The Differentiations in Loan Valuation with Retail and Corporate Exposure under Basel II By Jiun-Fei Chiu Associate Professor in Department of Finance, Yuan-Ze University 00-886-34638800 Ext 2666 fnjfchiu@saturn.yzu.edu.tw Chia-Tien Chang PhD student in Department of Business Management, Ji-Nan University 00-886-932834261 hcj.alex@msa.hinet.net Abstract The explicit differences in asset characteristics and risk management practices between retail and corporate exposures lead to differentiation in loan valuation. For corporate exposure, structured rating system assigning a specific rating to each borrower or loan is based on a combination of objective and subjective criteria. The judgment plays a significant role for banks that employ statistical rating models. While for retail exposure, portfolio of loans are divided into “segments” made up of exposures with similar risk characteristics assumed to exhibit homogeneous default characteristics. The loss performance will follow predictable patterns over the forecast periods. In this paper we focus on loan valuation in continuous time framework under the IRB approach. We extend the framework Merton (1974) combined with the theory of portfolio to characterize the dynamics of the value of loan portfolio for both retail and corporate exposures. By considering the specific differences in risk components inherent in between, both exposures exhibit quite different valuation of loan portfolio. The effects of asset return correlation and granularity in the loan portfolio on valuation are also examined. The main results are as follows: first, the differentiations in risk components will ultimately result in quite different risk profile in the whole 0 portfolio of loans; second, both the VaR and the value of loan portfolio move in tandem over time, which contrast to the single time period setting in literature; third, the value of bank’s loan portfolio depends on the instantaneous correlation coefficient between the instantaneous rate of return on the loans; fourth, the instantaneous idiosyncratic risk of the loan portfolio would wane if the number of loans in the portfolio increases, especially for retail exposures; fifth, when the average instantaneous coefficient of correlation decreases, the instantaneous systematic risk of the loan portfolio and the extent to which the value of the loan portfolio impacted by the business cycle would become less; sixth, when the level of concentration , granularity, increases over some critical level, the variance of the value of loan portfolio would increase with it. This would incur additional charged capital for the bank. Introduction As the new Basel capital accord (henceforth, Basel Ⅱ) has been finalized by the Basel Committee on Banking Supervision (henceforth, BCBS), along with it comes the new era for banks all over the world not only in the financial risk regulation but in the valuation of the portfolio of loans as well. The well-known three pillars in Basel Ⅱ including minimum capital requirements, supervisory review, and market discipline are proposed to increase substantially the risk sensitivity of the capital required. That is, the supreme purpose of the new financial risk regulation is to arrange capital adequacy assessment more closely with the key components of banking risk. To clarify the relationships between risk management and valuation of loans for banks, the impact of risk components, having been considered in capital charge, need to be further examined. Since in general the corporate loans constitute the major components of loan portfolio for commercial banks, it spontaneously incurs an important problem of how the loans to corporate obligors are valued over time in order to meet the requirements for risk management. One of the BCBS’s goals in setting forward an IRB approach is to align more accurately capital requirements with the intrinsic amount of credit risk to which a bank is exposed. The orientation of the IRB approach is to assess internally both their credit risk profile and their capital adequacy. There are three main elements to the IRB approach for corporate exposures: (1) Risk components: a bank must provide, using either its own estimates or standardized parameters; (2) Risk-weight function: which provides risk weights and hence capital requirements for given sets of these risk components; (3) A set of minimum requirements: a bank must meet in order to be eligible for IRB 1 treatment. Under the framework of internal ratings-based (IRB) approaches to credit risk constructed in Pillar I of Basel II, banks are allowed to compute the capital charges for each exposure based on the estimates of the four risk components, i.e. the probability of default (PD) of an obligor, the loss given default (LGD), exposure at default (EAD), and maturity (M) of the transaction. As the IRB approaches include two variants: the foundation approach and the advanced approach. In the former one, banks input their own assessment of the risk of default, i.e. PD, of the obligor, but estimates of additional risk factors, i.e. LGD, EAD and M are derived through the application of standardized supervisory rules. In the latter one, banks are allowed to use their own internal assessments of these components, subject to supervisory minimum requirements. In addition, banks may use their estimates of LGD, EAD, and/or the treatment of guarantees and credit derivatives subject to meeting additional minimum requirements specific to each risk component. Credit risk mitigation in the form of collateral, credit derivatives and guarantees and on-balance sheet netting, can materially impact upon a bank’s estimation of PD, LGD or EAD. In the advanced IRB approach, banks are permitted to use their own estimates for the effect of credit risk mitigation techniques on their estimates of PD, LGD and EAD. LGD is influenced by key transaction characteristics such as the presence of collateral and the degree of subordination. In most cases EAD will equal the nominal amount of the facility, but for certain facilities it will include an estimate of future lending prior to default. Thus a bank might be able to differentiate EAD and LGD values on the basis of a wider set of transaction characteristics (e.g. product type, wider range of collateral types) as well as borrower characteristics. The estimates of PD, LGD and in some cases M (M) associated with an exposure combine to map into a schedule of regulatory capital risk weights. The risk weights reflect the full spectrum of credit quality through use of a continuous function of risk weights. All banks take into account facility characteristics such as third-party guarantees, collateral, and seniority/subordination of the obligation in making lending decisions and in their credit risk mitigation processes. Moreover, facility characteristics are also explicitly considered in assessing the credit quality of an exposure and/or analyzing internal profitability or capital allocations. The intention to require banks to adopt IRB approach is to secure two key objectives: the first is additional risk sensitivity in that a capital requirement based on internal ratings can be more sensitive to the drivers of credit risk and economic loss in a bank’s portfolio; the second is incentive compatibility in that an appropriately structured IRB approach can encourage banks to continue to improve their internal risk management practices. 2 As the four risk components are inherent in the loans to corporate obligors, upon which the capital charges for banks depend, the estimates of these four risk components would inevitably exert impact upon the value of the loans. In this paper, we focus on corporate exposures and intend to value the corporate loans in continuous time framework under the IRB approach. A corporate exposure, in Basel II, is defined as a debt obligation of a corporation, partnership or proprietorship. In other words, a loan is an asset for a bank, meanwhile a debt for an obligor. Therefore, under certain circumstances the methodologies used to value a risky debt can be extended to price a loan. The valuation of risky debt is such an important issue that there have been plethoric studies in the financial literature. To value the corporate debt, we can trace back to Merton(1974), which initially utilizes the option pricing model to develop a structural model for valuing risky corporate debt. In his model, the value of a firm’s risky debt is contingent on the market value of its assets. By applying Black and Scholes’ (1973) option pricing formulae and define the market price of a risky zero-coupon bond, Merton derives the credit spread to price the corporate debt on which the issuer may default. Following the valuation model in Merton(1974), Black and Cox(1976) further analyze the impact of various types of provisions in corporate bond indenture upon the corporate debt value . Black and Cox(1976)indicate that some specific provisions do increase the value of corporate bonds. Other extensions from Merton(1974) include Brennen and Schwartz (1977, 1978, 1980), Geske (1977), Ingersoll (1976, 1977), Leland (1994), Leland and Toft (1996), Longstaff and Scvhwartz (1995), and Zou (1997), etc. Another stream of studying loan pricing is based on Gordy (2002) which releases a simple way to calculate economic capital charges with a portfolio model of credit value-at-risk. This stream stems from the concept of well-known traditional pricing theory, Capital Asset Pricing Model (CAPM). Gordy (2002) treats the marginal VaR contribution of an additional loan to a portfolio of loans as portfolio-invariant, and derives a single systematic risk-factor model. The marginal capital requirement for the portfolio depends on the properties it holds, but not the characteristics of the instruments. In order to reach portfolio-invariant, two conditions must be satisfied. First, the loan portfolio is well fine-grained, to diversify specific instrument risk. Second, there is only a single systematic risk factor. Gordy (2002) indicates that performance of the portfolio is affected by systematic risk factor, such as macroeconomic variables, and idiosyncratic risk factor to the individual instrument. By employing Gordy’s (2002) model, Dietsch and Petey(2002)devote to the risk modeling issues about small and medium-size enterprise (SME) loans portfolios. 3 Dietsch and Petey notice some features of retail loans portfolios. First, SME won’t be repaid like corporate loan, there is no market value for SME, and there is no transition process. So the existing models can’t be used to value retail loans. Second, the number of SME is much larger than that of corporate loan portfolios. It doesn’t behoove pricing retail loans with corporate models. It consumes too much time to simulate the parameters at the individual segments and levels. Finally, there are either rating agencies or financial market price for the models of corporate portfolios. By using Probit and Gamma distribution models to measure VaR in SME loan portfolios, Dietsch and Petey model the PD and use two types of information:(1)default score (2)the balance sheet amount of the firm bank debt to compute the risk of each small business and rank borrowers risk classes. Similar to Gordy (2002), the default rate is driven by a single systematic risk factor and the specific risk factor. The results show that capital requirements derived from an internal model are significantly lower than those derived by the standard capital ratio and the IRB approach as well. This demonstrates the interest of taking into account the correlation among the exposures in internal credit risk models explicitly even in the case of retail portfolios. Dietsch and Petey also verify that one of the main advantages of an internal credit risk model is to lead to a better allocation of capital and to better loan pricing. Linde and Roszbach (2004) employ data from two Swedish banks’ to display that SME and retail loan portfolios are not affected by systematic risk factors as much as corporate loan portfolios. Repullo and Suarez (2004) assess loans of portfolio with Gordy’s model under Basel capital requirement. It builds a model with a perfectly competitive market of business lending under the IRB approach. Repullo and Suarez show that low risk borrower will concentrate borrowing from banks that adopt the IRB approach and high-risk borrowers prefer borrowing from banks that adopt the standardized approach. The simulations show that IRB approach compare to Basel I may decrease the loan rates of 0.65% with a PD of 0.10%, and for loans with a PD of 10% rise about 1.25%. Repullo and Suarez also argue that to estimate the PD correctly is the most important in IRB approach. The supervisory should build an incentive system with penalties and rewords not only to avoid moral hazard in banking but to ensure the appropriate estimate and true report the risk of their loan portfolios. To value the corporate loans in continuous time framework under the IRB approach, we extend the pricing framework of Merton (1974) by embedding the characteristics of corporate exposures into the loan portfolio of a bank. That is, the four risk components PD, LGD, EAD, and M are taken as inputs for loan pricing in our model. As Bohn (2000) asserts that the structural model requires characterization of issuer’s asset value process, issuer’s capital structure, LGD, default-risk-free 4 interest rate, PD, correlation between the default-free interest rate and the asset price, and the terms and conditions of the debt issue. In this paper we assume LGD is a function of firm’s value, debt’s collateralization, and priority and is stochastic. In addition, we also utilize the framework of portfolio theory to model the dynamics of the value of loan portfolio. Notably, the effect of granularity to loan portfolio would be examined in this framework. Recall that both the transition probability matrics based on credit ratings in CreditMetrics and the one based on EDF in KMV approach reflect the fact that the value of portfolio of loans would fluctuate with the changes in credit quality of obligors over time. Hence, we consider the value of loan portfolio changes in continuous time framework, which would incur changes in the value of the capital charge through the linkage of the risk components between them. This apparently contrast to the single time period models posed in Dietsch and Petey (2002), Repullo and Suarez (2004), etc. As the purpose of the new financial risk regulation is to arrange capital adequacy assessment more closely with the banking risk in order to prevent the bank from being insolvent, we consider a bank as a levered firm with the probability of insolvency which would be supervised by regulatory agency. Further, we take the loans to corporate obligors into account to reflect the decision of risky investment made by the bank management. The main results in this study are as follows: first, the capital charge considered in terms of VaR in the risk management is liked to the dynamics of the value of loan portfolio; second, both the VaR and the value of loan portfolio move in tandem over time, which contrast to the single time period setting in literature. The results show that the credit spread of the loan increases with PD, LGD, M, and debt ratio of the obligors. The structure of this paper is as follows: section 2 is the valuation framework of the loans; section 3 demonstrates the dynamics of the value of loan portfolio; the effect of granularity is discussed in section 4, and section 5 concludes. The Valuation Framework Consider a time set [0, T] as a credit horizon for an economy , where T (0, ∞). A filtered probability space ( , F, F, P) is set with respect to this credit horizon, where F= {Ft : t [0, T]} satisfies increasing, right-continuous and augmented usual conditions and is the standard filtration of standard Brownian motion B. Let B= ( B1 , B2 ,..., Bd ) be the standard Brownian motion in R d and Ft a Martingale with 5 respect to the filtered probability space. Therefore, B represents the continuous resolution generated by the d sources of uncertainty over time that would determine the risks in the economy by influencing all external economic activities. Suppose that in this economy there exists one bank with its transaction counterparties including depositors and owners as its claimholders, and N corporate borrowers as its debt obligors. Further, suppose that each corporate obligor which may default during the credit horizon [0, T] with the probability of default, PDi , i= 1, 2, …,N, borrows from the bank one loan so that the asset portfolio of the bank is constituted by N loans of different credit qualities. For IRB purposes, the estimate of M will be based on a standard supervisory definition of effective M, which emphasizes the profile of a loan’s contractual principal payments over time. The credit quality of individual loan would be reflected in the credit spread charged by the bank. In specific, the bank finances its N risky projects of loan with two sources of funds: the first is a given amount of deposit which will be reimbursed to the depositors at the loan maturity date of time T; the second is the capital charged which is required by the banking supervisory agent and hence in turn depends on the value of the loan portfolio. By extending the assumptions in Merton (1974), we make the following ones: A.1 there are no transactions cost, taxes, or problems with indivisibilities of assets and restrictions of short sales. A.2 the assets are traded at the market price continuously in the credit horizon. A.3 the risk-free rate of return is r. A.4 prior to the maturity date, T, of the deposit and the N loans, any cash outflows incurred by cash dividends and share repurchase, or cash inflows incurred by issuing new securities are not allowed for both the bank and the N corporate obligors. A.5 without buying policies of deposit insurance, the bank has to handle its asset and liability management well enough to pay for two classes of claims. That is, the bank is required by the supervisory agent to reimburse D dollars to the depositors on the specified date T, and to charge adequate capital E to cover the loss in even the worst case faced by the bank during the credit horizon. A.6 all the N corporate obligors also have simple capital structure with two classes of claims: a single loan borrowed from the bank as its debt, and the equity. A.7 the value of the bank, V0t , and those of the corporate obligor i, Vi , i= 1, 2, …, N, through time follow Geometric Brownian motions with stochastic differential equations: d Vit / Vit = i dt+ i d Bit i= 0, 1, 2, …, N, and 6 t [0, T]. where i is the instantaneous expected rate of return on the Vi ; i is the instantaneous standard deviation of the rate of return on the Vi ; i and i are Borel measurable and satisfy the Lipschits and growth conditions; d Bi is a standard Brownian motion; d Bi d B j = ij dt, where ij is the instantaneous correlation coefficient between d Bi and d B j . For each loan i with the market value of Ait , the loan rate is Rit = r+ CSi , where CSi is the credit spread charged by the bank and is the function of the probability of default, PDit and the loss given default of loan i, LGDti , i= 1, 2, …,N, and t [0, T]. As usual, LGDti depends on obligor i’s value, debt’s collateralization, and priority and is stochastic. LGD reflects differences in lending standards, the type of collateral is taken, policies and procedures in pursuing recoveries from defaulted borrowers, and other areas. LGD can also be dependent on the economic cycle. The Banks see a range of borrower and transaction specific characteristics as having an impact on LGD. Borrower characteristics include asset size, country of incorporation, industry sector and whether the corporate is a holding or operating company. Transaction specific characteristics include the seniority of the transaction, the amount and nature of any collateral taken and loan covenants. In using estimates of LGD, the bank may takes any form of collateral and it can demonstrate that this serves to reduce its experience of loss, and then this should be recognized in the bank’s own internal estimates. For simplicity, all loans are lent to the N obligors at time 0 and would be reimbursed at time T to the bank without being collateralized or be guaranteed so that the exposure at default (EAD) to the obligor i is also Ait . The three risk components ( PDit , LGDti , Ait ) inherent in loan i combine to provide a measure of expected intrinsic, or economic loss, i= 1, 2, …,N. As for the deposit of bank, suppose that the deposit rate is R0 t = r+ CS0 , where CS0 is the credit spread to the depositors to reflect the insolvency risk of the bank, t [0, T]. Denote the deposit reimbursed at time T by D, so that at time 0 the market value of deposit is D e R0 0T . The bank would utilize D e R0 0T and VE 0 the initial value of equity at time zero to invest in N risky projects as loans to N obligors. That is, N A i 1 i0 =D e R0 0T + VE 0 (1) 7 N where Ai 0 is the initial value of loan i lent to the obligor i and A i 1 i0 is the initial value of loan portfolio at time zero. During the credit horizon [0, T], the value of the asset portfolio of the bank at any time t is equal to the sum of those of the N loans, i.e.: N V0t = Ait =D e R0 t (T t ) + VEt , t [0, T] (2) i 1 By applying the European call option pricing formula of Black and Scholes (1973), the value of equity of the bank at any time t, VEt , can be expressed as VEt = V0t ( x01 )-D e r ( x02 ), t [0, T] (3) where =T-t, t (0, T); x01 ={ ln[ V0t /D e R0 t (T t ) ]+( r+ 1 2 ) }/ 0 ; 2 0 1 2 ) }/ 0 ; 2 0 is the standard deviation of the instantaneous rate of return on the assets of x02 ={ ln[ V0t /D e R0 t (T t ) ]+( r- 0 the bank, d V0t / V0t ; V0t is the bank i’s asset; (.) is the cumulative Normal distribution function Note that the value of equity VEt is the target to be supervised. As the credit qualities of the corporate obligors may change over time which would be reflected in PDit , this will lead the value of loan portfolio of the bank V0t to change in response and then in turn would impact upon the equity value of the bank VEt . For the purpose of preventing the bank from being insolvent, the bank supervisor would require the bank to charge adequate capital to cover the potential loss incurred in even the worst case where most obligors default during the credit horizon [0, T]. In the perfectly supervisory reviewing situation that the value of equity VEt is regulated to the extent to which the capital charged is raised to an exactly adequate enough level, and the probability of insolvency of the bank goes down to zero: i.e., VEt >0 and VEt ↓ 0 , t [0, T] (4) However, it would be extremely difficult and may cost too much for the bank and the supervisor to meet such a strictly accurate requirement. Instead, a specified low level of the probability of insolvency of the bank is allowed in general. Consider that if V0t ≦ D e R0 t (T t ) , then VEt ≦ 0 which means that the bank will be insolent, and this 8 implies from the option pricing formula that V0t ( x01 )≦ D e r ( x02 ) (5) By assumption A.7, the value of the bank follows Geometric Brownian motions through time, V0t would be equal to V0t = V00 exp{ ( 0 1 0 2 )t 0 t Bt } (6) 2 with Bt ~N(0, 1), 0 and 0 being the mean and standard deviation of the instantaneous rate of return on the assets of the bank, d V0t / V0t , respectively. Substituting (6) into (5), we obtain V00 exp{ ( 0 1 0 2 ) 0 t Bt }exp{r(T-r)} / D≦ ( x02 )/ ( x01 ) 2 (7) Then the probability of insolvency of the bank can be expressed as ln Pr obins ( Bt ≦- ( x01 ) V 1 2 ln 00 r ( 0 0 )t ( x02 ) D 2 ) t ( x01 ) V 1 2 ln 00 r ( 0 0 )t ( x02 ) D 2 = ( - ) t since Bt ~N0, 1). ln (8) The probability of insolvency of the bank can be also considered as Pr obins ( V0t ≦D e R0 t (T t ) ) (9) where D e R0 t (T t ) is viewed as default point. Equation (9) implies that ln Pr ob ( Bt ≦ - = ( - ln V00 1 2 R0t ( 0 0 )t D 2 ) t V00 1 2 R0t ( 0 0 )t D 2 ) t (10) where =(T-t). If equations (8) and (10) are required to be equal, then ln ( x01 ) V 1 2 V 1 2 ln 00 r ( 0 0 )t ln 00 R0t ( 0 0 )t ( x02 ) D 2 2 = D t t which can be further simplified to 1 ( x01 ) 1 R0 -r= ln =- { ln ( x02 )- ln ( x01 )} ( x02 ) 9 (11) (12) Recall that the deposit rate is R0 t = r+ CS0 , then 1 CS0 =- { ln ( x02 )- ln ( x01 )} is the credit spread to the depositors. Under certain conditions, the credit spread in (12) would be equal to that in to the equation (14) in Merton (1974) as shown below: CSi = Ri ( )-r= - =- 1 ln{ ( x02 )+( V0t / A0 t ) (- x01 )} 1 { ln ( x02 )- ln ( x01 )} Then ( x02 ) + ( V0t / A0 t ) (- x01 )= ( x02 )/ ( x01 ) (13) (14) where A0 t =D e r is the market value of deposit at time t. Equation (14) can be reduced to V0t / A0 t = ( x02 )/ ( x01 )< 1 (15) It shows that when the deteriorating credit qualities of the obligors lead to the ratio of asset value of the bank over the deposit value decreases to a specified level ( x02 )/ ( x01 ) which is less than one, the bank will be insolvent even prior to the maturity time T. The dynamics of the value of loan portfolio The minimum capital required for an exposure will depend both on the risk of individual exposures and on the relationships between a bank’s exposures. The total minimum capital required for credit risk of the bank will be determined by the mean and variance of market value of the bank’s whole portfolio of loans. Since the market value of the bank’s loan portfolio would change with the credit qualities of all obligors in terms of transition in PD and EAD given the LGD and M in each loan unchanged, the dynamics of the value of loan portfolio would reveal the ongoing impact of the lending policies or asset allocation decisions made at time zero by the bank management. According to the equation (14) in Merton (1974), we know that the credit spread can be expressed as: CSi = Ri ( )-r=- 1 ln{ ( xi 2 )+( Vit / Ait ) (- xi1 )} where =T-t, t (0, T); xi1 ={ ln[ Vit / Ait ]+( r+ 1 2 ) }/ i ; 2 i 10 (13) 1 2 ) }/ i ; 2 i is the value of obligor i’s asset; xi 2 ={ ln[ Vit / Ait ]+( r- Vit Ait is the value of obligor i’s debt (.) is the cumulative Normal distribution function. By equation (13), it can be seen that the credit spread depends on the obligor’s firm value Vit , debt Ait , the volatility of the firm value i , time to maturity , and risk-free rate r. The yield-to-maturity Ri ( ) of loan i in the portfolio would change with the credit quality of obligor i which may transit over time during the credit horizon. Thus, at any time t the correlation between Ri ( ) and R j ( ) will depends on the credit quality of obligor I and credit quality of obligor j. Since the focus of this paper is to determine the relationship between loan pricing and the capital charged given the deposit D reimbursed at time T for the bank, we now proceed to examine the dynamics of the value of the loan portfolio. Recall from equation (1) that N A i 1 i0 =D e R0 0T + VE 0 where Ai 0 is the initial value of loan i at time zero which would mature at time T. The market value of loan i at any time t during the credit horizon would be Ait = Ai 0 e Rit t , t [0, T], where Rit ≡ Ri ( ) is defined in equation (13). Let AiT ≡ Ai 0 e RiT T be the payment of loan i reimbursed to the bank. By equation (13) in Merton (1974), the market value of loan i at any time t Ait can be expressed as Ait = AiT e r ( xi 2 )+ Vit (- xi1 ) (14) By the yield to maturity of loan i at time t, Ri ( ) in equation (13), and the market value of loan i at time t, Ait in equation (14), the rate of return RPt , and the variance of the loan portfolio Var ( RP ) at time t can be derived. As the value of loan i would change over time, the weight of loan i at time t in the loan portfolio is N Wit = Ait / Ait , t [0, T] (15) i 1 Note that the weight of loan i at time zero Wi 0 is determined by the bank through the allocation of fund from deposit and equity to loan i, while the weight of loan i at time 11 t (0, T] in the loan portfolio Wit would change over time as the results of changing market values of the all loans. From equations (13) and (15), the rate of return of the loan portfolio at time t is N RPt = Wit Rit , t [0, T] (16) i 1 where =T-t ,and RPt ≡ RP ( ). Rit is the yield to maturity on the loan i lent to the obligor i, i=1, 2, …, N. To grasp the characteristics of the loan portfolio in a continuous time framework, we need to examine the instantaneous rate of return of loan i, Rit . As in equation (1) in Merton (1974), the dynamics of the value of loan i’ can be expressed as d Ait / Ait = Ai dt+ Ai d B Ait i= 0, 1, 2, …, N, and t [0, T] (17). where Ai is the instantaneous expected rate of return on the Ait ; Ai is the instantaneous standard deviation of the rate of return on the Ait Ai and Ai are Borel measurable and satisfy the Lipschits and growth conditions; d B Ait is a standard Brownian motion. Assume that the asset value of obligor i, Vit and that of loan i, Ait are perfectly correlated, then d B Ait ≡d Bi , and d B Ait d B Ajt = ij dt, where ij is defined as the instantaneous correlation coefficient between d Bi and d B j in Assumption 7. By equation (17), Rit = Ai dt+ Ai d B Ait . Therefore the instantaneous correlation coefficient ij between d Bi and d B j would be equal to the one between d Ait / Ait and d A jt / A jt since Rit =d Ait / Ait = Ai dt+ Ai d B Ait is the instantaneous rate of return on the Ait , i= 0, 1, 2, …, N, and t [0, T]. Then Cov ( Rit , R jt )= Cov ( Ai dt+ Ai d B Ait , Aj dt+ Aj d B Ajt ) = E{[( Ai dt+ Ai d B Ait ) - E( Ai dt+ Ai d B Ait )][( Aj dt+ Aj d B Ajt ) - E( Aj dt+ Aj d B Ajt )]} = Ai Aj E{ d B Ait d B Ajt } = ij Ai Aj dt (18) 12 By equation (18), the instantaneous coefficient of correlation between Rit and R jt is ij =[ Cov ( Rit , R jt )/ ( Rit ) ( R jt )]/dt. (19) The instantaneous variance of the rate of return of the loan portfolio at time t is Var ( RPt )= 2 ( RPt ) N N i 1 i 1 j i = Wit2 2 ( Rit )+ WitW jt Cov ( Rit , R jt ), t [0, T] (20) where Cov ( Rit , R jt ) is the covariance between the yields to maturity, Rit and R jt , on the loan i and loan j per unit time. 2 ( Rit ) is the variance of the yield to maturity Rit on the loan i per unit time. Accordingly, on the right hand side of the second equality in equation (20) it can be seen that at any time t, the first term is the instantaneous idiosyncratic risk of the whole loan portfolio, and the second one represents the instantaneous systematic risk, t [ 0, T]. The instantaneous coefficient of correlation ij [-1, 1] would depend on the yield-to-maturity of loan i and loan j at time t, Rit and R jt , which in turn are influenced by the credit spreads of obligors i, and j. The lower is the ij , the smaller the 2 ( RPt ) is. In addition, although the weight of loan i at time t, Wit , would continuously fluctuate during the credit horizon, the instantaneous idiosyncratic risk of the loan portfolio would wane if the number of loans in the portfolio increases. Further, if the average instantaneous coefficient of correlation shifts down, other things being equal, the instantaneous systematic risk of the loan portfolio will decrease. This implies that the extent to which the value of the loan portfolio impacted by the business cycle would become less. In brief, if the number of loans N in the portfolio remains constant, the dynamics of the value of the loan portfolio would depend on the average instantaneous coefficient of correlation which is incurred by the changes in transition pattern in credit quality of obligors over time. 13 The Effect of Granularity The minimum capital required by the supervisor depends on the risk-weighted assets which result from multiplying the risk weights by the estimates of EAD, and then summing up the products amounts across the portfolio. The granularity adjustment is applied to the entire portfolio as a whole after the sum of all Baseline RWA for all portfolio exposures is computed. The granularity of a bank portfolio describes the extent to which there remain significant single borrower concentrations. The more thoroughly has the bank diversified away the idiosyncratic component of credit risk associated with individual positions, the lower is the loan portfolio’s economic capital requirement. In the limit of a perfectly-diversified loan portfolio, the idiosyncratic risk would wane down to zero. As there exists never a loan portfolio which is infinitely finely-granular, there is still a residual of undiversified idiosyncratic risk in the loan portfolio. Consider that the N loans in the asset portfolio are split into two heterogeneous components: one is a set consisting of n homogeneous loans with exposures of dollar amount ASit , i=1, 2, …, n, hereafter called portfolio S; the other called portfolio L is composed of m homogeneous loans with exposures of dollar amount ALjt , j=1, 2, …, m. The two portfolios are supposed to behave discrepantly in that n is much larger than m, but ASit is much less than ALjt . Thus, N=n+m, and the value of loan portfolio at time 0 is n m i 1 j 1 ASi0 + ALj 0 =D e R0 0T + VE 0 (21) During the credit horizon [0, T], the value of the loan portfolio of the bank at any time t becomes n m i 1 j 1 ASit + ALjt = V0t , t [0, T] (22) N Recall that V0t = Ait =D e R0 t (T t ) + VEt defined in equation (2). i 1 By equation (22), the loan portfolio is in effect a combination of two heterogeneous portfolios with weights WSt , and WLt , respectively: n m i 1 j 1 WSt = ASit / V0t and WLt = ALjt / V0t t [0, T] By equation (23), the rate of return of the loan portfolio at time t is 14 (23) RPt = WSt RSt + WLt RLt (24) n where RSt = WSit RSit is the rate of return of the portfolio S at time t; i 1 N RLt = WLjt RLjt is the rate of return of the portfolio L at time t. i 1 The mean and variance of the rate of return of the loan portfolio at time t are E( RPt )= WSt E( RSt )+ WLt E( RLt ) (25) 2 ( RPt )= WSt2 2 ( RSt )+ WLt2 2 ( RLt )+2 WSt WLt SL ( RSt ) ( RLt )dt = (1 WLt ) 2 2 ( RSt )+ WLt2 2 ( RLt )+2 (1 WLt ) WLt SL dt ( RSt ) ( RLt ) (26) since Cov ( RSt , RLt )= SL ( RSt ) ( RLt )dt and WSt + WLt =1. By equation (26), the weight on portfolio L, WLt , and the coefficient of correlation between loan portfolios S and L, SL will contribute to the volatility of value of the bank’s loan portfolio. Besides, since m < n and N=n+m, the portfolio L would be expected to be less well-diversified than portfolio S. That is, ( RLt ) is expected to be larger than ( RSt ). The effect of increasing WLt on 2 ( RPt ) is d 2 ( RPt ) =2{( WLt -1) 2 ( RSt )+ WLt 2 ( RLt )+(1-2 WLt ) SL dt ( RSt ) ( RLt )} dWLt (27) From equation (27), we obtain that if WLt > ( = )( < )[ 2 ( RSt ) - SL dt ( RSt ) ( RLt )]/[ 2 ( RSt ) + 2 ( RLt ) - 2 SL dt ( RSt ) ( RLt )] (28) d 2 ( RPt ) >(=)(<)0 dWLt For a specified level of SL , such as SL =1, 0, or -1, equation (28) can be reduced then further to a simpler form. For a given SL , let WLt* ≡ [ 2 ( RSt ) - SL dt ( RSt ) ( RLt )]/[ 2 ( RSt ) + 2 ( RLt ) - 2 SL dt ( RSt ) ( RLt )]. Apparently, when WLt is larger than (equal to)(less than) WLt* , the effect of increasing WLt on 2 ( RPt ) is positive(zero)(negative). WLt* is a critical point on which the risk of the whole loan portfolio will depend. If the concentration on 15 portfolio L is raised to a level higher than WLt* , the increased variance of 2 ( RPt ) would incur additional charged capital for the bank. Value at risk and the Capital Adequacy The term "Value at risk" is the expected loss from an adverse market movement with a specified probability over a particular period of time. In specific, the Value at Risk (VaR) for a bank to meet the requirements of capital adequacy is defined as: The worst loss expected from holding a loan portfolio over a given credit horizon, given a specified level of probability. For example, VaR = Expected Value of the loan portfolio– Worst Case Value at the 99% confidence level. That is, VaR is the maximum loss at the 99% confidence level, measured relative to the expected value of the loan portfolio and is the distance of the first percentile from the mean of the distribution. Expected Loss (EL) is the mean of the loss distribution, while Unexpected Loss (UL) is the chosen percentile cutoff of extreme losses. By Basel II, there is 0.1% likelihood that losses will exceed UL. The UL is the measure of VaR. According to the discussion in preceding sections, the value of bank’s loan portfolio depends on the instantaneous correlation coefficient ij between the instantaneous rate of return on the loans i, j, i= 0, 1, 2, …, N, and i≠j. The lower is the ij , the smaller the 2 ( RPt ) is. Besides, the instantaneous idiosyncratic risk of the loan portfolio would wane if the number of loans N in the portfolio increases. Further, when the average instantaneous coefficient of correlation decreases, the instantaneous systematic risk of the loan portfolio and the extent to which the value of the loan portfolio impacted by the business cycle would become less. As for the effect of granularity, the level of concentration is critical the value of loan portfolio. When it increases to a higher than some specific level, the variance of the value of loan portfolio would increase with it. Then, this would incur additional charged capital for the bank. The results show that given LGD and M, the impact of risk components PD, EAD on the yield to maturity of loan i will materially determine the risk of the individual loan and the instantaneous correlation coefficient between loans, which in 16 turn would influence the risk of the whole loan portfolio, and hence the capital charged. Conclusion In this paper, we focus on corporate exposures and intend to value the corporate loans in continuous time framework under the IRB approach. We extend the framework Merton (1974) combined with the theory of portfolio to characterize the dynamics of the value of loan portfolio of the bank and the effect of granularity. By taking the risk components inherent in the loan to obligors into account, the effects of asset return correlation and granularity are examined. The main results are as follows: first, the capital charge considered in terms of VaR in the risk management is linked to the dynamics of the value of loan portfolio; second, both the VaR and the value of loan portfolio move in tandem over time, which contrast to the single time period setting in literature; third, the value of bank’s loan portfolio depends on the instantaneous correlation coefficient between the instantaneous rate of return on the loans;fourth, the instantaneous idiosyncratic risk of the loan portfolio would wane if the number of loans N in the portfolio increases; Fifth, when the average instantaneous coefficient of correlation decreases, the instantaneous systematic risk of the loan portfolio and the extent to which the value of the loan portfolio impacted by the business cycle would become less; Sixth, granularity, when the level of concentration increases to a higher than some critical level, the variance of the value of loan portfolio would increase with it. This would incur additional charged capital for the bank; Seventh, the impact of risk components on the yield to maturity of loans will ultimately determine the risk of the whole loan portfolio, and hence the capital charged. Reference [1]Basel Committee on Banking Supervision ( 2001), The Internal Ratings-Based Approach Supporting Document to the New Basel Capital Accord Issued for comment by 31 May 2001 (Consultative Document) January 2001, Basel, Switzerland, available at www.bis.org/publ/bcbsca.htm.. [2] Black, F. and J. Cox, 1976, “Valuing Corporate Securities: Some E.ects of Bond Indenture Provisions,” The Journal of Finance 31, 351-367. [3] Black, F. and M. Scholes, 1973, “The Pricing of Options and Corporate Liabilities,” Journal of Political Economy 81, 637-654. [4] Carling, Kenneth, Tor Jacobson, Jesper Lindé and Kasper Roszbach (2002), Capital Charges under Basel II: Corporate Credit Risk Modelling and the 17 Macroeconomy, Working Paper Sveriges Riksbank No. 145. [5] Dietsch, Michel, and Joël Petey, (2002), The credit risk in SME loans portfolios: modeling issues, pricing and capital requirements, Journal of Banking and Finance, 26, pp. 303-322. [6] Dietsch, Michel, and Joël Petey, (2004), Should SME exposures be treated as retail or corporate exposures? A comparative analysis of default probabilities and asset correlations in French and German SMEs, Forthcoming in: Journal of Banking and Finance. [7 Estrella, Arturo, (2001), The cyclical behavior of optimal bank capital, forthcoming in: Journal of Banking and Finance. [8] Gordy Michael B., (2000), A comparative anatomy of credit risk models, Journal of Banking and Finance, 24, (1-2) , pp. 119-149. [9] Hamerle, Alfred, Thilo Liebig and Daneil Rösch, (2002), Credit risk factor modeling and the Basel II IRB approach, mimeo Deutsche Bundesbank. [10] Hsu, Jason C. and Jes’us Sa’a-Requejo Bond Pricing with Default Risk .This Draft: December 2002 [11] Jacobson, Tor and Jesper Lindé, (2000), ”Credit rating and the business cycle: can bankruptcies be forecast?”, Sveriges Riksbank Economic Review, 2000:4. [12] KMV Credit Monitor, Moody’s KMV, www.moodyskmv.com/products. [13] Merton, R.C., 1974, “On the Pricing of Corporate Debt: The Risk Structure of Interest Rates”, The Journal of Finance 29, 449-470. [14]Repullo, Rafael and Javier Suarez, Loan Pricing under Basel Capital Requirements, July 2004 [15]Tor Jacobson Jesper Lindé Kasper Roszbach. Credit risk versus capital requirements under Basel II: are SME loans and retail credit really different? Sveriges Riksbank Working Papers Series No. 162 April 2004 18