COMMERCIALIZING UNIVERSITY RESEARCH: BEYOND ECONOMIC INCENTIVES E. Richard Gold Introduction The difficulty of ensuring the commercialization of university research is not one that can be answered simply by setting up the right set of economic incentives. University research and its transfer to the private sector respond not only to economics, but to shifting cultural norms and other values that often override or reduce economic incentives. Culture obviously plays an important role in the economic growth of a society. This belief can be traced back to the work of Max Weber (1930) who argued that cultural changes play a critical role in the development of capitalism and its institutions.1 Lal (1999) demonstrated the importance of Western individualism for the growth of markets in the West. Culture can be defined as “the enduring behaviours, ideas, attitudes, and traditions shared by a large group of people and transmitted from one generation to the next.”2 As such, culture will shape the behaviours and actions of individuals, and consequently the institutions set up by a given society. 1 2 Stulz and Williamson Social Psychology Book This paper will show that economic incentives and institutional structures cannot alone explain the difference observed in the effectiveness of technology transfer at American universities. The cultural atmosphere at these institutions plays a critical role in achieving successful commercialization. Specifically, what is required is a culture of entrepreneurship. In Part I, we will discuss the necessity for New Institutional Economics to include culture as a fundamental element of economic theory. In Part II, we will provide examples of how culture impacts economic systems, particularly those related to patent law. In Part III, we will investigate the role of culture in the commercialization process at American universities. Particularly, we will show that successful technology transfer requires a specific cultural atmosphere at the university. Part I “The New Institutional Economics (NIE) is an interdisciplinary enterprise combining economics, law, organizational theory, political science, sociology and anthropology to understand the institutions of social, political and commercial life. Its goal is to explain what institutions are, how they arise, what purpose they serve, how they change and how – if at all – they should be reformed.”3 Although NIE claims to take culture into account, authors criticize the manner in which culture is incorporated into the theory. Klein states that although NIE appreciates social 3 Peter G. Klein phenomena such as corporate culture and organizational memory, it takes these as explananda, not the explanans.4 Zweynert criticizes NIE for externalizing culture and viewing it as something static.5 He states that by doing so, new institutional economics is at risk of repeating mistakes found in most empirical and neoclassical-oriented studies on the influence of culture in economic development. Specifically, culture appears as an ad hoc-variable that is used to explain unusual developments, but a variable that cannot itself be explained. He argues that there is an insufficient understanding of culture itself. Culture is not merely a factor which can organize social life in a peaceful and productive – and hence cooperative – manner; rather, culture’s structural importance for societal and political processes themselves ought to be appreciated. Part II i. Bankruptcy and Insolvency 4 Peter G. Klein The Two Transitions in Central and Eastern Europe and the relation between Path Dependent and Politically Implemented Institutional Change, Zweynert article 5 Global economics are rapidly changing the world and credit, particularly consumer credit which is being offered in greater amounts and to greater number of people in more countries than ever before.6 Commercial borrowing is also indicated to be on the rise.7 Many governments with developing economies have implemented new systems that do not arise from existing cultural conditions, but rather are transplanted from elsewhere. The hope is that cultural views will change with the laws. The United States is the source for many new bankruptcy laws; however countries that incorporate US regimes have significantly different cultural attitudes towards debt and insolvency. The American system rewards entrepreneurialism and is based on extensive consumer spending. Consequently, personal bankruptcy systems are designed to keep the consumer spending and the economy running. The United States also has a forgiving business reorganization system to avoid insolvency and to encourage risk taking and economic growth. The American bankruptcy system is essentially a social program that addresses many of society’s ills.8 Bankruptcy systems are essentially social tools, and as such they are value laden and must be drafted with care to reflect the particular values of a culture. Martin claims that it is not possible to simply transplant an American bankruptcy system into another 6 7 8 country.9 In fact, Martin indicates that even countries that share a common legal tradition, such as the Unites States, England, Canada and Australia, have marked differences in how they approach both business and personal bankruptcies. As well, many countries around the world tend to have cultures that are less forgiving about debt compared with the United States. In fact, in certain countries defaulting on debt is considered the ultimate disgrace.10 Despite these cultural differences, countries around the world are replicating the US bankruptcy regime. Varying attitudes towards debt can be seen around the world. In Britain, for example, the population is quite sensitive about financial failure and it is often looked upon as a failure of character. In fact, executives in companies that are failing financially will likely have a difficult time finding alternate work, and may even be black listed in the business community. The British government is attempting to change these attitudes in order to help fuel Britain’s flagging economy. However, as Martin points out, “the government is likely to be unable to tell people how to think or whom to invite to parties, even through drastic legal change.”11 In Continental Europe, as a rule, financial failure carries significantly more stigma than in common law countries, and personal bankruptcy laws are less forgiving than those in common law countries. As well, reorganization laws are more varied and reflect different societal concerns. European governments are attempting to reduce the negative stigma 9 10 11 associated with business and financial failure in order to fuel entrepreneurial spirits. They are specifically looking to the United States as a model.12 The German government, for example, initiated a more flexible insolvency law for businesses by allowing the appointment of a trustee, called an administrator, to operate the debtor’s business and avoid liquidation. However, two years after the New German Insolvency Code (InsO)13 was enacted, research indicates that the new law is still widely objected to if not entirely ignored.14 It appears that history and culture play a more important role in determining how insolvency cases are handled than the actual law itself.15 A recent European Union (EU) study examined stigma and financial failure in the 15 EU member states.16 The study concluded that even if domestic legislators adopt laws that promote a fresh start, like in the Unites States, there is a need to introduce a European culture campaign promoting the fresh start. Martin states that despite “the goals of the EU in modernizing and liberalizing the insolvency laws … it is unclear whether this will work. Long held and strong cultural values may stand in the way, despite the best intentions of lawmakers.”17 ii. Financial Development and Investor Protection 12 13 …. Page 39 of text for footnote 302 – see those articles 15 Page 39 of text for footnote 301 – see those articles 16 Page 41 of text – GET THE STUDY 17 Page 41 14 There is substantial evidence that financial development benefits economic growth.18 Despite this finding, there are significant differences across countries in the importance of capital markets, in firms’ ability to access external finance, and in the ownership of publicly traded firms.19 La Porta, Lopez-de-Silanes, Shleifer, and Vishy, show that this variation can be explained by how well the laws in a given country protect outside investors from expropriation by managers, controlling shareholders, and governments.20 Nevertheless, not many countries provide investor protection as extensively as the United States. Stultz and Williamson show that differences in culture can explain the variation in investor protection across countries.21 They suggest that culture can affect finance through at least three channels: (i) culture defines the predominant values of a country; (ii) culture affects the institutions of a country such as the legal system; and (iii) culture affects how resources are allocate in an economy. Stultz and Williamson used two proxies for culture – religion and language. First, they found that the relationship between culture and investor rights is especially strong for creditor rights, whereas language is largely unimportant for creditor rights. Specifically, they found that creditor rights are better in non-Christian countries than in Christian countries, and within Christian countries, better in Protestant countries than Catholic countries. Second, they found that religion is correlated with enforcement of rights, whereas language is irrelevant for enforcement of rights, except for accounting standards. 18 Stultz article pg. 1, fnt. 1 Stultz article and La Porta article 20 La Porta article 21 Stultz article pg. 1, fnt. 1 19 Specifically, Christian countries typically have better enforcement, and enforcement is significantly stronger for Protestant than for Catholic countries. These findings indicate that culture is an important factor that must be considered when attempting to understand why investor protection differs across countries. The precise channels through which culture impacts financial development and economic growth must be investigated in more detail. iii. Japan – still working on this Currently, in Japan, there is a pro-patent culture that involves a general orientation around patenting. This culture was triggered by the emergence of the pro-patent era in the 1980’s. This pro-patent culture is specifically apparent in Japanese large corporations. In fact, studies indicate that the level of IP resources in Japanese large technology-based corporations is considerably higher than in most comparable western corporations, as is the output in terms of both absolute number of patent applications and number of patent applications per R&D dollar. Research identifies a number of common features distinguishing patent organizations in Japanese large corporations from Western large corporations. These common features include increased resources devoted to IP activities (i.e. ten or more times in Japanese corporations than in their Western counterpart), elevated status for patent and IP departments, good working relations between patent departments and R&D, and the immersion of Japanese patent organizations in a patent culture.22 Japanese industry built strong corporate cultures to coincide with Japanese pro-patent policy: (i) top management is generally involved in patenting and IP, patenting is made a common concern for all engineers in a corporation; (ii) patent policies and strategies are integrated in business plans; (iii) clear and quantified objectives for patenting are developed; (iv) strong incentive schemes are employed for R&D personnel and organizational units; (v) behavioural attitudes and standards conducive to technology protection by patents and secrecy, and to technology intelligence are fostered; (v) visible organizational means such as patent promotion centres, patent liason officers, corporate wide patent campaigns; (vi) patenting prizes and patent strategy seminars are employed; and (vii) a common language, methodology and philosophy for a patent culture is developed. While, the United States and Japan were both able to institute successful patent systems that aim to promote innovation, the two patent systems conceptualize innovation in different manners. The American patent system emphasizes the inventor’s exclusive rights in the invention, whereas the Japanese patent system emphasizes the promotion of industrial development by encouraging the protection and exploitation of inventions.23 22 23 Corporate Management of Intellectual Property in Japan Daniel Lin Paper Over the past 50 years, studies show that Japanese industry focuses more on developing and improving external technologies, including American technology, rather than developing new internal technologies.24 This preference combined with the narrow scope of patent protection afforded to Japanese technology resulted in what is termed “patent flooding”. This involves Japanese industry filing volumes of patent applications covering minor variations and improvements on a core technology patent and essentially holding the latter “hostage” by charging a fee for use of the improvements. Whereas patent flooding generates considerable criticism by American industry, the culture of the “keiretsu” system in Japan allows Japanese industry to overcome any hindrances resulting from patent flooding. Keiretsu is a “unique organization of Japan’s economy and literally means “affiliation”. A keiretsu is a group of companies linked together by close and enduring bonds that transcend ties of legal contract or short-term market considerations.” This system, which fosters cooperation and minimizes business conflict, allows for patent pooling arrangements in Japanese industry. iv. Thailand Thailand is trying to enter into the global economy by adopting a Western style economy. Thailand represents an attractive market for investment and trade because of its location, market size and minimal interference from the government.25 The United States is 24 25 Daniel Lin Paper pg. 1 Thailand’s single largest trading partner with a 1998 two-way trade of $18 Billion.26 Thailand also provides a cost-effective regional manufacturing and distribution base for the Mekong region (Thailand, Laos, Cambodia, and Burma), which has a combined population of over 125 million people.27 Despite all of this, Thailand is struggling to incorporate the modern forces of Western technology and capitalism into its traditional Eastern based Buddhist culture. Thai and Western cultures vary significantly and their norms therefore come into conflict. Niffenegger and Krutngeon provide the following comparison of the conflicting cultures: Table 1 A Comparison of Conflicting Cultural Imperatives Thailand Western Culture A tradition of spiritualism as based on Buddhism; to A need for achievement and material rewards as a give more than one takes; to resist material sign of success. attachments. A desire to have trust in business relationships, Need for new regulatory procedures and through traditional, social business networks, built enforcement agencies, with modern and public over time. (transparent) reporting of data. Need to take care of employees, avoid layoffs and Need to speed up restructuring of insolvent protect investors from "taking a haircut" (loss), thus institutions, cutting the high ratio of non-performing suffering a loss of face. loans through implementing modern (Chapter 11) bankruptcy laws. Desire to keep the unemployment rate down, by 26 27 pg. 1 pg. 1 Need to see rapid progress in the restructuring of preserving low skilled jobs in labor-intensive export insolvent companies, layoffs, elimination of non- industries. performing loans, greater reliance on high-tech production methods. Desire for face-to-face business contacts, based on Need to utilize the increased productivity of e- trust and confidentiality. commerce via the internet, with public display of data. Encouragement by the King (Rama IX) to be a more A desire by Thais to possess Western goods as self-sufficient country, to produce what one needs, symbols of success and and status; a new culture of become less dependant on imports. profligacy among young consumers, students and business people. Thai economists and Western critics argue that the ultimate economic model that will succeed in Thailand will result from the constructive confrontation and compromise of Buddhism and capitalism.28 Klausner, a respected author and retired Yale anthropologist who spend many years in Thailand believes that a workable approach exists for successfully combining the conflicting mandates of capitalization and Buddhism.29 This approach involves the teachings of Buddhadasa, Thailand's controversial philosopher monk who believes that lay men and women can have access to the same spiritual attainment as formal Buddhist monks, even though they live very different lifestyles. v. Russia 28 29 The current intellectual property problems in Russia have historical and cultural roots and emerged during the administrative law system of the former Soviet Union.30 Under the Soviet regime, nearly all inventions belonged to the State and were protected by the Inventor’s Certificate. As such, the exclusive right to use, manufacture and commercialize an invention also belonged to the State. This gave rise to a particular cultural attitude towards intellectual property, namely that new technical solutions were considered to be part of the public domain and available for use without the inventor’s permission. When the former Soviet Union disintegrated, numerous changes were made to the political, economic, and legal landscapes of the country. A number of amendments were made to the intellectual property regime, including allowing private parties to obtain an exclusive right to use, manufacture, and sell an invention, and an increase in the requirements for obtaining a patent. As a result of these changes, there was a substantive cultural shift of attitude towards intellectual property rights. In fact, following the implementations of these changes, a reduction in inventive activity (up to 1998) was observed with respect to national applicants. Post 1998, Russian attitude began to change towards intellectual property and the priorities of the country shifted. For example, the number of national patent applications under A-category (necessity for life) rose and attracted the greatest level of activity. As well, since legislative amendments to the intellectual property regime made it possible for foreign companies to patent their technologies in Russia, there was a rise in foreign patent applications. 30 Karpova, N. “legal protection and commercialization of intellectual property in Russia” (2004), www.ZDNet.RU Despite the above-mentioned advances, a number of cultural limitations continue to exist in Russia. A number of scholars support the thesis that the current system of state regulation of intellectual property in Russia has low efficiency because it is rooted in the former Soviet intellectual property system.31 Moreover, scholars also attribute the problems facing Russian industry to the cultural attitude that intellectual property rights are not valuable or worthy of protection.32 Part of Russian society continues to believe that intellectual property is in the public domain and can be used without the inventor’s permission. This cultural attitude directly impacts commercialization of innovation as it diminishes the inventor’s financial return discourages investment in future technological advances. Marina Portona proposes that in order to improve patent protection in Russia, and in turn improve commercialization of innovation, the Russian government must take action to overcome the particular cultural attitude of communal nature toward inventions held by the Russian population. Portona states: “Russians have to realize that inventions are no longer owned by all the people, and that using an invention without its owner’s permission is theft. The recognition of patent owners’ rights by Russian officials and public and private companies would help decrease patent infringement in the country.”33 vi. Indonesia – TO BE COM0PLETED 31 Karpova article and Russian article – GET FROM MEMO Russian article – GET FROM MEMO 33 Portnova, M. “Ownership and Enforcement of Patent Rights in Russia: protecting an Invention Existing Environment” (1998) 8 Ind. Int’l & Comp. rev. 505. 32 Part III Technology transfer from a research university is a process that involves several steps.34 Rogers sets out those steps in the following diagram: The first step in the process is invention disclosure. This step requires the faculty member, graduate student, or staff member in a university to disclose the development of a new technology to the university technology transfer office. The second step in the process is applying for a patent. Once the patent is obtained, the research university owns the intellectual property rights in the patented technology. The third step in the process involves licensing the patented technology to an individual or organization, usually a commercial company. After this licensing agreement is executed, and, given commercial uses of the licensee, the research university may begin to earn income from the transferred technology. 34 Rogers The cooperation of faculty members, graduate students, or staff members is critical for successful technology transfer and commercialization of new technologies. Their willingness to disclose, help in the application for patents and the subsequent commercialization of the new technology is necessary. These requirements for successful technology transfer and commercialization require a particular cultural atmosphere of entrepreneurship. This culture of entrepreneurship is viewed by some academics as posing a threat to the traditional integrity of the university and its role as an independent critic of society.35 More specifically, it is viewed as being in conflict with the university culture that believes in the norms of pure science, academic freedom and openness. Studies indicate that there is great variation among universities in the effectiveness of commercialization and technology transfer offices.36 Rogers, Yin, and Hoffmann assessed the effectiveness of technology transfer offices at 131 U.S. research universities.37 They found a number of institutional factors that result in more effective technology transfer. These factors are: (i) higher average faculty salaries, (ii) a larger number of staff for technology licensing, (iii) a higher value of private gifts, grants, and contracts, and (iv) larger R&D expenditures from industry and federal sources. 35 Etzkowitz et al. pg. 314 Nelson, Richard R. (2001). Observations on the Post-Bayh-Dole Rise of Patenting at American Universities. Journal of Technology Transfer 26, no. 1-2:13-19. 37 Rogers, E.M., Yin, J. & Hoffmann J. (2000). Assessing the effectiveness of technology transfer offices at US research universities... 36 Siegal and Phan reviewed the literature on institutions and agents engaged in the commercialization of university-based intellectual property. Their review indicates that both institutional incentives and organizational practices, particularly informational and cultural factors, play an important role in enhancing the effectiveness of technology transfer. 38 This finding is contrary to conventional economic theory that attributes the variation in performance of technology transfer offices solely to environmental and institutional factors.39 Cultural barriers can limit technology transfer despite the presence of the appropriate institutional factors for technology transfer. Johns Hopkins University (JHU) is one of the world’s leading institutions of higher education and health. JHU receives more U.S. government research and development support than any other American academic institution,40 and JHU’s School of Medicine is the single largest recipient of research grants from the US National Institutes of Health.41 As well, JHU boasts 26 Nobel Prize winners among faculty and alumni.42 Despite all of this, however, studies show that JHU is lagging far behind its peers in the field of technology transfer. In 1997, JHU held only 103 revenue generating licenses for intellectual property, compared with 232 licenses 38 Rensselaer article See Rensselaer pg. 13-14 40 Feldman , Maryann and Desrochers, Pierre. “Research Universities and Local Economic Development: Lessons from the History of the Johns Hopkins University” Industry and Innovation, Volume 10, Number 1, 5–24, March 2003, p 1. 41 See footnote 6 in Feldman , Maryann and Desrochers, Pierre. “Research Universities and Local Economic Development: Lessons from the History of the Johns Hopkins University” Industry and Innovation, Volume 10, Number 1, 5–24, March 2003, p 1. 42 Feldman , Maryann and Desrochers, Pierre. “Research Universities and Local Economic Development: Lessons from the History of the Johns Hopkins University” Industry and Innovation, Volume 10, Number 1, 5–24, March 2003, p 1. 39 held by Harvard University and 201 held by Columbia University. As well, royalties generated per active license were lower at JHU.43 One might suspect that the disparity in technology transfer between JHU and other more entrepreneurial universities, such as M.I.T and Stanford, may be attributable to the nature of the research – pure vs. applied. Thursby and Thursby,44 empirically assessed whether the growth in licensing and patenting by universities (i.e. technology commercialization) is attributed to an increase in the willingness of professors to patent, without a concomitant, fundamental change in the type of research they conduct, or alternatively whether the growth reflects a shift towards more applied research. They found support for the former hypothesis that the rise in university technology transfer is the result of a greater willingness on the part of the university researchers to patent their inventions, as well as an increase in outsourcing of R&D by firms via licensing. Feldman and Descrochers provide an historical perspective to explain how culture impacts technology transfer at universities.45 These authors describe the culture fostered by JHU’s founding faculty as one that is openly hostile to the practical application of 43 Feldman , Maryann and Desrochers, Pierre. “Research Universities and Local Economic Development: Lessons from the History of the Johns Hopkins University” Industry and Innovation, Volume 10, Number 1, 5–24, March 2003, p 1. 44 Who is selling the ivory tower? Sources of growth in university licensing, management science, 48:90-104 45 Feldman , Maryann and Desrochers, Pierre. “Research Universities and Local Economic Development: Lessons from the History of the Johns Hopkins University” Industry and Innovation, Volume 10, Number 1, 5–24, March 2003, p 1. scientific research.46 The founders of JHU established an institution devoted to advanced study and graduate training, based on the ‘German model’ of universities. This model incorporates two features – the principle of academic freedom, and a commitment to Wissenschaft – the idea of knowledge for its own sake.47 An early JHU commencement speaker, Basil L. Gildersleeve, suggested in 1877 “that the word useful should be banished from the university vocabulary.”48 Henry Rowland, chosen to help start JHU’s physics program, declared an intention to pursue a “substantial reputation” rather than “filthy lucre.”49 Similarly, Ira Remsen, JHU’s first professor of chemistry and second president of the institution, deliberately maintained a posture of disdain for the practical applications of chemistry, disparaged what he described as “practicalism”, and refused any offers to consult to private industry as long as he occupied his university position.50 More recently, in the year 2001, Theodore Poehler, a man who spent more than 50 years at JHU and who is currently vice-provost for research, stated in an interview that commercializing research “just wasn’t something people did 46 Feldman , Maryann and Desrochers, Pierre. “Research Universities and Local Economic Development: Lessons from the History of the Johns Hopkins University” Industry and Innovation, Volume 10, Number 1, 5–24, March 2003, p 1. 47 Feldman, P. M. & Desrochers, P. (2004). Truth for its own sake: academic culture and technology transfer at Johns Hopkins University. 48 Hawkins, Hugh 1960: Pioneer: A History of the Johns Hopkins University, 1874-1889. Ithaca, NY Cornell University press. p 304 49 Rosenberg, Robert 1990: Academic physics and the origins of electrical engineering in America. PhD dissertation (History of Science), Johns Hopkins University, p 52. 50 Rosenberg, Robert 1990: Academic physics and the origins of electrical engineering in America. PhD dissertation (History of Science), Johns Hopkins University, p 19. [at Hopkins] … Hopkins was a place where you would come to be an academic person and do research, and that’s that. Most people here today are still here for that reason.”51 In fact, most scientific breakthroughs at JHU traditionally did not bring direct economic benefit to the academic staff or the University.52 JHU inventions became part of the public domain even though the university would have reaped financial benefits given their commercialization. Some of these scientific breakthroughs include the discovery of Heparin, a drug used to prevent blood coagulation, and the discovery of vitamin D, which set the stage for an effective polio vaccine. These examples are indicative of the culture at JHU being one that gives priority to basic research and scientific publication. Feldman and Descrochers explain that JHU’s anti-commercialization outlook can be linked not only to the value of particular individuals that help found and establish the university but also to the general climate that characterized the Progressive Era at the turn of the century. Specifically, this era was characterized by promoting expert and disinterested scientific planning and mitigating the ill effects of laissez-faire enterprise.53 Given the cultural atmosphere at JHU, invention disclosure to the technology transfer office may not be looked upon favourably. Field studies and survey research indicates that many faculty members are not disclosing to their technology transfer offices, despite 51 Rosenberg, Robert 1990: Academic physics and the origins of electrical engineering in America. PhD dissertation (History of Science), Johns Hopkins University, p 52. 52 Feldman, P. Maryann & Desrochers, P. (2004). Truth for its own sake: academic culture and technology transfer at Johns Hopkins University….. 53 Rosenberg, Robert 1990: Academic physics and the origins of electrical engineering in America. PhD dissertation (History of Science), Johns Hopkins University, p 52. the Bayh-Dole Act stipulation that faculty members working on federal research grants must disclose their inventions.54 The difficulty in obtaining faculty disclosures is one of the main challenges for technology transfer offices. Bercovitz and Feldman investigated the mechanisms that result in disclosure. They used JHU and Duke University as their study sample and collected data for over 2500 faculty members across 15 departments in two medical schools for the years 1990-1999. Medical schools were examined since most technology transfer activities originate within medical schools. As well, they chose departments for which there was variation in disclosing rates across the universities. The findings indicate that the decision to disclose is influenced by social learning both prior to joining an institution (in your training years) and afterwards by observing others in the institution. In other words, researchers are influences by their surrounding culture. Specifically, the decision to disclose is strongly influenced by three factors: training effects, leadership effects and cohort effects. With respect to training effects, faculty members that previously disclosed were more likely to continue disclosing if the experience was reasonable, that is, if the culture supported it. Moreover, the probability of disclosing decreased by about 1% for each year from the completion of graduate study. In other words, older researchers were less likely 54 Siegal and Phan to disclose due to the increased likelihood that they were educated in a cultural environment that was anti-commercialization. With respect to leadership effects, if the chair disclosed inventions to the technology transfer office in the past five years, then the probability the faculty member disclosed increased by 4%. This illustrates that the chair of the department sets the cultural attitude towards technology transfer. In addition, faculty with appointments in more than one academic department, were 7% more likely to disclose. The authors indicate that this result may be due to training effects or may be due to an entrepreneurial orientation of these individuals. It was also found that a graduate degree from a pro-technology transfer institution increased the probability of disclosing. With respect to cohort effects, a 1% increase in the percentage of faculty in the department who engaged in technology transfer activities increased the probability that a faculty member disclosed by 8%. Moreover, a 1% increase in the percentage of faculty, in identical academic rankings, who engaged in technology transfer, increased the probability of disclosing by 10%. Similarly, Louis, Blumenthal, Gluck and Stoto,55 analyzed the propensity of life-science faculty to engage in various aspects of technology transfer, including commercialization. Their statistical sample consisted of life scientists at the 50 research universities that received the most funding from the National Institutes of Health. They found that the 55 Rensselaer pg. 26 most important determinant of involvement in technology commercialization was local group norms. In fact, university policies and structures had little effect on this activity. Conclusion