CASE GROUP RULE ANYTHING ELSE IMPORTANT? Marbury v. Establishing Supreme Court has the power of Madison judicial judicial review. review; separation of powers This was NOT a federalism question. Martin v. Hunter's Lessee Separation of Supreme Court has the power of powers judicial review of state civil cases. Test in Judiciary Act of Section 25, footnote 5, p. 71 - 3rd where clause. Storey looked at art 3, section 2,clause 1 Cohens v. Virginia Separation of Supreme Court power to review state powers criminal cases. Same judiciary act, 2nd where clause Supremacy Clause Art 6, Clause 2 – but the intention wasn't to cover outside of DC; so convictions of state upheld, even though SCOTUS has judicial review over state criminal courts. Ex Parte McCardle Separation of Congress has at least some power to powers control SCOTUS appellate jurisdiction. They still sometimes do hear habeas corpus cases. McCulloch Federalism v. Maryland Congress can use appropriate means to obtain a legitimate and constitutionally enumerated end. Meaning today: SCOTUS will not strike down a statute if the means are not prohibited in the constitution, and the ends are rationally related to the enumerated powers in the constitution. Necessary and proper clause interpreted broadly – not interpreted as “absolutely necessary” or “indispensable” Federal government is not subject to state taxes; federal government is allowed to establish a bank by the necessary and proper clause, as a “means” to the enumerated ends of – spending, taxing, war, etc.. Pretext issue: when Congress enacts a statute and uses a legitimate means/ends as a pretext to a non-enumerated means/ends... void. U.S. Term Federalism Limits, Inc. v. Thorton (1995) States cannot fix their own term of years for their congressmen... certain things are reserved for states by the 10th Amendment – i.e. powers not delegated to the Federal Gov't by the constitution, nor prohibited to the States. The present day court line-up is tenuous with respect to federalism issues (demonstrates that we've had a shift since the New Deal Era). Gibbons v. Commerce Ogden Clause (1824) Article 1, Section 8 Congress can legislate with respect to all commerce that concerns more state than one. “Commerce” is more than buying and selling, it is all “commercial intercourse” - including transportation. Federal government now allowed to license vessels. Congress could regulate interstate commerce affecting matters occurring within a state, as long as the activity had some commercial connection with another state. But completely internal commerce of a State... may be considered as reserved for the State itself. Sole remedy is to elect a new legislature. United States v. E.C. Knight The Sugar Trust case (1895) Congress can only regulate “intrastate” activities that have a direct effect on interstate commerce. Manufacturing – indirect Commerce – direct (Holds that manufacturing is not commerce.) Commerce Clause CASE GROUP Shreveport Commerce Rate Case Clause – economic regulatory laws (1) RULE ANYTHING ELSE IMPORTANT? Upheld the ICC's right to regulate intrastate charges, at least of interstate carriers. Commerce power necessarily included the right to regulate “all matters having such a close and substantial relation to interstate traffic that control is essential or appropriate to the security of that traffic...” As long as the ultimate object was the protection of interstate commerce. First look at the “affecting commerce rationale”: 1) what is the local activity? 2) what is the relationship between the local activity and interstate commerce? 3) what is the rule for the local activity? 4) is the rule a means to some interstate commerce end? Involves interstate commerce act. The opinion held that the commerce power necessarily included the right to regulate "all matters having such a close and substantial relation to interstate traffic that control is essential or appropriate to the security of that traffic." The fact that the activity being regulated was intrastate did not place it beyond congressional control, since the ultimate object was protection of interstate commerce. Look at the effect that the local activity has on interstate commerce. Combination of the N&P clause and commerce clause! Southern Railway Commerce Clause – affecting commerce Congress has the power to prescribe safety rules to ensure interstate commerce will not be interrupted. Swift v. United States Commerce clause – stream of commerce Congress upholding the Sherman Antitrust Act Champion v. Ames The Lottery Case 1903 Commerce Upheld the Federal Lottery Act, clause – which prohibited the interstate police power shipment of lottery tickets 1st case to say - “prohibiting” IC is included within the commerce clause (which says “regulating commerce”) Court is prohibiting interstate transport of certain items or persons. “Commerce-prohibiting” technique... since Congress is limiting only the interstate shipment, they are not interfering with intrastate matters. Lottery are clearly an “evil” which are desirable for Congress to regulate. Hipolite Egg co. v. United States – Bad Egg Case (1911) Commerce Upheld the Pure Food and Drug Act clause – of 1906. police power Federal officials could seize a shipment of bad eggs after they had arrived in their destination. This was “certainly appropriate to the right to bar them from interstate commerce, and completes its purpose, which is not to merely prevent the physical movement of bad articles, but to use them.” Hoke v. United States (1913) Commerce Upheld the Mann Act, which clause – prohibited the transportation of police power women in interstate commerce for immoral purposes. Facility of interstate transportation can be taken away from the systematic enticement to and the enslavement in prostitution and debauchery of women. Congress has power over transportation among several states, that power is complete in itself, and Congress can adopt means necessary and convenient to exercise – and means may have police quality. When goods are sent to a place w/in state w/ expectation they'll be purchased and then taken to another, and this happens over and over, the goods are in a "current of commerce." Uses practical rather than technical definition of commerce. Hammer v. Commerce Daggenhar clause – t – Child police power Labor Case (1918) Struck down an act because manufacturing is not to be touched by Congress, it should be left to the states Distinguished from Lottery Case, Hippolite Egg and Hoke because in those cases because the “evil” was being transported in those cases. Here, the goods are fine, the “evil” is the employment and manufacturing, which is up to the states to regulate. Railroad Commerce Retirement Clause Board v. Alton 1935 Invalidated a law establishing a compulsory retirement and pension plan for all carriers subject to Interstate Commerce Act Court doesn't see the relationship between promoting happy workers --> efficient transportation system (IC). He thinks this is an attempt to affect social welfare, out of federal government's reach. CASE GROUP RULE ANYTHING ELSE IMPORTANT? Schechter Poultry – Sick chicken case 1935 Commerce Clause – barrier to New Deal NIRA held unconstitutional (NIRA was an effort to control hours and wages.) Activities must be in the “current” or “stream” of commerce; interstate transactions ended when the shipments reached the NYC Slaughter houses. Nor was the “affecting commerce” rational allowed, what was required was a “direct affect.” Carter Coal 1935 Commerce Clause – barrier to New Deal Bituminour Coal Conservation Act held unconstitutional (which set maximum hours and minimum wages for workers in coal mines). Distinguishes “production” and “commerce.” Production – purely local activity. Even though materials would ultimately be sold in IC. The production did not “directly affect” IC. Furthermore, local relationship like employer-employee relationships – are “local evils”, which cannot be controlled by Congress. Dissent – Cardozo – look at Sherveport, regulating prices should be okay. That provision of the Act wasn't even looked at by the majority, but Cardozo believed it should have been upheld. (1) NLRB v. Jones & Laughlin Steel Corp. 1937 Commerce Uses the “affecting commerce” Clause – post rationale and says that manufacturing court packing CAN be viewed as affecting IC. plan, new SC majority “Affecting Commerce” means burdening or obstructing commerce or the free flow of commerce. This is the beginning of modern rules and cases. Relation to IC must be “close and substantial” Huge transformation in the understanding of the Commerce Clause Proper inquiry is not the nature of the thing regulated, but its effect or burden on commerce. Have to look at regulated activities at a high level of generality. Wickard v. Commerce Filburn Clause 1942 Broadest stretch of Commerce Clause Not possible to parse out effects of individual action – cases! individual action may be regulated if it has a substantial economic effect on interstate commerce, whether local and themselves not commerce. US v. Darby 1941 Commerce Clause 2 rationales US v. Sullivan Commerce Clause *Court deference to a Congressional determination that a local activity affected IC. Shift towards trusting the political process? 2 rationales Overall – no federal police power, Congress has to get at these ends in a different way. US v. Five Gambling Devices Commerce Clause Dissent - Bootstrap approach? Not really, because court says its not a “regulation” just “reporting requirements.” Necessary and proper clause. 1) Regulating a local activity as a means of prohibition on IC – bootstrapping rationale 2) Affecting Commerce Uses necessary and proper clause? 1) Affecting Commerce: -LA – local retail sales of drugs -IC – druggist who labels properly has higher cost of production -Means – Drugist has to properly label ALL drugs -Ends – Prevents a depression of interstate drug purchases. 2) Bootstrap – regulating labeling as a means of making effective the prohibition of interstate shipment of mislabeled drugs. Dissent - Regulating local activity (incidental registration and reporting provisions, on any manufacturer and dealer involved in gambling devices, even if purely intrastate) – as a means of effectuating the prohibition of interstate shipment of the gambling devices. Struck down the statute, doesn't say its “unconstitutional”, but says that there aren't any sufficient findings to prove that it is connected to IC. Perez v. Commerce United Clause States Loansharki ng Case Uses Darby – holds that a “class” that affects IC... a member of that class (even if purely an intrastate loanshark)... can still be regulated. This was a federal criminal statute. So the the broad reach of the commerce power can apply to criminal statutes as well. No proof of connection to IC on an individual basis is necessary, when it is difficult to separate the intrastate and interstate actors. CASE GROUP United States v. Bass Commerce Clause Maryland v. Wirtz (1968) Commerce Clause RULE Struck down a statute because there were no findings . ANYTHING ELSE IMPORTANT? Unable to touch criminal activity (which is normally reserved to the states) because didn't proffer findings to show the connection. Court said that it has never declared that Congress may use a “relatively trivial” impact on IC as an excuse for broad regulation of state activities. Hodel v. Commerce Virginia Clause Surface (1981) Min. & Recl. Ass'n Upheld the constitutionality of the surface mining control and reclamation act of 1977 When congress has determined that an activity affects IC, the courts need inquire only whether the finding is rational. US v. Lopez (Baby Lopez 1972) Commerce Clause Although isolated, intrastate dealers may not have an affect on IC; as a class, congress provided findings to show that there is an impact on IC. Impossible to distinguish intrastate and interstate. Therefore, can't just say that 1 intrastate dealer has a “trivial impact” that rationale is not good here. Heart of Atlanta (1964) Commerce Clause / Civil Rights Civil Rights Act can constitutionally be reached through the commerce clause. It is okay that the court is allowing the congress to correct a moral wrong. It is clear that the national interest here is correcting a moral wrong in addition to the economic effect – court not bothered by this. Court noted that racial discrimination discourages travel for a substantial part of the black community. The court also found that Congress had power to regulate local incidents of interstate travel which might have a substantial effect on IC. “It is said that the operation of the motel here is of a purely local character. But, assuming this to be true, "if it is interstate commerce that feels the pinch, it does not matter how local the operation which applies the squeeze. Thus the power of Congress to promote interstate commerce also includes the power to regulate the local incidents thereof, including local activities in both the States of origin and destination, which might have a substantial and harmful effect upon that commerce. One need only examine the evidence which we have discussed above to see that Congress may -- as it has -prohibit racial discrimination by motels serving travelers, however "local" their operations may appear.” Katzenbac h v. McClung (1964) Ollie's BBQ Commerce Clause / Civil Rights Aggregation – although Ollie's is small, the combination of similar activities bya number of small operations will certainly have an impact on interstate commerce. Two classes of restaurants that discriminate: one class affects IC, the other does not; it is impossible to tell them apart, so Congress can reach all of them (even though no formal findings). *Careful to use Civil Rights cases' rationale in non-civil rights cases – SCOTUS is much more lenient in application of commerce clause in civil rights cases. US v. Lopez (1995) Commerce Clause / Modern Congress gave no findings that that the activity actually being regulated affected commerce. Congress made no connection to interstate commerce with the statute (jurisdictional hook) – for example, could have made it a crime to possess a gun that had been transported in interstate commerce. This is distinguished from Wickard, which was “commerce”. This is a non-economic activity. Gives us 3 rationales to consider (see below)! This is the “substantial affect” rationale here. Analogous to Bass – need an additional nexus to interstate commerce so that it will not significantly change the federalstate balance. 4 things in Lopez that matter – 1) no economic basis, 2) no express jurisdictional element, 3) no formal findings 4) tenuous relationship b/w local activity and interstate commerce CASE GROUP RULE ANYTHING ELSE IMPORTANT? US v. Morrison (2000) Commerce Clause / Modern Congress gave findings, but the court rejected them finding the connection too attenuated. If the court accepted such findings, it would allow Congress to regulate any criminal behavior, based on its “aggregate effect” on IC. Test: 1-Is it an economic thing; 2Express jurisdictional element to limit the statute's reach; 3-Formal findings, particularly for doubtful cases; 4Attenuated relationship between IC and Economic activity? Court agreed that the act was beyond Congress's power, mostly because the court felt that gender-based crimes are not economic in nature. Congress could not regulate violent crime that is not directed at the instrumentalities, channels, or goods involved in IC, leaving this duty to the states. Eldred v. Ashcroft (2003) Copyright Case Copyright clause (and other explicit clauses) allow Congress to do more, without judicial scrutiny. (Compare to Commerce Clause – which is subject to judicial approval.) Gonzales v. Raich Commerce Clause (2005) “New era” commerce clause cases can be justified under 3 rationales: 1) channels of IC; 2) instrumentalities of IC and persons or things in IC; 3) substantial affect – this case is (3). Unlike those at issue in Lopez and Morrison, the activities regulated by this statute are quintessentially economic (but is that really true?). REAL CHECK – political process Uses Wickard, “class of activities”, relies on Congress's findings A general regulatory statute bears a substantial relation to commerce, the de minimis character of individual instances arising under that statute is of no consequence.” Failure to regulate that class of activity would undercut the regulation of the interstate market in that commodoty. McCulloug Taxing h v. Power Maryland States cannot levy taxes on the US Government. Both the US Government and the states have the power to tax, but not concurrently. This case turns on the supremacy clause – Art. 6, Clause 2 Trust the political process. The states can vote their representatives out if the taxes are too high. But the subjects of a tax (US gov't) could not, if the states were allowed to tax the gov't. When Congress taxes the states – it must be uniform. Dictum – national government can tax a state bank. All on part vs. part on all Bailey v. Drexel Furniture Co. (1922) Taxing Power (Article I, Section 8) Child Labor Act struck down. Court said this was a regulation with a “tax” as the penalty – NOT a tax with incidental regulations imposed. Congress looked at the means/ends. Look at the purpose – regulation OR raising revenue? Marshall pretext? It is okay to use taxes to regulate, long as it is an enumerated end / AND that it is done fairly. Veazie Taxing Cited in Bailey, a non-analogous case 1) Imposing a tax, by using the N&P clause to achieve an Power (1869) because in Veazie – they had an enumerated end – thru commerce clause. enumerated end – securing a uniform 2) Use the TAX clause, to achieve an enumerated end. national currency. McCray Taxing Cited in Bailey Power (1904) After Bailey (which approves Deremus), okay for Congress to have more than 1 motive in mind, but the means have to have some relationship to raising revenue, not just solely related to the un-enumerated power of suppressing drugs. US v. Kahriger (1935) Taxing Power 2 possible purposes: 1) Raise Revenue; 2) Supress gambling (regulatory) Just because the revenue raised by the tax is negligible doesn't make it invalid; just because it discourages the activities taxed doesn't make it invalid. Upheld the constitutionality of an occupational tax imposed by the 1951 Revenue Act – which levied a tax on persons engaged in the business of accepting wagers and required such persons to register with the IRS. CASE GROUP US v. Butler (1936) Spending Power RULE Congress may not regulate in a particular area merely on the ground that it is thereby providing for the general welfare; only taxing and spending may be done for the general welfare. Dissent – rule now - 1) purpose must be national; 2) must not be a coercion in order to regulate an area of state control; 3) means must be related to the ends; 4) political check exists. ANYTHING ELSE IMPORTANT? The tax is unconstitutional because the spending is unconstitutional. Congress has no right to regulate areas of essentially local control, including agriculture, and it also could not coercively purchase compliance with a regulatory scheme. Conditional appropriation of funds would be appropriate, but that wasn't the case here because the farmer was coerced to join the program. Charles C. Spending Steward v. Power Davis (1937) Sustained the unemployment Abandoned the requirement for distinction between compensation provisions of the Social conditional appropriations and appropriations requiring Security Act. Unlike Butler, funds binding promises. were not earmarked. Employer was entitled to a credit of up to 90% of the federal tax for any contributions to a state unemployment fund certified by a federal agency as meeting the requirements of the act. Helvering v. Davis (1937) Spending power Upheld the old age benefits provisions of the Social Security Act, a federal program that established an entirely federal program. Upheld because Cardozo found that a system of old age pensions is best left to national interests. Congress has broad discretion to determine spending for general welfare; problem is a national one. Oklahoma v. CSC Spending Power Federal govt, offers 90% of road money on condition is that Hatch Act must apply to every employee involved. OK wanted an elected highway commissioner, SCOTUS upholds federal power if OK wants money they need to have an non-elected highway commissioner Oklahoma v. Civil Service Commission grant o highway funds given on condition that no state highway employee is elected. Spending is valid since means (condition) are related to the end (building the highway) since elected official may give preference to certain constituents. Woods v. Miller Co. (1948) War Power Congress sought to impose rent controls because of the post-war housing shortage. Court held that even though actual combat had terminated, a state of war still technically existed, additionally the court had a right to take all N&P means to remedy the post-war problems. Missouri v. Treaty Power Congress has the power to make Holland treaties, and the states must follow. (1920) McCulloug Modern h v. Federalism Maryland Limits on National Powers IS THERE A PARITY OF INTERGOVERNMENTAL IMMUNITES??? NO-Marshall says a national tax on a state bank would be invalid. Why not? Everybody is represented in Congress so there is a national political process. Not all people of the US are represented in Maryland's political process. If all the people of the US are represented in Congress, then we have a check because those who impose the tax are taxing their own constituents. However, the TAX MUST BE UNIFORM according to the constitution. So you can't only tax South Dakota. The dictum is that the national govt can tax a state bank-this dictum does not hold up initially--The initial fate is that Marshall's dictum is rejected. COLLECTOR v DAY (1871) rejects this; then at 362 GRAVES OVERRULES THIS AGAIN. In the years after McCullough, federal immunity from state taxes grew. State immunity was not reciprocal, but after the Civil War, state immunity grew. Then after the 1930's, state immunities shrank again. CASE GROUP Collector v. Day Heverling v. Gerhardt RULE ANYTHING ELSE IMPORTANT? State immunity from federal taxation State judges salary is immune from national taxation-the state is immune from national taxation so the employee is derivitively is immune from tax. Really a decision that state's are immune from national taxation. DERIVITIVE IMMUNITY. Contraction of state immunity Two guiding principles when Didn't overrule Collector, only limited it to its own facts. deciding whether state instrumentality should be immunized from national What is the constitutional source of state immunity from taxation national taxation or state immunity from national regulation? Federalism – structural principles – derived from 1.Excludes from immunity activities constitution... no-one can deny constitution defines a federal not essential to preservation of state government. governments though the tax collected from state treasury The whole constitution points to having two separate a.Want to see gain from limiting governments – state and federal. The power to tax is the national taxing power power to destroy. 2.Burden on state government should be other than speculative a.Should be some corresponding tangible protection to the state b.All the state is losing here is ability to pay employees less than going rate “the State is as sovereign and independent as the general government.” Graves v. O'Keefe No immunity of federal employees Collector v. Day overruled. from state income tax. No implied constitutional immunity from income taxation of the salaries of officers or employees of the national or a state government or their instrumentalities. New York v. United States (Mineral Waters Case) As long as its not discriminatory, and as long as we don't tax a state as a state, then the tax is fine. Although NY had a conservation interest, they were still acting as a company – and that can be taxed. Look at how ALL the states operate, to see what ONLY a state can own. Stone's Concurring – a non discriminatory tax criteria is not a good criteria. “the problem is not one to be solved by a formula.” The limitation upon the taxing power of each (state and federal governments), so far as it affects the other, must receive a practical construction which permits both to function with the minimum of interference each with the other. Black and Douglas dissent – any activity that they engage in within its police power should be considered a legitimate gov't activity; constitution is a compact between sovereigns; want to see the feds and state as co-equals. Automatic Couplers are required! This is an interstate commerce rationale case. State-owned railroad at port of San Francisco; state owned RR is charged with federal violation; they did not have the auto couplers. Stone says if in southern railway we have to worry about a private railway having an accident disrupting IC, the problem is just as present if a state owns the RR. Cal v. Daley (Haley?) RAILWAY LABOR ACT-national govt can delay strikes. Interstate Commerce case Sets rules for col bargaining. CA says no col bargaining; court says national requirement for col bargaining must be used. Case v. Bowles WAR POWER STATUTE EMERGEGNCY PRICE CONTROL LEGISLATION STATE OF WA sells timber to run a public school systemthe court says WA can't do this against the price regulation; national interest in controlling inflaction is more important than state interest in education. California v. US National Government can regulate states Congress imposes price limits to hold down inflation during war. Maryland v. Wirtz National minimum wage upheld for state employees. Interstate Commerce CASE GROUP Oklahoma v. Civil Service Fry First modern signal of growing sensitivity on the Court to federalistic limits North Carolina v. Califano National League of Cities Gives new vitality to state autonomy RULE ANYTHING ELSE IMPORTANT? If you want to get highway funding, must structure it the way we want to do it. Government has a legitimate interest in how their money is spent. Seems like if wages paid are an essential state function, then the highways and roads also seem to be an essential, traditional state role. So this case, which tolerated governmental interference? OK still good law b/c it was controlled by spending power, not the commerce power. Sustained the application of temporary federal wage controls to state employees, but opinion was narrow, because Fry concerned a national emergency. Carved out exception to the “limitless” commerce power. Fry – balancing Limits imposed by commerce power, don't apply when using war power, spending power, or to enforce the 14 th amendment. Commerce Power limits Conditions for national aid to the states for hospitals, medical care – provided states had to undertake a certain kind of economic regulation to hold down the cost to deliver medical care – was inconsistent with North Carolina constitutional limits. Response - “Look at footnote 17 – regarding Fourteenth Amendment.” The supreme court allowed this-you got to break your constitution to get national money. So limits on Commerce Power are not the same as limits on other powers. Why not? Brennan in dissent says that spending power could be used to get around this-but if the interference is the same why does it matter which power is used. Court held that the 10th Amendment barred Congress from making federal minimum wage and overtime rules applicable to state and municipal employees. Three part test for invalidation: 1) Statute must be regulating states as states 2) Must be addressing matters that are indisputably attributes of state sovereignty 3) Compliance would directly impair the ability of states to perform integral features of state regulation. Violated the 10th Amendment sentiment that Congress many not exercise power in a fashion that impairs the State's integrity or their ability to function effectively in the federal system because compliance would have cost the states and their municipal subdivisions substantial sums, and the rule stripped the states of their discretion to decide how to allocate a fixed pool of funds available for salaries. Doesn't overrule Fry. Dissent wanted a balancing test – national interests vs. intrusion on the states. FRAMEWORK Three types of National Statutes 1) Regulate private sector (under any power) 2) Regulate states and sometimes local activities - Garcia 3) Regulate states as agents to regulate private sector OR establishing an agency 1) Using the spending power or commerce power to regulate private activity, less room for states to regulate. Ex. Regulations that individuals be paid a certain wage. Ex. Hodel – Congress' power to regulate surface mining because it leaves ugly scars on earth – under the Commerce clause. 2) Like National League of Cities – extending rules of private activities to the public sector. Ex. Regulating states as states – as a result, states can raise taxes or cut funding in some other area. 3) Get states to pay and enforce national law. Ex. Hodel – using states to determine nationally-created standards, within a year, 35/38 states with surface mining decided to appropriate funds. Ex. “cooperative federalism” Hodel v. Virginia Surface Min. & Recl. Ass'n Category 1 – regulates private activity Court re-stated the three part National League of Cities test. Hodel rejected pre-enforcement facial challenges, based on the commerce clause and the 10th Amendment, to surface mining control and reclamation Act, a law which imposed significant limits on private mining operations. 1.There must be a showing that the challenged statute regulates the States as states – FAILS HERE! 2.The Federal regulation must address matters that are indisputably attributes of state sovereignty 3.It must be apparent that the state's compliance with the Federal law would directly impair their ability to structure integral operations in the areas of traditional governmental functions 10th Amendment challenge fails because #1 in the test failed. Can't invalidate. This does not require the states to participate, Feds can do all the regulating. However, if a state wants to, then they CAN establish a program of “cooperative federalism” that allows the states within limits established by the federal minimum standards, to enact and administer their own regulatory programs. CASE GROUP RULE ANYTHING ELSE IMPORTANT? United Category 2 – Transporta states as tion Union states v. Long Island Railroad Co. Court focused on part 3 of the Hodel test. RR operation not typically a state function (usually private sector). State policy is overridden. Railway Labor Act is designed to deal with employeremployee disputes. Congress says no strikes unless there has been mediation and a cooling off period. Ferc v. Miss. Not invalid because there was an immediate effect on interstate commerce. No interference with traditional functions, so not invalid. As for state autonomy - EEOC v. Wyoming Congress suggests regulation standards for electric & natural gas facilities 1.WI objected because they had jumped through procedural hoops and done all they wanted to do -States had to go through administrative proceedings to decide whether to adopt national standard OR -They couldn't regulate at all -State regulation of electric & natural gas is preempted (this is a position like Steward Machine) National law pre-empts a Wyoming law, when Wyoming Game Wardens must retire after age 55. Used the 3-part test from Hodel, National League: Part 1) met, Part 2) Majority doesn't decide, Part 3) “Directly Impair” - no So, not invalid. There is sufficiently less serious degree of intrusion, so it is unnecessary to curb Congress's decision to extend its regulatory authority. La Pierre thinks this was correctly decided The Fair Labor Standards Act at issue here is the only one ever held unconstitutional (now as applied to city of San Antonio) Garcia v. San Antonio Category 2 South Dakota v. Dole Category 3 Congress enacted a law which directed the secretary of transportation to withhold 5% of federal highway funds to state with a drinking age of less than 21 years old. Congress may use the spending power to induce states to cooperate with regulations in areas that are not easily controlled. Compliance with this law is voluntary and the stakes are not high. Additionally, if the funds are accepted by the state, the conditions are laid out unambiguously and are fully understood by the states. NY v. United States Category 3 Statute invalid, Congress may not simply commandeer the legislative process of the State by directly compelling them to enact and enforce a federal regulatory program. Congress was forcing NY to choose between 2 unconstitutional options. - Congress can regulate by giving states incentives, so that state chooses to accept regulation & get federal benefit, or not. OK so long as choice exists - 10th amendment is a truism, but doesn’t make it meaningless; confirms the background understanding that federal government can’t displace state role -Congress cannot tell states to regulate, nor can it tell states to take title to something, so it can’t give them the “choice” between two unconstitutional means. Can’t force states to enact or administer programs. To do otherwise is commandeering - White dissent: This was something that states actively sought as a resolution to a collective action problem; majority’s “civics lesson” assertion of federalism as protecting freedom rings hollow when compared to this crisis of figuring out how to dispose of nuclear waste; Congress could attain the same goals through other powers (condition grants under the spending clause on taking title, for ex.) - Majority response: it doesn’t matter if the states wanted this. Individual political actors might prefer to do away with balance (shift responsibility), but federalism doesn’t exist at sufferance of states; it’s for the preservation of individual liberty - Stevens concurrence/dissent: Why can’t federal government tell states what to do here? They can and do direct state officers all the time. Issue of Congress regulating SAMTA Incidentally, San Antonio wages were well above the - extension of rules for private minimum (Blackmun may have had national across-the-board sector applied to public sector standards on his mind) National League of Cities overruled 1.Unworkable decision - to hard to Majority – only wants political process as a safeguard to figure out what fit decide protection of state sovereignty. The effectiveness of 2.Tripartite test of NLC and Hodel too the procedural limit is evident by the fact that the states are difficult exempt from the operation of many federal statutes and receive significant federal aid for their own programs. Overrules National League of Cities CASE GROUP RULE ANYTHING ELSE IMPORTANT? Printz v. US Category 3 Statute invalid, the court concluded that the Brady Bill violated the provision of NY v. US which said that the federal government may not compel the states to enact or administer a federal regulatory program. Court found that the responsibilities take away from the duties of the police and diminish the balance of power in the branches of government. La Pierre: Court has a problem with provisions under which the federal government compels states to take certain steps. However, Congress CAN condition funds, give states a choice, etc. *Distinguish Printz and NY from Garcia? Garcia – statute was generally applicable to states and private enterprise. P & NY – federal government was trying to force a state or local government to enact legislation or regulation or tried to force state or local officials to perform particular governmental functions. This is violating the state's basic exercise of sovereignty. Reno v. Condon Category 2 FACTS? Statute upheld, in enacting this statue, Congress did not run afoul of the federalism principles enunicated in NY v. US and Printz. (Category 3 cases.) This is within the commerce power to regulate. This is a law of general applicability – regulates both the state and those who have acquired the information and it applies to the public and private sector. National government is not burdening the public sector more than the private sector. Although the court talks about general applicability – doesn't insist on it. Leaves open the possibility of circumstances that we don't need general applicability... may be some laws that fall exclusively on the public sector that are constitutionally valid. Fits under the commerce clause in 2 ways - “thing in IC”, substantial impact General Info. Dormant Commerce Clause Article 1, Section 8 Dormant Commerce clause is used when Congress has been silent on an issue, it has taken no action, express or implied, indicating its own policy on a given subject matter. The objection to state authority rests entirely on the dormant commerce clause. On the unexercised commerce power itself, and on the free trade value it symbolizes. Distinguished from the Commerce Clause power – in this situation, Congress has exercised the commerce power, has indicated its legislation which compels inconsistent state action to give way – by virtue not only of the exercise of the commerce power under Article 1, Section 8, but also because of the effect of the supremacy clause in Article 6. COURT'S JOB FOR DCC: 1.Inquire into state ENDS 2.Scrutinize means-ends relationship (to what extent does state law achieve this end?) 3.Look at burden on interstate commerce 4.Look at interest state intones (economic? Health & safety? Can't have bad purpose) Gibbons v. Not really a Ogden DCC case Marshall found the New York steamboat monopoly grant to be in conflict with the federal laws licensing those engaged in coastal trade. State law invalid under the supremacy clause of Article 4. No analogy between tax and commerce power. Yes, states can have these laws, but source is not from any power to regulate commerce.... source is the background set of powers, “police powers”. State power to regulate local activity, comes from police power. National power to regulate local activities comes from the fact that the local activity has an affect on commerce. And supremacy clause lets national law win. Wilson v. Black Bird Creek Marsh Co. DCC Act authorizing the building of a dam in the creek (which flowed into the Delaware river) was not repugnant to the Commerce Clause. Court noted that the Act was trying to enhance property value and the health and safety of the inhabitants. Proper use of police powers. Cooley v. DCC Board of Wardens of the Port of Philly The Pennsylvania law of 1803 was struck down because the states were divested of this power by the grant of the commercial power to Congress in an act of 1789. There are national and local subjects of commerce. Court has now abandoned Cooley doctrine. CASE GROUP RULE ANYTHING ELSE IMPORTANT? Buck v. DCC Kuykendall Judicial inquiry into the purpose Buck was struck down because it seemed to rest on economic regulations Bradley v. Public Utilities Comm'n DCC Judicial inquiry into the purpose Upheld because seemed to rest on safety concerns Georgia Railroad cases DCC Judicial inquiry into the effect 1st case – law upheld, safety measure, slow down and blow the whistle 2nd case – railroads provided evidence that compliance with the GA law would turn a normally 4.5 hour run to a 10 hour run. Law rejected! S.C. State Highway Departmen t v. Barnwell Bros. DCC (Modern Balancing Approach) RR and Trucking Cases They upheld the S.C. Law. As long as the state does not discriminate, the burden is one which the Constitution permits because it is an inseparable incident of the exercise of a legislative authority, which under the Constitution, has been left to the states. Two part test: 1) Whether the Legislature in adopting regulations such as the present has acted within its province (ends). 2) Whether the means of regulation chosen are reasonably adapted to the end sought. Stone does not look into the affect. Stone does not scrutinize the legislative basis. No inquiry into the burden on IC. *Use this case if: defending state laws. Southern DCC Pacific Co. v. Arizona RR and Trucking Case Arizona Train Limit Law prohibited operating railroad trains of more than x cars struck down. Stone uses the balancing test. Balances the burdens on IC – which seem to be plenty; with the state's interests – which seem to be conflicting w.r.t. safety. Stone also goes beyond Barnwell and scrutinizes the means/ends. Difference b/w this and Barnwell articulated by the court – this is a RR case. *Use this case if: defending economic interests that are regulated by state laws. Bibb v. Navajo Freight Lines, Inc. RR and Trucking Case This is the first case when the court decided to exercise greater scrutiny that in Barnwell w.r.t. trucking. State law was that you had to use contour shaped mud flaps. This law was struck down. The truckers argued that getting new mudguards would be too costly, but this was not enough. However, 45 states required straight mudguards. This was important because the effect – would require truckers to shift their cargo to completely different trucks. This essentially runs afoul of the policy of free trade reflected in the Commerce Clause. Burdens IC! State's interest – safety (even though the trial court found that the contoured were no more effective than straight) – interest is illusory! Douglas looks to see whether the regulations actually work to offset the costs – would have been different if there were a stronger showing of safety. RR and Trucking Case An Iowa statute prohibits the use of certain large trucks within the State – this was held to unconstitutionally burden IC. The total effect of the law as a safety measure in reducing accidents and casualties is so slight and problematical that it does not outweigh the national interest in keeping interstate commerce free from interferences that seriously impede it. All burdens are imposed out of state – Iowa's highways don't get wear and tear. (Even though the statute did allow these kind of trucks to go to the border cities.) When the legislature is burdening those who do not participate in the political system, then it is time for judicial intervention. Four part test: 1) Look at the state's means 2) Identify means/ends relationship 3) Identify burdens imposed on IC a. Higher costs b. More singles on the road = more accidents c. Burden of de-coupling 4) Balancing tests – state interests vs. burden on IC Brennan concur – even if you use Barnwell, this does not pass. Wants rational basis – and look at the legislation's face value. Rehnquist dissent – useless to speculate why legislators voted for certain policies. Line-drawing is not for the court; state legislature is more intimately attached to the issue. Does not like balancing. Be careful using transportation cases in other contexts – these are in a field of their own! DCC Kassel v. DCC Consolidat ed Freightway s Corp. CASE GROUP RULE ANYTHING ELSE IMPORTANT? DCC Milk Cases NY statute wanted to say you have to buy milk at a certain price, was invalidated. NY refused to license Seelig to sell milk in NY unless it agreed to conform to the state's price regulation regarding the sale of imported milk. Court held that to be unconstitutional. Cardozo does not allow this because of the BURDENS/EFFECTS on IC. Court held that this amounted to a customs duty, which is unconstitutional. This is economic protectionism of the NY dairy farmers. Cardozo says this is economic, but can also view as safety purpose. NY state children need milk and NY has an interest in making sure there is a steady supply. Court says we can always find a health and safety measure lurking behind an economic purpose, but the reverse is true as well. PURPOSE: Aim and effect of establishing an economic barrier against competition of products of another state. Henneford DCC v. Silas Mason Co. State taxes stuff coming in at the same rate that in-state stuff was already taxed at. The purpose is economic, protecting local retailers from people going out of state to buy. Distinguish from Baldwin – Baldwin eliminates the competition because everybody is paying the same price. Here, just add 2% to everybody's overhead, but the cheapest is still the cheapest. Breard v. DCC Alexandria Prohibited door-to-door solicitation of orders to sell goods except by consent of the occupants. No constitutional objection to the ordinance. Even though there might have been an effect of discriminating against IC. Because its purpose was to protect the privacy rights of homeowners, not to provide an economic advantage to local businesses. Mintz v. Baldwin DCC Upheld a NY law prohibiting the importation of cattle unless the were from herds certified as being free from Bang's disease. This was considered to be a health and safety purpose! Welton v. Missouri DCC Invalidated a MO license requirement Purpose – H&S? Shoddy techniques were the same in state for OOS peddlers. The law applied and OOS, hard to argue sanitation end. only to peddlers of merchandise; Seems real purpose is protecting economic interest. peddlers of MO goods did not need a license. Dean Milk Co. v. Madison DCC Milk Cases Ordinance barred the sale of pasteurized milk unless it had been processed and bottled at an approved pasteurization plant within five miles of the central square of Madison. Court strikes statute. Court says this is a health and safety regulation. However, in practical effect, it excludes from distribution in Madison wholesome milk produced and pasteurized in Illinois. This took a new view – in town vs. out of town interests, rather than just in state vs. out of state interests/burdens. Burdened parties cannot participate in the political process. Reasonable alternatives were available. Justice Black Dissent – no burden because any milk producer can bring their outside milk into Madison to have it pasteurized and sold in Madison. Milk Cases Mississippi tried to enact a reciprocity agreement that wouldn't allow LA milk unless LA allowed Miss. milk. Court struck down. Uses the Pike Test – p. 317 – when a law is burdensome! Burden is on the challengers of the law to say that it is burdensome. Pike Test: 1) Legitimate local interest 2) Effects on IC incidental 3) Legislation upheld unless the burden imposed is clearly excessive in relation to local benefits. 4) Also, can it be promoted with a lesser impact on IC? Court said that a self-help, reciprocity agreement is not allowed, should have taken LA to court if they thought LA was behaving badly by not accepting their milk. Reciprocity agreement here is definitely not a H&S measure, because they would have taken the LA milk as long as LA signed the agreement. Miss. Had the obvious alternative of inspecting the LA shipments of milk to their own standards (Dean Milk teaches us that the burden of the reciprocity clause cannot be justified in view less burdensome means.) Baldwin v. Seelig Great DCC Atlantic & Pacific Tea CASE GROUP RULE ANYTHING ELSE IMPORTANT? Hunt v. DCC Wash State Apple Advertis. Comm. When a regulation is discriminatory – use the Hunt Test! Shifts the burden to the lawmakers, to justify that it WASN'T discriminatory. NC Statute saying that all containers of apples should bear UDSA grade or none at all. WA apples have their own stamp, NC doesn't want to allow. Consumer protection? Not likely, since they allow for no grade at all. Balancing test applied. 1) burdens and discriminates against IC – increased costs of OOS growers, WA loses competitive advantage. 2) Discriminatory, since NC apple growers were behind legislation. Burden falls on state to demonstrate non-discriminatory alternatives – failed to sustain burden. Failed means/end inquiry: Illusory end, does not provide consumers w/ helpful information, consumers don't buy the containers – distributors do! Alternatives – Require grades at least or beyond USDA grade. Discrimination against WA outweighs the burden that the state proved. Exxon v. Governor of MD 1973 Gas shortage – MD statute prohibited producers and refiners of petroleum from operating gas stations in MD. 8-1 majority opinion, majority says no burden imposed. 34 OOS nonproducer/refiner companies in light of 3,780 local retailers. Others can still compete in the market, the flow of gas in IC will not cease. No discrimination on sales once gas is in state. Plenty of OOS retail dealers left to compete with MD independent retailers. Blackman says that the discrimination does not have to be universal to be discrimination., because of Hunt. The big problem for Blackman is that almost all of the burdens are hitting out of state people. Majority doesn't care because this does not impede ISC. But this is probably because MD has no refineries. MD is an anamoly. This is the law today! Law invalid since the discrimination exists with respect to the retailers, since 98% of the affected retailers are owned out of state and so have no recourse to the legislature. By Hunt, no need for 100% discrimination to be discriminatory law. HUNT TEST: 1) Burden falls on State to justify the legitimate local benefits to justify inequality 2) Show that alternatives are inadequate a. State has an interest in fostering competition in the market place b. Don't let them favor their own stations 3) At least one non-discriminatory alternative (e.g. Prohibiting competitive pricing) 4) MD has not knocked out ALL competition, just clobbered the most effective OOS competitors. Very clever, but discriminatory. Blackmun dissents and La Pierre agrees w/ him. Milk Cases Hood was a Boston milk distributor who obtained milk from NY producers and maintained three receiving depots there, sought a NY license to establish a fourth. NY commissioner denied a license for the depot under the state law stating that licenses for new plants could not be issued unless the commissioner was satisfied that “issuance of the license will not tend to a destructive competition in a market already adequately served, and that the issuance of the license is in the public interest. LP: The denial of the NY receiving depot is a direct restriction on the amount of milk that Hood can purchase in NY for distribution in another state. Although states may impose even burdensome regulations in the interests of local safety and health, this was a purely commercial interest . Therefore, a state may not use its admitted powers to protect the health and safety of its people as a basis for suppressing competition. Because this statute has the prohibited effect, it is invalid. H.P. Hood & Sons v. Du Mond DCC DCC Limiting OOS-ers to local products and resources. La Pierre – wants us to think about considering distinction between 197 OOS and 34 non-p/r Dissent – Black – The language is not discriminatory, it was not intended to be discriminatory, and it was not administered in a discriminatory way. The real issue is whether all phases of interstate business are judicially immunized from state laws against destructive competitive business. Not up to the Court to revise a state's economic judgment. Dissent – Frankfurter – This case should be remanded. We should balance the state's interest in the prevention of destructive competition with the effect that the act would have on IC. CASE GROUP RULE ANYTHING ELSE IMPORTANT? But the way it was written – PA rule imposed burdens on their own constituents. NY is bumping up price on all dairy farmers, out of state as well; imposing burdens on out of state farmers too. The purpose of the law obviously is to reach a domestic situation in the interests of the welfare of the producers and *Compare to Baldwin – Distinguished consumers of milk in PA. In rejecting the challenge, he because that act attempted to wholly emphasized that the activity affected was essentially local in affect interstate commerce by setting PA. If dealers who shipped any fraction of their milk outside up a tariff barrier against milk the state were exempt, then there would be a crippling effect imported into the enacting state. on local enforcement of the law. Additionally, only a fraction of the milk produced in PA is shipped elsewhere, so the effect Winners – PA dairy farmers, hav ea on IC is minimal. minimum price floor Losers – NY milk consumers, PA consumers, all milk dealers Milk Control Board v. Eisenberg Farm Products DCC Milk Cases Sustained the application of a PA minimum price regulation to a NY milk dealer who bought milk from PA for shipment out of state. Cities Service Gas Co. v. peerless Oil & Gas Co. DCC Court rejected a commerce clause attack on a state regulation of natural gas prices designed to conserve an important local resource. An OK agency fixed a minimum price on all natural gas taken from a field, requiring a pipeline company to pay more than the prevailing rates. Most of the gas was destined for consumers outside of OK. Law is valid, applies to all gas taken from the field, whether destined for in state or out of state. Waste Cases Court held unconstitutional the NJ law which prohibited the importation of most “solid or liquid waste which originated or was collected outside the territorial limits of this state.” Regardless of its purpose, a state cannot discriminate against movement of goods in IC. LP: The court finds that the law is discriminatory on its face, and in purpose, and the court recognizes a long standing per se invalidity rule for state legislation with the intent of simple economic protectionism (Baldwin, Buck, Welton). Hunt test – once there is a showing of discrimination – burden shifts to state to show that the legitimate state interest outweighs the discrimination and that there are no other less discriminatory means to achieve the state's end. This statute is different than in Hunt, because it is discriminatory on its face, so didn't use the Hunt test. Stewart (maj) sees this as economic protectionism. Pennsylvan DCC – state ia v. West restraints on Virginia exports of natural resources West Virginia required that all local needs for natural gas be met before any gas could be exported. Majority found that requirement a “prohibited interference” with IC. Dissent – Holmes – could see nothing in the commerce clause to prevent a state from giving a preference to its inhabitants in the enjoyment of its natural advantages. Foster Fountain Packing Co. v. Haydel DCC LA statute prohibited export of shrimp until heads and shells had been removed. LA said needed the heads and shells for fertilizer. Invalid Court – prohibition was an effort to force the packing industry to locate from neighboring Mississippi back to Louisiana. Pike v. Bruce Church DCC Modern home-state processing requirement. Arizona required that cantaloupes be packed in Arizona, and identified as coming from an Arizona packer. Invalid. AZ wanted to ensure that they got “Arizona Grown” stamp and wanted to enhance AZ reputation. Yes, interest was legitimate, but didn't outweigh the burden imposed on interstate commerce. Where the statute regulates even-handedly to effectuate a legitimate local public interest, and its effects on interstate commerce or only incidental, it will be upheld unless the burden imposed on such commerce is clearly excessive in relation to the putative local benefits. Philadelph DCC ia v. New Jersey Winners – local OK people, hold on to their gas reserves. Losers – NG companies and consumers Rehnquist – dissent – Takes seriously the health and safety purpose of the legislation and equates it to legislation establishing quarantine laws. CASE GROUP RULE ANYTHING ELSE IMPORTANT? Hughes v. Oklahoma DCC OK law forbidding any person to transport or ship minnows for sale outside the state which were procured within the waters of the state, invalid. The law was facially discriminatory (used the Hunt test), while it may have served a legitimate purpose, nondiscriminatory alternatives were not considered by the state. *So should have applied the “virtual per se rule of invalidity”. (Like in Philadelphia). Rehnquist – dissent – thinks its not discriminatory, so use Pike, and it easily survives the Pike test. The law says “noone” can take the minnows out. Applies alike to both in-state and out of state minnow growers. Minnesota v. Clover Leaf Creamery DCC Upheld a statute that banned the retail sale of milk products in plastic nonreturnable containers but permitted sales in nonreturnable containers – mainly containers made of pulpwood. Legislature found that the use of nonreturnable containers presents a solid waste management problem, promotes energy waste, and depletes natural resources. Plastic containers originated out of state, pulpwood is a major instate product. State interests outweighed the interstate burden. This is the place to go if you need to validate state ends! Court accepts at face value , the state's articulation of ends. No approach with a lesser impact on interstate activities is available. Uses Pike test. Maine v. Taylor DCC Court upheld a Maine statute prohibiting the importation of live bait-fish because of the adverse biological consequences of nonnative species and parasites. Court has upheld express discrimination against interstate commerce where the statute serves a legitimate local purpose that cannot be served as well by an available nondiscriminatory means. (Proved that testing and screening wouldn't work. No alternatives!) American Trucking Associatio ns, Inc. v. USF Holland, Inc. DCC Michigan Statute – flat $100 fee for trucks moving intrastate P – Interstate trucking companies, complaining because if they only have a small amount of business, or a small number of trips through Michigan, then they are paying more money per trip than a company who only, and frequently, travels intrastate. Upheld the statute. On its face – did not discriminate, applied even handedly to all carriers. Why didn't court pay attention to P's argument? Because the record contained no evidence that P's argument mattered... that it actually affected anything. Neither burdens nor discriminates. On its face does not discriminate—everybody pays they same so this applies EVANHANDEDLY. *Since this is not discriminatory on its face but seems to be even handed, the challenger has to show us the burden. *This is the PIKE BALANCING TEST—so the challenger must prove the burden and prove what is wrong with this statute. *There is no burden and no discrimination, so not violating the dormant commerce clause. This is also EXXON. Granholm v. Heald DCC Invalidated MI and NY laws providing that in-state wineries could ship wine directly to consumers, but OOS wineries could not. Laws discriminate against IC. This is explicit discrimination against IC. It mandates different treatment of instate and OOS economic interests that benefits the former and burdens the latter. Mere fact of non-residence should not foreclose a producer in one State from access to markets in other States. Necessity for reciprocal sale privileges risks trade rivalries and animosities. Essentially – this is a low level trade war! *Invalidity per se, facially discriminatory. *21st Amendment does not allow States to regulate the direct shipment on terms that discriminate in favor of in-state producers. CASE GROUP South Central Timber Dev., Inc. v. Wunnicke Exceptions to DCC – but really this WAS a DCC case, b/c didn't qualify for Market Participation Exception RULE ANYTHING ELSE IMPORTANT? Market Participation Case This case allowed Alaska to include in its contracts a clause requiring that the purchaser would partially process the timber in Alaska before it was shipped out of the state. Designed to protect existing timber-processing industries, promote new industries, and derive revenue from the State's timber resources. IF Alaska is acting as a “market participant” rather than as a market regulator, then the dormant commerce Clause places no limitation on the activities. HOWEVER – holds that it was regulating. Just because a contract was involved, doesn't mean that this is a “market participant” case. Analyzes Hughes, Reeves, and White Distinguish from White – limit of the market-participant doctrine must be that it allows a State to impose burdens on commerce within the market in which it is a participant. Market must be narrowly defined (like in White – state employees)! Court says – Alaska is not a market participant in the timber processing market. Scrutinized under Pike – cannot survive scrutiny. Hughes v. Exceptions to Alexandria DCC Scrap Corp. Reeves, Inc. v. Stake Market Participant Case Metal processors – junkyards / scrap yards Receive a bounty for every car they crunched into a pile of metal Junk yards would share this bounty with towing trucks If you were a Maryland junkyard – to get bounty, needed next to nothing documentation that the vehicle was abandoned. If out of state – had to have much more extensive documentation. If you own a tow truck – obviously going to bring the vehicles in state. Exceptions to Market Participant Case DCC Government ownership of cement plant – SD. Cement plant produced far more cement than could be used in SD. Between 1970 and 1977 – 40% was sold out of state. 1978, SD enjoyed an economic boom – demand for cement rocketed. In state demand exceeded supply of state-owned cement plant. State government adopted a policy – no cement produced at the plant should be sold outside of SD until in-state demand is satisfied. Court – state's activity as a market participant – not subject to dormant commerce clause scrutiny. This clause is supposed to be concerned with the state as a regulator, the state regulating private markets. THIS case was more like... a state as a buyer of goods. Yes – Market Participant. Supreme Court holds – State's decision to sell its state-owned cement instate only, is not subject to the dormant commerce clause scrutiny. It is not a market regulator. State as a seller of goods! If there is a cement problem: privatize, subsidize, gov't ownership (market participant case), i.e., socialism—three possible solutions to the a cement problem or transportation. ALL THREE WAYS OF ACHIEVING PUBLIC GOODS. White v. Exceptions to mass DCC Council of Constructi on Employers, Inc. What did the mayor of Boston do? On any construction publics work project, financed with residents of Boston, 50% of jobs must be to Boston residents. How did he ensure this? Court – dormant commerce clause does not apply. Mayor is a purchaser of labor, entered into labor market, made rule for the city with respect to purchasing labor. How did court take this view? What was the mechanism by which the Mayor went? Spending... here's the money, on this condition. Must have 50% city employees. What else could the Mayor have done? This approach: same rule embodied in an ordinance – viewed as a regulation. However, doesn't the city have the same regulatory purpose in mind in both situations? Sure. When city lawyers have read the case... and its a condition contract, dormant commerce clause exception. Is that what this boils down to? For now, settled. Whether good or bad idea, be alert to such circumstances! (In state AND in town...) Corfield v. Coryell NJ could limit access to its shellfish grounds b/c this isn't a fundamental right guaranteed to all people. Read P&I clause as a guarantee of certain “fundamental rights” to all citizens, regardless of the rights states have afforded to its citizens. All citizens of free governments are clothed with certain fundamental rights. Fundamental Principles – difficult to enumerate: Protection under the gov't Liberty, pursuit of happiness, right to property... Subject nevertheless... to things Gov't thinks it has to do to promote general good. Privileges and Immunities CASE GROUP Toomer v. Witsell P&I RULE S.C. Statute – imposed license fee for shrimp boats, $25 fee for residents, $2500 fee for outsiders. We need more than just “your OOS, so you must pay more.” S.C. Hadn't done anything to nurture or add anything to its fishing – to sustain this law. But they haven't, so they are just discriminating. Baldwin v. Montana Fish and Game Comm'n P&I Court rejected an Art. IV, Section 2 attack on a Montana elk hunting license scheme that imposes substantially higher fees on non residents than on residents. Uses “fundamental rights” approach. Elk hunting by nonresidents is not a fundamental right. Hicklin v. Orbeck P&I ANYTHING ELSE IMPORTANT? Must have a reason for the discrimination other than just “in state vs. out of state” person. Denying OOSers means of livelihood! FRAMEWORK FOR ANALYSIS: · REASON FOR DISCRIMINATION apart from mere fact of out of state residency · RELATIONSHIP OF DISCRIMINATION TO THE PROBLEM: is the regulation closely related to the discrimination (a means/end analysis)… · ALTERNATIVE TO DISCRIMINATION are part of the means/end analysis Brennan dissent - Dissent – says, he doesn't care if hunting elk is a fundamental right. He thinks that any discrimination should have to be justified by the double inquiry. 1) Is the presence or activity of non-residents the source of problem? 2) Does discrimination practiced against nonresidents bear a substantial relation to the problem they present How do we get to trigger that inquiry – state is letting its citizens do something, not letting outsiders do something. How does it answer for Justice Brennan what is protected by P&I clause? Doesn't want court to make value choices... Brennan would turn to state law. If the state lets their own citizens do something, it must be important. Relies on Toomer approach to invalidate an Alaska law requiring that residents be preferred over nonresidents in certain jobs. Follows Brennan's dissent in Baldwin. 1) Alaska had not demonstrated “that non-residents were a peculiar source of evil”. Alaska's unemployment problem was not caused by the influx of nonresidents. 2) Alaska's discrimination against non-residents did not bear a substantial relationship to the particular “evil” they were said to present. United P&I Building & Constructi on Trades Council v. Mayor and Council of Camden Ordinance required that at least 40% of the employees of contractors and subcontractors working on city construction projects be Camden residents. Court determined that it did impinge on the fundamental rights of interstate employees, but remanded to determine whether there was a substantial reason for the different treatment. P&I Clause applies to municipalities b/c municipalities exist by virtue of the state. Uses this two part test: 1) Is the interest a fundamental right or a privilege? Yes. 2) Give the state a chance to justify the burden. Significant debate between Blackman and Rehnquist – whether or not we have political checks. Yes – Blackman – we don't really need a judicial check. Rehnquist –roll for judicial intervention, because we don't really have a political check. New P&I Hampshire v. Piper NH limited bar admission to state residents. Court held that it violated the P&I clause. Uses same 2-step test: 1) Is it a P&I protected by the clause? 2)What type of interest state has advanced that are not the same thing as – just wanting to discriminate... & whether the rule is related to that interest. ALSO – make SURE – to see if there are less discriminatory alternatives (like shrimp case) 1)Yes – as an occupation, its important to the national economy, out of state lawyers are usually willing to represent persons with unpopular claims. 2)Reasons advanced by the state: -state citizens familiar with local rules and procedures (what does court say – state gave no evidence to support that evidence... AND if you have passed the bar, then why does it matter where you live.) -behave ethically (court – all lawyers, regardless of where they live care about their reputation, care about discipline of bench and bar, etc.) -be available for court proceedings (only viable claim! court you can be required to retain local counsel to represent you and your clients when you cannot get to court in a quick fashion – less restrictive measure.) -more likely to do pro bono work in the state (court - all state has to do is assign pro bono work) *Why did Rehnquist dissent? Took a nobler view of practice of law, had a different understanding of state's interests – want to have state representatives be lawyers.) CASE GROUP Perez v. Campbell RULE ANYTHING ELSE IMPORTANT? Preemption In a 5-4 decision (typical for preemption cases) – found that the AZ statute was preempted. Found a conflict with the AZ statute and full scope of National Law. Perez seeks to get out of paying $, seeks voluntary discharge in bankruptcy, one of the debts is a motor vehicle violation tort judgment. Arizona law – discharge in bankruptcy does not clear you from loss of drivers license and suspension of registration if you fail to pay motor vehicle judgment. Interest – uninsured drivers are not good to have on the road, in order to make people pay, they would lose their license, etc. Arizona thought uninsured motor vehicle drivers failing to pay those injured by their negligence was a big problem. BUT... section 17 of bankruptcy act – purpose of bankruptcy laws, to give debtors a new opportunity in life, clear field for future, free from debt. Arizona suspended license, Perez said they can't do it, b/c inconsistent with bankruptcy debt. AND, he has a job, can't get to work without his license. Can't get “fresh start to life” without his license. Pacific Preemption Gas & Elec. Co. v. State Energy Resources Cons & Dev. Comm'n Sustained a CA law dealing with the problem of finding a long-term solution for nuclear waste. Background: ATA – federal government relaxed its monopoly over fissionable materials, while promoting civilian development of nuclear energy and safeguarding the public and the environment from the unpredictable risks of a new technology. States could continue their traditional role of regulation of electricity production. *Shortage of storage space for spent fuel. *There are both safety and economic aspects to the nuclear waste issue – first, if not properly stored, nuclear wastes might leak and endanger both environment and human health. Second – lack of long-term disposal option increases the risk that the insufficiency of interim storage for spent fuel will lead to reactor-shutdowns, rendering nuclear energy an unpredictable and uneconomical adventure. HOLDINGS: 1) state law is intruding on turf that congress reserved – court – yes gov't has the safety element, but looks at this regulation as an economic regulation (with a small amount of safety within) 2) Conflict with NRC provisions - NRC – it IS safe to proceed with these provisions. Court – Federal doesn't REQUIRE utility to proceed, just permits it. These are not conflicting rules. 3) CA law frustrates the goal of developing nuclear technology. Court – promotion of nuclear power is not to be accomplished at all costs. Preservation of state regulation in traditional areas belie that. THIS IS AN EXAMPLE OF – giving states deference. Now days – less sympathetic Florida Lime and Avacado Growers Invalid preempted because conflicts with statute enacted under commerce power Involed avocados certified as mature under the federal regulations but containing less than the minimum CA oil content ? Preemption CASE GROUP C&A DCC carbone, Inc. v. Town of Clarkstown RULE ANYTHING ELSE IMPORTANT? Clarkstown enacted a flow control ordinance, which required that all solid waste be deposited at a station they wanted to finance. Holding – a local government cannot require that all solid waste within its boundaries be processed by a specific local processor. Economic effects reach IC – deprives out of state businesses access to local market, increases private collector's costs, etc. City complained that it was not discriminatory b/c it applies to all waste, before it leaves town. Court - it DOES discriminate b/c it allows only the favored processor to process waste within the town's limits. This is just an example of local processing requirements that have been held invalid – like Dean Milk. This case – even more restrictive than Dean Milk b/c it leaves no room for outside investment. Discrimination against IC in favor of local business is per se invalid, unless the municipality has no other means to advance a legitimate interest. D has a variety of nondiscriminatory means; fundraising is not adequate to justify discrimination against OOS business. O'Connor – concurrence – D's ordinance is different b/c it does not give more favorable treatment to local interests as a group as compared to OOS economic interests. Thus, does not discriminate against IC. But it does impose an excessive burden! Dissent – Souter – No evidence that any OOS trash has been harmed. The ordinance treats all OOT investors and facilities to the same constraints as local ones, so there is no economic protectionism. The only right to compete that the commerce clause protects is the right to compete on terms independent of one's location. Ordinance merely imposes a burden on local citizens who adopted it, this is only subject to political process! West Lynn Creamery, Inc. v. Healy DCC Held invalid a pricing order imposing an assessment on all fluid milk sold by dealers to Massachusetts retailers. Two thirds of that milk was processed out of state. The entire assessment is distributed to Massachusetts dairy farmers. Unconstitutionally discriminates against IC! Compares this to a protective tariff or customs duty, which taxes imported goods only and thereby makes them more expensive. Such a duty both raises revenue and benefits local producers at the expense of out-of-state producers. *The purpose for the milk order is to allow higher-cost in-state dairy farmers to compete with lower-cost producers in other states. The effect of the milk pricing order is to make milk produced out of state more expensive. *Even though the pricing order is imposed on milk produced Holding – A state may not impose a in state as well, its effect on Massachusetts producers is more tax on all sales of a particular product than offset by the subsidy. Consequently, functions like a in order to subsidize in-state tariff. producers of that product. *State may properly tax all milk dealers, may also finance the subsidy of in-state farmers – however the combination impairs *Distinguish from Hughes v. the state's political process because those in-state interests who Alexandria – because in that case, would otherwise oppose the tax are mollified by the subsidy. they were using their own money to *The fact that the taxes are paid by in-state businesses and subsidize. consumers is irrelevant. The impact of the order is to divert the market share to Massachusetts, which hurts OOS. Concurrence – Based on the court's rationale – any state subsidy would be invalid because the mere act of assisting instate businesses neutralizes advantages possessed by competing OOS. Court SHOULD enforce a self-executing “negative” commerce clause only where the state law facially discriminates against IC OR where the state law is of a type previously held unconstitutional. State could not (i) impose higher tax liability on OOS business, (ii) apply nondiscriminatory tax that has an exemption for instate members. Here – (iii) a nondiscriminatory tax, the proceeds of which were then placed in a segregated fund to pay rebates or subsidies. (iv) Subsidies local businesses using funds form its general revenues. (iii) is closer to (ii) so should be unconstitutional. Dissent – Rehnquist – Political reality is that there are other groups, namely the milk dealers and consumers, who could still oppose the tax, even if the dairy farmers choose not to. No precedent justifies applying the negative Commerce Clause against a subsidy funded funded from a lawful neutral tax. CASE GROUP Sabri v. United States N&P Clause Spending Power / Commerce Power (Dissent) RULE ANYTHING ELSE IMPORTANT? (1)Statute prohibiting bribery involving federal funds was not facially unconstitutional on the ground that it did not require a nexus between criminal activity and federal funds. (2) Statute did not exceed Congress's authority under the Spending Clause (3) Statute did not amount to an unduly coercive, and impermissibly sweeping, condition on grant of federal funds. *The absence of a jurisdictional hook does not imply unconstitutionality. *Just because every bribe does not affect the spending w.r.t. the general welfare, doesn't mean that this is invalid. People accepting bribes are in control of monies and spending. We don't want them to be untrustworthy. *Here, we do not need inference upon inference ... we can easily show that the reliability of those who use public money has A LOT to do with the congressional spending power. *Validity of attacks alleging overbreadth are not common. *On its face – does not give a connection between Concurring – Kennedy and Scalia – we should still scrutinize a facial challenge, preserve Lopez and Morrison. Dissent – Thomas – doesn't want to use the N&P clause, just look at it on its face. Majority is requiring a rational basis connection – he would require a tighter fit between the means and the ends. Focuses on means/ends relationship – and can use appropriate means and reasonably calculated means. LA PIERRE DORM. COMM. CLAUSE CHART ECONOMIC H&S BURDEN Baldwin (VT dairy) Silas Milk Cond v. Eisenberg City Serve (Natl Gas) Foster (shrimp) Pike (cantaloupe) Breard? (door-to-door) Barnwell (T) So Pac (T) Bibb (T) Kassel (T) Mintz (diss. cattle) MN v. Clover Lf Crm Breard? DISCRIM (on face/in effect) Phil v. NY (DISS see as Envir) PA v. WV (Natl. Gas) Hunt (possible) Hood Jackson MAJ Welton (shoddy) Breard? Hunt Contrell Dean Milk Blackman DISS in Exxon Frank & Black DISS in Hood Hughes (DISS: is Burden) Maine Breard? WAY TO ANALYZE PROBLEMS: JUDICIAL POWER IN GENERAL 2 fundamentally different ways to use Article III judicial power (from Cohens v. Va): 1. Look at nature of question involved, regardless of the parties 2. Look to see the parties involved To show a statute is valid, need 1 of these 2: 1. Direct exercise of enumerated power 2. Valid exercise of enumerated power coupled with Necessary & Proper clause 2 possibilities of judicial power of Congress’ powers: 1. Inquiries into ends 2. Inquiries into mens/ends relationship Marshall’s pre-text reservation (from McCulloch): -Congress cannot enact a law under the pretext of exercising an enumerated power, when the purpose of the law is really to do something not enumerated TAX POWER Immunities from Taxation: 1. Federal Government immune from State taxation (McCulloch) 2. State immune from Government—only when activity is only performed by the States (NY v. US—mineral case) SPENDING POWER Restraints on Spending Power (from US v. Butler, Stone’s dissent, which is the law today): 1. Must be national in scope 2. Must be choice (no coercion) 3. Means must be related to ends 4. Political checks -Spending power is a separate, distinct power from other enumerated powers 4 limits on Spending Power (from South Dakota v. Dole) 1. Must be for general welfare 2. Unambigious conditions 3. Must be related to federal interests 4. Other constitutional provisions may provide an independent bar to conditional grant of federal funds National government “compelling” states to do things: 1. Can condition funds (Dole) 2. Can give a choice between state or national implementation (Hodel) 3. Can say regulate our way or don’t regulate at all (FERC) 4. Can regulate area where both states & private parties can act (NY—mineral act) 5. Cannot compel state government to act (Printz, NY—radioactive) COMMERCE POWER Old Commerce Power -Direct/Indirect (Knight) -Substantial Effect (Wickard, Shreveport Rate?) 4 areas in which Commerce Power can be used to regulate: (p. 2 of Gibbons notes) 1. Prohibit interstate movement of goods (Shreveport Rate) 2 Prohibit people or things in IC (Lottery, Darby) 3. Regulate local activities which substantially affect IC (affecting commerce rationale) (Jones & Laughlin, Wickard, Perez, 5 Gambling Devices) 4.Bootstrap—regulating local activity as means of making affective prohibition against interstate movement of goods (Alternative ground in Darby) 3 categories of activity that Congress may regulate under Commerce Power (Lopez): 1. Channels of IC (Darby, Heart of Atlanta) 2. Persons or things in IC (Shreveport Rate) 3. Activities that have a substantial relation to IC (Jones & Laughlin) 4 points from Lopez: 1. Substantial economic effects on IC 2. No jurisdictional element 3. Lacked formal findings as to burden on IC 4. Attenuated link between gun possession & IC Questions for Commerce cases: 1. What is local activity? 2. Where is IC? 3. What is relationship between local activity and IC? 4. How can Congress regulate this? (means of achieving ends) 3 categories of national legislation: 1. Regulating private activity 2. Regulating state and local governments 3. Requiring state and local governments to perform tasks DORMANT COMMERCE CLAUSE Dormant Commerce Clause 1. Burden (in-state and out-of-state treated the same)use Pike test --unconstitutional if burden on IC outweighs state interest (or other less burdensome alternatives(?)) 2. Discriminationuse Hunt test --State has burden to show that: 1. Local interest outweighs discrimination 2. No less discriminatory or non-discriminatory alternatives 3. Per se Invalidityuse Philly test (use when economic purpose, discrimination on face) 3 types of factors in Dormant commerce cases: 1. Purpose of state law --Buck; Bradley 2. Effect of the state law on IC 3. Extent to which state regulation worked to achieve the state’s interests (Barnwell) 4 catgories: 1. Economic and Burden --Pike, Baldwin v. Seelig, Henneford (V), Eisenberg (V), Foster Fountain 2. Health & Safety and Burden --Barnwell (V), Southern Pacific, Bibb, Kassel, Mintz (V), Minnesota (V) 3. Economic and Discriminatory --Philly, Hunt, Welton, Hood, Pa v. WVa, Polar Ice Cream, Hood (Majority) 4. Health & Safety and Discriminatory --Hunt, Maine (V), Hughes, Dean Milk, Exxon (V), A&P, Hood (Dissents) PRIVILEGES & IMMUNITIES 2 distinct threads of Privileges & Immunities Clause 1. See whether interest at stake is fundamental right (Corfield) 2. Focus on rights created by state law and a focus on discrimination (Toomer) --4 part test: 1. Fundamental right 2. Has to be substantial reason for discrimination independently from discrimination (i.e. non-residents are the source of the problem) 3. Discrimination must bear close relationship to means 3a. Inquiry into less restrictive means [alternatives] (Piper) PREEMPTION 1. Express preemption provision—Congress clearly says certain state laws are preempted 2. Express savings clause—Congress doesn’t want their law to oust certain state laws THE PIKE TEST A state law that does not discriminate against interstate commerce is presumed to be valid. It is void only if the challenger to the law can show that the burdens placed on interstate commerce by the law are clearly excessive in relation to the putative local benefits of the law. 1. US v. Lopez 3 broad categories of activity that Congress may regulate under its commerce power: 1. 1) The use of the channels of interstate commerce power to prohibit 1. Moral Objective = ok 2. Direct exercise of the commerce power – no use of the necessary and proper clause 3. Punishing those who violate interstate shipment = use of the necessary and proper clause 4. Champion v. Ames Lottery tickets – function of Congress’ moral judgment that gambling is bad; pretext to accomplish an end not given to the Congress 5. Hoke v. US Mann Act – can’t bring women across state lines for commercial purposes 1. Congress may adopt not only means necessary but convenient to exercise commerce power, and the means may have the quality of police regulations. 1. Fines and jail time for violators = ok means to reach the ends of regulating commerce 2. Caminetti v. US Mann Act should only be applied to commercial prostitution, not individual acts of prostitution 6. US v. Darby Fair Labor Standards Act §15A1 prohibited interstate shipment of goods produced by individuals working under substandard working conditions (working for less than minimum wage or for more than 45 hours/week without being paid overtime) 2. 2) The instrumentalities of interstate commerce, or persons or things in interstate commerce, even though the threat may come only from intrastate activities 1. Shreveport Rate Congress can regulate local rates to prevent lower prices in interstate travel 2. Southern Railway 3. Prohibition of destruction of aircraft 4. Affect on interstate commerce rationale still ok? – justify statute under category 2 and try to justify it under category 3 at the same time 3. 3) Activities that have a substantial relation to interstate commerce substantially affect interstate commerce 1. A) Intrastate economic activity where the court has concluded that the activity substantially affected interstate commerce 1. McCulloch – Court can’t tread on Congress’ power to judge relation between local activity and interstate commerce 2. Here the court takes back the power to judge affect on interstate commerce 3. Cardozo’s Dissent in Carter Coal 4. Perez 5. Ollie’s BBQ 6. Heart of Atlanta 7. Wickard v. Filburn 8. VAWA is not an economic activity and has no substantial jurisdictional hook