The Gender-Specific Effect of Working Hours on Family Happiness in South Korea Robert Rudolf and Seo-Young Cho Georg-August-Universität Göttingen New Directions in Welfare Congress, Paris, July 8th 2011 Stylized Facts South Korea: long working hours, high female education, traditional gender roles, low female labor force participation – gradually decreasing working hours over the last two decades; adoption of 5-day working week in 2004 Still 2nd longest working hours in the OECD in 2009! – Korea among the lowest female labor force participation rates in the OECD (61.5% among those aged 20-54 (JP 71%; GER 81%)) – Korea with lowest time spent on „unpaid work“ in OECD, also lowest time spent on childcare (OECD, 2011) – Korea ranks very low on male housework participation (17%) – High female education often „to increase likelihood to find a welleducated husband“ (Lee, 1998): women 50.5% of all college graduates in 2005 – Part-time work in most cases only available in low-skilled jobs – Before marriage education and labor force participation of women positively related, after marriage negatively (Lee et al., 2008) Introduction • Paper objectives: – Extend happiness literature‘s spatial coverage to East Asia – Estimation of the effect of overall working hours reduction on family happiness – Evidence from a society with very strong traditional gender roles – Use of latest ordered logit fixed-effects estimators • Findings: – Reduction in working hours makes Korean families happier – Part-time jobs still dispreferred („아르바이트“, so-called „Arbeit“) – Strong gender-specific effects: • Husbands derive much higher utility from working than wives even after controlling for income • Wives most happy when housewife or working 31-40h and when their husband works full time • Husbands most happy when working full time without overtime hours (31-50h) Presentation Outline I. Background II. Data and Methodology III. Satisfaction Regression Results a) Life Satisfaction b) Hours and Job Satisfaction IV. Family Division of Labor V. Concluding Remarks I. Background (Theory) Employment as a means of social inclusion and self-fulfillment: – Positive welfare gains even after controlling for income (Clark and Oswald 1994; Winkelmann and Winkelmann 1998) Positive incentive for female engagement in labor market Akerloff and Kranton‘s gender identity hypothesis (2000): individual behavior largely determined by our various identities, particularly by our gender, and related expected behaviors Negative incentive for female engagement in labor market in societies with very traditional gender roles Time constraint (housework + market work + … = 24h/day) Labor market constraints (part-time options, childcare, etc.) I. Background (Empirical Evidence) Booth and Van Ours (2008, The Economic Journal): BHPS, GB Findings: controlling for family income, women prefer working to notworking; their life satisfaction peaks at 30-40 hours; yet their hours and job satisfaction is highest below 30 hours; men most happy with fulltime work Booth and Van Ours (2009, Economica): HILDA Survey, Australia Findings: women indifferent between not-working and part-time job, working more than 35 hours decreases their satisfaction; men most happy when working full-time between 35 and 50 hours Part-time jobs in GB and Australia: solution for the pursuit of both expected gender identity as the main family care-taker and selffulfillment via market work II. Data and Methodology Data used – 11 waves of the Korean Labor and Income Panel Study (KLIPS) from 1998 to 2008 – Nationally representative longitudinal study of urban Korean households modelled after the US‘s NLS and PSID – 1998 started with 5,000 households and 13,783 individuales aged 15 or older (76.5% maintained throughout all waves) – Broad information on education, employment, demographic, and socio-economic variables II. Data and Methodology Sample restrictions – Married and co-residing couples living with children – Women aged 20-54 (prime years of motherhood) – Men aged 20-64 (husbands often older than wives and a high percentage still working with 64) – Unbalanced panel, thus minimum requirement that an individual is present in at least two waves – Resulting sample: 25,461 person-year observations for women and 25,214 person-year observations for men II. Data and Methodology • Life satisfaction: – “Overall, how satisfied or dissatisfied are you with your life?” • Job satisfaction (only from wave 3 onwards): – “Overall, how satisfied or dissatisfied are you with your main job?” • Hours Satisfaction: – “How satisfied or dissatisfied are you with regard to your main job on the following aspects?” “Working Hours” • Respondents are asked to choose among: 5 (very satisfied) 4 (satisfied) 3 (neither satisfied nor dissatisfied) 2 (dissatisfied) 1 (very dissatisfied) II. Data and Methodology Table 1: Distribution of Satisfaction Measures by Gender (in %) Wifes Life Hours Job satisfaction satisfaction satisfaction 1 (very dissatisfied) 1.5 2.7 1.0 2 11.4 23.0 13.8 3 54.8 43.5 58.6 4 31.5 29.5 25.9 5 (very satisfied) .8 1.3 .8 Total 100 100 100 Mean 3.19 3.04 3.12 N 25,461 11,411 9,610 Husbands Life Hours Job satisfaction satisfaction satisfaction 1.4 3.0 1.0 11.1 23.7 15.1 54.4 45.4 56.9 32.1 26.9 26.3 .9 1.1 .8 100 100 100 3.20 2.99 3.11 25,214 Hours and job satisfaction only for individuals with non-missing and non-zero working hours. 21,509 18,267 II. Data and Methodology 0 10 20 30 Average Weekly Working Hours by Sex, 1998-2008 0 10 20 30 40 50 Working wives 60 70 80 90 100 110 120 130 Working husbands II. Data and Methodology 2.8 52 3 54 3.2 56 3.4 58 Trends of Weekly Working Hours and Satisfaction, 1998-2008 50 2.6 1998 2000 2002 2004 2006 Year Working hours Hours satisfaction Life satisfaction Job satisfaction 2008 II. Data and Methodology Table 2: Average Satisfaction by Working Hours Hours 0 Hours 1-30 Hours 31-40 Hours 41-50 Hours 51-60 Hours 60+ Life satisfaction Wifes Hours Job satisfaction satisfaction 3.23 (13390) 3.13 (1636) 3.27 (1751) 3.27 (3388) 3.09 (2370) 2.98 (2881) 3.31 (1546) 3.43 (1676) 3.34 (3152) 2.88 (2250) 2.43 (2787) 3.05 (1291) 3.28 (1508) 3.27 (2789) 3.05 (1949) 2.90 (2073) % wageempl. 57.2 71.0 80.1 65.7 31.2 Life satisfaction Husbands Hours Job satisfaction satisfaction 2.68 (2137) 2.99 (1192) 3.34 (2328) 3.36 (7322) 3.24 (6111) 3.14 (6053) 2.92 (1131) 3.37 (2231) 3.32 (6814) 2.93 (5660) 2.52 (5673) 2.77 (912) 3.26 (2054) 3.25 (5934) 3.07 (4894) 2.96 (4473) % wageempl. 47.0 72.7 76.8 67.0 50.1 II. Data and Methodology Fixed-effects ordered logit estimation Ordered logit inconsistent if unobservables correlated with covariates (e.g. personality trait with occupation status) Thus fixed effects models usually estimated in subjective well-being literature: Psychology/sociology: cardinal interpretation of satisfaction scores, linear FE Economics: ordinal approaches, no standard work horse yet Recent advances: Fixed-effects ordered logit estimators (e.g. Ferrer-i-Carbonell and Frijters, 2004; Baetschmann, Staub and Winkelmann, 2011) III. Results Table 3: Life Satisfaction Regressions Wife Family Log per-capita income Log of regional per-capita income Own house N of old females N of old males N of sons age 0-14 N of daughters age 0-14 N of sons age 15-30 (econ. dep.) N of daughters age 15-30 (ec. dep.) Own working hours Hours 1-30 Hours 31-40 Hours 41-50 Hours 51-60 Hours 60+ Partner's working hours Hours 1-30 Hours 31-40 Hours 41-50 Hours 51-60 Hours 60+ Log likelihood Observations Individuals Clusters Husband BUC FF (6) (7) Ologit (1) BUC (2) FF (3) FE-OLS (4) Ologit (5) FE-OLS (8) .414*** -.809*** .521*** -.006 -.012 -.026 .024 .037 -.049 .183*** -.700*** .293*** .062 -.496*** -.145** -.111* -.002 -.127** .189*** -.810*** .283*** .035 -.461*** -.121** -.040 -.014 -.069 .056*** -.203*** .076*** .014 -.140*** -.036** -.031** -.002 -.037** .401*** -.437** .506*** .010 -.086 .005 .021 .033 .009 .195*** -.585*** .308*** -.010 -.469** -.047 -.137** -0.039 -.098 .202*** -.425* .326*** -.101 -.465*** -.025 -.107* -.055 -.091 .059*** -.149*** .085*** .002 -.120*** -.013 -.032** -.010 -.028* -.218*** -.063 -.083* -.288*** -.349*** -.117 -.085 -.087 -.117* -.065 -.058 -.055 -.092 -.128* -.020 -.028 -.018 -.019 -.029* -.011 .619*** 1.18*** 1.25*** 1.02*** .958*** .606*** .871*** .947*** .843*** .910*** .574*** .854*** .918*** .786*** .856*** .176*** .259*** .283*** .255*** .274*** .395*** .863*** .924*** .703*** .684*** -23,622 25,153 4,024 .455*** .678*** .748*** .647*** .711*** -12,220 33,779 13,634 3,227 .509*** .673*** .730*** .657*** .730*** -9,163 22,349 3,121 - .151*** .203*** .220*** .197*** .216*** 25,153 4,024 - -.199*** -.059 -.084* -.215*** -.368*** -23,261 24,919 3,998 -.130* -.021 -.050 -.002 -.166** -12,198 34,162 13,542 3,226 -.095 .003 -.020 -.012 -.162** -8,999 22,160 3,096 - -.037* -.005 -.010 .003 -.042** 24,919 3,998 - Notes: All specifications include control variables for household head and spouse as well as dummies for year of survey. Pooled cross-sectional orderered logit specifications in (1) and (5) include additionally age, age2, years of schooling, and dummies for province of residence. These specifications were also corrected for clustering of observations. ***/**/* indicate a parameter estimate is significant at the 1%/5%/10% level respectively. Data: KLIPS 1998-2008. Reference category for working hours: 0 hours per week (not working). Table 4: Hours and Job Satisfaction Regressions Wife Ordered logit Dep. Variable: Hours Satisfaction (1) Job type (1=wage; 0=non-wage) Own working hours Hours 31-40 Hours 41-50 Hours 51-60 Hours 60+ Partner's working hours Hours 0 Hours 31-40 Hours 41-50 Hours 51-60 Hours 60+ Log likelihood Observations Individuals Clusters .091 BUC FF FE-OLS (2) (3) (4) Ordered logit (5) .527*** .045 .034 -.201*** Husband BUC FF (6) (7) FE-OLS (8) .213*** -.360*** -.106*** .001 -.025 -.036 -.004 -.269*** -.246** -.233** -.076*** -1.11*** -.941*** -.982*** -.319*** -2.06*** -1.62*** -1.58*** -.579*** .826*** .491*** .579*** .199*** .644*** .346*** .418*** .155*** -.206*** -.238*** -.274*** -.086*** -1.13*** -.911*** -.949*** -.359*** -.077 .232** .189** .122 .033 -11,535 11,128 2,539 .168*** .124 .056 .080 -.041 -22,618 21,182 3,791 .075 .180 .156 .090 .058 -6,201 19,693 4,035 1,875 .005 .170 .225* .066 .049 -3,816 9,587 1,709 - -.002 .059 .063* .030 .032 11,128 2,539 - .101 .160* .036 .073 .002 -13,828 45,511 12,281 3,222 .068 .104 -.002 .067 -.011 -7,931 19,219 2,917 - .024 .050* .022 .038 .026 21,182 3,791 - Table 4 cont’d Dep. Variable: Job Satisfaction Job type (1=wage; 0=non-wage) Own working hours Hours 31-40 Hours 41-50 Hours 51-60 Hours 60+ Partner's working hours Hours 0 Hours 31-40 Hours 41-50 Hours 51-60 Hours 60+ Log likelihood Observations Individuals Clusters (9) (10) (11) (12) (13) (14) (15) (16) .101 -.111 -.092 -.008 -.037 -.068 -.215** -.049** .255*** .262*** .095 -.140 .086 .062 -.074 -.009 .212* .144 .035 .027 .054* .046* .024 -.008 .897*** .861*** .559*** .424*** .314*** .266*** .136 .149 .612*** .544*** .336*** .229** .163*** .161*** .111*** .084*** .195 .481*** .296*** .264** .191* -8,427 9,439 2,346 -.041 .236* .063 .118 .147 -6,137 22,616 2,853 1,824 .077 .378** .229 .221 .228 -2,797 7,256 1,377 - -.001 .080** .045 .036 .048 9,439 2,346 - .213*** -.063 -.053 -.068 -.089 -16,814 18,097 3,563 .152* .0001 0.00001 -.077 .056 -13,529 48,285 9,544 3,113 -.007 -.102 -.076 -.075 -.100 -5,983 14,980 2,415 - .021 -.013 -.010 -.006 -.002 18,097 3,563 - Hours and job satisfaction regressions include the following control variables: four dummies for number and composition of children, logs of household and regional percapita income (no regional income in job satisfaction regressions), 10 occupation dummies, 16 industry dummies, a dummy for wage employment as well as dummies for year of survey. Pooled cross-sectional orderered logit specifications in (1), (5), (9) and (13) include additionally age, age2, years of schooling, and dummies for province of residence. Pooled specifications were also corrected for clustering of observations. ***/**/* indicate a parameter estimate is significant at the 1%/5%/10% level respectively. Data: KLIPS 1998-2008. Reference category for own working hours: 1 to 30 hours per week. Robustness checks (1) Different reference groups in life satisfaction regressions (2) Earnings instead of household income (Interesting finding: Women value men’s earnings higher than their own) (3) Separate working hours dummies for wage vs. non-wage employed (wage-employed slightly happier) (4) Subjective health as additional control (only available from wave 6, problematic because endogenous) No changes in main results IV. Gender-specific time-use patterns 1 .9 .8 .7 .6 .5 .4 .3 .2 .1 0 0-.3 .3-.4 .4-.5 .5-.6 .6-.7 .7-.8 Men's share of market work Young men (age 20 to 39) .8-.9 .9-1 Older men (age 40 to 64) Table 5: Reported increased activities after reduction of working hours (in %) Women 1st choice Men 2nd choice 3rd choice 1st choice 2nd choice 3rd choice Income-earning activities 3.4 1.6 1.5 2.0 1.5 0.7 Household work 55.2 11.7 8.4 9.3 6.2 8.5 Self-development 7.8 9.8 9.4 16.7 11.1 12.3 Rest (sleep, etc.) 13.4 38.7 21.3 28.0 21.9 16.6 Watch TV 0.8 6.6 17.3 2.9 15.0 16.6 Travel/tour 11.9 12.5 17.3 15.4 15.4 17.1 Sports/excercise 3.4 10.2 10.4 20.5 17.3 11.6 0 0 0.5 0.9 2.5 3.7 Social/group activities 1.9 5.5 8.4 2.5 6.8 9.9 Civil/volunteer activities 0.4 1.6 2.0 0.4 0.9 1.8 Religious activities 1.1 1.2 3.5 0.6 0.9 0.7 Other 0.8 0.8 0 0.9 0.4 0.4 Total 100 100 100 100 100 100 N 268 256 202 689 675 543 Games Source: KLIPS, 2004-2008. Statistics are pooled over time. V. Concluding remarks – Reduction of working hours made Korean families happier – Still strong gender-specific effects of working hours on happiness due to strong traditional gender roles – Men derive much higher beyond-income utility from working than women – Controlling for family income, women are most happy when being housewives or working 31-40 hours; men when working 31-50 hours – Part-time jobs no alternative in Korea yet due to low quality nature – Results support gender-identity hypothesis – Results robust to different fixed-effects estimators and changes in model specification V. Concluding remarks – Policy Implications: • Further hours of work reductions • Equality of chances at the work place • Encouraging change in gender identities • Flexible job and child care solutions • Create part-time jobs in high-skilled sector Thank you for your attention. II. Data and Methodology Fixed-effects ordered logit estimation Ferrer-i-Carbonell and Frijters (FF-estimator): individual fixed effects ui and individual-specific thresholds λik are introduced into the model; this allows reformulation of the ordinal logit as a binomial logit Baetschmann, Staub and Winkelmann (2011) show that the FFestimator is slightly downward biased since cutoff points are chosen endogenously They suggest an own estimator: BUC-estimator BUC-estimator performs best in Monte-Carlo simulations II. Data and Methodology Fixed-effects ordered logit estimation We chose to apply BUC-estimator, FF-estimator, and linear FE Why FF still necessary? FF-estimator converges to the true value as N ↑, T ↑, and K ↓ as in the case of our sample Comparability of results with Booth and Van Ours, who use FF-estimator (2008, 2009) BUC performance needs further validations under different circumstances (e.g. extreme distributions, unbalanced panel) Why linear FE additionally? Linear FE shown to produce similar results in satisfaction regressions (Ferrer-iCarbonell and Frijters, 2004) Straightforward interpretation