Theory of Consumer Choice • • • • • The Individual Demand Curve The Market Demand Curve Utility Theory and Consumer Demand Consumer Surplus Consumer Choice Using Indifference Curves The Individual Demand Curve Bob’s Demand Curve for Hamburgers b 3.00 Price of burgers ($) The individual demand curve shows the relationship between the price of a good and the quantity that a single consumer is willing to buy [quantity demanded] during a particular period of time. The individual demand curve is negatively sloped, consistent with the law of demand. c 2.00 8 11 Burgers per month Income and Substitution Effects • Substitution effect: The change in consumption resulting from a change in the price of one good relative to the price of other goods. • Income effect: The change in consumption resulting from an increase in a consumer’s real income. • Real income: Consumer’s income measured in terms of the goods it can buy. Market Demand Curve with Two Consumers Market demand curve g 3.00 Price of burgers ($) To determine the market demand at a given price, we add the quantities demanded by all consumers. For example, at a price of $3, Betty consumes 4 burgers (point g) and Bob consumes 8 burgers (point b), so the total quantity demanded is 12 (point j). b j 2.00 Betty’s demand Bob’s demand curve curve 4 8 12 Burgers per month Market Demand Curve with Many Consumers b Quantity ($) demanded 3.00 250 2.20 850 2.00 1,000 3.00 Price of burgers ($) The market demand curve shows, for each price, the quantity of the good demanded by all consumers. A decrease in the price of burgers from $3 to $2 increases the total quantity demanded from 250 (point b) to 1,000 (point c). Price d 2.20 c 2.00 250 850 Burgers per month 1,000 Total and Marginal Utility Marginal Utility (Utils) Total Utility (Utils) 182 152 140 50 26 1 2 1 2 26 24 7 8 Burgers per month [A] Total Utility 12 8 Burgers per month [B] Marginal Utility 14 In Panel A, as the quantity of burgers consumed increases, the utility or satisfaction increases at a decreasing rate, and eventually falls. In Panel B, as the quantity of burgers increases, the marginal utility (the change in utility from one more burger) decreases. Both curves reflect the law of diminishing marginal utility. Marginal Utility and the Marginal Principle Number of Burgers Marginal Benefit of Burgers = Marginal Utility of Burgers (Utils) Number of Tacos Marginal Utility of Tacos Marginal Cost of Burgers = 3 times the Marginal Utility of Tacos (Utils) 5 18 15 1 3 6 16 12 2 6 7 14 9 3 9 8 12 6 4 12 9 10 3 5 15 10 8 0 6 18 Marginal cost (utils) 5 18 3 6 16 6 7 14 9 8 12 12 r 18 Marginal benefit or marginal cost (utils) Marginal benefit (utils) Quantity t 16 12 m 6 s 3 q 5 6 8 Burgers per month Marginal Principle and Demand The marginal benefit of burgers equals the marginal cost at 8 burgers, so the marginal principle is satisfied at point m. Consumer Surplus for an Individual Consumer t 25 24 Price of CDs ($) The individual demand curve shows how much a consumer is willing to pay for each unit of the good; for example, $21 for the first CD, and $18 for the second. Consumer surplus equals the difference between the amount a consumer is willing to pay and the price; for example, $11 for the first CD, and $8 for the second. u 21 20 v 18 $11 15 15 12 10 109 w $8 $5 x $2 y 5 0 0 0 11 22 33 44 55 Number of CDs per month Quantity Willing to Pay ($) Consumer Surplus when price = $10 ($) 0 24 1 21 11 2 18 8 3 15 5 4 12 2 5 9 Consumer Surplus for the CD Market A 25 h Price of CDs ($) 20 i 15 The market demand curve shows how much a marginal consumer is willing to pay for the product. The market consumer surplusis equal to the area between the demand curve and the horizontal price line. B 10 Price = $10 C Market demand curve 100 200 300 Numbers of CDs per month Increase in Price Decreases Consumer Surplus A Price of CDs ($) 25 The consumer surplus at a price of $10 is shown by triangle ABC. The consumer surplus at a price of $14 is shown by the smaller triangle ADE. The loss of consumer surplus is shown by the trapezoid EDBC. D 14 Price = $14 B 10 Price = $10 C Market demand curve 100 200 300 Numbers of CDs per month Quantity of tacos 30 Budget Set and Budget Line y The budget set (the shaded triangle) shows all the affordable combinations of burgers and tacos, and the budget line (with endpoints x and y) shows the combinations that exhaust the budget. 18 j i 10 e 6 x 2 4 Quantity of burgers 8 10 Indifference Curve and the MRS Quantity of tacos The indifference curve shows the different combinations of burgers and tacos that generate the same level of utility. The slope (3.0 between points e and f) is the marginal rate of substitution between the two goods. h f 9 e 6 g 7 Quantity of burgers 8 Indifference Map An indifference map shows a set of indifference curves, with utility increasing as we move “northeasterly” to higher indifference curves. C1 Quantity of tacos C3 C2 h 11 6 5 e g 7 Quantity of burgers 8 9 Consumer Maximizes Utility Quantity of tacos 30 To maximize utility, the consumer finds the combination of hamburgers and tacos which an indifference curve is tangent to the budget line, meaning the MRS equals the price ratio. j C2 18 k i 10 e 6 2 4 Quantity of burgers 8 10 Price of burgers ($) Quantity of tacos 30 Consumer’s Response to a Decrease in Price y C4 C2 e 8 6 n x 8 10 11 3 z 15 Demand Curve b 2 c 8 11 Quantity of burgers A decrease in the price of burgers tilts the budget line outward. The indifference vcurve is tangent to the budget line at a larger quantity of burgers (11 instead of 8). This is consistent with the law of demand. Individual Demand Curve At a price of $3, Bob maximizes his utility with 8 burgers (point e above and point b below); at a price of $2 Bob maximizes his utility with 11 burgers (point n and point c respectively). The Marketplace as a Signaling Mechanism Prices convey information to producers about the benefits consumers receive from goods and services - and give information to consumers about the costs of producing goods and services. Given our assumptions that producers are maximizing profits and consumers are maximizing utility, we can infer that, as firms and consumers respond to changing price signals, they will achieve an efficient solution in the marketplace - provided that prices confront decision-makers with the marginal benefits and marginal costs of their choices. Economists refer to this requirement as an efficiency condition. Price Signals and Maximizing Behavior S1 Price per pound (cents) Market equilibrium generates a price that equates the quantity demanded to the quantity supplied. It also results in a price at which the marginal benefit of a pound of tomatoes equals its marginal cost. The price of 69 cents signals consumers that 69 cents worth of other goods and services were given up to produce the last pound of tomatoes. 69 D1 Q1 Pound of tomatoes per week Price Signals and Maximizing Behavior S1 Price per pound (cents) Here we see that a change in consumer preferences reduces the demand for tomatoes from D1 to D2, reflecting a reduction in the marginal benefit of the good. Producers will reduce their production to Q2, freeing resources for the production of other goods and services. The falling price signals producers that the benefit of tomato production has fallen. 69 60 D1 D2 Q2 Q1 Pound of tomatoes per week Price Signals and Maximizing Behavior S2 Price per pound (cents) Higher input costs (fertilizer prices) increase the marginal cost of producing tomatoes, shifting the supply curve from S1 to S2. This will result in an increase in the price of tomatoes, signaling consumers to reduce their consumption. In the case shown here, the price rises to 65 cents per pound. S1 65 60 D2 Q3 Q2 Pound of tomatoes per week