Globalization on Poverty and Income Distribution in Venezuela Abstract By using the World Development Indicators (2007) provided by the World Bank, this study seeks to investigate how globalization has affected the income distribution, poverty, and quality of life in Venezuela. This case study focuses on data since 1990 and uses a social accounting matrix and model simulation to determine how a growing world economy has affected a country whose government favors a social economy rather than a liberal democratic plan. My analysis suggests that globalization has worsened the income distribution and poverty headcount in Venezuela; however, the poverty gap fared worse under globalized conditions than it would have under relative autarky. Accordingly, many human development indicators suggest improvements in Venezuela, but it still falls behind the rest of Latin America on a few measures. Jane Doe1 I. Introduction How has globalization affected the income distribution, poverty, and quality of life in Venezuela? The research question addressed in this paper is whether globalization has paved a favorable or grim path for future economic development in Venezuela. Using data provided by the World Bank (such as the 2007 World Development Indicators), this study 1 Contact: jane@uvm.edu. Phone: 802-656-6600. I would like to acknowledge the inspiration of my colleagues in the Human Development Network of the World Bank. After having the opportunity to act as an intern in the network’s Chief Economist’s Office, I have gained insightful exposure to how poverty and development affect human development outcomes in developing countries. My experiences at the World Bank, specifically with my mentor Dr. Amartya Sen, have strengthened my interests in economic development. I would also like to acknowledge Professor David Ricardo for his relentless assistance and insight throughout this research. Lastly, I would like to thank my family and friends, both here at the University of Vermont and in Pennsylvania, for their continued love and support through the good times and bad that have made me strong enough to fight, stay positive, and continue to do what I am most passionate about. Without them, I would not be where I am today. All errors are the exclusive responsibility of the author and all usual disclaimers hold. conducts a simulated Mundell-Fleming model with a Social Accounting Matrix (SAM) for a base year of 1990. The evidence suggests that the effects of globalization on the Venezuelan economy heavily depend on fluctuations in the demand and price for oil and on the political culture dominating policy making. Overall, because of this monopolized market, a lack of diversity in the market, and over-spending on ineffective social programs, Venezuela has failed in the game of globalization. Despite this, there have been gradual improvements in some indicators of quality of life such as fertility, literacy, and infant mortality. The structure of this paper is as follows: In section II, I provide an overview of policy issues in Venezuela and its lack of acceptance of liberal foreign policy while thoroughly describing the country’s macroeconomic profile from 1980-2005. Section III discusses Venezuela’s rejection of globalization as it retracted from progress in the late 1990s; section IV explains my methodology and describes my simulation models testing the counterfactual with an empirical analysis of Venezuela’s economy since 1990; section V provides my poverty and income distribution analysis; and section VI describes a more detailed look into Venezuela’s dependence on oil exports and the dangers of a monopolized market and what this means for the future of Venezuela’s economic development. I complete this investigation in section VII with my conclusions. II. Policy Issues With strict currency controls, price controls, nationalization of important aspects of the economy (the oil industry), and policies that strengthen trade unions, Venezuela’s present economic policies do not adhere to the Washington Consensus; but, the country has opened its economy for international trade (with most of the country’s income depending on its oil exports). The present government values socialist economic prospects rather than the more liberal perceptions held by the World Bank and IMF. From 1958 to 1978, 2|Page however, Venezuela demonstrated good economic performance, high growth, low inflation, decreasing poverty, and low unemployment (Monaldi et al. 2006). Since 1978, on the other hand, economic performance has been quite dismal: it has experienced the worst per-capita GDP levels in Latin America, high inflation, increasing unemployment, and increasing poverty (Monaldi et al. 2006). Although the institutions that were created in the 1960s generated cooperation, reforms were implemented in the 1980s that were intended to improve democracy but actually weakened the party system. This resulted in volatile policy making, increased stakes of power, a lack of cooperation, and a highly polarized public sphere (Monaldi et al. 2006). According to the World Development Indicators (2007), the level of income held by the richest 20% of the population dropped from 60% in 1981 to 52% in 2003, yet the income share held by the poorest 20% of the population has remained steady around a mere 3%. The unequal income distribution continues to worsen. GDP per capita (PPP, constant 2000 USD) has dropped from $6,714 in 1981 to $5,900 in 2006, but was much higher before this time period (hitting $7,301 per capita in 1975). Many researchers argue that GDP per capita is not a clear indication of human development outcomes, but the World Bank also provides that the poverty headcount ratio (at $2 a day) has dramatically increased from 25% in 1981 to 40% in 2003 and unemployment has risen from 7% to 17% in the same time frame. In a society with such an unequal income distribution, rising unemployment rates and increasing poverty levels, one might suspect that the quality of life would be steadily decreasing as well. Although this is true in some regards, Venezuela has managed to increase its literacy rate of those over the age of fifteen from 89% in 1990 to 93% in 2006 and infant mortality rates have dropped from 46% in 1980 to 21% in 2005. At the same 3|Page time, due to changes in the budget composition, Venezuela’s debt growth has been one of the highest in Latin America while public spending has simultaneously grown dramatically during the period 1999-2004 (Puente et al 2007). With President Chavez (who criticizes globalization and American foreign policy) taking office, increases in public spending on “social” programs actually have proven to be unsustainable and inefficient, diverting resources from high to low value uses, and inequitable/regressive, redistributing income from lower to higher income groups. The allocation of resources also tends to reflect the preferences of interest groups (Puente et al 2007). With these tendencies, of course the income distribution has continued to worsen as the intended beneficiaries become worse off and the government is infiltrated by corruption. Weisbrot and Sandoval (2007) point out that there was an overall economic downturn in Venezuela: it lost 24% of its GDP as a result of an oil strike from December of 2002 until February of 2003. This demonstrates the dangers of Venezuela’s dependence on the oil industry. Since then, however, real GDP has grown by 76%. Weisbrot and Sandoval (2007) claim that the government’s expansionary fiscal and monetary policies have contributed to this expansion. Table 2.1 illustrates the real GDP composition by percentage from 1990-2005 as provided by the World Development Indicators (2007). Government spending increased from 8.4% of GDP in 1990 to 11.3% of GDP in 2005 as consumption dropped from 70.5% to 58.6% in the same time period. Weisbrot and Sandoval (2007) note that the poverty rate decreased from 55.1% in 2003 to 30.4% at the end of 2006. Unemployment, also, dropped from 19.4% in June 2003 to 8.3% in June 2007 (Weisbrot and Sandoval 2007). Table 2.1 Real GDP Composition, 1990-2005 YEAR Consumption Investment 1990 70.50 10.20 1991 76.20 18.70 Government 8.40 9.70 Exports 39.50 31.40 Imports 20.20 26.20 4|Page 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 78.80 81.50 77.30 76.60 68.30 65.10 71.10 69.70 64.20 69.10 66.50 67.60 62.40 58.60 23.70 18.80 14.20 18.10 16.60 27.70 30.70 26.50 24.20 27.50 21.20 15.60 21.50 21.70 9.20 8.50 7.20 7.10 5.00 13.50 13.50 12.30 12.40 14.20 13.00 12.90 12.60 11.30 26.40 27.00 30.90 27.10 36.50 29.30 20.90 22.90 29.70 22.70 30.40 33.80 36.20 41.00 28.90 27.20 22.30 21.80 21.30 22.00 22.70 19.20 18.10 19.40 18.10 17.00 20.10 21.30 Source: World Bank (2007) Venezuela has a fixed exchange rate and capital controls in place. The main challenge facing the economy at the moment is the rate of devaluation and inflation. With the Bolivar pegged at 2,150 to the dollar, the Venezuelan currency is overvalued and has devalued to more than 4,000 Bolivar per dollar since 2006 (Weisbrot and Sandoval 2007). As 17.6% of GDP in 1990, the current account balance fell to -6.4% of GDP in 1992. Since 1992, the current account balance increased to 13.1% of GDP by 1997 suggesting that the Bolivar was indeed overvalued. Again, the current account balance dropped to 4.9% of GDP in 1998 and then rose to 13.7% of GDP by 2003 (World Development Indicators 2007). Inflation rose rapidly during stages of political instability and the oil strike in December of 2002; the inflation rate declined since the strike, but has been steadily increasing since June 2006 and reached 19.4% in June 2007. With exchange controls and a government current account surplus, there are no forces that would normally provoke devaluation (Weisbrot and Sandoval 2007). This demonstrates what is commonly known as Dutch disease which describes the relationship between exploitation of resources and a decline in the manufacturing sector. By raising the exchange rate, the manufacturing sector is less competitive on the global stage (Ebrahim-Zadeh 2003). 5|Page When compared to the rest of Latin America, as shown in Table 2.2, Venezuela is falling behind. Although the country’s current account balance remains more stable (and positive as a surplus) while Latin America’s overall current account balance has been inconsistent and mostly a deficit, Venezuela has still relentlessly fallen below par in GDP per capita measures and inflation, which are key indications of a country’s health. Table 2.2 provides a comparison chart of these measures. Table 2.2 Venezuela Falling Behind, 1990-2005 GDP/capita Current Account Balance units, PPP current int'l $ (tens of millions YEAR Venezuela LAC Venezuela LAC 1990 4702 4925 828 -102 1991 5222 5215 174 -1736 1992 5539 5427 -375 -3348 1993 5558 5666 -199 -4554 1994 5423 5981 254 -5120 1995 5632 6070 201 -3781 1996 5611 6310 891 -3893 1997 5947 6646 373 -6582 1998 5914 6767 -443 -8966 1999 5534 6789 211 -5567 2000 5756 7102 1185 -4756 2001 5983 7204 198 -5312 2002 5449 7217 760 -1604 2003 5040 7414 1145 769 2004 5990 7929 1383 1899 2005 6632 8410 2536 3315 Inflation Venezuela 42 21 28 32 63 52 116 38 19 26 30 8 33 35 31 29 LAC 22 22 12 11 13 11 7 5 5 4 7 4 5 6 7 6 Source: World Bank (2007) It is also evident that investors perceive Venezuela’s economy unfavorably with negative expectations, thus deterring foreign direct investment, which would help economic development if present or more substantial (Weisbrot and Sandoval 2007). In 1990, foreign direct investment accounted for only 1% of GDP. Although foreign investment rose and peaked at 7.2% of GDP in 1997, it dropped back down to a mere 2.1% of GDP by 2005 (World Development Indicators 2007). Kentor (2001) notes that foreign capital 6|Page dependence has a positive effect on income inequality; however, some level of income inequality, if not too severe, is healthy for growth and poverty alleviation. III. Venezuela’s Rejection of Globalization Although there have been general increases in GDP per capita measures and the current account balance has (generally) maintained a surplus, the high government spending has forced its public sector borrowing requirement (PSBR) to be higher than the 3% target specified by the Washington Consensus. Table 3.1 shows that the PSBR in Venezuela has consistently been above this 3% target and has remained above 11% since 1997 indicating a lack of fiscal discipline. Inflation continues to be a problem along with the country’s overall openness (or lack there of) to trade, which mostly depends on oil exports. Openness, measured as net exports divided by real GDP, has staggered over the last fifteen years but remains relatively low compared to the rest of Latin America. Table 3.1 provides the trend of openness from 1990-2005. Table 3.1 Openness, 1990-2005 YEAR PSBR 1 1990 8.4 1991 9.7 1992 9.2 1993 8.5 1994 7.2 1995 7.1 1996 5.0 1997 13.5 1998 13.5 1999 12.3 2000 12.4 2001 14.2 2002 13.0 2003 12.9 2004 12.6 2005 11.3 Openness2 0.2 0.05 -0.03 0 0.08 0.05 0.15 0.07 -0.02 0.04 0.11 0.03 0.11 0.17 0.16 0.2 Source: World Bank (2007) and author's calculations Notes 1. PSBR expressed as a percentage 2. Openness is computed by dividing net exports by real GDP 7|Page Figure 3.1 illustrates the trend of openness from 1990-2005. Although Venezuela’s openness was somewhat sporadic from 1990-1998 and it appears that the economy was actually becoming less open, there has been a general upward trend since 1998, indicating that although the progress has been slow, Venezuela has been moving toward a more open economy. Considering Venezuela’s high, inconsistent inflation rates and its fixed exchange rate, it is evident that the Bolivar has been repeatedly revalued in an economically inefficient manner providing a noncompetitive exchange rate. After calculating the devaluation based on the changes of the real exchange rate and calculating the appropriate exchange rate based on domestic and world inflation rates, it is evident that the Bolivar has been consistently overvalued. Table 3.2 provides the nominal devaluation of the Bolivar, the change in the real exchange rate, and the inflation differential from 1991 to 2005. It is evident that the Bolivar has not been appropriately valued as shown by the differential. Figure 3.2 illustrates all three trends, demonstrating the differences between the real exchange rate and the nominal devaluation. Table 3.2 Exchange Rate, 1991 to 2005 8|Page YEAR Nominal Devaluation 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 0.174 0.170 0.247 0.389 0.160 0.576 0.146 0.108 0.096 0.109 0.060 0.377 0.278 0.150 0.095 Change in Real Exchange Rate 0.050 -0.032 0.011 -0.140 -0.268 -0.509 -0.188 -0.031 -0.126 -0.136 0.020 0.087 -0.031 -0.112 -0.146 Inflation Differential 0.124 0.202 0.236 0.529 0.428 1.085 0.334 0.139 0.222 0.245 0.040 0.290 0.309 0.262 0.241 Source: World Bank (2007) and author's calculations A simple indication of a country’s acceptance of globalization can be witnessed in its capacity to import and export. As previously seen in Table 2.1, Venezuela’s tendency to import and export has been relatively sporadic, although export growth has been more consistent than import growth. Since 1985, annual export growth has maintained positive figures with just a few exceptions and the import growth has been positive since 2003. Figure 3.3 provides a visual of the trade growth patterns since 1985. 9|Page Although there is some evidence of Venezuela opening its economy to join the game of globalization, it has played the game poorly and is now retracting any progress it did make in the 1990s. The country’s inconsistency, political instability, and corruption have proven to be risky for foreign investors. Foreign direct investment has increased slightly over the past twenty years, but it peaked in 1997 at only 7.2% of GDP. Since then, it has drastically fallen and has failed to maintain a level higher than 4% of GDP since 2000. Figure 3.4 provides the trend of foreign direct investment as a percentage of GDP since 1985. 10 | P a g e Not only has Venezuela started to move away from globalization after reaching its most open period in the late 1990s, but it has also failed to privatize its domestic affairs. According to the World Bank Indicators (2007), it took 141 days in 2005 to start a business in Venezuela when on average in Latin America and the World it required only 67 days and 47 days, respectively. With a process that requires significant amounts of time and work, individuals are less likely to have the incentive to open private businesses and to therefore diversify income resources. Accordingly, the state owns the most prominent corporation in Venezuela: Petroleos de Venezuela, S.A. As a stated-owned petroleum company, it is the world’s third-largest oil company generating about 80 percent of the country’s total export revenue, half of the central government’s income, and one-third of the country’s GDP (Alvarez 2008). Venezuela’s oil dependence and its implications are further discussed in section V, but it is important to note here that this lack of diversification provides great risk for the economy and also monopolizes most of the country’s wealth. Any monopolization of power as seen in Venezuela is a rejection of the Washington Consensus and fails to diversify the country’s economy. IV. Model and Theory This research follows the Mundell-Fleming growth model to analyze poverty and development in Venezuela. Although Venezuela has been sporadic in liberalizing its economy and still fails to follow an open-economy framework, I use 1990 as the base year in this case study due to the change in political leadership. The aggregate demand balance for Venezuela is written as X = a1X + C + I + G + E - epmMc where X is the gross value of production, a1 is the input-output coefficient, C is the household consumption supplied by domestic firms, I is investment demand supplied by 11 | P a g e domestic firms, and G is the government demand for goods and services. Net imports is given by (E - epmMc) where E denotes demand for exports, e refers to the nominal exchange rate (which is equal to 1 in the base year), pm refers to price of imports (which is also 1 in the base year), and Mc represents competitive imports. Only the input-output coefficient, the nominal exchange rate, and the import price are previously determined parameters. The following consumption function is used to determine C: C = Cbar + cYd where Cbar is autonomous consumption, c is the marginal propensity to consume, and Y d is household disposable income. Autonomous consumption and the marginal propensity to consume are parameters, but disposable income can be determined with this equation: Yd = Yh(1-th) In the previous function, Yh is household income and th represents direct taxes on households. Direct taxes on households are already given for my model, but the following equation can be used to find household income: Yh = (1-tπ)πX + ∑iwiliX + Tr + T* + ∑wg The parameters of this equation include: X, tπ (profit tax rate of direct taxes on firms) and li (the labor coefficient which is defined as the amount of labor of type i used to produce one unit of X). Now, I will first provide the functions to determine each variable, and then move on to detail the equations needed for variables within those equations. To solve for π, the profits per unit of output, we can use the following function: π = τB where τ is the mark-up on unit costs (a parameter) and B denotes unit costs. The wage rate (wi) can be found with a wage adjustment equation where t represents time (year): 12 | P a g e wit = (1 + gwi)wit-1 here, there are two parameters: gwi is the growth in nominal wages (according to the strength of labor unions and other distortions that may affect the labor market) and wit-1 is the lagged wage rate (or the wage rate from the year before the base year). Trt (the government transfers to households) are evaluated with the following government transfer equation: Trt = (1 + gTr)Trt-1 The growth rate of government transfers (gTr) and the lagged government transfers (from one year before the base year) (Trt-1) are calibrated from my base SAM. The following equation is used to determine the foreign transfers to households (T*t) in year t: T*t = (1 + gT*)T*t-1 where (gT*) is the growth rate of foreign transfers and (T*t-1) represents lagged foreign transfers (both calibrated from base SAM). The last variable from the household income equation is the government wage equation: Wgt = (1 + gwg)wgt-1 where (gwg) is the growth of government wages and (w gt-1) denotes lagged government wages. The only variable from the household income equation left to define is for unit costs (B) which are needed to solve for profits per unit of output: B = pa1 + ∑iwili + ep*a* where p* and a* are parameters for the price of imported intermediates and the inputoutput coefficient for imported intermediates, respectively. Now, we must go back to our original aggregate demand balance and solve for I, investment: I = (I0 + I1u)K where I0 is the autonomous investment and I1 is the sensitivity of investment to capacity utilization (u). Capacity utilization can be found with the following function: 13 | P a g e u = X/Q where Q is capacity. We define K, the capital stock from our investment function, as follows: Kt = It-1 – δKt-1 where It-1 is the lagged autonomous investment and δ is the depreciation rate. Now we must address the unknown variable Q from our capacity utilization function: Q = AKβL(1-β) where β is the share of profits in value added (calibrated from the base SAM) and A is the calibration parameter for capacity. Employment, L, can be defined as: L= (1-β)Q / (w/p) The price, p, is equal to one in the base year and can be found from the following: p = (1 + t)(1 + τ)B To return to the original aggregate demand balance, the government demand for goods and services, (G,) can be determined: Gt = (1 + gG)Gt-1 where both inputs are parameters: gG is the growth of demand by the government and Gt-1 is the lagged government expenditure. To find exports demanded, the following function is used: E = E0 + E1er where E0 represents autonomous exports and E1 is the parameter for the sensitivity of exports to the real exchange rate. To further this equation, we calculate the real exchange rate: er = (ep*) / p 14 | P a g e The final variable from the aggregate demand balance still to be addressed is for competitive imports (Mc): Mc = mcX where mc is the competitive import coefficient and can be found for year t with the following function: mct = (1 + gmc)mct-1 Here, gmc is the growth rate of competitive imports and mct-1 are both previously calibrated parameters. Based on the previous 21 equations, 21 variables, and 32 parameters, I am able to use my calibrated SAM from the base year of 1990 and data collected by the World Bank to create a growth model for Venezuela. This is a dynamic Mundell-Fleming model with five income classes (quintiles) that can be illustrated with an IS-LM-BP diagram (but since Venezuela maintains a fixed exchange rate, the money supply floats and only the IS and BP curves are relevant). The only static variable in this model is the capital stock which depends on investment and depreciation. By running simulations I am able to judge whether Venezuela would have been better off without globalizing (the counterfactual), focusing the analysis on the Gini coefficient, Poverty Headcount, Poverty Gap, and Squared Poverty Gap, which are calibrated to match the historical data in the base year 1990. Although the country still maintains some aspects of a closed economy such as a fixed exchange rate, it did open up for trade and thus the counterfactual can still be considered as a closed economy (which may be where Venezuela is now heading). Figure 4.1 shows the counterfactual (relative autarky) versus the actual GDP measured in constant local currency units (LCUs). Based on this analysis, real GDP grew an average of 38.32% annually in the simulation and 38.35% historically. Although these 15 | P a g e average growth rates are close, the actual growth rate still exceeds the simulation, suggesting that Venezuela’s economy would not have developed as much as it did if the economy was closed. Figure 4.1 illustrates the simulated counterfactual versus the actual data from 19902004 as a base run with the simulation passing through many of the actual data points. However, as further noted later in this paper, this does not necessarily imply human development or poverty alleviation. Venezuela’s government deficit has been volatile. Although the actual data provides an average growth rate of 36%, this is not representative of its inconsistent nature. As seen in Figure 4.2, the government deficit has been significantly negative for most of the years presented, but its recent (random) improvement has offset the average. Overall, the growth of the government deficit in the counterfactual is more consistent, but it is a growing deficit, so the actual data portrays an economy that is better off with a smaller deficit. Venezuela’s government deficit would be more severe if it had continued with a closed economy. 16 | P a g e Venezuela’s current account balance has also been somewhat sporadic; however, with the exception of 1992, 1993, and 1998, it has remained a surplus. As seen in Figure 4.3, the simulated model represents the overall negative trend in the current account balance. Although it still provides evidence that the balance decreased between 1990 and 2004, it is much more persistent than the historical data, and it remains a surplus over the entire time period. Figure 4.3 illustrates that the simulation trend is much better than what Venezuela actually faced. 17 | P a g e Figure 4.4 shows the trend of consumption from 1990-2004. Based on the figure below we can see that the counterfactual reveals lower levels of consumption from 1995 to 2001, but since 2001, the actual consumption level has been lower than the counterfactual with an increasing gap between the two. Although both trends reveal significant growth, the trend under autarky projects higher levels of consumption and we can conclude that since liberalization, the growth of the counterfactual has been more substantial. Since consumption is consistently one of the largest parts of aggregate demand, increasing levels of household consumption imply enough demand for there to be high levels of investment, as well. Figure 4.5 demonstrates this. 18 | P a g e There is significant growth in investment in both the counterfactual and actual trends, but the average growth rate of the actual trend is higher than the growth rate of the counterfactual. From this we can conclude that the aggregate demand also grew significantly in this time period, which was previously shown to be evident in Figure 4.1. The last variable to address that influences the aggregate demand is net exports. Figure 4.6 shows the counterfactual and actual trends from 1990-2004 revealing that Venezuela’s trade balance would have been significantly better under relative autarky. The counterfactual illustrates a positive trend since 1990 while the actual data reveal a negative trend. The increasing disparity can be seen in Figure 4.6. 19 | P a g e V. Human Development and Poverty Analysis An increasing level of real GDP can indicate that an economy is growing, but that does not necessarily reflect the living conditions and human development within that country. Diverse perceptions of Venezuela’s economy are conceptualized depending on the data chosen to analyze. Venezuela’s GDP per capita in PPP international dollars has grown from 4702 in 1990 to 6632 in 2005 while its current account balance has improved from 828 current LCUs to 2536 LCUs (tens of millions) according to the 2007 World Development Indicators. However, this fails to reveal the poverty devastating large portions of the country. Table 5.1 provides a more realistic picture of how Venezuelan citizens fit into the profile of this “growing” economy. The poorest 20% of the population held only 5.5% of total income in 1993 and that decreased even more to 3.3% in 2003. In the same time period, the richest 20% of the population increased its income share from 47.5% to 52.1%. Accordingly, the poverty gap (at $2 a day) increased from 5.1 to 19.1 in that decade. Table 5.1 Income Distribution, 1993-2003 YEAR Poorest 20% 1 Second Poorest 20% Middle 20% Second Richest 20% Richest 20% 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 5.5 .. .. 3.7 .. 3.0 .. 4.6 .. .. 3.3 10.0 .. .. 8.4 .. 8.2 .. 9.4 .. .. 8.7 15.0 .. .. 13.6 .. 13.8 .. 14.8 .. .. 13.9 22.1 .. .. 21.3 .. 21.8 .. 22.4 .. .. 22.0 47.5 .. .. 53.0 .. 53.2 .. 48.9 .. .. 52.1 Source: World Bank (2007) Notes 1. Measured as income shares and indicated as percentages 20 | P a g e Despite overall GDP increases, economic disparities within Venezuela are worsening as the poverty gap widens (almost quadrupling over the 10 year period) and the difference in shares of income become even more apparent. Four main measures are used to analyze poverty and inequality including the poverty headcount (the percentage of the population with incomes below the poverty line), the poverty gap (the shortfall from the poverty line expressed as a percentage reflecting both the depth and incidence of poverty), the squared poverty gap, and the Gini coefficient (the difference between exact equality and the level of income inequality at the given time). Table 5.2 provides this data and clarifies the worsening condition of Venezuela’s poverty since the early 1990s. Since 1987, the best condition Venezuela experienced was in 1989 when the poverty headcount level below the $2/day poverty line was 14.5% of the population. This is also when the poverty gap was lowest at 4.6, the squared poverty gap was 21.2, and the GINI coefficient was 0.60 (second lowest in the time period). Table 5.2 Poverty Analysis, 1987-2005 Headcount (% Poverty Gap (at Squared Gap (at GINI YEAR below $2/day) $2/day) $2/day) Coefficient 1987 24.7 8.5 72.3 0.63 1988 1989 14.5 4.6 21.2 0.60 1990 1991 1992 1993 17.9 5.1 26.0 0.59 1994 1995 1996 36.4 15.7 246.5 0.61 1997 1998 30.6 14.5 210.3 0.61 1999 2000 27.8 10.3 106.1 0.60 2001 2002 2003 40.1 19.2 368.6 0.61 21 | P a g e Source: World Bank (2007) and author's calculations When analyzing the growth of a developing country, Ray (1998) notes that indicators about the population can provide a deeper look at how the economy might prosper in the future and where the growth may lead. Indications of an economy that is actually developing include decreasing fertility rates, low population growth rates, and a falling percentage of the labor force in the agricultural sector (Ray 1998). According to these indicators, Venezuela’s prospects for future development appear positive. Venezuela is improving on all three measures however it still falls behind the Latin American average for population growth. See Table 5.3 for a more detailed analysis. Table 5.3 Labor Force, Fertility, and Population Growth, 1990-2003 YEAR 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 Agriculture (% of labor force) Venezuela 13.4 12.6 11.8 11.3 13.8 13.5 13.5 10.8 10 10.2 10.2 9.5 9.8 10.7 Population Growth Fertility LAC 18 Venezuela 3.4 LAC 3 18 19 3.3 3 19 18 18 17 3.1 3 3 2.9 2.9 2.8 2.8 2.8 2.7 3 17 17 16 3 3 Venezuela 2.3 2.2 2.3 2.2 2.2 2.1 2.1 2 2 1.9 1.8 1.9 1.8 1.8 LAC 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 2 1 1 1 Source: World Bank (2007) Lastly, Ray (1998) notes the universal acceptance in development economics that we cannot define growth with merely the level or growth of per capita income. It is generally accepted that income (wealth) has a lot do with the overall development of a 22 | P a g e nation and provides the stability necessary to make vital changes, but development is also the “removal of poverty and undernutrition” (Ray 1998). This can be measured by an increase in life expectancy, access to sanitation, clean drinking water and health services, the reduction of infant mortality, increased access to school (which serves as an investment to human capital), and literacy. These fare as human development indicators showing how the citizens of a country are actually benefitting (or hurting) as a result of an economy’s development (Ray 1998). Table 5.4 shows that the life expectancy, malnutrition, infant mortality, and school enrollment rates improved from 1990-2005 in Venezuela and the country fares better than the overall average in Latin America on all measures except primary school enrollment rates. See Table 5.4 for a more detailed comparison. Table 5.4 Human Development Indicators, 1990-2005 YEAR 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 Life Expectancy Venezuela 71.2 71.7 71.8 72.1 72.2 72.4 72.6 72.7 72.9 73.3 73.4 73.6 73.8 74 74.2 Infant Mortality (per 1000) Malnutrion (under 5) LAC 68 .. 69 .. .. 70 .. 71 .. .. 71 .. 72 .. .. 72 Venezuela 13.8 13.5 13.6 12.8 13.2 14.1 14.4 14.9 14.3 13.6 12.8 .. .. .. .. .. LAC .. .. .. .. .. .. 19 .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. .. Venezuela 26.9 .. .. .. .. 23.6 .. .. .. .. 20.7 .. .. .. .. 18.1 Primary School Enrollment LAC 43 .. .. .. .. 36 .. .. .. .. 30 .. .. .. .. 26 Venezuela .. 87.5 .. .. .. .. .. .. .. 85.6 87.8 90.1 93 91.7 92 91.3 LAC .. 85 .. .. .. .. .. .. .. 93 94 95 96 96 95 .. Source: World Bank (2007) Venezuela is indeed improving according to these human development measures, but perhaps not fast enough, and the country still falls behind the rest of Latin America in 23 | P a g e some regards. Venezuela lags in education: in 2004, the primary school enrollment rate was 92% in Venezuela but 95% on average in Latin America. Also, in 2004, only 68% and 83% of Venezuela’s population had access to improved sanitary and water resources, respectively, while those percentages were 77% and 91% in Latin America overall (World Bank 2007). Although Venezuela falls short when measured by these indicators, the country is still showing improvements, nonetheless. Simulations comparing the counterfactual (autarky) and the actual data can be used to analyze the effects of globalization on poverty and income distribution. Figure 5.1 reveals that the Gini Coefficient is much more ideal than what is historically true. With such an unequal income distribution, Venezuela has maintained a Gini coefficient around 0.6 since 1993 (actual data is scarce). However, in the counterfactual, it hovers around 0.3, which would be preferred relative to reality. Globalization therefore has had negative effects on the income distribution in Venezuela. Due to complications with data accessibility, this research does not use actual published data for the poverty gap and heacount at a national poverty level (only at $2/day measures as provided in Table 5.2) to compare to the counterfactual simulations. Instead, 24 | P a g e we can only assume that similar trends in the poverty headcount and gap were felt at the national level as they were at the given levels in Table 5.2. As previously noted, both measures significantly worsened from 1990-2004: the headcount increased from 24.7% of the population in 1987 to 40.1% in 2003. The simulation indicates a similar trend with an increasing poverty heacount; however, it is not nearly as drastic, implying that poverty worsened when Venezuela liberalized. Figure 5.2 demonstrates the poverty headcount from 1990 to 2004, increasing from 800 to 1056 in that time frame. Contrasting conclusions can be made from the simulated poverty gap. Again, plotting the counterfactual with the provided historical data is irrelevant since different poverty lines are used; however, Table 5.2 provides an increasing trend in the actual poverty gap since 1987. The counterfactual also indicates that the poverty gap would have worsened even more if the economy had not liberalized. Figure 5.3 illustrates that under autarky, the poverty gap would have grown from 9 in 1990 to 601 in 2004, significantly worse than the actual increase from 4.6 in 1989 to 19.2 in 2003. 25 | P a g e Based on the simulations provided and the historical data, it is evident that globalization has had adverse effects on the income distribution and poverty headcount in Venezuela; however, although the poverty gap increases both historically and in the counterfactual, the poverty gap conditions would have been worse under autarky. VI. Policy Implications: Oil Dependence, Social Spending, and Corruption Venezuela derives a large proportion of its revenue from external rents, specifically, oil rents. In the last three decades, oil rent has accounted for more than 80% of total exports, 90% of total foreign assets income and 50% of total fiscal income (Puente et al. 2007). When countries rely heavily on oil rents, they tend to tax their population less, or not at all, and spend resources inefficiently. Accordingly, Venezuela has charged the lowest tax rates in Latin America while maintaining some of the highest profits, wages, price controls and subsidies (Puente et al. 2007). Citizens, therefore, lack the incentive to demand budgetary transparency and accountability from their governments. The tax policy in a given country can have serious implications for its globalization prospects. Overall, tariffs should be decreasing while direct taxes are increasing. Table 6.1 provides a historical perspective on Venezuela’s tax composition. From the provided data it 26 | P a g e is evident that although taxes on firms and households make up the majority of tax revenue, the rates that firms are taxed have significantly decreased while those on households have steadily increased. Tariffs have been inconsistent, peaking at 11.3% of the revenue composition in 1992 and then again rising to 10.9% in 1998, but it seems as though the recent trends have pushed taxes on international trade to fall, hovering around 4-5% of the total tax revenue, consistent with the Washington Consensus. This is illustrated in Table 6.1. Table 6.1 Tax Composition by Percentage, 1990-2005 YEAR Firms Households Tariffs 1990 1991 1992 1993 1994 1995 1996 1997 1998 1999 2000 2001 2002 2003 2004 2005 63.9 63 53.7 51.4 40.8 37.6 38.2 38.8 17.4 20.5 26.7 19.6 12 13.4 15.2 21.5 3.2 3.5 7.5 12.4 20.9 32.7 27.8 30.2 38.1 33.6 24.9 25.2 22.5 23.5 28 24.9 6.8 8 11.3 11 9 9.2 6.9 6.8 10.9 9.4 7.1 7 5.5 3.5 4.7 4.9 Source: World Bank (2007) Venezuela’s oil dependence has led to overall growth while veiling the country’s inefficiencies, particularly institutional weaknesses of the public administration. Oil was a main factor allowing Venezuela to create social conditions required for a cohesive party system (Karl 1986). Without oil, there will be little chance for democracy (Monaldi et al. 2004). 27 | P a g e Despite the risk of oil price volatility, Weisbrot and Sandoval (2007) argue that the government has planned conservatively with respect to oil prices and a “bust” would not injure the economy as severely as most expect: “a decline in oil prices of 20% or more could be absorbed from international reserves” (Weisbrot and Sandoval 2007). However, based on econometric analysis, Puente et al. (2007) note that oil shocks and unexpected increases have a significant impact on the fiscal balance and the dependence on oil revenue negatively affects the allocation of public resources due to the monopolization of economic power. Governance and corruption can partly explain these skewed allocations, which are further investigated later in this section. The allocation of resources tends to reflect the preferences of interest groups in Venezuela, and in the first part of 1999, the budget suffered seven different adjustments equivalent to 1.5% of GDP (Puente et al. 2007). “The bases of Venezuelan budgets have become encumbered with programmes which are unsustainable, non-adaptable, inefficient (they divert resources from high to low value uses) and inequitable/regressive (they distribute income from lower to higher income groups)” (Puente et al. 2007). For example, the education sector (which receives one of the larger shares of social expenditures), only allocated 11% of the total budget for education in 1999 to pre-school and elementary education, which accounted for 80.0% of all enrolled students. This can be generalized to the inequity of resource allocation in the public sector overall: public goods and services attain goals set out by the government as opposed to focusing on improving living conditions (Puente et al. 2007). Although Venezuela’s economy (in GDP terms) has expanded as provided earlier in this research, Venezeula’s debt growth has been one of the highest in Latin America (Puente et al. 2007), which is mostly due to the increased public financing for social programs as previously described. The sustainability of such public financing for social 28 | P a g e programs is seemingly doomed to fail as the government refrains from increasing domestic tax and depends on oil rents to finance such programs. Central government spending has increased from 21.4% of GDP in 1998 to 30% in 2006 (Weisbrot and Sandoval 2007), most of which was intended to be allocated to social spending on healthcare, food, and education. The state oil company was responsible for 13.3 billion dollars allocated toward social spending in 2006 (Weisbrot and Sandoval 2007). With central government social spending increasing from 3.2% of GDP in 1998 to 13.6% of GDP in 2006, significant improvements in human development (such as in the poverty gap and in the income distribution) should be apparent. But they are not. How can this increasing disparity be explained? As previously noted, the allocation of resources seems to be slightly skewed toward interest group demands and government interests. One of these avenues could possibly be explained by the impeding corruption that continues to disrupt efficiency in Venezuela. As shown in Table 6.2, Venezuela’s percentile rank determined by the World Bank Governance indicators measuring control of corruption has worsened between 1996 and 2007, along with regulatory quality, rule of law, political stability, and voice and accountability, each of which can contribute to the failed efficiency of the government. Table 6.2 Governance, 1996-2007 Voice and YEAR Accountability 1996 51.2 1997 1998 50.5 1999 2000 46.2 2001 2002 32.7 2003 35.1 2004 32.2 2005 30.3 2006 32.7 Political Stability 18.8 Government Effectiveness 15.6 Regulatory Quality 36.1 Rule of Law 28.1 Control of Corruption 23.8 30.8 35.1 43.9 27.1 20.4 28.8 26.1 33.7 26.2 30.1 12.5 12 11.5 13.5 14.4 15.6 15.2 15.6 22.7 26.5 28.3 13.7 12.2 11.2 9.8 13.3 9 9 9.5 6.2 10.7 10.2 15.5 15 16 29 | P a g e 2007 30.8 12 16.6 4.9 3.3 10.1 Source: World Bank (2007) It is evident that Venezuela falls consistently low when ranked by percentile on all six indicators of “good governance”. The rankings have drastically gotten worse since 1996 with the exception of its position in government effectiveness (which has remained low the entire time period, but also mostly reflects the government’s ability to mobilize the populist rather than necessarily pursue open, liberalizing policies). In a cross-country study of more than 150 countries, Kaufmann, Krayy, & ZoidoLobatón (1999) provide evidence of a strong causal relationship from better governance to better development outcomes such as higher per capita incomes, lower infant mortality, and higher literacy. Indeed, “of particular relevance to developing countries is the possibility that corruption might reduce the effectiveness of aid flows, through the diversion of funds from their intended projects” (Maura 1997). When corruption affects the composition of government expenditure, as was previously shown to be evident in Venezuela with increasing government expenditures on (ineffective) social programs, inferior public infrastructures are maintained. Despite the quantitative evidence of increased social spending in Venezuela, this is not translated into human development improvements. It has been accepted among scholars that merely allocating funds or increasing public spending for goods and services does not necessarily lead to outcome changes; however, “no serious empirical work has been carried out to support it” (Rajkumar & Swaroop 2002). Financial assistance to developing countries is not sufficient to ensure improvements in actual service delivery. Rajkumar & Swaroop (2002) conclude that the link between public spending and desirable 30 | P a g e outcomes may be severed without an incentive mechanism in the public sector to use funds for productive purposes. With poor governance, simply increasing expenditures on social programs will continue to be futile. VII. Conclusion Based on my model and analysis, it is evident that if Venezuela continues to maintain its current economic policies which do not adhere to the Washington Consensus, it will only face globalization with fierce opposition. The simulations illustrate that the counterfactual (relative autarky) suggests a less sporadic and more consistent current account balance and government deficit. The current account balances in both the counterfactual and in the historical data are decreasing; however, the declines are less substantial under relative autarky. On the contrary, the counterfactual presents a consistently increasing government deficit, and although the government deficit increases on average historically as well, there were at least some periods of decline instead of incessant worsening. The Gini coefficient and poverty headcount were more ideal in the counterfactual suggesting that Venezuela has failed in the game of globalization; however, the poverty gap increased at a faster rate in the counterfactual than it did historically in a globalizing world economy. Although the country has opened its economy for trade and foreign investment, political instability and market monopolization create a volatile and risky environment for foreign investors. On the surface, increased government expenditures on social programs seemingly intend to benefit the development of health and education, but corruption and poor governance in Venezuela redirect these funds and create inefficiencies in public spending. The programs aim to benefit the poor, yet they fail to be properly implemented and Venezuela’s income distribution has continued to worsen, consistently falling behind the 31 | P a g e rest of Latin America when considering many human development indicators. If the administration wishes to maintain high government expenditures on these programs, the corruption devastating the economy’s efficiency must first be negated. Only then will the efforts prove to be effective. For now, however, the rest of the world is not stopping to wait for Venezuela to catch up. It continues to grow and globalize and become more and more interdependent as Venezuela retracts from adhering to the Washington Consensus. Facing this reality, Venezuela must diversify its economy and privatize businesses. With two thirds of GDP dependent on the state owned oil company, the health of the economy is too dependent on one sole source. Venezuela must cut back on government spending and allocate the resources to more efficient uses, such as investing in new businesses or creating smaller social programs with more oversight and accountability. And this spending must come from resources generated domestically as well as foreign investment. With a persistently unequal income distribution, Venezuela must reconsider its tax policies to more adequately redistribute the wealth. As long as the government is not transparent and held accountable for its actions, its spending will remain inefficient.References Alvarez Herrera, Bernardo (2008), “Revolutionary Road? How Chavez Has Helped the Poor [An Empty Revolution]”, Foreign Affairs 87(4) (July-August): 158-60. Alvarez, Cesar J. (2008), “Venezuela’s Oil-Based Economy”, Council on Foreign Relations, Edited by Stephanie Hanson, June 27, 2008 Central Bank of Venezuela: http://www.bcv.org.ve/EnglishVersion/Index.asp Centre for Economic Policy Research: London, United Kingdom. www.cepr.org Constitution of the Bolivarian Republic of Venezuela: http://ww.venezuelanalysis.com/constitution Ebrahim-Zadeh, Christine (2003), “Back to Basics—Dutch Disease: Too much wealth managed unwisely”, Finance and Development 40(1)(March) 32 | P a g e Faria, Hugo J (2008), “Hugo Chavez against the Backdrop of Venezuelan Economic and Political History”, Independent Review 12(4) (Spring): 519-35. Kentor, Jeffrey (2001), “The Long Term Effects of Globalization on Income Inequality, Population Growth, and Economic Development”, Social Problems 48(4)(November): 435-455. Kaufmann, Daniel, Aart Krayy, & Pablo Zoido-Lobatón (1999), “Governance Matters,” Policy Research Working Paper 2196, October 1999, Washington, DC: The World Bank Maura, Paolo (1997), “The Effects of Corruption on Growth, Investment, and Government Expenditure: A Cross-Country Analysis”, Corruption and the Global Economy edited by Kimberly Ann Elliott, Institute for International Economics, Washington, DC: pp. 83-107 Monaldi, Francisco, Rosa Amelia Gonzalez, Richard Obuchi and Micheal Penfold (2006), “Political Institutions, Policymaking Processes, and Policy Outcomes in Venezuela”, Inter-American Development Bank, Research Network Working Paper #R-507: Washington, DC Puente, Jose Manual, Abelardo Daza, German Rios & Alesia Rodriguez (2007), The Political Economy of the Budget Process in the Andean Region: The Case of Venezuela, Country Studies Series, Inter-American Development Bank, January 2007: Washington, DC Wagner, Sarah (2004), “Corruption—How Does Venezuela Measure Up?”, December 10, 2004. http://ww.venezuelanalysis.com/news/832 Weisbrot, Mark and Luis Sandoval (2007), “The Venezuelan Economy in the Chavez Years”, Center for Economic and Policy Research: Washington, DC. World Development Indicators (2007), Washington, DC: The World Bank. 33 | P a g e