Macroeconomic Experiments Charles Noussair Tilburg University Barcelona, June 14, 2015 Outline of this lecture • This talk is divided into three segments: – (1) Institutions and Growth – (2) Asset Market Bubbles – (3) DSGE Economies • I will describe three lines of research. The idea is that they may stimulate research ideas on your part. The experimental approach to studying models Economic Model Structure of Economy (objectives, constraints, rules) Behavior of Agents Outcomes Theory Experiment A Assume structure Asssumption on Rationality, Expectations Equilibria, simulated Outcomes Compare Create structure Some features may not be feasible, some may not be sensible ? Data The experimenter specifies the structure of the economy, and observes behavior and outcomes. Main source Theoretical models specify structure and behavior, and study outcomes of hypotheses Piece “A” is sometimes easy (desirable), and sometimes not Part I: Growth and Institutions • • THE STRUCTURE OF THE MODEL A representative consumer in the economy has a lifetime utility given by: (1 ) t 0 • t U (C t ) ρ is the discount rate, Ct is the quantity of consumption at time t, and U(Ct) is the utility of consumption. The economy faces the resource constraint: Ct Kt 1 A F ( K t ) (1 ) Kt • δ is the depreciation rate, Kt is the economy’s aggregate capital stock at the beginning of period t, and A is an efficiency parameter on the production technology. The production function is concave. • • • THE ASSUMPTION ON BEHAVIOR: The agent maximizes lifetime utility • The optimal steady state given by the solution to: C* = F(K*) – δK* and K* = ρ + δ OUTCOME OF MODEL: the principal result of the model is that Ct and Kt converge asymptotically to optimal steady state levels. If individuals are given incentives to solve the dynamic optimization problem on their own, it is very difficult. Social Planners Figure 6: Time Series of Consumption: Social Planners High Endowment 25 Consumption 20 A1 A2 C1 C2 E1 E2 C* 15 10 5 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 21 22 23 24 25 26 27 28 29 30 31 32 33 34 Time Suppose a team of five people is making the decision instead. They do better but still have a lot of trouble Implement model as a Decentralized Economy. • There are five agents in the economy • The economy’s production capability and utility function is divided up among the five agents. • Agents are made asymmetric. • A market is available to exchange capital (using double auction rules, because a competitive model is being tested). • There is money, an experimental currency, in the economy, which agents use for purchases and sales of capital. Timing within a period t • At the beginning of period t, production occurs mapping kt into output (ct + kt+1) • A double auction market for output is open for two minutes in which they can exchange output. • Agents have one minute to allocate any portion of their output to consumption ct • At the beginning of period t+1, production occurs mapping kt+1 into output (ct+1 + kt+2). Timing within a period Timing of sessions (ending a session) • A horizon refers to the entire life of an economy. • Implementation of infinite horizon with discounting: In each period, there was a /(1+ ) probability that the horizon would end. • If a horizon ended with more than one hour to go in the experimental session, a new horizon was started. • If a horizon still had not ended at the scheduled end of the session, the horizon would be continued on another evening. • Subjects would have the option of continuing in their roles in the continued session. • If they chose not to continue, a substitute would be recruited to take her place. The original subject would also receive the money earned by the substitute. Results: Consumption patterns in the decentralized economy C*=12 18 K*=10 16 Ko =20 14 Consumption 12 C2 E2 F3 G4 C* 10 8 6 4 2 0 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 11 Time 12 13 14 15 16 17 18 19 20 An environment with multiple equilibria • Now suppose that there exist two stable equilibria, which are Pareto-ranked so that the inferior equilibrium represents a poverty trap. • The value of the productivity parameter A depends on the economy’s capital stock. There exists a threshold level of capital stock, above which A has a higher value. A, A A, if K if K ˆ K ˆ K Production function includes threshold externality Aggregate Production Function 220 200 180 O utput 160 140 120 100 80 60 40 20 0 0 25 50 75 U nits of Input 100 125 150 Theoretical Predictions for data in the following slides • • • • There is an optimal steady state in which (C*, K*) = (70,45) From any initial level of capital stock, optimal decisions (of a benelovent social planner) at each point in time imply monotonic convergence to (C*, K*). However, if the economy is decentralized, there are two stationary rational expectations competitive equilibria at (CH, KH, pH) = (70,45,118) and (CL, KL, pL) = (16,9,334) RESULT: The decentralized economy converges to the poverty trap. Results: Observed and Equilibrium Aggregate Consumption (Five Sessions) C* optimal = 70, C* poverty trap = 16 Emory B1 60 60 40 40 20 20 0 0 Dat a Horizontal axes: time Time Time C* opt im al Dat a C* inferior Emory B3 Consumption 60 40 20 0 C* opt im al C* inferior Breaks in series: New horizon beginning Caltech B1 80 80 Consumption Vertical axes: aggregate consumption Consumption Consumption Emory B2 80 80 60 40 20 0 Time Dat a Time C* opt imal Dat a C* inferior C* opt imal C* inferior Results: Caltech B2 Consumption 80 No economy surpasses the capital stock threshold. 60 40 20 0 Time Dat a C* opt im al C* inferior §= Each data point represents a period in a horizon. Horizons are separated by spaces Convergence to near poverty trap is typical outcome The Communication treatment – Identical to the baseline treatment, except that before the market opened, subjects were allowed to communicate with each other. – Each agent’s screen displayed a chat-room, which they could use to send and receive messages in real time. – Communication was unrestricted and all agents could observe all messages. Observed and Equilibrium Aggregate Consumption, Communication Treatment; C* optimal = 70, C* inferior = 16 Emory C1 80 Consumption Vertical axes: aggregate consumption 60 40 20 However, which equilibrium it converges to varies between sessions. 0 Horizontal axes: time Time Dat a Consumption C* opt im al C* inferior Emory C2 80 60 40 Example of how institutional structure affects mean and variance of income. 20 0 Time Dat a C* opt im al C* inferior Caltech C1 Consumption Consumption Emory C3 80 60 40 20 80 60 40 20 0 0 Time Dat a C* o p t im al Time Dat a C* in ferio r Caltech C2 Consumption 60 40 20 C* o p t im al C* in ferio r Caltech C3 80 80 Consumption Breaks in series: New horizon beginning Results: Individual sessions converge to near one of the equilibria. 60 40 20 0 0 Time Dat a C* o p t im al Time C* in ferio r Dat a C* o p t im al C* in ferio r The Voting treatment – – – – – Identical to the baseline treatment except that consumption and investment decisions were determined in the following manner: Two agents were randomly chosen in each period to make proposals on how much each agent in the economy should consume. Before submitting proposals, proposers received information indicating the current stock of capital held by each agent. Proposals were followed by majority voting. All agents were required to vote in favor of exactly one of the two proposals. The proposal that gained at least 3 (of the 5 total) votes became binding. Each agent consumed the quantity of output specified under the winning proposal, and began next period with the amount of capital allotted to her under the winning proposal. Observed and Equilibrium Aggregate Consumption, Voting Treatment C* optimal = 70, C* inferior = 16 Results: Emory V1 -In most sessions, economy escapes poverty trap 40 20 0 Time Dat a C* o p t im al - High variance from one period to the next within sessions. C* in ferio r Emory V2 Horizontal axis: time Consumption 80 60 40 - Convergence toward equilibrium typically does not occur 20 0 Time Dat a C* o p t im al C* in ferio r Emory V3 Caltech V1 Consumption 80 80 60 40 20 60 40 20 0 0 Time Dat a C* o p t imal Time C* in ferio r Caltech V2 80 Consumption Breaks in series: New horizon beginning 60 Consumption Vertical axis: aggregate consumption Consumption 80 60 40 20 0 Time Dat a C* o p t imal C* in ferio r Dat a C* o p t im al C* in ferio r The hybrid treatment: Both communication and voting are present Timing in the hybrid treatment Observed and Equilibrium Aggregate Consumption, Hybrid Treatment; C* optimal = 70, C* inferior = 16 Hybrid (Emory se ssion 1) Data C* optimal 90 90 80 Aggregate consumption Aggregate consumption 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 70 60 50 Horizontal axis: time 40 30 20 Breaks in series: New horizon beginning 10 10 0 0 Time Time Hybrid (Emory session 3) H ybrid (C alte ch session 1) D ata 90 C* op tim al C* infe rio r 90 Ag greg ate Con su mpt ion 80 Aggregate consumption Vertical axis: aggregate consumption Hybrid (Emory session 2) C* inferior 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 0 Time Time H ybrid (Calte ch se ssion 2) 90 Ag g reg at e Co ns ump tio n 80 70 60 50 40 30 20 10 0 Time Result; The addition of voting and communication allows the economy to escape poverty trap in all sessions. Results • Baseline: The economies of the baseline treatment converge to near the poverty trap. Does not escape poverty trap in any session. • Communciation: The economies of the communication treatment converges to close to one of the stationary equilibria. However, the one it converges toward varies between sessions. Probability of avoiding the poverty trap greater than under baseline. • Voting: The voting treatment exhibits variable behavior from one period to the next. Probability of avoiding the poverty trap greater than under baseline. • Hybrid: Also shows variable behavior from one period to the next. Escapes the poverty trap in all sessions. Part 2: Bubbles and Crashes • I will discuss work on experimental markets for long-lived assets. • In such markets, the bubble and crash pattern in pervasive. • I will first describe the effect of different market institutions and parameters on bubble formation • Then I will concentrate on differences between sessions but within treatments. The type of asset considered: the type first studied by (Smith, Suchanek Williams, 1988) • The asset has a life of 15 periods. At the end of each period, the asset pays a dividend which is equally likely to be 0, 8, 28 and 60 cents, determined independently for each draw. • After the last dividend is paid, the asset has no value. • Assuming traders are risk neutral, the fundamental value of this asset can be calculated at any point in time. It is equal to the expected total future flow of dividends. • Since the expected dividend in any dividend draw is equal to 24, the fundamental value is equal to the number of dividend draws remaining times 24. • Therefore, the fundamental value is 360 at the beginning of the life of the asset, and declines by 24 cents every period. The fundamental value of this asset over time What happens in such a market? b) Benchmark Rather than tracking the fundamental value, a bubble and crash pattern is typically observed. Effect of Increasing Cash: Raising prices Effect of allowing short selling: lowering prices Effect of adding a futures market, improving price discovery The effect of experience: pricing closer to fundamentals The role of the fundamental value time path: Increasing FV trajectory Decreasing fundamental value trajectory Decreasing treatment tracks fundamentals more closely than increasing Modeling trader types • Can we explain what is observed in the data with a model in which there are multiple trader types? • Consider the following model (based on DeLong, Shleifer, Summers, and Waldmann ,1990) • Assume three types of trader: (1) Fundamental value traders, (2) Rational Speculators, and (3) Momentum traders. – Fundamental value traders purchase if prices are below fundamentals and sell if they are above. – Rational speculators anticipate future price movements. They buy if the price is going to increase in the next period, and sell if it is going to decrease. – Momentum traders follow the current trend. They buy if the price has been going up and sell if it has been going down. Demand functions of the three types • The three types have net demand functions of the following form: – Fundamental value trader: -α(pt – ft), where pt is the price in period t, and ft is the fundamental value in period t. – Rational speculator: γ(E(pt+1) - pt), – Momentum trader: -δ + β(pt-1 – pt-2) • Six parameters: α, β, γ, δ, and the proportion of traders that is of each type. • This structure generates bubbles and crashes, is consistent with treatment differences, and the types correlate with other behaviors. • Now I will explore the relationship between trader characteristics and market behavior. Loss aversion measurement Cognitive reflection test (Frederick, 2005) • This consists of three questions, in which the first answer that comes to mind is incorrect, but the correct answer is simple after some reflection. • Example: If it takes 5 people 5 minutes to make 5 units, how much time does it take 100 people to make 100 units? – First answer that comes to mind is 100 minutes – With reflection realize the answer is 5 minutes • • Other two questions: A bat and a ball cost 1.10 Euro in total. The bat costs 1 Euro more than the ball. How much does the ball cost? In a lake, there is a patch of lily pads. Every day, the patch doubles in size. If it takes 48 days for the patch to cover the entire lake, how long would it take for the patch to cover half of the lake? • Risk aversion measurement (Holt and Laury, 2002) Correlation between price level and average risk aversion in the market: Bullmarket treatment Correlation between number of trades in the market and average loss aversion: Bearmarket treatment Average CRT score and departure from fundamental value Final Individual Holdings and Risk Aversion Level Number of trades at individual level and loss aversion Individual CRT score and earnings Determinants of bubble magnitude: measured with average dispersion (AD) and average bias (AB) Correlation between trader characteristics and strategies Emotional correlates of asset price movements • Positive emotions have typically been associated with higher prices – Irrational exuberance (Greenspan, 1996) – Speculative euphoria (Galbraith, 1984) • Empirical support – Weather affects returns (Hirshleifer and Shumway, 2003; Kamstra et al, 2003) – Outcomes of sporting events also affect prices (Edmans et al., 2007) – Twitter mood (Bollen et al., 2010) and anxiety level in blog postings (Gilbert and Karahalios, 2009) predict stock price movements. • Fear has been associated with low prices and volatility Emotions and markets in the laboratory • We consider whether these and other connections between emotions and market behavior appear in the laboratory • We construct an experimental asset market with a monotonically decreasing fundamental value. • All traders are videotaped throughout the session • The videotapes are analysed with Noldus Facereader at a later date. • The Facereader reads a facial expression and classifies it along seven dimensions. – These correspond to the basic universal emotions identified by Ekman (1978, 1999) Facereading software • We use facereading software to track traders’ emotional state while the market is operating. • These are – Happiness – Anger – Sadness – Disgust – Fear – Surprise – Neutrality • Facereader also reports the overall valence of emotion. • Unlike other neuroeconomic methodologies, Facereader translates physiological responses directly into of psychological models “Smiling” for a picture Absence of negative emotions …not so happy Neutrality, anger and disgust Neutrality with some anger Very happy Market Prices Initial valence and average prices We hypothesize that: (1) More positive valence is associated with higher prices. = .708, p < .01 Valence is typically negative: Experiments are not fun for subjects Initial fear and average prices We hypothesize that: (2) Fear is associated with lower prices = -.549 p < .06 People who are more neutral during crash period earn more money Crash period: The period with the largest price decrease Hypothesis 4: Neutrality during market turbulence is associated with greater earnings Correlations Between Loss Aversion Measure and Emotions Loss aversion Fear Valence Happiness Anger Surprise Disgust Sadness Neutral 0.3427*** -0.3012** -0.0459 -0.0680 -0.0851 0.2098 0.1096 -0.1989 (0.025) (0.759) (0.649) (0.569) (0.157) (0.463) (0.180) (0.018) Correlations between initial emotional state and likelihood of being a FV trader Initial Emotional State Fundamental Value Trader Neutral .202** Happy .012 Sad -.050 Angry Surprised -.195** -.091 Scared -.207** Disgusted -.182* Valence .097 More positive valence predicts more purchases Buy t Buy t Sell t Sell t Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 valence t-1 .237* .238* fear t-1 2.151 2.690 money t-1 7.29e-06 4.95e-06 money t-1 5.79e-06 6.25e-06 units t-1 -.021** -.015 units t-1 .050*** .046*** P level t-1 -.00007 -.00008 P level t-1 -.00012 -.00012 Buy t-1 .355*** Sell t-1 .362*** Prob>chi2 =0.000 Prob>chi2 =0.0586 Prob>chi2 =0.000 Prob> chi2 =0.0000 9770 obs 9770 obs 9971 obs 9971 obs 49 groups 49 groups 50 groups 50 groups Momentum traders buy more when they are in a more positive emotional state Buy t Fundamental Value Trader Momentum Trader Rational Speculator Trader Valence t-1 .280 .521** -.025 Money t-1 .00003 -.00004 -.00007** Units t-1 .015 -.119*** -.068*** Price level t-1 -.0004* .0007*** 3.15e-06 Buy t-1 .435*** .141* .370*** Obs: 3762 Obs: 3396 Obs: 2612 Groups: 19 Groups: 17 Groups: 13 Prob>F =.0000 Prob>F =.0000 Prob>F =.0000 More fear correlates with more sales Buy t Buy t Sell t Sell t Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 Model 4 valence t -.004 .003 fear t 4.995*** 4.861*** money t-1 9.00e-06 money t-1 3.42e-06 units t-1 -.020** units t-1 .048*** P level t-1 -.00011 P level t-1 .00012 Buy t-1 .355*** Sell t-1 .363*** 6.50e-06 -.015 -.00011 3.87e-06 .044*** -.00012 Prob>chi2=0.000 Prob>chi2 =.1950 Prob>chi2 =0.000 Prob>chi2 =0.000 9769 obs 9769 obs 9970 obs 9970 obs 49 groups 49 groups 50 groups 50 groups More neutral traders are less active submitting offers bids t asks t Bids&asks t neutrality t-1 -.247** -.031 -.126* money t-1 -.00008*** .00005*** 9.81e-06 units t-1 -.058*** .054*** .020*** price level t-1 -.0002 .0001* -.0001 bids t-1 .128*** asks t-1 .097*** Bids&askst-1 .103*** Obs: 9770 Obs: 9971 Obs: 9971 Groups: 49 Groups: 50 Groups: 50 Prob>F =.000 Prob>F =.000 Prob>F =.000 Better overall financial position improves traders’ emotional state Valence t Valence t money t-1 2.51e-06* 4.01e-06** units t-1 .0013* .0022*** P level t-1 -.000044*** -.000087*** valence t-1 .480*** const. -.028** -.046*** Obs: 9927 Obs: 9970 Groups: 50 Groups: 50 Prob>F =.000 Prob>F =.000 Profitable purchases lead to higher valence Valence t Valence t Valence t Model 1 Model 2 Model 3 const -.031*** -.016*** -.005* buy t-1 .001 .001 .002 sell t-1 .004 .003 .002 .483*** .472*** valence t-1 (FV-Price)*buy t-1 .00002** (Price-FV)*sell t-1 -.00001* Obs: 9970 Obs: 9927 Obs: 8990 Groups: 50 Groups: 50 Groups: 49 Prob>F =.6734 Prob>F =.000 Prob>F =.000 R2=0.0001 R2=0.355 R2=0.351 Excessive prices associated with negative valence At the market level, fear increases the probability of prices decreasing, while the rest of the emotions appear to help sustain bubbles Random Effects Fixed Effects Fear 354.45** 98.08 Neutral -6.35** -14.27*** Happiness -6.14** -15.19*** Anger -5.40* -14.30*** Disgust -6.17 -20.25*** Sad -2.96 -10.68** constant 6.46** Conclusions • Bubbles and crashes in experimental markets are a complex phenomenon, with many determinants of their magnitude. • Cash balances and quantity of shares available for sale influence price levels. • Some time paths of fundamentals are more conducive to mispricing than others. • The preference parameters of risk and loss aversion predict prices and quantity traded. • Cognitive ability/motivation predicts mispricing. • There are consistent emotional substrates to market bubbles and crashes. • Emotional state of traders responds to and can predict subsequent market activity. Part 3: An experimental DSGE economy • Construct an experimental macroeconomy, similar in structure to a New Keynesian DSGE macroeconomy. Close enough so that hypothesis from NK DSGE model can be evaluated. • Three types of (infinitely lived) agents – Consumers: supply labor, purchase (3) products, and save for the future – Producers: purchase labor, produce one of the (3) products, sell output – Central bank: sets interest rates • Preferences and productivity subject to shocks What we want to model Producer incentives • Maximize profit: Пit = pityit – wtLit yit = AtLit At = A0 + γAt-1 + δεt Where Пit = profit of firm i in period t pit = price of good i in period t yit = production of good i in t wt = wage in t Lit = labor bought by i in t At = productivity parameter in t εt = productivity shock in t γ = 0.8, δ = 0.2, A0 = 0.7 Consumer incentives • • • • • Payoff in period t of consumer j = βt[Ujt(Cjt) – Dj(Ljt)] Ujt(Cjt)=∑ihijt[cijt(1-σ)/(1- σ)] hijt = μij + τhijt-1 + δεjt D(Ljt) = d*Ljt1+η/ (1+η) Where Cjt= consumption at time t of consumer j Ljt = labor supplied at t Dj(Ljt) = disutility to j of labor he supplies at t cijt = consumption of good i by consumer j at t ε jt = preference shock for consumer j in period t β = .99, μij = 120, τ = 0.8, d = 15, η = 2, n = 3. Consumer incentives • Faces a budget constraint: wtLjt + 1/n∑iΠi,t-1 + (1 + rt)sj,t-1 = ∑ipitcijt + sjt • sjt can be thought of as savings or bonds • Create monopolistic competition with different preference shocks for each good. Experimental Design • Timing within a period • Stage 1: Labor market – There is a shock to productivity at the beginning of each period. – A double auction market operates for labor. – Cost of supplying labor and productivity is (privately) known at the time of trade. – Sales take place in terms of (fiat) experimental currency. Costs of labor supply are incurred in terms of utility (Euros). • Production occurs automatically – Each producer has available a quantity of his product to sell for stage 2 Labor market: Consumer Labor Market: Producer Stage 2 of a period: Product market • There is a shock to consumer preferences. • Sellers post prices • Buyers purchase units of each of the three products at their own pace – Product transactions take place in terms of (fiat) experimental currency – Valuations are in terms of utility (Euro paid to the subjects) – It is possible that some units will go unsold, or that stock will have been depleted at the time a consumer wants to buy. Product market: Producer Product Market: Consumer Savings, producer profit, discounting, and ending the experiment • Consumers’ unspent cash is saved for later periods, and earns interest. • Producers’ unspent cash (profit) is awarded to the consumers in equal shares. – However, the agents acting as producers received a payment in Euro equal proportionally to their profits. The payment was corrected for inflation. • The game goes at least 50 periods, randomly stopping between periods 50 - 70. • Utility (euro earnings) from consumption and labor supply exhibit a decreasing trend of 1% per period. • The final cash balance of consumers is “bought out” by the experimenter. • Interest rate set by an instrumental rule: rt = π* + 1.5(πt-1 - π*), π* = .03 where, πt = inflation in period t, π* = inflation target Timing of a session • • • • A session took 3 ¾ – 4 ¾ hours. Instructions read (~30 minutes) 5 period practice economy (~30 minutes) > 50 period economy that counted toward earnings. • Placed bounds on wages and prices for the first two periods. The treatments • (1) Baseline – The conditions described above • (2) Human Central Banker: In each period, three agents each chose an interest rate. The group’s decision (and thus the rate in effect) was the median of the three choices. The agents had an incentive to minimize the loss function Losst = (πt – π*)2 Central bankers were paid an amount equal to max{0, a – b*Loss} • (3) Menu Cost: – To change the price from one period to the next, producers had to pay a cost equal to: 0.025*pi,t-1*yit – Otherwise identical to Baseline • (4) Low Friction – Valuations are the same for each good (μij = μ0), though differ by individual and by time period (εjt > 0). – Otherwise identical to Baseline – Parameters set to equate welfare to Baseline under a simulation we conducted. Treatments Monopolistic Competition Human central banker Menu cost for product price change (= .025[pi,t-1*yit]) Baseline Y N N Menu cost Y N Y Human central banker Y Y N Low friction N N N Hypothesis • Persistence of shocks (effect beyond the current period): – Treatment differences – In treatments Baseline, Human Central Banker, and Low Friction no persistence, in treatment Menu Cost, shocks are persistent (both Menu Cost and market power are needed for persistence in New Keynesian DSGE model). • Empirical stylized fact is that a shock to interest rates, output, or inflation, has persistent effects on itself and on some of the other two variables. • Also can compare between treatments – GDP, inflation, welfare, employment, etc… Results: GDP GDP is highest under Low Friction GDP is lowest in the late periods under Human Central Banker Menu Costs do not affect GDP Results: Inflation -20 Inflation rate 0 20 40 Inflation - across treatments 0 10 20 30 40 50 ppp HCB menu_cost baseline low_friction Inflation rate is similar on average in all four treatments, including Human Central Bankers Volatility is lowest under Menu costs Volatility is highest under Human Central Banker A degree of heterogeneity exists within each treatment 600 400 0 200 Real GDP 800 1000 Real GDP - baseline treatment 0 10 20 30 40 ppp session2 session11 session3 session12 50 Impulse Responses: Baseline treatment Shock to GDP/Produc tivity Productivity shock persistent Inflation Shock Persistent Interest Rate Shock persistent Row 1-3: Effect on output, inflation, interest rates Shock to demand Inflation Shock to Interest Rate Price Puzzle Inflation shock has persistent effect on policy Impulse Responses: Baseline treatment Shock to GDP/Produc tivity Productivity shock persistent Inflation Shock Persistent Interest Rate Shock persistent Row 1-3: Effect on output, inflation, interest rates Shock to demand Inflation Shock to Interest Rate Price Puzzle Inflation shock has persistent effect on policy Impulse Responses: Menu Cost treatment Shock to GDP/Produc tivity Shock to demand Inflation Shock to Interest Rate Productivity shock persistent Price Puzzle Interest Rate Shock persistent Row 1 - 3: Effect on output, inflation, interest rates Impulse Responses: Low friction Shock to GDP/Produc tivity Productivity shock persistent Productivity shock lowers prices Row 1: Effect on output Row 2: Effect on inflation Row 3: Effect on interest rates Shock to demand Inflation Shock to Interest Rate Impulse Responses: Human Central Banker Shock to GDP/Produc tivity Productivity shock persistent Productivity shock lowers prices Interest Rate Shock persistent Row s1-3: Effect on output, inflation, interest rates Shock to demand Inflation Shock to Interest Rate GDP responds positively to interest rate shock. Income effect Price Puzzle Inflation shock has persistent effect on policy Evaluating the hypothesis • Very little persistence in the Low Friction treatment. • Somewhat more persistence in Menu Cost than in Baseline. • More persistence of policy (interest rate) shocks in Human Central Banker treatment • Mixed evidence with regard to hypothesis. Monopolistic competition alone generates shock persistence, and menu costs add to it. Persistence of shocks in each session, all treatments How do the human central bankers set interest rates? • Consider the following regression • rt = β0 + β1rt-1 + β2πt-1 + β3(GDP – GDP*) • System GMM Dynamic Panel Estimator (Blundell and Bond, 1998) • Taylor rule coefficient (relationship between interest rate and inflation) = β2/(1- β1) [Bullard and Mitra, 2007] Interest rate at t rt Estimate (std err) Constant .4212 (.2609) Interest rate at t1, rt-1 .9395 (.0146) Inflation at t-1, πt-1 .1538 (.0114) Output gap GDP-GDP* .0184 (.0074) • Implied coefficient is close to 2, consistent with the Taylor principle since it is greater than 1. Hazard Rate of Price Changes Average duration of price spells similar except for Menu Cost, in which it is longer. In Menu Cost, the hazard function is upward sloping. Price is more likely to change the longer it has been unchanged Conclusions • Methodology – It is feasible to construct a DSGE model in the laboratory. It is possible to verify stylized facts and consider the effect of some assumptions from a behavioral standpoint. • Persistence – Monopolistic competition, in conjunction with multiple agents and bounded rationality, is sufficient to generate some persistence – Menu costs add somewhat to this persistence. – Discretionary central banking affects shock persistence. – Negligible persistence in Low Friction. Biases in decision making of producers and consumers alone do not generate persistence.