Chile, Globalization and Poverty Abstract Benchmark economic theory suggests that free trade between economic agents produces the best possible result for both agents involved, and is the basis for globalization. This paper investigates the validity of this theory through the extensive use of a simulated dynamic Mundell-Fleming model calibrated to Social Accounting Matrices (SAMs) for a base year of 1972. The end result is that if any of the agents are not fully prepared structurally to accommodate globalization, there will always be a loss of utility on the part of the less prepared agent. (not generally true) Such results are the basis for claims that developing countries would be better off had they not engaged in free trade, forming the foundation for the analysis used throughout. Using Chile as a case study, this paper will ask if Chile might have been better off without liberalization by projecting previous trends from 1973-1993. The analysis suggests that Chile is in fact better off by integrating themselves in the global economy. John Doe1 I. Introduction Strictly defined, globalization is simply the removal of barriers to the flow of international goods, services and capital. Given to us more than 200 years ago by Adam Smith and David Ricardo, the theory states that all parties involved, and thus society, are better off as a result. This theory is strongly advocated even today and is the underlying basis for making the Washington Consensus the preferred policy for all countries, developed and developing. More than a decade has passed since the ascendancy of the Washington Consensus and critics charge that the gains from trade University of Vermont and State Agricultural College, Burlington VT 05405; xxx@uvm.edu. I would like to thank Professor William Gibson, whose support and infinite patience have proved to be crucial inputs. 1 have been distributed in a lopsided fashion. This begs the very important question of whether countries that benefit less would be better off under autarky. It is this question that creates the motivation for the analysis in this paper. Chile is frequently cited as an example of a successful development strategy based on current and capital account liberalization.(Cite source.) Using a simulated Computable General Equilibrium (CGE) model based on the Mundell-Fleming IS-LM-BP framework, this paper compares a counterfactual for Chile under the assumption of continued relative autarky of the 1980s. The paper demonstrates that, had the country not opened its borders in the way they did, Chile would have been worse off economically. This paper is separated into six parts. The second section is concerned with the theory of globalization and what should happen when the terms of trade are favorable to poor countries and thus implemented correctly. Section three gives a brief outline of Chile’s economic history prior to the opening of its markets, while the fourth section presents the empirical results and analyzes them with respect to Chile’s history and the theory presented in the second section. Section five discusses the dynamic Mundell-Fleming model and shows how it how it was calibrated to match pre-liberalization data and gives basic forecasts based on the trajectory pattern presented in section four as well as policy recommendations. The sixth and final section concludes that Chile would have been better off without implementing globalization on such a large scale than it has been with it. II. Theory Based on the theory given to us by Ricardo more than 200 years ago, Repetitive. Comparative Advantage states that two nations, in the case 2 of no input factor mobility, should specialize in the good in which they can produce relatively more efficiently. There are of course a number of other assumptions at work in this simplified theory, but as a point of reference it is necessary. For all of its significance, however, comparative advantage says nothing of the distribution of post-trade utility, which is where the present discussion begins. In the event of two countries (one rich, one poor) engaging in free exchange, and the poor country, as a result of the exchange, realizes strong economic growth from there on, then the terms of trade were favorable to the poor country and they have experienced “pro-poor growth.” According to certain experts (Bhalla, 2002), this type of growth has been the norm since the early 1980s, and is what will be investigated in this paper, in the example of Chile III. Chilean Economic History, 1972-1993 The best place to begin discussion of relevant Chilean economic history is with Salvatore Allende. Elected president in 1970, Allende is the man whose Marxist Socialist economic policies contributed the basis for Chile’s later economic frustrations. Grounded in the popular dependency theory, Allende’s policy package assumed economic growth was constrained by domestic demand (Schatan, 2001). As a result, subsidies were given to agriculture and industry as well as tax and tariff incentives to promote growth. In line with the theory of import substitution industrialization, policies were enacted, however, with the intent of minimizing imports rather than 3 increasing exports. The export sector was based on a few commodities, mainly copper (Schatan, 2001, p. 61). Furthermore, when the Chamber of Deputies refused to pass legislation raising taxes, the Allende government borrowed from the Central Bank; when inflation accelerated, the government simply fixed prices for staple goods (Schatan, 2001, p. 60). This combined with a multiple exchange-rate system, dampened incentives to produce for the formal market and thus a black currency and thus exchange market were spawned (Schatan, 2001). The end result, of course, was that, in terms of dollars, the marginal cost of producing these staple goods rose above their prices, thus creating spot shortages (Schatan, 2001). Expectations were widely frustrated and Dornbusch and Edwards (1991) later described the process as TABLE 3.I Real GDP Composition, 1965-1983 Year GDP Consumption Investment Government Exports Imports 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 17.78 19.56 20.27 21.03 21.76 22.22 24.23 24.03 22.84 23.41 20.75 21.46 23.32 25.06 27.24 29.46 30.86 27.67 26.62 12.50 13.47 14.04 14.62 15.05 15.06 16.70 17.55 17.93 14.52 15.09 14.71 16.89 17.72 19.17 20.82 22.98 20.83 19.51 3.25 3.70 3.80 3.99 3.87 4.27 4.17 3.53 2.39 5.82 3.52 3.37 4.05 5.27 5.74 6.19 7.00 3.12 2.62 1.86 2.17 2.20 2.25 2.35 2.77 3.60 3.77 2.93 3.68 3.25 3.00 3.40 3.62 3.89 3.67 4.06 4.24 3.78 Source: World Bank (2004) Note: Tens of million Chilean pesos of 1965.. 4 2.42 2.90 2.89 2.94 3.58 3.25 2.67 2.36 3.12 4.77 5.28 5.39 4.81 5.16 6.34 6.72 5.07 5.36 6.39 2.23 2.68 2.66 2.77 3.09 3.12 2.91 3.18 3.53 4.61 5.69 4.46 5.23 6.00 7.11 7.95 8.26 5.88 5.68 “macroeconomic populism.’’ Some macroeconomic data from the period are shown by Table 3.1, the gains made by the Allende regime were less than impressive, to say the least. Language too informal for an academic paper. The latter part needs further explaination. As shown in the table, the growth of GDP and its components were slow, as they grew by an nine percent after Allende’s first year, but negatively in the next two years, respectively. Nonetheless, Allende was overthrown by a military during September of 1973 and Augosto Pinochet became President. TABLE 3.2: Real GDP Composition by Percentage, 1965-1983 Year Consumption Investment Government Exports Imports 1965 1966 1967 1968 1969 1970 1971 1972 1973 1974 1975 1976 1977 1978 1979 1980 1981 1982 1983 70.00 68.86 69.26 69.52 69.14 67.76 68.94 73.02 78.50 62.02 72.72 68.56 72.42 70.72 70.37 70.68 74.49 75.29 73.27 18.26 18.92 18.75 18.99 17.80 19.20 17.20 14.70 10.47 24.84 16.97 15.69 17.35 21.03 21.06 21.02 22.70 11.28 9.85 10.47 11.11 10.84 10.69 10.78 12.44 14.86 15.69 12.84 15.73 15.67 13.98 14.57 14.43 14.30 12.45 13.15 15.32 14.19 13.61 14.81 14.27 13.98 16.46 14.61 11.03 9.82 13.65 20.38 25.44 25.12 20.62 20.58 23.28 22.82 16.42 19.37 24.01 12.56 13.70 13.13 13.16 14.19 14.02 12.02 13.23 15.47 19.71 27.41 20.80 22.42 23.93 26.11 26.98 26.75 21.25 21.32 Source: World Bank (2004) and author's calculations Convinced by “Los Chicagoboys” and their mentors, Pinochet decided to make Chile free of “the stigma of statism,” and thus a free market economy, which would require a significant amount of changes.(Cite 5 source.) The first of these was freeing the price system of the controls imposed by the previous regime and slashing government spending (Collins, 1995, p. 26). After price controls are lifted, the economy falls prey to repressed or pent-up inflation created below controls. Thus the prices of domestic goods rose by nearly 375 percent annually, clearly outstripping wage growth (Collins, 1995, p. 27). Furthermore, despite the cuts in spending, the budget deficit approached nearly 32 percent of GDP (Collins, 1995, p.?). The next step in the Chicago reform package was to increase efficiency through privatization. In short, the Commanding Heights, as well as the financial and transportation sectors were privatized, resulting in nearly 15 percent unemployment (Collins, 1995, p.?). These reforms, however, still failed to produce the predicted results, as by 1975 Chile found itself in a deep recession with real output shrinking by eleven percent, per annum. Soon thereafter, Milton Friedman was brought in to give Pinochet a “one-hour course” on proper economic planning, resulting in an additional 20 percent decline in Government expenditure (Collins, 1995, p.). This is reflected in Table 3.2, which shows the composition of GDP in percentage terms. What the table also shows is the volatility of investment as a result of such policies, falling 32 percent in 1973, only to increase by more than 140 percent in 1974 and fall by 39 percent the following year. The changes continued throughout, as import tariffs were further decreased, thus resulting in increased openness2, shown in Figure 3.1. As the chart clearly shows, the influence of neoliberal economic philosophy Here openness is defined as the sum of export and imports as a percentage of GDP: (X+M)/Y. 2 6 continued as import tariffs fell and thus trade as a percentage of overall GDP, increasing Chilean dependency on foreign goods. What the graph also shows is the break between the Allende era and that of the Chicagoschool dominated Pinochet regime. From 1977-81 the Chilean economy grew rapidly, prompting further efforts to reduce government borrowing,, most notably the privatization of the social security and health care system. Chile also enacting a new labor code that severely reduced workers’ rights and undermined their position at the bargaining table (Collins, 1995, p. 30). Unemployment rose to nearly 25% of the workforce. Starting in November 1981, a number of major banks and businesses began to fail, partially as a result of the poor performance of the US economy. GDP in the following year fell by ten percent, and unemployment rising to nearly thirty three percent (Collins 1995, p. 33). The recession deepend, despite efforts by the government to issued\ a series of bailout loans to the private sector. The public sector absorbed the massive debts accumulated in the financial sector and in many businesses (Collins, 1995, p.10). 7 Figure 3.1: Chilean Openness, 1965-1998 0.8 0.7 Openness (% of GDP) 0.6 0.5 0.4 0.3 0.2 0.1 0 1960 1965 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 2000 Year Source: World Bank (2003) and author’s calculations. Not long after, Chile found itself faced with serious balance of payments deficits, for which they ultimate had to seek support from the World Bank and the International Monetary Fund (IMF) (Schatan, 2001, p. 62). To qualify for the stand-by facility, Chile was required to submit to “stabilization package” that called for: 1. Liberalization of foreign exchange and import controls 2. Increased Hospitality to Foreign Investment 3. Anti-Inflationary programs such as higher interest rates and control of credit, as well as salary increases (Collins, 1995, p.). The results of Chile’s “choice3” to follow the Washington Consensus, (this is not the WC) surprisingly, were very solid ones. Openness clearly increased, as shown by Figure I, while GDP grew by a steady pace, averaging about seven percent annually from 1985-1998. The major The argument here is that there is not exactly much choice for these developing countries, considering the state that they are in. For more on this, see Stiglitz (2001). 3 8 components of GDP also experienced steady growth throughout the rest of the surveyed period. However, though growth is good for the overall economy it may not necessarily be good for all of its participants and thus to arrive at an appraisal of Chilean economic performance, it is imperative that we examine such growth, post and pre-liberalization, in terms of poverty and inequality. IV. Poverty and Inequality There are a number of methodological concerns surrounding the measurement of poverty and inequality, mainly the lack of credible data.(Cite source.) Four measures are used concerning these two economic variables. They are the poverty headcount, the poverty gap, squared poverty gap and the Gini coefficient, all of which are used throughout the literature. (Cite Lipton and Ravallion) The simplest and most widely used is the headcount, which is merely the percentage of individuals with incomes below the poverty line. The second is the poverty gap, an aggregate of the difference between the poor and the poverty line divided by the population size. This index is used to illustrate the depth to which poverty extends. The fourth index is the Gini coefficient, which is the difference between complete equality and the current level of income inequality. These are the four main measurements in which the trends in poverty and inequality will be discussed. During the period 1973-1976, the Chilean economy, on average, shrank by three percent annually.Repetitive. Much of this could be attributed to the adjustment to the policy prescription of Friedman and company.Repetitive. The effects of such poor performance were felt, nonetheless, as they present a bleak picture for its income distribution as well as poverty. Noting a lack of data on Chilean Income Distribution in 1973, the Gini coefficient rose from 0.468 to 0.543 between 1974 and 1976, 9 as shown by Figure 4.1 (Mesa-Lago, 2000). A good portion of this could be explained by the fact that, as a result of government prohibition of unions, strikes and collective bargaining, and a 12.7 percent average rate of unemployment, the real wage fell by 7.4 percentage points (Mesa-Lago, 2000, p. 43). Here the relationship should be clear: in the event of falling wages, other things constant, inequality will increase. Furthermore, the poor performance of the economy resulted in an average decline of 4.43 percent in per capita (Italicize all Latin, indeed, foreign words) income (Mesa-Lago, 2000). The effects of this trend as well as that of real wages were felt by workers—namely the poor, with the end result being a 39.9 percentage point increase in the poverty headcount between 1970 and 1976 and a 22 percent increase in indigence (Mesa-Lago, 2000). Figure 4.1: Gini Coefficient, Selected Years (1974-1993) 0.580 0.560 0.540 0.520 0.500 0.480 0.460 1970 1975 1980 1985 Source: Mesa-Lago (2000). 10 1990 1995 Following the crisis of 1975, from 1976-81, the Chilean economy was characterized by strong economic growth (otherwise known as “The Chilean Economic Miracle”), rapidly falling deficits (that eventually became a surplus), rates of unemployment, rising real wages and significant growth in the export sector (Mesa-Lago, 2000, p.58). In 1976, GDP grew by three and a half percent, and by eight percent during the period 1977-81. Furthermore, per capita income rose by an average of 1.5 percent and the average wage rose to 38 percent above its 1976 level and the minimum wage rose 48 percentage points (Mesa-Lago, 2000). Part of these wage gains could be attributed to the seven percent decrease in unemployment, as it fell from a fifth of the total labor force to about 15 percent (Mesa-Lago, 2000). Such impressive gains were instrumental in decreasing the poverty headcount from 57 to 44 percent and indigence falling by 13 percentage points (Mesa-Lago, 2000, p. 62). In addition, the Gini coefficient fell from 0.543 to 0.531, as shown by Figure 4.1. Despite such impressive growth during the previous period, there were signs that such an expansion was coming to an end. One was that during the year 1981, the growth of the industrial sector fell from 7 percent during 1977-81 to 2.6 percent, with an eight percent decline in total production (Mesa-Lago, 2000, p. 58). Furthermore, the peso became overvalued, the trade surplus became a growing deficit and external debt doubled (Mesa-Lago, 2000). Rather than change course, the Chicago policy prescription was pushed even further. This lack of foresight on the part of policymakers contributed to Chile experiencing the worst recession since the 1930s. GDP fell by an average of 7.3 percent between 1981 and 1983. Such a drastic reduction in income had an adverse affect on employment, as the unemployment rate rose from 11 to nearly 20 percent of the labor force (Mesa-Lago, 2000 p. 76). Most of 11 this was felt in industry, as employment in this sector fell by 23 percent (Mesa-Lago, 2000). Furthermore, half of these unemployed were from the lowest income quintile, which resulted in an increasing Gini coefficient from 0.521 to 0.542 (Mesa-Lago, 2000, p. 77). According to government surveys (namely ECLAC), poverty incidence fell 14 percentage points during this time; but these numbers are questionable, considering a 17 percent decline in per capita consumption and a nearly 9 percent drop in per capita income (Mesa-Lago, 2000). The economy recovered quite impressively in 1984-85 and continued with sustained growth from 1986-89. During this period, GDP grew by 6.3 percent from 1984-85, and continued the upward trend to a peak of 9.9 percent in 1989 (Mesa-Lago, 2000, p. 93). Real wages declined between 1984 and 1987, Table 4.1 Wage Share, 1987-1993 Year Wage Share 1987 31.92% 1988 30.88% 1989 32.20% 1990 33.78% 1991 34.17% 1992 35.27% 1993 36.62% Source: Penn World Tables (2004) but grew thereafter (Mesa-Lago, 2000). Additionally, the number of unionized workers increased by 22 percent (Mesa-Lago, 2000 p. 90). Such gains indicate a macroeconomic climate more favorable towards workers, shown by the fall in the unemployment rate from 14.6 percent in 1983 to 5.9 percent in 1989 and the continued growth of the wage share, shown in Table 4.1 (Mesa-Lago, 2000). Such growth continued in the period 1990-93, as GDP and Per Capita GDP grew by an average of 5.8 and 5.3 percent annually, considerably higher than the growth rates for 1974-77 (-4.4), and 1982-83 (-9%) and 1984-89 (4.6%). Such a strong expansion was partially due to an improvement in the state of the labor market during the period, as there was a 3.1% annual rate of employment creation as a result of the government creating new training programs that emphasized skilled labor and productivity (Mesa-Lago, 2000, p. 124). This resulted in 75% of the 600,000 individuals trained finding jobs, 50% 12 above the minimum wage (Mesa-Lago, 2000). This was reflected in the share in agriculture falling 2.8 percentage points (Mesa-Lago, 2000). Income distribution worsened during this period, as the Gini coefficient increased slightly from 0.556 to 0.562 (Table 4.1). However, the ratio of the highest quintile to lowest income quintile fell from twenty three to eighteen, closer to its pre-liberalization levels. The poverty headcount fell from 0.4945 in 1990 to 0.4891 in 1992 (World Bank, 2001). Interpreted in the context of households rather than individuals, the headcount fell from 48 to 24 percent during the period (Mesa-Lago, 2000, p. 125). A good portion of such gains were due to the unemployment rate of the lower income sector falling by nearly ten percentage points (Mesa-Lago, 2000). These country specific trends of poverty and inequality are for the most part inconsistent with the aggregate trends in greater Latin America, as during the seventies, Latin America’s Gini coefficient fell consistently, while Chile’s faced a continuously faced positive growth rate (Londono and Szekely, 2000). However, the two trends would move together during the 1980s, with Latin America’s Gini index (58.3) rising past Chile’s 55.6 in 1990 (Londono and Szekely, 2000). In terms of poverty, incidence in Latin America as a whole fell during the 1970s while that of Chile rose considerably. During the eighties the headcount fell in Chile, while it rose sharply for Latin America. For Latin America, this trend continued on through the 1990s, while the headcount in Chile continued to fall. V. Simulations The simulations discussed investigate the path of Chile’s growth and development under relative autarky. As noted above, they are done in a simulated dynamic Mundell-Fleming model calibrated to a Social Accounting Matrix (SAM) for a base year of 1972. It is a one sector model, with two income classes (rich and poor) and three variables that adjust to excess demand, according to the the Walrasian adjustment process: the 13 interest rate, exchange rate, and the wage rate. The Mundell-Fleming model can be best described statically with an IS-LM-BP diagram which gives the reader a flavor of exactly how the model works. Since it is a dynamic model, the only “state” variable the model accounts for is the capital stock as it changes from period to period according to investment and depreciation in the standard stock-flow analysis. Based on these simulations, we will have a more concrete tool to analyze whether or not Chile would have been better off under autarky. This analysis will primarily be done based on the Gini coefficient, Poverty Headcount, Poverty Gap and the Squared Poverty Gap, all of which are calibrated to match the actual data at the year of liberalization (taken here as 1983) and projected relative to the trend produced by the counterfactual. These variables have no direct feedback into the model and are thus calculated exogenously. (They obviously have indirect feedback in the sense that they depend on wages and employment which does feed back.)( Anybody sophisticated enough to read this paper will already know what is deleted.) Figure 1 shows the counterfactual (i.e., relative autarky) versus the actual of Chile’s Net exports during the surveyed period. As shown in the figure, Chile is at a small trade deficit in the base year, where the two are equal. As shown in the figure, despite the initial trade deficit, for every period during the twenty one years surveyed, Chile’s trade balance is steadily improving at a rate of fifteen percent annually, reaching a high of 15.7. 14 Figure 5.1: Net Exports, 1972-1993 30.00 20.00 10.00 0.00 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 Counterfactual Actual -10.00 -20.00 -30.00 -40.00 put the legend and source statement on the graph. Source: World Bank (2003) and author’s calculations. This is significantly better than the trend that Chile faced under the actual case of rapid liberalization. Based on the figure above, we can confidently deduce that Chile’s trade balance would have definitely fared better under relative autarky. It is worth noting that even in the base year of 1972 Chile’s import share was 13.23, significantly different from zero (Table 2.2). Figure 5.2 shows the trend of consumption during the twenty one year period. As is the case with Figure 5.1, the counterfactual is calibrated to the actual. Figure 5.2: Household Final Consumption, 1972-1993 15 400.0 350.0 300.0 250.0 Counterfactual 200.0 Actual Linear (Actual) 150.0 100.0 50.0 0.0 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 Source: World Bank (2003) and author’s calculations. Based on the figure above, we can see that there is also a stark difference between the consumption levels under autarky and liberalization. This is really based on volatility; the pink line is better because it is less volatile. As can be expected, the counterfactual follows a more stable growth pattern while the actual fluctuates a bit. However, since in this case we are modeling consumption, the actual is still relatively stable, based on consumption usually being the largest and most stable component of aggregate demand. Even with levels produced by the counterfactual being stable as the marginal propensity to consume rises by a respectable one percent annually, the upward trend in consumption since 1983 (the year of liberalization), culminates with the actual surpassing that of the counterfactual in the final period, allowing us to conclude that since liberalization has taken place, the growth of the actual is considerably more striking than that produced by the 16 counterfactual and thus liberalization has had a positive effect on consumption levels, meaning that there has been significant enough demand to merit high levels of investment in Chile, post-liberalization. This is shown by Figure 5.3. Figure 5.3: Gross Private Investment, 1972-1993 160.0 140.0 120.0 100.0 Counterfactual Actual 80.0 Linear (Actual) 60.0 40.0 20.0 0.0 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 Source: World Bank (2003) and author’s calculations. As predicted, the actual trend in Figure 5.3 is one of almost uninterrupted positive growth. There is of course more than one reason why investment has followed such a progressive path over the final ten years of the surveyed period (falling interest rates are also a large factor), but the influence of demand cannot be discounted. Such positive results for investment would obviously push GDP growth significantly, which is the case in Figure 5.4. Figure 5.4: Real GDP, 1972-1993 17 600.0 500.0 400.0 Counterfactual Actual 300.0 Linear (Actual) 200.0 100.0 0.0 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 Source: World Bank (2003) and author’s calculations. Looking at figures 5.3 and 5.4 one is able to fully see the effects that globalization has had on Chile’s macroeconomic climate. While not only attracting considerable amounts of foreign direct investment (FDI), which has grown from 3.2 to 33.2 percent of GDP between 1980 and 1990, globalization has also had a significant impact on poverty and inequality (UNCTAD, 2004). Figure 5.5 shows the Gini coefficient for Chile over the surveyed period. As noted above, in the year of liberalization, the counterfactual is calibrated to the actual data for the four measures presented. As the actual trend shows, Chile was a country of rising inequality from the 1970s forward. With liberalization, such inequality has continued to rise, reaching its peak 1989. In the simulated model, this measure was performed by subtracting share of income from share of population. 18 Figure 5.5: Gini Coefficient, 1972-1993 0.7000 0.6000 0.5000 0.4000 Counterfactual 0.3000 Actual 0.2000 0.1000 0.0000 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 Year Source: World Bank (2004), Mesa-Lago (2000) and author’s calculations. Given 1983 as the year of liberalization, there is a very clear divergence of the counterfactual from the actual, as the former falls considerably while the latter somewhat tapers off. Income inequality, in the era of liberalization is a great deal lower for the counterfactual. Shown by the distance between the actual and counterfactual, the distribution of the gains to trade have had a negative impact on income inequality are in fact . Figure 5.6: Poverty Headcount, 1972-1993 19 0.70000 0.60000 0.50000 0.40000 Counterf actual 0.30000 Actual 0.20000 0.10000 0.00000 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 1995 Source: World Bank (2003) and author’s calculations In terms of poverty incidence, the opposite is true: globalization has lifted a greater percentage of the population up out of poverty than would have been under autarky (see Figure 5.6). However, the poverty gap, which essentially measures the depth of poverty, is lower under autarky, meaning that by not liberalizing, the depth of poverty in Chile would have been comparably less. This is corroborated by Figure 5.7 below. Interesting. Figure 5.7: Poverty Gap, 1972-1993 0.80000 0.70000 0.60000 0.50000 Counterfactual 0.40000 Actual 0.30000 0.20000 0.10000 0.00000 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 Source: World Bank (2003) and author’s calculations 20 1995 Finally, we have the squared poverty gap which measures the incidence of extreme poverty. This is depicted in Figure 5.8. As the figure clearly shows, the case of extreme poverty is one that looks significantly different from the other poverty measures, based on the u-shaped curve that is produced by the counterfactual. What this tells us is that under autarky, the proportion of individuals living in extreme poverty would have fallen pre-liberalization and risen post-liberalization. What is most significant about Figure 5.8 is that after 1986, the level predicted by the counterfactual is greater than the actual trend. Overall, the results of the simulation corroborate the case made by classical trade theory: that in the long run the welfare of a given society’s people are better off with trade, also giving weight to Ricardian growth theory’s argument that inequality is a prerequisite for growth. However, the results of the simulation do not support Ravallion’s (1997) claim that the rate of poverty reduction is lower in countries with higher inequality because the growth elasticity of poverty reduction with respect to growth declines as the distribution worsens. Figure 5.8: Squared Poverty Gap, 1972-1993 14.00000 12.00000 10.00000 8.00000 Counterfactual 6.00000 Actual 4.00000 2.00000 0.00000 1970 1975 1980 1985 1990 -2.00000 Source: World Bank (2003) and author’s calculations. 21 1995 Income inequality in Chile is still very high by international standards, as it has the fifth highest Gini coefficient in Latin America during the 1990s (Londono and Szekely, 2000). Conversely, its headcount index is in fact the fifth lowest in Latin America (Londono and Szekely, 2000). Using the growth elasticity of income inequality, and based on the results of this simulation, I found Ravallion’s argument only to be the case up until 1984. Show some details; the is the change in the poverty level, HC, gap or gapsquared, with respect to growth. Not surprisingly, the trend of the growth elasticity of the poverty gap continued to increase with every subsequent period—even after 1984! These results are shown in the attached model. Cannot do this. The result have to be in this paper. VI. Policy Options The simulations presented in this paper have demonstrated that, in the case of liberalization, Chile has experienced a rate of growth in not only GDP but its components as well, that is much greater than that implied by the continuation of autarky. Therefore, it does not seem that decreasing their level of openness through creating trade barriers would be a very plausible solution. However, though Chile is better off now, her economy did in fact go through two major shocks during the twenty one year period surveyed. Good! In order to avoid such shocks, a slower transition would have to take place between the decision to liberalize and the actual opening up of the economy even further. After all, shock therapy, like all theories, has its limits as well. This really should have been the theme of the paper from the very beginning. It is much more convincing than lib/no lib in the case of Chile. In terms of poverty reduction, my recommendations are in line with those of the World Bank, that Chile continuously find a way to allow the 22 poor to invest in human capital (as they have done in the past), and to find a way to allow them to use their greatest economic asset: labor. (World Bank, 2001) It is worth noting that in the final period of the simulation, the level of capacity utilization was more than 95 percent, which is excellent; but there does exist the possibility that the economy could overheat due to lack of excess capacity on the part of the private sector. So I recommend that the government continue to subsidize training programs, allowing the economy to continue rapid expansion. Finally, acknowledging the many dangers of rapid capital flight, I recommend that, as a means of ensuring that the amount of hot money entering and leaving the country stays relatively stable, the central bank place a somewhat modest tax on speculative funds leaving the country— similar to an exit tax discussed by Collazo (2003). VII. Conclusion The simulations presented in this paper have given much weight to the claims that developing countries are slow to develop because they are slow to integrate themselves into the global economy. When examined in the context of economic growth, Chile has proven to be a definite success story; but on the other side of the story, there have indeed been casualties: namely, increased inequality and less than stellar progress in reducing the depths to which poverty extends, allowing us to conclude that such growth has not been as pro-poor as it could have been. These simulations, however, do show that, despite the impressive growth experienced post-liberalization, there were many setbacks to the Chilean economy. These setbacks were of course the result of rapidly liberalizing the current and capital accounts of a country that is economically immature. While this is no longer the case, it should be noted that if Chile is to continue on the successful growth path that she is on currently, there 23 must be continued expansion with less volatile investment and consistently low levels of unemployment coupled with high levels of job growth. References 1. Collazo, F., “Capital Mobility in a Dynamic Structuralist CGE.” University of Vermont (available at www.uvm.edu/~wgibson). 2. Collins, J. and , J Lear., 1995, Chile’s Free Market Miracle: A Second Look. Monroe, OR: Institute for Food and Development Policy. 3. Litchfield, J., 2001, “Updated Income Distribution and Poverty Measures for Chile: 1987-1998.” Background Paper #1 in Chile: Poverty and Income Distribution in a High-Growth Economy – The case of 19871998. Report No. 22037-CH (Volume II), August 30, Washington, D.C. 4. Londono, J., and M. Szekely., 2000,“Persistent Poverty and Excess Inequality: Latin America, 1970-1995.” The Journal of Applied Economics 3(1): 93-134. 5. Mesa-Lago, C., 2000, Market, Socialist, & Mixed Economies: Comparative Policy and Performance, Chile, Cuba and Costa Rica. Baltimore, MD: Johns Hopkins University Press. 6. Ravallion, M., 1997,“Can High-Inequality Developing Countries Escape Absolute Poverty?” Policy Research Working Paper #1775. World Bank. Washington, D.C. 7. Schatan, J., 2001,“Poverty and Inequality in Chile: Offspring of 25 Years of Neoliberalism.” Development and Society. 30 (2): 57-77. 8. Stiglitz, J., 2001, Globalization and Its Discontents. New York, NY: W.W. Norton. 9. United Nations Conference on Trade and Development, Investment Report, 2004. (available at www.unctad.org) 2004. World 10. World Bank. 2001,Chile: Poverty and Income Distribution in a HighGrowth Economy – The case of 1987-1998. Report No. 22037-CH (Volume I), August 30, Washington, D.C. 11. World Bank, 2004, World Development Indicators CD-ROM. 24 12. World Bank, 2001, World Development Report: Attacking Poverty. Washington, D.C. VIII. Appendix Figure 8.1: Growth Elasticity of Poverty Gap 0.00000 1970 -0.05000 1975 1980 1985 1990 -0.10000 -0.15000 -0.20000 -0.25000 -0.30000 -0.35000 -0.40000 Source: World Bank (2003) and author’s calculations. 25 1995