2009 Oxford Business & Economics Conference Program ISBN : 978-0-9742114-1-1 Domestic and Global impacts on Australian manufacturing prices: Ken Coutts (Cambridge) & Neville Norman (Melbourne) Submitted for the 6 th GCBE Conference, Oxford, June 24 -6, 2009 Written and finalized 28 November, 2008 Corresponding author: n.norman@unimelb.edu.au June 24-26, 2009 St. Hugh’s College, Oxford University, Oxford, UK 1 2009 Oxford Business & Economics Conference Program ISBN : 978-0-9742114-1-1 Abstract With all the current interest in global transmission of economic influences, pricing linkages have been relatively neglected. We assemble data on Australian producer prices with matched cost data and the price of competing manufactured imports. We follow a similar approach we used previously to analyse foreign and domestic competition for the UK manufacturing sector and a variety of sub-sectors. Our results for Australian aggregate manufacturing are remarkably similar to the earlier UK study and indicate that while imported prices have an influence on domestic price setting; domestic unit cost movements dominate the explanation. The results are striking. They are very relevant to understanding global economic influences on businesses and they are not consistent with orthodox classical economic predictions. Key words: price setting; global influences; trade and tariff analysis; econometric testing JEL classification: C22;C32;C81;D43;F12;F14;L60 . The purposes of this paper are: (a) to expound and sharply define the differences between various approaches to industrial economics and especially the use of industrial economics in international economic analysis; (b) to contrast methods and predictions of modern trade and tariff analysis with their classical alternatives; (c) to present tests of how (or whether) modern trade and tariff analysis is reliable and responsible in portraying global influences on business decisions; and (d) to test by prediction analysis the forecasting ability of alternative economic theories about global pricing influences. We have fresh and contemporary empirical research to present that bears significantly on point (d) in this list. A. Classical and Alternative Settings of Trade and Tariff Theory: The Differences While economics has progressed in many ways, the type of trade and tariff theory presented in most textbooks and taught in most universities has not moved since the 1950s. Yet alternative approaches have been available since the 1970s, including imperfect competition models within the neo-classical tradition (Paul Krugman’s 2008 Nobel Prize may bring these into greater prominence) and many more heterodox/alternative approaches. Rather than diverting into complex theoretical specifications here, we are able, succinctly in tabular form, as in Table A below, to explain the quite divergent approaches as between classical-orthodox and alternative/behavioral/heterodox set-ups of trade and tariff analysis. Table A: Central Features of Orthodox and Alternative Trade and Tariff Analyses June 24-26, 2009 St. Hugh’s College, Oxford University, Oxford, UK 2 2009 Oxford Business & Economics Conference Program Characteristic ClassicalOrthodox ISBN : 978-0-9742114-1-1 AlternativeModern Temporal Set-up One period/comparative statics Dynamic, multi-period Product Structure Homogeneous products Differentiated, changing products; new products Substitutability between home and overseas products Perfect; invariant Imperfect; changing over time Business Operational Objective Maximize Profits Various presumed goals, including profit constraint, sales maximization Domestic competition form Perfect competition Oligopoly/imperfect competition/quasi-monopoly Information basis for business decisions Perfect information Imperfect information: quasi perfect in Krugman models Driver variables Tariffs, exchange rates, world prices (e.g. oil prices) Tariffs, exchange rates, world prices (e.g. oil prices) The conventional, orthodox models used in the trade and tariff literature include the core trade models (comparative advantage: Ricardo, Hecksher-Ohlin), exchange rate set-ups (for demonstrating the Marshall-Lerner condition); the Marshallian (Schuller-Barone) partial model of tariff effects, effective protection analysis and formulae, the Law of One Price, and the purchasing power parity approach. There is market-clearing equilibrium everywhere in a fundamentally Walrasian set-up. The clearest and most direct exposition of these orthodox models is in Corden (1971). By contrast, in the alternative approaches, adjustment processes are endemic and incomplete, decision-making errors are rife and recognized; productive capacity is slack and underused; cost-based pricing is used as a device to handle the uncertain oligopolistic environment; products are dynamically changing and in any snapshot of them they are differentiated (at least in the minds of buyers). An extreme post-Keynesian alternative approach is presented in Norman (1996) and is described in Brinkman (1999) as the core of non-orthodox international economics relevant to trade policy analysis. This is partly because post Keynesian economists have substantially overlooked this field. June 24-26, 2009 St. Hugh’s College, Oxford University, Oxford, UK 3 2009 Oxford Business & Economics Conference Program ISBN : 978-0-9742114-1-1 In Coutts and Norman (2007: 1206-7) we describe the main differences between orthodox and alternative trade and tariff approaches as follows: “In standard trade and tariff theory, domestic firms simply match and adjust their prices to the duty-corrected prices of imported goods; consequently, domestic demand and cost conditions play no role whatever. Contrarily, cost-based pricing theories emphasize the degree of market power and the discretion it confers on firms, including domestic firms competing with foreign products, to set prices as a mark-up on some (unit) cost base, with demand and the prices of competitors playing a minor role, or none at all. Most industrial-economic analyses of price-setting take no explicit account of foreign competition (implicitly assuming that any rivals are domestic and that tariff, exchange rate and world price changes are irrelevant); they tend to be static, giving little basis for time-series analysis of actual pricing data. Nor do they harmonize with cost-based pricing approaches. This is because they presuppose that demand functions are known, whereas cost-based pricing is founded explicitly on the premise of uncertain demand outcomes in the face of price-setting decisions.” We now present a generic set-up that embodies both extremes as a prelude to fuller understanding and empirical testing. If the orthodox approach fails these tests, then decades of conventional economic theory and policy advice will have been misleading and potentially damaging to the welfare improvements it purports to enhance. We find that this is precisely the case. Figure 1 is best read from the left. There is a set of products available from foreign sources (f) (indexed {1,2,, … i, …n}) and a set available from domestic or home production (h) {1,2, … j, … r} (r>n), of which the first n are matched with similarly-described foreign-sourced products and the balance (r-n) are non-traded goods. Without necessarily assuming that the home country is a price-taking ‘small’ country, the initial play can start with foreign prices being given. Two sets of them are relevant to the home country: some enter in competition with local production, and some enter are partly-processed ‘materials’. In our generic set-up, labour costs, domestic demand pressure and forces impacting on domestic materials markets can influence any and all of these prices. June 24-26, 2009 St. Hugh’s College, Oxford University, Oxford, UK 4 2009 Oxford Business & Economics Conference Program ISBN : 978-0-9742114-1-1 Figure 1: The Setting: Formal Analysis Determinants of foreign prices Pf1, Pf2, Ph1, Ph2, Pfi, Phj, Unit labour costs of domestic industry activities Domestic demand pressure Pfn Foreign prices of inputs into home industry Phn, Phn+1 Materials inputs used in domestic industry activities Phr In all the main orthodox approaches, all of the right-hand boxes/influences in Figure 1 can be discarded. The conventional models simply make all trade-competitive prices determined and dictated by the (duty and exchange-rate-corrected) prices of the foreign goods. No domestic demand or cost factors ever get to influence domestic prices in this extreme but dominant version of the neo-classical approach. To show how extreme (and limiting) the standard orthodox approach was, and remains today, Norman (1996) produced an equally extreme heterodox alternative where NONE of the left variables dominating the classical approach had any relevance and only the cost factors in the top right box of Figure 1 determined domestic prices, despite the presence of global competition. B. Methods and Predictions of Alternative Trade and Tariff Analysis Orthodox trade and tariff analysis relevant to price and quantity effects of trade policy uses tools that hardly progress beyond conventional first-year micro-economics in most standard economics courses in universities around the world: supply-and-demand determination of competitive markets, with rising marginal costs adopted by profit-maximizing firms in a comparative static setting where foreign competitive products are perfect substitutes. So what is the alternative? As there is little attention in the literature to alternative tariff analysis, we provide selected extracts from Norman (1996) to show the approach adopted in a post-Keynesian alternative specification. This simple structure will be found directly to support the central alternative June 24-26, 2009 St. Hugh’s College, Oxford University, Oxford, UK 5 2009 Oxford Business & Economics Conference Program ISBN : 978-0-9742114-1-1 pricing approach that performs well in empirical analysis. Tariffs are applied to materials and finished-goods imports of the home country, respectively. Analytically, the impacts of these two types of protective policy are developed in turn. As the finished-product tariff diverts demand towards locally-produced finished goods but does not affect materials prices1 or the mark-up, the effect of finished-goods tariffs on domestic product prices is zero( as is the price-tariff elasticity.) The rate of production in the finished goods sector is increased, in accordance with the size of the tariff and a measure of demand substitutability. We then suppose that a tariff is imposed on importable materials as well, and then consider a number of implications and possible secondary responses or qualifications and extensions. The prices of domestically-produced finished goods are given by a mark-up system, geared to normalized unit production costs. To investigate the effect of imposing the tariff rates we begin with the tariff rates set to zero. We get the results that when final goods-tariffs are applied alone, final goods prices are insensitive to final-product tariffs and production responds entirely to demand cross-effects2 , each being distinctly different from standard theory results. When tariffs on materials inputs are imposed alone, whatever price effects transmit to finished-goods arise through materials tariffs and costs exclusively. These price effects tend to be small, given that (i) materials-good tariffs are typically smaller than finalgoods tariffs; and (ii) their fractional weight in all costs and a terms-of-trade effect each further diminish the price effect. Inspection of these pricing results will confirm why the price effects of protection in this PKTP are normally small. These results are consistent with the findings of very heavily constrained price effects of exchange rate changes and world price shocks that empirical research has already confirmed, such as Norman (1975) and Isard (1978), and more recently the Bank of England Economics Department (1993). The general result is that, under the PKTP, the effect of protection on the prices of finished products is small and arises entirely from materials tariffs, while the production effects depend entirely on demand factors. In standard orthodox tariff theory the results are quite obverse: product prices are fully (or mostly) reflected in finished-goods prices, and materials tariffs never are, while production effects are entirely supply determined.3 1It can be argued that the action of protecting the finished-goods sector might work to raise materials prices through the increase in demand so created. But this is not likely if the home materials sector is price-constrained by more homogeneous rival imports, which we do not rule out, or by internal pricing procedures, such as the Eastman-Stykolt rule, where import-competing oligopolists decide strategically to match rival import prices. 2Here the cross-elasticity is exactly applicable, since p=0 and only cross-effects work on demand. 3See Corden (1971) for verification of this. June 24-26, 2009 St. Hugh’s College, Oxford University, Oxford, UK 6 2009 Oxford Business & Economics Conference Program ISBN : 978-0-9742114-1-1 This striking contrast in results means that the alternative PKTP opens up a distinct and different approach to analyzing commercial policy that does not merely replicate classical predictions and implications. C. ‘Responsible Economics’ and Objections to Alternative Theory We can start with the notion of realism. Every theory, model or hypothesis is bound to unrealistic, so we have an issue of type and degree. The best ways to make a dissenting claim against orthodoxy is to protest that the operating assumptions are: (a) so absurdly unrealistic that the analysis cannot possibly relate to the real-world circumstances to which it purports to apply; and/or (b) the unrealistic premises of orthodoxy are so central to the analysis that they bring down the orthodox analysis ab initio. In this are we can document both claims. There is a substantial body of objection to orthodox trade and tariff analysis and especially to its setting, operational assumptions and procedures. These are the main bases for objection, and indirectly the central support for an unorthodox alterative being developed and used. (a) Realism of the set-up: Armington (1969a: 159) argued that for purposes of any responsible international economic analysis, "perfect competition and perfect substitution is neither realistic nor attractive theoretically". Robinson (1971: 98-9) is adamant that "The normal state is imperfect competition and capacity underutilization". Benson and Hartigan (1983: 132) opine: "Clearly, real world markets are typically neither monopolized nor perfectly competitive...It is surprising that international economists have failed to consider the implications of oligopolistically interdependent market structures" Helpman and Krugman (1989: 6) say it’s an elementary observation that "markets are nearly all imperfect these days. Markets like computers, aircraft /Boeing are now normal.” (b) Predictions or results are sensitive to and better more realistic operational premises: Aw(1991: 202) supports Krugman and Helpman’s contention that "imperfect competition leads to non standard impacts of trade policy (so) evaluation of trade policy should take imperfect competition into account from the start." Lancaster (1980) explains intra-industry among similar countries; Brander (1981) explains cross-hauling; Brander and Krugman (1983) explain reciprocal dumping /cross hauling. "The only good reasons for challenging the traditional approach is that it does not seem to do an adequate job of explaining the world, and alternative approaches do better" (Helpman and Krugman (1985: 2)) Helpman and Krugman (1989: 185) list five "unusual results" (p. 185) and unconventional results that can only come from breaking with the traditional assumptions: - protection can reduce the output of protected industries; - an import subsidy can improve the terms of trade; - an export subsidy can raise the profits of firms by more than the cost of the subsidy; June 24-26, 2009 St. Hugh’s College, Oxford University, Oxford, UK 7 2009 Oxford Business & Economics Conference Program ISBN : 978-0-9742114-1-1 - a tariff can reduce domestic prices; - protection can increase the profits or foreign forms as well as domestic firms. Thus economists should be cautious in their predictions of policy effects" (Helpman and "The standard practice has been to assume that competitive models give more or less the correct predictions, needing only a little touching up to apply to the oligopolies that are the concern of most actual trade policies. The theory surveyed here suggests otherwise. The evaluation of trade policy should take imperfect competition into account from the start." (Helpman and Krugman 1989: 185) Panagariya (1981: 16) considers monopoly in domestic production in a 2-sector GE model, whence "most of the standard results of the effects of tariffs remain valid only under very restrictive conditions...an increase in the tariff rate may (cause) a fall in the domestic price of the import good, even in the elastic range of the foreign offer curve." (p 16) Markusen (1981: 550) shows that "the conventional wisdom regarding the pro-competitive aspects of trade in only partly correct. If trade leads to a contraction in (monopolized) production, it may be acting to drive the country further away from its welfare-maximising production bundle." Flam and Helpman (1987) show when tariff raises domestic profits and can increase incentives for R&D, many traditional results fail, price probably rises, but more variety and scale economies come from R&D". "Free trade can never be optimal in imperfectly competitive industries" (Helpman and Krugman (1985: 185) Brander and Spencer (1981: 386) demonstrate how a country has an incentive to extract rent (the price-MC discrepancy) from a foreign imperfect competitor, using Dixit's model of entry deterrence. They conceded this is a highly specific model of oligopolistic behaviour (p. 385) Somewhat reluctantly, they say they are "not advocating the use of tariffs here.. (Their aim is just to) understand a country may have incentives to use them." Having set up the rival claims, we now turn to the evidence. D. Testing Orthodox and Alternative Approaches Tests of economic hypotheses can be by survey or numerical; analysis. In this area there is both. Relevant survey findings are related in Coutts and Norman (2007): they do not favour orthodoxy. The central test is the foreign price (or tariff) to domestic price elasticity, which is orthodox theory is everywhere unity and in alternative models is either very low or zero, as in the extreme post Keynesian model briefly outlined in this paper above. On the numerical side, Isard (1977: 942-7) long ago established that the "law of one price" (LOOP hereafter), equivalent to the orthodox price theory of tariff protection and full exchange rate pass-through, hardly ever applied and should be categorically rejected. In June 24-26, 2009 St. Hugh’s College, Oxford University, Oxford, UK 8 2009 Oxford Business & Economics Conference Program ISBN : 978-0-9742114-1-1 strongly language, supported by his analysis, he claims "students have been seduced by visions of an imaginary world ... with homogeneous (products). In reality the law of one price is flagrantly and systematically violated by empirical data." Isard accepts that basic commodities will follow LOOP, but many manufactured products (he cites agricultural machinery) diverge after foreign exchange movements and the disparity persists, especially for disaggregated product categories. Because of short data spans (often annual for US machinery prices) the analysis is very casual, but still impressionable - mostly over the short span early 1968 to late 1975. These findings are similar to those reported in Norman (1975), following similar findings by product category (differentiated machinery especially) in Norman (1974), Appendix A especially. Isard's machinery product categories are internal combustion engines; agricultural tilling machinery, office calculating machines, metalwork machinery, pumps and forklift trucks. In the period June 1970 to June 1975, the German DM/US$ ER went to 155, while the export price indexes went to 148, 123, 148, 142, 139 and 139, respectively.. he then turns to unit value import price data, and is aware of the limitations of compositional shift (p 947) - went quarterly 1/68 to 1/75, because of handcopying limitations. Aw (1991: 203) used an explicit imperfect competition framework and finds the price effects of trade restriction through VER are positive by small. Because British producer price data are so refined and distinguish between home sales and exports, it is possible to study pricing relations very closely for the United Kingdom for which there is some important recent work done by the Bank of England (Melliss 1993), Martin (1997) and Coutts and Norman (2007). In every case the foreign price/tariff to home price elasticity is very low, typically around 0.5-0.3. We described in Coutts and Norman (2007: 1220-1) our UK econometric findings and their relevance as follows: “Our results detail considerable heterogeneity in price responses to global competition between sectors, within manufacturing itself. Prediction, trade policy and model specification needs to be sensitive to this finding. There is a pattern. We have identified three broad categories of price adjustment for the later 1990s and early 2000s: (a) Sectors that produce mainly homogeneous products traded at international prices. The chemicals and base metals sectors largely belong to this group. In both sectors, the sterling prices of imported goods fell in line with exchange rate appreciation between 1996 and 2000, and domestic prices fell substantially. (b) Sectors in which international competitor prices fell in line with the exchange rate rise, but in which domestic prices increased, or fell by modest amounts. (c) Sectors whose competitor prices fell by only about 8% or less, while domestic prices increased, or fell by only modest amounts. June 24-26, 2009 St. Hugh’s College, Oxford University, Oxford, UK 9 2009 Oxford Business & Economics Conference Program ISBN : 978-0-9742114-1-1 An implication of these results is relevant to the transmission of inflation and (via the terms of trade) to swings in aggregate demand. Although a floating exchange rate will directly influence the prices of finished goods imported into domestic markets, we find that the impact on competing domestic goods is rather small. An important complementary development of this study will be to compare the price responses of UK manufactured goods produced for export markets with those of similar products within the EU market. Explanations of the pricing decisions of manufacturing firms will remain defective until trade and tariff theory incorporates partial price adjustment rather than import price dominance as the normal circumstance, and unless and until industrial economics admits any influence of global pricing forces. The message of our findings is that price effects of global competition on domestic markets are normally not dominant; they are often delayed and they differ between products, in each case in contrast to the core postulates of standard trade and tariff theory.” As a prelude to our findings we recall that, contrary to orthodox theory that in so many ways presumes or implies that relative prices are everywhere rigid, huge and sustained variations in relative prices are in evidence in Australia. As reported in Norman (2008): The Australian PPI data show a striking picture of divergence in price movements between products and sectors, over the period from 1983 to the end of 2007. The Australian all-manufacturing PPI rose in the 18 years to December 2007 by 62 per cent, clothing and footwear products PPIs by 29 per cent, petroleum refining and coal products PPIs by 365 per cent, chemicals PPIs by 29 per cent, and scientific equipment PPIs by 25 per cent, while electronic equipment PPIs fell by 85 per cent. The data show persistent divergence in (relative) price movements, which is a feature of most pricing structures captured by PPI data in many countries. Plainly, there is no apparent convergence mechanism at work here. To check the Australian scene, we assembled analogous data to that used in the UK study and to run the tests. Based on a generic, general and generous version of the price formation process as in Figure 1 above, we used the all-manufacturing Australian PPI for quarterly data from March 1983 to December 2007, with matched import prices and unit costs. Our econometric methods were similar to those used for the UK, involving both the EngelGranger two-step estimation procedure and an error-correction (ECM) procedure. We describe the main result here in non-technical terms, with emphasis on the coefficient (which is an elasticity in our log-log specifications) associated with the foreign price variables in home-price subject variable specifications. This is the central result: the relevant foreign-to-domestic price elasticity is numerically lower and even better determined (lower standard errors) than we found for the UK. When orthodox theory is propounding that such a coefficient is everywhere unity, our preferred estimate is ). The domestic–foreign price elasticity for Australian data in the period 1983–2007 is 0.20 for the long-run auto regressive distributed lag procedure (ARDL). There is a stable relation between the Australian producer price, normalized unit costs of production and competitive import June 24-26, 2009 St. Hugh’s College, Oxford University, Oxford, UK 10 2009 Oxford Business & Economics Conference Program ISBN : 978-0-9742114-1-1 prices. As for our UK results, the dominant relationship is with domestic costs, with competitive import prices playing a subsidiary role. This is exactly what alternative trade and tariff theory predicts. Another way to test this set of relationships between economic variables and the PPIs is to compare prediction errors for the last three years, or 12 quarters, all-manufacturing PPIs, from rival economic hypotheses. We test three hypotheses: (1) the standard trade/tariff theory approach, embodied in the ‘law of one price’, using adjacent import prices only; (2) the cost based pricing approach, using only normal unit costs of domestic manufacturing akin to the post-Keynesian extreme alternative; and (3) a hybrid of both using regression analysis to determined the weights. It will be evident from looking at the data that method (1) has nearly seven-fold the prediction error of method (2), while the hybrid (3) has the smallest prediction error. Figure 2 plots the behaviour for all-manufacturing output PPI with import prices of manufacturing goods in the same statistical categories. It shows the spectacular ‘crocodile jaws’ result for this relationship, a striking replay of our findings for the United Kingdom when sterling strengthened in the period 1996–2001. Rather than converging as orthodox theory leads one to expect, the home and foreign price series are getting further apart. The message is that, while foreign prices clearly impact on domestic product price setting, the relationship is far weaker and more indirect than simple economic theory is conveying to policy-makers. June 24-26, 2009 St. Hugh’s College, Oxford University, Oxford, UK 11 2009 Oxford Business & Economics Conference Program ISBN : 978-0-9742114-1-1 Figure 2 Australian and Imported Manufacturing Product Prices 5.4 Main data logs 5.2 log scale 5 4.8 4.6 4.4 4.2 M ar -8 3 M ar -8 4 M ar -8 5 M ar -8 6 M ar -8 7 M ar -8 8 M ar -8 9 M ar -9 0 M ar -9 1 M ar -9 2 M ar -9 3 M ar -9 4 M ar -9 5 M ar -9 6 M ar -9 7 M ar -9 8 M ar -9 9 M ar -0 0 M ar -0 1 M ar -0 2 M ar -0 3 M ar -0 4 M ar -0 5 M ar -0 6 M ar -0 7 4 PP PMAT PM ULC ULCN The strikingly divergent form of figure 2 is an almost exact replica of what we found for the UK in the later 1990s when the appreciation of sterling led to similar results. We show this in figure 3 for the food, drink and tobacco sector. Figure 3:U.K. Price Pairs - Food Drink Tobacco 120.0 100.0 80.0 60.0 40.0 20.0 June 24-26, 2009 St. Hugh’s College, Oxford University, Oxford, UK Mar-98 Mar-96 Mar-94 Mar-92 Mar-90 Mar-88 Mar-86 Mar-84 Mar-82 Mar-80 Mar-78 Mar-76 Mar-74 0.0 12 2009 Oxford Business & Economics Conference Program ISBN : 978-0-9742114-1-1 E. Why has Alternative Global Pricing Analysis Not been accepted? If the findings are so consistently in favour of the non-orthodox specifications, why the resistance to making alternative approaches the orthodoxy? One suspicion is that many economists are closet free traders and fear that heterodox approaches will contract their policy preference predilections. With few exceptions, it is difficult to substantiate these charges, valid as they may be. A second, more verifiable explanation is that orthodox economists, much as they may dislike protectionism, are exceptionally protectionist … of their own theoretical constructions. Here are some examples: "To abandon the assumption of perfect competition must have very destructive consequences for economic theory" (Hicks (1939), p. 83). Having urged economists to incorporate imperfect competition into trade analysis as long ago as 1935 (Haberler (1936) born 1900, died 1995) in later writings seems to have regretted saying it. In an impressive and completely neglected demonstration, Staelin (1976: 39) urges attention to the pricing equation rather than making the models as "general" as possible. But, then he laments, "Given the relative disarray of theories of imperfect competition, the use of competitive models for both theoretical and empirical applications is hardly surprising." A third explanation, without our own hands, is that alternative economists have failed in their mission: first, by failing to embrace trade and tariff analysis as a subject; secondly, by shunning econometrics as a method; and thirdly by being poor and ineffective advocates. We throw put threes observations and assertions as challenges for discussion and action. Where do we go from here? The pointers for exposition and research concerning the effect of protection and policy implications seem clear, even if they are substantially unheeded: 1. Recognize and reveal that what most economists (still) call "the" theory of protection is a very special case, with industrial economics premises decried even by orthodox industrial economists, predictions discredited by evidence and policy implications driven often by predilection. 2. Be open-minded about the industrial economic consequences of protection policy: theory establishes a wide range of possibilities. 3. Determine more fully how industries the subjects of protection policy actually work. June 24-26, 2009 St. Hugh’s College, Oxford University, Oxford, UK 13 2009 Oxford Business & Economics Conference Program ISBN : 978-0-9742114-1-1 F. Conclusion: We have introduced fresh and contemporary findings about price formation in Australian industry. Orthodox models and predictions of global influences on industrial pricing are unrealistic and unreliable. Indeed their prediction errors are totally unacceptable. By contrast, even crude alternative models are appealing and predict pleasingly. Our finds are in line with our own and other previous work in the UK and with the main core of other empirical evidence on price making in the face of global influences. With relatively few exceptions, economists working in the field of trade protection are not listening to the message that modern industrial economics, let alone alternative economics, is delivering. In the absence of better empirical material, the predictions and policy pointers which most economists will give to questions about protection will be both definite and mostly wrong. Here lies the challenge, and opportunity, if we are to represented realistic economics and genuinely help the understanding of global influences on businesses around the world. We have sketched the way ahead. June 24-26, 2009 St. Hugh’s College, Oxford University, Oxford, UK 14 2009 Oxford Business & Economics Conference Program ISBN : 978-0-9742114-1-1 References Armington, Paul S. (1969a) A Theory of Demand for Products Distinguished by Place of Production, I.M.F. Staff Papers, XVI, March, pp. 159-178. Armington, Paul S. (1969b) The geographic Pattern of Trade and the Effect of Price Changes, I.M.F. Staff Papers, XVI, July, pp. 179 - 201. Aw, Bee-Yan (1991) Estimating the Effects of Quantitative Restrictions in Imperfectly Competitive Markets: The Footwear Case, Ch 7 of Robert E. Baldwin (ed.) Empirical Studies of Commercial Policy, Chicago U. P., Chicago, pp. 201-213. Barker, Terry (1977) International Trade and Economic Growth: An Alternative to the Neoclassical Approach, Journal of International Economics, 1(2), pp. 153-172. Benson, Bruce L. & James C. Hartigan (1983) Tariffs which lower Price in the Restricting Country, Journal of International Economics, 15, pp. 117-133. Brander, James (1981) Intra-Industry Trade in Identical Commodities, Journal of International Economics, 11(1), February, pp. 1-14. Brander, James & Paul Krugman (1983) A 'Reciprocal Dumping' Model of International Trade, Journal of International Economics, 15(4), pp. 313-321. Brinkman, Henk-Jan (1999) Explaining Prices in the Global Eco0momy A Post-Keynesian Model, E Elgar, Cheltenham Coutts, K.J., Godley, W.A.H., Nordhaus, D. (1978) Industrial Pricing in the United Kingdom. Cambridge University Press, Cambridge. Coutts, K. J. and Norman, N. R. (2007) Global influences on U.K. manufacturing prices: 1970–2000’, European Economic Review, 51, pp. 1205–21. Flam, Harry and Elphanan Helpman (1987), Industrial Policy under Monopolistic Competition, Journal of International Economics, 22 (1), pp.79-102. Haberler, Gottfried (1936) The Theory of International Trade, Hodge, London. Helpman, Elphanan & Paul Krugman (1985) Market Structure and Foreign Trade. Increasing Returns, Imperfect Competition and the International Economy, Wheatsheaf, Brighton. Helpman, Elphanan & Paul R. Krugman (1989) Trade Policy and Market Structure, M.I.T., Cambridge Mass. Hirshleifer, J, Glazer, A and Hirshleifer, D. (2007) Price Theory and Applications, CUP, New York. Hicks, John R. (1939) Value and Capital, OUP, Oxford. Isard, P. (1977) How far can we push the ‘‘Law of One Price’’? American Economic Review 67, pp. 942–948. Krugman, Paul R (1979) Increasing Returns, Monopolistic Competition, and International Trade, Journal of International Economics, 9(4), pp. 469-479. Krugman, Paul (1982) Trade in Differentiated Products and the Political Economy of Trade Liberalization, Ch 7 in J.N.Bhagwati (ed.), Import Competition and Response, NBER, Chicago, pp. 197-208. June 24-26, 2009 St. Hugh’s College, Oxford University, Oxford, UK 15 2009 Oxford Business & Economics Conference Program ISBN : 978-0-9742114-1-1 Krugman, Paul R.(1990a) Industrial Organization and International Trade, Ch. 20 of Richard Schmalensee and Robert D. Willig (eds.), Handbook of Industrial Organization, volume II, North-Holland, Amsterdam, pp. 1179 - 1223. Krugman, Paul R.(1990b) Rethinking International Trade, M.I.T., Cambridge Mass. Lancaster, Kelvin J. (1980) Intra-Industry Trade under Perfect Monopolistic Competition, Journal of International Economics, 10 (2), pp. 151-175. Martin, Stephen (1993) Advanced Industrial Economics, Blackwell, Oxford. Martin, C (1997) Price Formation in an Open Economy: Theory and Evidence for the United Kingdom, 19511991, Economic Journal, 107, pp 1391-1404. Melliss, C. (1993) Tradable and non-tradable prices in the United Kingdom and the European community. Bank of England Quarterly Bulletin 33 (1), pp. 80–91. Menon, J., 1995. Exchange rate pass-through. Journal of Economic Surveys 9, pp. 197–231. Norman, Neville (1974) The Economic Effects of Tariffs on Industry, PhD dissertation, Cambridge Norman, Neville R. (1996) A General Post Keynesian Theory of Protection, Journal of Post Keynesian Economics, 18 (4) , pp. 509-531. Norman, N.R., 1975. On the relationship between prices of home-produced and foreign commodities. Oxford Economic Papers 27, 426–439. Neville R. (2008) Producer Price Indexes: Properties, Problems and Potential Applications, The Australian Economic Review, 41 (4), pp. 441–9. Panagariya, Arvind (1981) Quantitative Restrictions in International trade under Monopoly", Journal of International Economics, 11(1), pp.15-31. Robinson, Joan (1971) Economic Heresies. Some Old-Fashioned Questions in Economic Theory, Macmillan, London. Staelin, Charles P. (1976) A General-Equilibrium Model of Tariffs in a Noncompetitive Economy, Journal of International Economics, 6(1), pp. 39-63. June 24-26, 2009 St. Hugh’s College, Oxford University, Oxford, UK 16 2009 Oxford Business & Economics Conference Program ISBN : 978-0-9742114-1-1 Appendix: A Formal statement of trade and tariff theories 1. Subject Definition: We have domestic prices P, being either macro all-product price indexes or specific micro price series, and world prices, W that are exogenously determined. Our interest is in how W bears on P, either directly, or through exchange rates and tariffs, in which the "home" country can influence this “mapping of W into P”. 2. "Orthodox" International Economic Theory: Based on a very narrow view of industry economics, standard international economic theories of pricing in response to world influences (LOOP), of exchange rates (PPP) and of tariffs (FPTP) invoke or arrive at a one-to-one correspondence from W movements into P movements. It is essential to understand why this is postulated, what this means, as a testable proposition, and what necessary or sufficient assumptions about economic structure and behaviour produce this result. As to meaning, if we are focussing on a product or small sector of the economy in which internationally-traded products are significantly involved, then we mean that a given (percentage) movement in W, designated "w", produces a movement in the affected series P which in percentage change terms can be written "p", such that p=w. (If foreign prices go up by 10%, then value added (GDP), then the macro price series P will rise in the percent -on effects working through the economy. So "w” is the generator of relevant changes we study in international price relations: it is in application an exogenously-given departure in (or from the trend of) world prices, or of exchange rates or tariff rates As to assumptions for the model specifications, the standard set include (i) products that are identical (homogeneous) both within the home sector and as compared with foreign products; (ii) perfect competition in the home sector, thus profitmaximisation, perfect information, rising marginal costs, long-run free entry and exit or firms; and (iii) no terms-of-trade effects - the home country has no influence on W by varying what it buys from or sells into the world economy. 3. Examples of Orthodox Theory in Economic Analysis: The classic pure standard cases are found in the conventional theory of import protective tariffs, such as the textbook "Marshallian" model, the general-equilibrium equivalent of this and the "effective protection" approach. In these models, the "w" variable is represented by the tariff rate imposed, which in turn is equal to the (percentage) increase in the world price of imports faced by domestic consumers when the standard assumptions designated above are fully in place. Providing imports are not eliminated, P moves exactly in the percentage change, w(=t). This result is so much embodied in standard approaches that economists (and their students or audience, in public-policy discussions) seldom ever discuss it. The international price relation then becomes axiomatic without further examination. For the reasons given below, this is intellectually unacceptable. For example, in standard expositions of the effective rate of protection approach, which invokes standard assumptions entirely and without question, tariff rates are inserted as price impacts from the beginning. 3. The Case for Alternative Theory: The industry economic assumptions on which the standard approaches are built are, in general, both empirically unsupported and extremely significant in the generation of the pricing results obtained. Indeed, by substituting the more realistic assumptions of imperfect product differentiation and imperfect competition and significant scale economies, the impact on the predicted domestic price responses is dramatically changed. In fact, the extreme alternatives of p=0 or p<0 cannot be ruled out (Helpman & Krugman 1985, Norman 1996) 4. Examples of Alternative Theory: Any departures from the standard assumption set produces immediately the result that p w or p -classical in approach but they use imperfect substitution and imperfect competition; Krugman's model gives p=0, and various Keynesian approaches consistently generate low values of p relative to w, which aligns neatly with nearly all the empirical work producing low values of p relative to w (or t), including a massive amount of testing of the exchange-rate "pass-through" (Menon). June 24-26, 2009 St. Hugh’s College, Oxford University, Oxford, UK 17