2 < DnE1. The third effect, then, is that the equilibrium wage differential, (wBE – wAE), also must have risen. From equation (9-2), with DnE2 < DnE1 and all other things equal, (wBE2 – wAE2) must be greater than (wBE1 – wAE1). ---------------------------------------------------------------------The Long-Run equilibrium here – in fact all Long-Run equilibria with heterogeneity – have several nice characteristics. The first is that heterogeneity eliminates the small analytical problem faced by models where everyone is alike. That problem is that, if all individuals are identical, all must make the same decision at the same period. In the equilibria with homogeneity, all equilibriua in Chapter 8, since everyone is the same, everyone must all choose either A or B at t=0. So "equilibrium" with homogeneity is a state where everyone chooses, say B until the LHS of equation (8-4) is less than the RHS, then everyone chooses A until the LHS of equation (8-4) is greater than the RHS, then everyone chooses B ... . That "equilibrium" is cyclical rather than steady-state, characterized by “bouncing” from having everyone choose B to having everyone choose A to having everyone choose B to having everyone choose A to … . With heterogeneity, the equilibrium is steady-state: ENB/EN proportion of the new cohorts choose B at their t=0, and ENA/EN proportion of the new cohorts choose A. Individuals’ discount rates, i , which are here the way individuals vary, cause them to self-select who goes to which market. The second nice characteristic is that now an increase in demand for the B-skill causes an increase in the Long-Run equilibrium wage differential. It does so because the new Long-Run equilibrium requires that a greater proportion of the cohorts choose B. These additional workers are workers at the margin of discount rates, so they have somewhat higher discount rates than does Cohort-B in the initial Long-Run equilibrium. The wage differential must increase in order to attract these marginal workers in the self-selection process. This means that moving from homogeneous workers to heterogeneous workers gives upward-sloping Long-Run supply curves for all skill markets. Note also that, as observed by an outsider, the Long-Run equilibrium is now characterized by ambiguity about lifetime income differentials. An outsider observing lifetime incomes would have to use a single discount rate to evaluate them. If that observer used the “cut” discount rate, E, no lifetime income differential would be found. But if she used a lower discount rate than E, lifetime income at B would be observed to be greater than lifetime income at A; if she used a higher discount rate than E, lifetime income at A would be observed to be greater than lifetime income at B. Since the “cut” discount rate is unobservable, an outside observer could find anything. Keep in mind that while lifetime income differentials are ambiguous, the situation of each individual is not. Those choosing B get a lifetime income at B that is higher to them because their discount rates are lower than the “cut” discount rate, E; those choosing A get a lifetime income at A that is higher to them because their discount rates are higher than E. Allen: labour economics, Chapter 9 page 5 Finally, note that this analysis has had a substantial effect on public policy. In the 1960s, a sociologist named Daniel Patrick Moynihan – who was to gain greater fame as a United States Senator of some prominence – studied, empirically, the situation of children raised in poor families in the US. He found that they had much higher discount rates than middle class chldren. This makes sense: kids raised in urban ghettos had good reason to discount the future at very high rates. But our analysis shows that individuals with low discount rates are less likely to choose Human Capital. At the time Moynihan did his study, there also existed in North America a strong ethic that government should do its best to equalize opportunity. So, to encourage kids from poorer families, who had relatively high discount rates, the student loan program was approved, with very low interest rates on those loans. Exercise 9-I: The equilibrium here has a single equation (9-2) with two unknowns: DnE and the wage differential: (wBE– wAE). To solve the system we need a specification of the distribution of the Dnis, which means adding another unknown, NBE and Demand functions for both the A and the B skill markets. This is very messy algebraically; it is inherently non-linear and it’s not useful to use a linear approximation, and it involves four equations and four unknowns. [Even simplified hugely by assuming that the A-market is very large relative to the B-market so wAE is a given, the equations that must be solved simultaneously are: 1) wBE = (DnE•h•wAE + OCB + DCB)/DnE•h; 2) distribution of the Dnis: DnE = Dnmax – d•NBE ; and 3) demand in the B-market: wBE = $x – y•NBE , where d, x, and y, are parameters. This is three equations and three unknowns, and the first equation combined with the third makes it non-linear, so soultions are difficult.] Luckily, however, we can closely approximate a solution using EXCEL Below is an EXCEL exercise using the short-cut we used before: wAE is a “numeraire”, a “given”. The numbers used in this exercise are: wAE = $10/hour, h = 2000, ohB = 1000, DCB = $10,000, and n = 10. The reduced form of equation (9-2) is: wBE = wAE + (OCB + DCB)/DnE•h . With these numbers, the reduced form equation becomes: wBE = $10 +[$20,000/(2000•D10E)] = $10 + $10/D10E. ROUND ALL COLUMNS TO TWO DECIMALS! A The exercise assumes 31 workers with a uniform distribution of the Dnis. Column A is for the individuals; this is also the number of workers in the B-market, NB. In A1 type “N(B)”. In A2 type “1”; in A3 type “=A2+1”; copy A3 to A4:32. Column B is for the Dnis, so in B1 type “D(10)”. In B2 type “10”. In B3 type “=B2-.2”; copy B3 to B4:32. B32 should be 4. Column C is the “supply” curve; it is the wBEs determined from the D10is, so in C1 type “w(B),S1”. In C2 type “=10+10/B2”; copy C2 to C3:32. And Column D is for the demand in the B-market. In D1 type “w(B),D1”. In D2 type “=11.99-0.03*A2”; copy D2 to D3:32. Now run down Column D remembering the rule: a worker chooses B if the wB found from her D10 is less than the market wage. The market wage is in Column D and declines as more workers enter B. Run down Column D until the number in Column C is lower. The equilibrium wage in B, wBE , is the last value of Column D which is greater than the value of Column C in the same row. From this equilibrium value of wBE , move left and find NBE and D10E . Now two changes: B First, an increase in demand in the B-market. Use column E; in E1 type “w(B),D2”. In E2 type “=12.48-0.03*A2”; copy E2 to E3:32. Now run down Column E comparing with Column C, and Allen: labour economics, Chapter 9 page 6 repeat what you did in A above with Columns C and D, until you find a new wBE . From this value, move left and find new values of NBE and D10E . Comparing with the initial equilibrium of A, what changes in each of these variables was caused by the increase in Demand in the B-market? C Last, a new value of DCB, which shifts the supply curve. The new DCB = 6,000. The new reduced form equation for wBE is wBE = 10 + 16,000/2000•D10E = 10 + 8/D10E . Use Column F: in F1 type “w(B),S2”. In F2 type “=10+8/B2”; copy F2 to F3:32. Now run down Column D comparing with Column F, and repeat what you did in A above with Columns C and D, until you find a new wBE . From this value, move left and find new values of NBE and D10E . Comparing with the initial equilibrium of A, what changes in each of these variables was caused by the increase in Demand in the B-market? Write out your answers and turn them in along with the completed spread-sheet. -------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------Note that the exercise shows the three effects of an increase in demand in the B-market: 1) NBE is higher after the demand increase; 2) D10E is lower after the demand increase, and 3) with wAE held constant, wBE is higher after the demand increase. Finally, note the effects 1) and 3) taken together give us a long-run supply curve for the B-skill which is upward sloping. (And, if we weren’t holding wAE constant, we would also have a long-run supply curve for the A-skill which is upward sloping.) EXERCISE: Show that if an individual can borrow at a low interest rate, r, to pay for the Bskill, the individual’s decision must be rewritten with r used where i was used before. Individuals’ discount rates will no longer cause a selection process for the B-skill. If that B-skill is a university education, university education should no longer select against kids with high discount rates. Allen: labour economics, Chapter 9 page 7 B. Differences in Preference for Leisure (Hours Worked): A third variable that obviously varies between individuals is the preference for Leisure. Here that preference will be viewed as the preference for Hours Worked, since it is Hours Worked, h, that is in the decision equations and in the long-run equilibrium equation. To note that this now varies between individuals, I subscript the hs, Hours Worked, with i: hi. Varying Hours Worked are shown on Figure 9-3. For simplicity this is shown as a uniform, or rectangular, distribution of the his. On that Figure, the Hours Worked vary between a minimum of 1000 Hours per year, and a maximum of 3000 Hours per year. Each individual entering the initial period chooses A or B according to how many Hours per year she plans to work, that is, based on her value of hi . Since the wage differential between B and A is worth more the more Hours the individual works, the value of any given differential is higher to individuals who intend to work the most. Once again, consider equation (8-4), which has the return to choosing B on the LHS and the cost of B on the RHS. We now slightly rewrite it as an inequation, adding subscripts for individuals: (9-3) Dn•hi•(wB– wA) >< OCB + DCB . Individuals choose B when the LHS is greater than the RHS. Note that with the “all other things equal” condition, we assume all costs to be the same for all individuals. Given a long-run equilibrium wage differential, (wB– wA), individuals with the highest values of hi are the first to choose B. For them the value of the LHS of inequation (9-3) are highest. And individuals with the lowest values of hi are the first to choose A. For them the value of the LHS of inequation (9-3) are the lowest. [Note: look back at the numbers of Exercise 8-A. Compare parts a) between Problems 3 and 6. From these and inequation (9-3) you can see that facing a wage differential (wB– wA) = $1.10, individuals with hi = 2500, will choose B; individuals with hi = 2000 will choose A.] Figure 9-3 Number Of Workers i(E) i(1) i(2) Cohort-A hi = 1000 hi increasing i(99) i(100) Cohort-B h hi = 3000 Equilibrium is still stasis: the number of new entrants to A is equal to exits from A, and the number of new entrants to B equals exits from B. So there is an equilibrium proportion of the new entrants choosing A, and an equilibrium number choosing B. ENA is the cohort entering the Amarket; ENB is the cohort entering the B-market. hE is the value of hi which splits the cohort, EN, into its equilibrium proportions: ENA/EN and ENB/EN. And hE sets the LHS equal to the RHS of inequation (9-3): Long-Run equilibrium is now: (9-4) Dn•hE•(wBE – wAE) = OCB + DCB . Long-Run equilibrium is again a double equilibrium. Long-Run equilibrium simultaneously determines both the equilibrium wage differential (or, really, the wage relation, wBE = XwAE + Z), and the equilibrium value of the “cutting” Hours Worked: hE. Allen: labour economics, Chapter 9 page 8 To illustrate, assume the cohort is 100 individuals enter the work force each period. Order these individuals on the basis of their values of hi , and denote them as i(1), i(2), i(3), …, i(98), i(99), i(100). Individual i(1)’s hi = 1000, individual i(2)’s hi = 1020, etc; individual i(100)’s hi =3000, individual i(99)’s hi = 2980, etc. If skills A and B exist, then some must choose A and some must choose B. The first to choose B will be i(100), since for her the return to choosing B – that is, the value of the LHS of inequation (9-3) – is the highest. The next to choose B is i(99), the next i(98), … . Meanwhile, the first to choose A will be i(1), since for her the return to choosing B – that is the value of the LHS of inequation (9-3) – is the lowest. (Remember that A exists, so some workers must choose A) The next to choose A will be i(2), the next i(3), … . This self-selection process continues until, somewhere in the middle of the rectangle on Figure 9-3 one individual is indifferent. This individual’s value of hi is such that the LHS of inequation (93) equals the RHS. (Since she must make a decision, we will have her choose B.) Her value of hi is the equilibrium hE , where hE sets the LHS of inequation (9-3) equal to the RHS. Given long-run wage differential (wBE – wAE), this is individual i(E), with a value hE , on Figure 9-3. Individual i(E) is the “cut” individual – the individual who divides the group of all new entrants into those who choose A, Cohort-A on Figure 9-3, and those who choose B, Cohort-B on Figure 9-3. Reaching equilibrium is now a two-stage process analytically. To describe this, we will consider an exogenous change: an increase in productivity in the B-sector that increases the demand for the B-skill and increases the wage at B in the Short Run. (This is the process described on pages 7 and 8 of Chapter 8.) Its effects on equilibrium Hours Worked are shown on Figure 9-4. We begin with long-run equilibirum, E1, shown on Figure 9-4. The increase in the wage at B causes the wage differential to increase in the short-run. More new entrants choose B, and some of these will have lower preferences for Hours Worked, hi – that is, higher preferences for Leisure – than the first cut, hE1 on Figure 9-4. So the “cut” decreases in the initial Short-Run to hSR . This will cause an increase in Cohort-B, from B1 to BSR, and simultaneously a decrease in Cohort-A from A1 to ASR. Figure 9-4 Number Of Workers i(E2) i(E1) Cohort-A2 Cohort-A1 ASR hi = 1000 Cohort-B2 hSR Cohort-B1 BSR hE2 h1 hi increasing hi = 3000 SR to LRE2 This increase in new entrants to B causes NB to increase and wages at B to decrease. Simultaneously the decrease in new entrants to A causes NA to decrease and wages at A to increase. (See the graph and description on pages 7 and 8 of Chapter 8.) These dual changes reduce the wage differential between B and A, which causes the hi of the “cut” individual to rise. The process continues until the new Long-Run equilibrium is reached. This will be characterized by Long-Run wage differential, (wBE2 – wAE2) and a new “cut” individual, i(E2), whose hi is hE2. This process is illustrated on Figure 9-4. Three things must be true of the new Long-Run equilibrium. Look back at the Long-Run equilbrium condition, equation (9-4). The initial change is that the wage at B, wB, rises from the Allen: labour economics, Chapter 9 page 9 productivity increase in sector B. In the Short-Run, the equation no longer holds. The RHS remains constant, so to get back to equality, to Long-Run equilibrium, the LHS must fall. That fall, t he movement to Long-Run equilibrium, must be caused by a greater supply of labour to the B-market, NB, which means a lesser supply of lbaoaur to the A-market, NA. These in turn reduce the B-wage, increase the A-wage, and reduce the wage differential. And as the size of the B-sector increases, hE must fall. The approach from the Short-Run to the new Long-Run equilibirum is a simultaneous reduction of hE and a reduction of the wage differential, as a greater proportion of workers choose B. So the first thing that is true of the new Long-Run equilibrium is that it must be characterized by a greater NB and a smaller NA than the initial Long-Run equilibrium. This is shown on pages 7 and 8 of Chapter 8, and is shown on Figure 9-4, where Cohort-B2 is larger than Cohort-B1, and Cohort-A2 is smaller than Cohort-A1. Figure 9-4 also makes it clear that this first effect strictly implies the second – that the preference for Hours Worked of the “cut” individual must have fallen – preference for Leisure of the “cut” individual must have risen. This too is shown on Figure 9-4. There individual i(E2) is not as far along the continuum of individuals ordered by their preference for Hours Worked than is individual i(E1). So h2 is less than hE1 . The third effect, then, is that the equilibrium wage differential, (wBE – wAE), also must have risen. From equation (9-4), with h2 < hE1 and all other thins equal, (wBE2 – wAE2) must be greater than (wBE1 – wAE1). -----------------------------------------------------------------------Again, the Long-Run equilibrium here has those same several nice characteristics. The first is that heterogeneity here also eliminates the small analytical problem faced by models where everyone is alike. The problem is described above, on page 4. Here it is individual preferences for Leisure, reflected in preferences for Hours Worked, that cause individuals to self-select into the different skill markets. This keeps the system in stasis, and it makes the Long-Run equilibrium a steady-state. The second nice characteristic is that, again, an increase in demand for the B-skill causes an increase in the Long-Run equilibrium wage differential. It does so because the new Long-Run equilibrium requires that a greater proportion of the cohorts choose B. These additional workersare workers at the margin of preferences for Hours Worked, so they have somewhat lower preferences for Hurs Worked than does Cohort-B in the initial Long Run equilibrium. The wage differential must increase in order to attract these marginal workers to B in the self-selection process. This means that moving from homogeneous workers to heterogeneous workers gives upward-sloping Long-Run supply curves for all skill markets. Note also that, as observed by an outsider, for the first time the Long-Run equilibrium is characterized by unambiguously positive lifetime income differentials. To illustrate, let’s assume that hE2 = 2000, and that the equilibrium wage differential – here (wBE2 – wAE2) – is wA = $10/hour and wB = $12/hour. For the “cut” individual, whose preference for Hours Worked is 2000, this pair of wages makes the lifetime income of the A-market equal to the lifetime income of the B market. But the average Hours Worked for all workers in the B-market is 2500, and the average Hours Worked for all workers in the A-market is 1500. So for the actually observed B-workers, the lifetime income in the B-market is 20% higher than that of the “cut” individual. And for the actually observed A-workers, the lifetime income in the A-market is 25% lower than that of the “cut” individual. The lifetime income differential depends on the equilibrium wage differential, but, for the first time in the model, we actually generate substantial lifetime income differentials. And, since the equilibrium wage differential increases as the elasticity of demand for the B-skill Allen: labour economics, Chapter 9 page 10 increases, now, as Part D of the Exercise below shows, lifetime income differentials will be higher the more elastic the demand for the B-skill. -------------------------------------------------------------------Exercise 9-II: The equilibrium here has a single equation (9-4) with two unknowns: h and the wage differential: (wBE – wAE). To solve the system we need a specification of the distribution of the his, which means adding another unknown, NBE and Demand functions for both the A and the B skill markets. This is, again, messy algebraically. It is inherently non-linear, and it’s not useful to use a linear approximation; and it involves four equations and four unknowns. [Even simplified by assuming that the A-market is very large relative to the B-market so wAE is a given, the simultaneous equations one must solve are: 1) wBE = (D10•hE•wAE + wAE• + OCB + DCB)/D10•hE; 2) distribution of the hEs: hE = hmax – d•NBE; and 3) demand in the B-market: wBE = $x – y•NBE , where d, x, and y, are parameters. This is three equations and three unknowns, and the first equation combined with the third makes it non-linear, so soultions are difficult.] Luckily, however, we can again closely approximate a solution using EXCEL Below is an EXCEL exercise using the short-cut we used before: use wAE as a “numeraire”. The numbers used in this exercise are: wAE = $10/hour, n = 10; D10 = 8, ohB = 1000, and DCB = $10,000. The reduced form equation for wBE is wBE = wAE + (OCB + DCB)/Dn•hE . Solving with the numbers given here, that becomes wBE = 10 + (20,000)/8•hE = 10 + 2500/hE . ROUND ALL COLUMNS TO TWO DECIMALS! A The exercise assumes 31 workers with a uniform distribution of the his. Column A is for the individuals; this is also the number of workers in the B-market, NB. In A1 type “N(B)”. In A2 type “1”; in A3 type “=A2+1”; copy A3 to A4:32. Column B is for the his, so in B1 type “hours-1”. In B2 type “2700”. In B3 type “=B2-50”; copy B3 to B4:32. Column C is for the wBEs determined from the his, so in C1 type “w(B),S1”. In C2 type “=10+2500/B2”; copy C2 to C3:32. And Column D is for the demand in the B-market. In D1 type “w(B),D1”. In D2 type “=11.470.03*A2”; copy D2 to D3:32. Now run down Column D remembering the rule: a worker chooses B if the wB found from her hi is less than the market wage. The market wage is in Column D and declines as more workers enter B. Run down Column D until the number in Column C is lower. The equilibrium, wBE, is the last value of Column D which is greater than or equal to the value of Column C in the same row. From this equilibrium value of wBE , move left and find NBE and hE . Now find the median value of hours for the B-group and the median value of hours for the A-group. The median here is the middle value. If there are two in the middle, which will happen if there is an even number in the group, take the midpoint of the two. Here the median will be the same as the mean because the distribution is uniform. Use these values, the values above, and the equilbrium value of wBE that you found to compute lifetime income differences an observer would find between A and B. Remember the equilibrium wage comes from the Demand column, and remember that an observer will “see” only n, not Dn. Now three changes: B First, an increase in demand in the B-market. Use column E; in E1 type “w(B),D2”. In E2 type “=12.5-0.03*A2”; copy E2 to E3:32. Now run down Column E comparing with Column C, and repeat what you did in A above with Columns D and C, until you find a new wBE . From this value, move left and find new values of NBE and hE . Comparing with the initial equilibrium of A, what changes in each of these variables was caused by the increase in Demand in the B-market? Allen: labour economics, Chapter 9 page 11 Now find the median value of hours for the B-group and the median value of hours for the A-group. The median here is the middle value. If there are two in the middle, which will happen if there is an even number in the group, take the midpoint of the two. Here the median will be the same as the mean because the distribution is uniform. Use these values, the values above, and the equilbrium value of wBE that you found to compute lifetime income differences an observer would find between A and B. Remember the equilibrium wage comes from the Demand column, and remember that an observer will “see” only n, not Dn. C Second a new supply curve. But now we’ll have a change in behavior to a lesser preference for leisure, or a greater preference for work, by everyone. Use Column F for new hours: in F1 type “hours-2”; in F2 type “3200”; in F3 type “=F2-50”; copy F3 to F4:F32. Column G is new “supply” curve. In G1 type “w(B),S2; in G2 type “=10+2500/F2”; copy G2 to G3:G32. Now run down Column D comparing with Column G, and repeat what you did in A above with Columns D and C, until you find a new wBE . From this value, move left and find new values of NBE and hE . Comparing with the initial equilibrium of A, what changes in each of these variables was caused by the increase in Demand in the B-market? Now find the median value of hours for the B-group and the median value of hours for the A-group. The median here is the middle value. If there are two in the middle, which will happen if there is an even number in the group, take the midpoint of the two. Here the median will be the same as the mean because the distribution is uniform. Use these values, the values above, and the equilbrium value of wBE that you found to compute lifetime income differences an observer would find between A and B. Remember the equilibrium wage comes from the Demand column, and remember that an observer will “see” only n, not Dn. D Finally, an increase in the elasticity of demand in the B-market. Use column H: in H1 type “w(B),D3”. In H2 type “=11.47-0.015*A2”; copy H2 to H3:32. Now run down Column H comparing with Column C, and repeat what you did in A above with Columns D and C, until you find a new wBE . From this value, move left and find new values of NBE and hE . Comparing with the initial equilibrium of A, what changes in each of these variables was caused by the increase in Demand in the B-market? Now find the median value of hours for the B-group and the median value of hours for the A-group. The median here is the middle value. If there are two in the middle, which will happen if there is an even number in the group, take the midpoint of the two. Here the median will be the same as the mean because the distribution is uniform. Use these values, the values above, and the equilbrium value of wBE that you found to compute lifetime income differences an observer would find between A and B. Remember the equilibrium wage comes from the Demand column, and remember that an observer will “see” only n, not Dn. Write out your answers and turn them in along with the completed spread-sheet. -------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------------Note that the exercise shows the three effects of an increase in demand in the B-market: 1) NBE is higher after the demand increase; 2) hE is lower after the demand increase, and 3) with wAE held constant, wBE is higher after the demand increase. Finally, note the effects 1) and 3) taken together give us a long-run supply curve for the B-skill which is upward sloping. (And, if we weren’t holding wAE constant, we would also have a long-run supply curve for the A-skill which is upward sloping.)