On Level Ground? Gender, Trial Employment, and Initial Salaries in Organizations Adina D. Sterling Olin Business School Washington University in St. Louis sterling@wustl.edu Roberto M. Fernandez MIT Sloan School of Management robertof@mit.edu October 11, 2014 Do Not Cite or Circulate Without Permission The authors thank Ezra Zuckerman, Emilio Castilla, Damon Phillips, Anne Marie Knott, participants at the People and Organizations Conference at Wharton Business School and participants at the European Groups and Organizations Conference for feedback on previous versions of this paper. All errors are the responsibility of the authors. ABSTRACT Gender disparities in wages exist due to the shortfall in wages women sustain relative to men at the point of organizational entry. This paper develops a trial approach to test for the presence of demand-side contributions to initial wage inequality and proposes an organizational practice through which it is lessened – internships. We predict that internships reduce the gender gap in initial salaries because it provides organizations a first-hand look at candidates, differentially benefiting women. Using data on several hundred professionals that attended an elite private business school, we find that internships narrow that gap between men and women’s initial salaries. For men, there is no difference in salary offers from employers where an internship occurs versus one where an internship does not occur. However, women receive higher salaries from employers where an internship takes place versus where an internship does not. Within the limits of our research design we are able to pinpoint a mechanism through which salary disadvantages for women in traditional hiring scenarios are generated and the remediation of it in internships. We close by discussing implications of our findings for literature on inequality, organizations, and labor markets. 2 Introduction It is well-documented that within work organizations professional women do not earn what men earn (England, 1992; Tomaskovic-Devey, 1993; Bielby, 2000). While scholars have studied many reasons for wage inequality within organizations including supervisor evaluations (Castilla, 2011), promotions (Elliott and Smith, 2004; Hultin and Szulkin, 2003) and the demographic composition of organizations (Cohen and Huffman, 2007; Sorensen, 2007), most prior studies investigate internal labor markets and their contributions to wage inequality (Stolzenber, 1978; see Stainback, Tomaskovic-Devey, and Skaggs, 2010 for a review). Yet, professional women earn less than men because they receive lower initial salaries at the point-ofhire (Petersen and Saporta, 2004; Morgan, 1998). Women are sorted into jobs or employers that offer lower wages than men upon organizational entry (Petersen and Morgan, 1995; Reskin and Roos, 1990; Fernandez and Mors, 2008). Once initial salaries are in place women’s salaries fall behind men’s because initial salaries provide a baseline for future compensation (Barnett, Baron and Stuart, 2000; Elman and O’Rand, 2004; DiPrete and Eirich, 2006; FernandezMateo, 2009). One reason women might start out making less is that organizations evaluate men and women differently during the hiring process. Yet, documenting the differential evaluation of women and men during hiring is difficult. Organizations are less transparent about decisions affecting salaries at the point-of-hire than they are after organizational entry (Petersen and Saporta, 2004; Dencker, 2008). Additionally, explanations of men and women being differentially evaluated are hard to disentangle from alternative explanations for wage inequality regarding rationale assessments of candidates by employers. While models with detailed aspects of individuals – i.e. grades and educational credentials – indicate women make 3 less than men, generally scholars implicitly assume that unexplained variance in these models is due to quality differences in individuals unknown to researchers but observable to employers. This paper develops a novel approach to test for the presence of demand-side contributions to initial wage inequality and proposes an organizational practice through which this inequality is lessened. Conceptualize a setting where employers screen candidates as they do in a conventional hiring process but additionally, before employers make full-time salary offers, they are able to observe candidates as they work in organizations over a period of time. If implicit assumptions about unobserved quality hold there should be an improvement in wages after a trial period for all candidates that are offered jobs, but preexisting ratios in wages between groups of candidates should be unchanged (Becker, 1993; Jovanovic, 1979). However, if salaries increase for one group of candidates more than the other – e.g. for women more than men – this would be evidence that a conventional hiring process discounts this group’s salaries. In this paper we introduce this ‘trial test’ to evaluate the ways organizations assign salaries to entry-level professionals. Trial employment, or a tryout period, is a period whereby organizations observe individuals first-hand prior to making longer-term hiring and salary decisions (Kalleberg, 2000). This personnel practice differs from the more commonly studied practice of probationary employment (Lazear, 1999). During probationary employment an organization hires an employee for a period of time during which the organization may terminate the employee at-will. Probationary employment is an “opt-out” policy after individuals have been hired for a permanent job. In contrast, trial employment is an “opt-in” policy. We argue that trial employment lessens the discount in women’s initial wages. Trial employment provides a period of extended and heightened visibility to prospective employees. Because longer-term hiring and salary decisions occur after organizations receive a first-hand 4 look at candidates, this may lead to a lessening of the differential evaluation of men and women, reducing the gender gap in initial salaries. To test this prediction we use a setting well-suited for our inquiry: internships. Internships serve as a ‘twelve week job interview’ whereby candidates complete short-term assignments in organizations. They are common in ‘learned’ professions including business, law, and engineering. We collect data on several hundred new professionals that attend an elite, private business school. This setting is well-suited for our inquiry. By electing to investigate salary offers from new professionals at the same institution we are able to net out institutional and employer differences in the pool of applicants to jobs. Because nearly all of the new professionals attended the same graduate school and completed internships, supply-side factors that might otherwise make isolating employer-side mechanisms difficult are largely mitigated. Additionally, in our sample, new professionals apply and compete for the same jobs so structural characteristics of jobs themselves are tempered as the probable cause of wage disparity (Tomaskovic-Devey, 1993; Petersen and Morgan, 1995; Padavic and Reskin, 2002; Fernandez and Mors, 2008). We begin by modeling salary offers with a rich stock of detailed information about candidates for jobs, such as grades and test scores. Once these variables are in the models, we assess how full-time salary offers differ when individuals do and do not complete internships at an employer. This allows us, within the limits of our research design, to investigate how internships affect salaries, and to document a demand-side mechanism that contributes women’s disadvantage in salary offers in traditional hiring. 5 Organizations, Inequality, and Hiring Organizations influence inequality on the demand-side of the labor market by matching individuals to organizations and jobs that vary in wages (Granovetter, 1981; Sorensen and Sorenson, 2007). Research indicates that in professional occupations women are matched to organizations and jobs where they receive lower returns on their educational credentials than men (Hagan and Kay, 1995; Buchmann, Diprete, and McDaniel, 2008) and lower returns on their academic performance while in pursuit of a professional degree (Dixon and Seron, 1995; Huang, 1996). This shortfall in wages serves as a source of inequality in earnings over the long-term. Using detailed data from a single organization Gerhart (1990) finds that gender differences in salary are largely the result of a one-time salary shortfall for women at the point of hire. In a study of business professionals, Olson, Frieze, and Good (1987) find that men’s and women’s salaries differ but once initial salary differences are accounted for disparities in wages are largely non-existent. More recently, Weinberger (2011) finds similar results using data from the NSF and the National Survey of College Graduates: a gap in earnings persists in the range of 30% to 45% depending on job-type, driven in large part by the initial salaries men and women receive from organizations. Sociological approaches to wage inequality suggest disparities exist because men are allocated to jobs and organizations that pay more, and to higher pay structures within the same job (Bielby and Baron, 1986; Petersen and Morgan, 1995; England et al., 1994; Fernandez and Mors, 2008). Experimental evidence suggests one reason this may occur is that organizations differentially evaluate men and women. Organizational managers may rely on stereotypes when making hiring and salary decisions (Tosi and Einbender, 1985; Heilman, 1995; Reskin and Roos, 1990; Reskin and McBrier, 2000; Heilman et al., 2004). In the case of professionals, women do not fit the normative expectation of those that pursue professional careers (Ridgeway, 1997). As 6 a result, employers perceptions of women’s value may be lower than men’s, leading to a female wage discount (Heilman and Hayes, 2005). Despite laboratory evidence that employers engage in differential evaluation, documenting its occurrence at the organization-labor market interface is difficult. The main reason is that it is hard to unravel the outcomes of differential evaluation from efficiency claims. In neoclassic analysis rational employers hire to maximize efficient output and may discount women’s wages after a detailed assessment of that expected output (Becker, 1993). Specifically, employers may screen candidates on hard-to-observe factors and use these assessments in ways unknown to scholars (Heckman, and Siegelman, 1993). For this reason, an implicit assumption in most large scale studies is that differences in wages that exist between men and women is attributable to the unobserved heterogeneity of candidates (see Neumark, 2012 for a review). That is, wage inequality is due to differences in human capital, training, or motivation that are unobservable to researchers (Becker, 1975; Barron et al., 1985). Compounding the difficultly, approaches suitable for examining other phases of hiring are less tenable at the salary-setting stage. For example, audit studies find that gender affects the likelihood that individuals are interviewed or receive call-backs for jobs. At the salary-setting stage, however, audit studies are unpredictable: candidates must make it past several stages of the hiring process to secure salary offers, thus requiring candidates to interact face-to-face in interviews, complete tests, and make it successfully past other screens (Neumark, 1996; Bertrand and Mullainathan, 2004; Pager, 2007). Given variation on the applicant and employer side it is 7 hard to examine processes affecting salary-setting because it is the final stage of the hiring process. 1 We believe an alternative approach lends itself to significant gains in documenting initial wage inequality and understanding its sources. As prior literature on labor markets suggest, employers and researchers vary in the type of information each has available (Altonji and Pierret, 2001). 2 On the research side, rather than collect more detailed information on candidates, we can find hiring scenarios when some candidates are hired twice: once during a trial period and then again as a full-time employee. If there are different adjustments in salaries across men and women over the pre- and post-trial periods, this informs our understanding of differential evaluation in the pre-period – i.e. what would have occurred in the absence of the trial. A Trial Approach to Differential Evaluation Here we present a framework for our trial approach to assessing whether or not organizations differentially evaluate candidates on the basis of gender. Consistent with prior literature on differential treatment, we begin with a model that relates individual-level characteristics to a value assessment by employer – i.e. salaries. Suppose that candidates have two characteristics related to compensation, X1 and X2. Let’s assume the first characteristic, X1, is easily observed (i.e. GPA), while the second characteristic, X2, may or may not be 1 No audit studies to date have directly examined the effects of gender on starting salaries. Neumark, Bank, and Van Nort (1996) investigate the influence of gender on hiring decisions at restaurants that vary in quality. In a recent Australian study, Booth and Leigh (2010) study the effect of gender on call-backs. Riach and Rich (1987 and 2006) investigate the effects of gender on requests for interviews and follow-up phone calls. 2 Labor market studies, such as Altonji and Pierret (2001) note that this is a particularly difficult problem for researchers. In that study the authors used a fact unobservable to employers (AFQT scores) but observable to scholars to investigate discrimination. 8 observable to organizations but is definitely unobservable to researchers. The output of a candidate within an organization is given by V(X) where X=(X1, X2) Candidates belong to one of two groups G, equal to 1 for women and 0 for men. Salary, S, is a function of a candidate’s characteristics and gender: S(V(X),G) Let’s assume there is no difference in the actual performance of men and women once they are hired or that VM*=VW*. We can define a term gamma as follows: S(V*, 0) – S(V*,1) = γ Differential evaluation is detectable when gamma is not equal to 0. Existing approaches to testing may find that initial salary differences exist for men and women, but cannot “rule in” differential evaluation because of what is unobserved on the part of researchers. That is, differential treatment in salary-setting, or gamma, is only detectable by researchers if they are able to observe γ + E(XW) –E(XM) In other words, identifying differential evaluation relies on getting the expected values of both X1 and X2 correct. In our trial approach we avoid the problem of unobservability by examining salaries of the groups during the pre and post-period. That is, by observing the ratio of men’s and women’s salaries, differential treatment in salary-setting in the pre-period can be taken as differences in these ratios T2W/T2M – T1W/T1M 9 In sum, our trial approach framework permits us to model the outputs – i.e. salaries. As long as the differential evaluation is not persistent, as in the case of taste-based discrimination (Becker, 1957) or status-based characteristics (Correll and Bernard, 2006), we are able to identify the level of differential treatment under a typical pre-period scenario within a given context as long as 1) the pre-period hiring scenario conforms to the traditional hiring process and 2) there is a theoretical rationale underlying how differential evaluation in the interim (between the pre-post period) is attenuated. We suggest internships meet these requirements. Internships, Inequality and the Tryout Period Internships refer to a period of time organizations employ individuals to complete tasks prior to making long-term hiring decisions. It is a practice consistent with the externalization of the labor market, whereby organizations engage in more market-like transactions with individuals before fully internalizing some as employees (Baron, 2000; Davis-Blake and Uzzi, 1993). In the United States internships are an important way that employers and entry-level employees are matched (Baron and Kreps, 1999). Surveys of organizations indicate that recruiting full-time employees is the primary aim of employer internship programs. The National Association of Colleges and Employers (NACE) survey in 2009 indicated that nearly 68% of interns within organizations were offered fulltime positions, and that 84% of these offers were accepted. 3 Evidence suggests that because organizations use internships as an interim step to hiring full-time employees, organizations screen and select interns in largely the same way as they do in 3 Overall, more than one-third of the employers’ full-time, entry-level college hires came from their internship programs. 10 traditional hiring processes. Interns must make it past several stages of the hiring process, including initial and later-stage interviews. Additionally, the qualifications for interns are similar to qualifications for full-time employees, including grades, references, and extra-curricular activities (ERC report). 4 That is, the selection for internships is similar to selection for full-time employees. Having discussed how internship selection is similar to the traditional hiring process we now lay out a theoretical rationale for why internships may lessen wage inequality post the trial period. Literature on organizations and labor markets suggests organizations select individuals and assign salaries based on two types of candidate characteristics: hard and soft skills. Organizations weigh hard skills, or those based on technical ability to complete task when assigning salaries. They also weigh soft skills or those involving “personality, attitude, and behavior rather than to formal or technical knowledge” (Moss and Tilly, 2001: 44). Hard skills involve what tasks get completed, while soft skills involve how work gets done. For example, writing computer software involves hard skills like coding, but also soft skills involving behaviors – e.g. fact-finding, interactions with leadership, political savvy – that determine the fate of the commercial computer software (i.e. whether or not it is sold in the market). Research suggests that when hiring new professionals organizations may view soft skills as at least as important as hard skills (Bills, 2003; Rivera, 2011). Since professionals enter jobs with a greater span of control than others, they require skills such as leadership, team-building, and strategic thinking to gain buy-in for their ideas and move projects forward within 4 For example, the ERC reported that in a survey of 122 organizations, college major, professionalism, communication skills, work ethic, career goals, and coursework are heavily relied upon by employers when selecting interns. These largely coincided with the selection criteria organizations reported when hiring recent college grads (http://www.yourerc.com/_CE/pagecontent/Documents/survey/research-studies/13-ERC-NOCHEIntern-Pay-Rates-and-Practices-Survey.pdf). 11 organizations (Briscoe and Kellogg, 2011; Kalev, 2009; Pfeffer, 1997; Podolny and Baron, 1997). This may be particularly problematic for female professionals, since soft skills are more apt to be linked to stereotypes of behavior (Ridgeway, 1999). An evaluation of soft skills by organizations is inherently subjective, as hiring managers extrapolate behavior based on limited data gained during the hiring process (Moss and Tilly, 2001; Cappelli, 1999). Because professional occupations are associated with masculine characteristics, organizations may doubt that female professionals have the soft skills needed to perform (Castilla, 2008; Reskin and McBrier, 2000). Men and women may both benefit from internships, as it provides the chance to develop skills within a specific organization (Becker, 1993). However, we expect that internships benefit women more than men. Internships provide the chance for individuals to have a period of extended visibility with decision-makers prior to the salary-setting stage (Beenen and Rousseau, 2010). This visibility may allow women to disconfirm stereotypes of behavior and an opportunity for organizations to update their evaluations (Leahey, 2007; Kalev, 2009; Briscoe and Kellogg, 2011). In traditional hiring contexts, women are segregated to lower-levels of organizations, removing the opportunity for them to interact with decision-makers (England, 1992; Pierce, 1995; Petersen and Morgan, 1995; Cohen and Huffman, 2007). Internships offer a chance for individuals to interact with managers and peers in the organization in highly visible ways –i.e. assignments, presentations, networking events, and on project teams. In this way, prospective employees’ skills become better known. It is possible, of course, that differential evaluations of men and women may persist during internships. However, compared to a traditional hiring scenario, internships offer organizations a much better chance to counter differential evaluations based on more detailed 12 information (Altonji and Blank, 1999; Rissing and Castilla, 2014). Further, because of the visibility an internship affords, managers may be held more accountable to pay individuals according to their demonstrated level of skill within organizations (Lerner and Tetlock, 1999; Padavic and Reskin, 2002). Because internships make hiring and salary assessments that are typically external to organizations more transparent, this may reduce differential evaluation. Our rationale leads to a set of testable hypotheses. Overall, we expect that women are offered lower initial full-time starting salaries than men. We expect however, that the full-time salary offers from organizations where individuals did internships versus where they did not are greater for women than for men. DATA AND SETTING We investigate the salaries of entry-level business professionals from an elite private institution that graduated with their Masters of Business Administration (MBA) degree approximately one year after completing internships. There are several aspects this setting that help inform our understanding of inequality in entry-level professional careers. The MBA degree is a popular degree for women in U.S. business schools. In 1970 women made up only 4% of those earning MBA (Masters of Business Administration) degrees, a number that increased tenfold by 2006, to 43% (Bertrand, Goldin, and Katz, 2010). Moreover, business management represents an important segment of professionals. More women enter business than any other profession, including law, medicine, architecture, engineering, and natural science combined (Jacobs, 1992). 5 5 Bureau of Labor Statistics, Household Data 2013, Table 11, “Employed persons by detailed occupation, race, and Hispanic or Latino ethnicity”, http://www.bls.gov/cps/cpsaat11.pdf. 13 Internships are an important route through which individuals are matched to organizations in the early stages of their careers. Approximately three-quarters of organizations hiring MBA graduates indicate they consider job candidates that completed internships for fulltime jobs before opening up their recruiting to those without internship experience at the firm. 6 Our interviews with managers indicate that internships in this setting are used as a tryout in the organization (Baron and Kreps, 1999). Managers indicate there are benefits to hiring candidates through internships versus other methods of hiring. In a statement representative of the sentiments of managers, one HR manager put it this way, I see the internship as a long term interview within the department. The interns are at an advantage against the candidate who might look equally good on paper, because they have had that experience with the company. They’ve gotten some internal experience and they’re not as much, they’re not a risk, as much of a risk, as somebody you only interview and assume that they’ll do well based on the interview. And that sounds negative calling them a risk, but you know, you haven’t had experience with them. Sample Our sample is comprised of business professionals that completed internships in 2008 and 2009 and graduated from the same institution. In the spring of their graduating year the MBA Career Development Office (CDO) sent an email to all of the individuals in a cohort inviting them to participate in a survey. There were 394 individuals in the class of 2009 and 389 individuals in the class of 2010. Among these 783 individuals, 708 responded to the survey, a response rate of 90%. We checked for response bias to determine if respondents differ from the larger MBA population at the institution regarding gender and GMAT scores. There is no difference. 6 The Graduate Management Admission Council® surveyed 690 employers of MBAs, and three-quarters of the organizations reported using interns to fill positions prior to opening up an employee search to the broader labor market. http://sacramento.bizjournals.com/sacramento/stories/2003/03/17/daily11.html 14 In our setting new professionals apply and compete for the same jobs. This is important because jobs can yield different wages and act as a source of inequality (Tomaskovic-Devey, 1993; Petersen and Morgan, 1995; Padavic and Reskin, 2002; Fernandez and Mors, 2008). Nearly all (97%) of those eligible to complete an internship prior to the second year of their MBA program do so. Given that almost all individuals opt to do internships this reduces concerns about self-selection. 7 We assess the ways in which men and women select internships. For one of the cohort years – i.e. 2010 – we were able to gather in-depth information about the internship selection process using data from a survey conducted by the CDO. We found that in this setting men and women select internship offers from employers for largely the same reasons (see Figure 1 below). This is important because if women in our setting select internship offers in different ways than men then an improvement in women’s full-time salaries from an employer where an internship occurred might reflect a “better match” from the internship search. Overall, no evidence suggests this is the case. We find that the job function, industry, and job content are the primary factors for internship selection for both men and women. Where there are differences across groups they largely point toward women facing more constraint in their internship selection than men. For example, 4% of men but 8% of women indicated that location was a primary reason for selecting an offer from an internship employer. [INSERT FIGURE 1 HERE] 7 This internship completion rate is similarly in line with the internship completion rates of MBA students in the top 50 MBA programs (i.e. based on Business Week rankings). 15 Variables The dependent variable is the maximum initial salary offer that business professionals received. The maximum initial salary offer received is used as the dependent variable rather than the total compensation, because the initial salary provides the baseline for future salary growth (Gerhart, 1990; Petersen and Saporta, 2004). 8 On the survey respondents had space to list up to four offers. This was enough space for nearly all respondents to list their full slate of offers (i.e. less than five reported having more than four offers). The median number of offers respondents received is 1, the average number is 1.69. The average difference in the maximum and minimum salary offers is $9,627 for the entire sample, and $20,707 for those with two or more offers. We focus on the maximum salary offer received because it indicates the best offer available from the job search. Our first explanatory variable, gender, is noted as female. Our second explanatory variable is the source of the salary offer. In the survey individuals were asked about the primary source of a job offer for each of the offers received. They were given a set of sixteen options from which to choose. We collapsed this list of sixteen options into four main categories: internships, formal job sources, informal job sources, and other. The internship category refers to offers received from an employer after an internship is complete. The formal job search category includes offers from formal job search methods, including on-campus recruiting by employers, online applications, and newspaper applications. The informal job search category includes offers that originated from information or leads from social contacts such as family, friends, faculty and alumni. Our fourth and omitted category, other, is coded as 8 Additionally, total compensation is a less direct indicator of the expected value an employer perceives of an employee. Total compensation is more related to an individual’s specific needs (e.g. their location relative to the employer, education, and partner status). 16 such when the respondent chose this option on the survey (i.e. the method of job finding was outside of the sixteen listed categories). We observe the source of offers for individuals in the study. We might be concerned that if source rates differ across groups this reflects different criteria for assessing candidates. For example, if full-time offers from an internship employer are lower for women, this might indicate that employers are using more stringent criteria for selection. 9 The proportion of offers from each source for all maximum offers received is shown in Table 1. We find that in our setting the proportion of offers from internships for men and women is 30% for both groups (i.e. 30.4% and 29.7% for men and women, respectively). There is also very little difference in the proportion of offers coming from other sources. To assess this more fully we conduct an analysis of variance to examine if there are differences in the sources of offers for each gender. We find there is no statistically significant difference in the source through which men and women receive offers (F-stat < 0.3). [INSERT TABLE 1 HERE] Control Variables To isolate the hypothesized relationships several other factors that might affect salaries are controlled. Notably, by studying the job-finding outcomes of professionals from the same institution we are able to implicitly account for factors that affect salaries but differ across educational institutions such as the institution’s reputation and the availability of career 9 Because we are comparing the relative effect of internships on salary offers across men and women, one concern might be that women who have full-time offers from their internship employers are comparably better than men who have full-time offers from their internship employer. In addition to the steps we took above, we ran a logit model where we regressed a dichotomous offer variable onto the control variables and gender to predict the likelihood of getting a full-time job offer from an employer, conditional on having an internship. Gender did not have an effect on getting a full-time offer from an employer after an internship is complete. 17 services. Additionally, we control for several other factors that may affect salary offers using detailed information collected from the survey. We control for the relative quality of applicants using their GPA and GMAT scores. Since all respondents attended the same MBA program these measures usefully provide an indication of professionals’ relative quality versus their peers (Chatman, 1991; Bills, 1990; Rivera, 2011). We account for respondents’ pre-MBA salary using a previous salary control variable. Additionally, the years of prior work experience is included in the models. On the survey respondents were asked to report their years of prior work experience before pursuing an MBA. We include experience intervals for the number of years of prior experience (1-3 years, 3-5 years, more than 5 years). The one-year-or-less interval is omitted from the models. Some respondents took part in a sponsorship program while getting their MBA. Because these individuals have experiences that might be valued by employers we include a sponsorship dummy variable in the models. Further, prior work suggests that salary differences might be due to supply-side factors. For instance, there is some indication that women in business are less likely to pursue more quantitative fields such as finance, which pay professionals more (Correll, 2001; Barbulescu and Bidwell, 2013). To account for this we include functional dummy variables for finance, consulting, and general management (other is the omitted category). Finally, we include demographic variables for age (measured in years), and race — i.e. Caucasian, African-American, Hispanic-American, Asian-American (other is the omitted category). Analysis Our baseline analysis is OLS regression. Because respondents might appear more than once – i.e. have a maximum offer from two or more sources – non-independence is a problem, 18 so we cluster standard errors by respondents. We begin by regressing maximum salary offer on the female dichotomous variable, and then gradually add the controls. Consistent with our theorizing, this allows us to assess if there is a direct effect of being female on salary offers, and to ascertain if there is possible discounting of women in our sample even after accounting for factors that might explain salary. Next, to test the relative importance of the source of offers for men and women we add the job source variables into our models. We interact the internship source variable with the female dichotomous variable to evaluate the relative impact of internships on salary offers. After conducting these baseline analyses we run a selection model (Heckman, 1976), to account for the fact that some respondents sought out job offers but did not receive them. In the first stage we regress whether or not a respondent received a job offer using the model covariates and a selection variable. The selection variable predicts the likelihood of the first stage dependent variable – i.e. getting an offer – but not salary. Our selection variable is whether or not a respondent originated outside of the U.S. This affects the likelihood of getting a job offer because firms are legally required to cover the visa expenses for non-domestic workers. 10 We examined differences in job offers for all the respondents for whom this data was available in our study (N=434 domestic, 209 international). These differences are shown in Table 2. Non-domestic individuals were significantly less likely to have job offers (t=4.78, p < 0.01), but there was no significant difference in salary offers conditional on an offer being received (t=-.21, not significant). [INSERT TABLE 2 HERE] 10 http://www.uscis.gov/ 19 RESULTS Out of 708 respondents to the survey, 566 individuals indicated they sought employment after graduation, and 497 received offers. Out of these, 147 respondents did not report salaries or they had other missing data. Our final sample for the main analysis is 350 respondents. Table 3 provides the means, standard deviations, and correlations for the variables for the main sample. The average maximum offer was $110,929 and respondents made $74,995 prior to entering the MBA program. Respondents had a 711 total GMAT score, on average, and a 4.61 GPA (on a five-point scale). Approximately 40% of the respondents had more than 5 years of work experience prior to entering the MBA program, and averaged 27.7 years of age. In the sample 46%, 2%, 4%, and 19% of the respondents are white, black, Hispanic, and AsianAmerican, respectively. [INSERT TABLE 3 HERE] Table 4 provides descriptive statistics on the maximum salary offer for men and women in the main sample. Men and women have an average maximum salary offer of $113,147 and $106,023, respectively. The $7,124 difference is statistically significant (p < 0.05). [INSERT TABLE 4 HERE] Descriptive statistics may not fully depict the relationship between gender and salary offers, particularly if gender masks underlying differences between the groups. To understand the effects of gender net of other factors that might affect salaries we conduct multivariate regression analysis. In Model 1 we regress the maximum salary offer on the female dummy variable using OLS regression with clustered standard errors. Consistent with our baseline 20 prediction we find a negative and statistically significant effect of being female on salary (p < 0.01). To see if the gender effect is due to quality differences between men and women, we include the GPA and GMAT variables in Model 2. GPA has a positive and statistically significant effect on salary. The GMAT score is not significant. 11 Notably, with inclusion of these variables the negative and statistically significant effect of being female on salaries remains. [INSERT TABLE 5 HERE] In Model 3 we add variables for prior salary and years of experience. None of the intervals for years of experience significantly impact salaries, though previous salary has a positive and statistically significant effect (p < 0.01). Model 4 adds additional variables for supply-side factors that may affect salaries, including the field in which a respondent is employed and whether or not the individual is sponsored while getting an MBA. Model 4 indicates individuals that chose to enter consulting fields had higher salaries than those who did not, while the other fields – i.e. finance and general management – did not have a significant effect on salaries. Model 5 includes the full model with all the covariates. In this model the negative and statistically significant effect of being female on salaries remains (p < 0.01). The marginal effect of being female on salaries is $6,390, or women receive a maximum salary that is 5.8% lower, net of all other factors affecting salaries, than men. Next, we investigate the relative influence of different job offer sources in Table 6. In Models 6-8 we add each job source into the models. The only source that affects salaries is informal job sources, which has a negative and statistically significant effect on salaries. The 11 One reason for a lack of an effect for GMAT score may be that the distribution is highly skewed to the right: 71% of the respondents had a GMAT score of 700 or higher, or scored in the 89th percentile or above. Given that almost all respondents scored well on the GMAT, these scores may have been less influential on salary offers. 21 negative and statistically significant effect of informal sources on salary is also seen in Model 9, which includes all of the source variables. While somewhat surprising, this is consistent with other research that suggests individuals may turn to their networks only after exhausting other sources to locate jobs. In Model 10 we interact the female dummy variable with the internship source. The female-internship interaction is positive and statistically significant (p < 0.05). Because the female dummy dichotomous variable is included in the model, the coefficient on the interaction variable indicates that the marginal effect of a woman getting an offer from her internship employer versus the offer coming from another source. The marginal effect of salaries on women getting an offer from an internship employer versus any other source is $9,857. [INSERT TABLE 6 HERE] As mentioned previously, we additionally run Heckman selection models to account for the fact that salary offers cannot be observed for all those looking for jobs. We run a first stage model where we regress having a job offer on the covariates and the international selection variable. Table 7 shows the results. In Model 11 we show the full model with control variables. The female dichotomous variable remains negative and statistically significant (p < 0.01). In Model 12 we run the two-stage Heckman with the source variables. Similar to the baseline models, only the informal job source has a significant effect on maximum salary. In Model 13 we show the interaction effect. Consistent with our expectations, the interaction effect is positive and marginally significant (p= 0.07). 22 [INSERT TABLE 7 HERE] The baseline analysis and Heckman selection models provide support for our predictions. Women receive lower offers from employers than their male counterparts. However, this discount seems to lessen when offers are generated from employers where an internship has occurred. There is a positive and statistically significant interaction effect between gender and internship source. This is consistent with the idea that internships provide a period of extended visibility within organizations, leading to a lessening of a differential evaluation for women after an internship is complete. Salaries before and after internships Thus far our analysis has provided evidence that women receive higher full-time salary offers from organizations where an internship has occurred versus organizations where an internship has not occurred. While our setting and the nature of our data allow us to eliminate many explanations for our effects, ideally we could observe what would have occurred in the absence of internships for the same individuals. To do this we collect data on the salaries of professionals in our study at following stages 1) prior to entering the MBA program 2) during the internship and 3) full-time employment. The first two stages serve as a ‘pre-treatment stage’, before organizations are able to observe behavior during a trial period. The third stage allows us to examine the effect of salaries on men and women post-trial. We start by investigating salaries across these stages for all those reporting salary information (i.e. the sample is no longer restricted to those whom have a full set of controls available), or for 181 women and 418 men. Women and men made $68,685 and $75,560 23 annually prior to getting an MBA respectively, a difference that is statistically significant (p < 0.01). There are 152 women and 297 men in our data that had internships and reported their salaries (on a monthly basis). These annualize to $76,272 and $83,676 for women and men, respectively, which again is a statistically significant difference (p < 0.01). Turning to the posttreatment stage the maximum salary for men and women is $112,075 and $106,258, respectively. These are slightly different from the salaries reported in Table 4 because this is the average maximum salary for all 317 men and 147 women that reported salary information. The difference in the maximum offers for this sample is statistically significant (p < 0.01). Notably, though, there is a narrowing of the difference in salaries. In the two pre-treatment stages, women made approximately 91% of the salary that men made. In the post-treatment stage this ratio improved to 95%. Now we turn to how the offers differed depending on the job source. A total of 136 men and 60 women received offers from their internship employer and reported their salaries. Among these 196 individuals, men received an initial salary offer of $108,196 and women received a salary offer of $108,600. That is, women did slightly better than men (the few hundred dollar difference is not statistically significant). Overall, we see a leveling effect on salaries generated from internships (see Figure 3 below). [INSERT FIGURE 3 HERE] Further, we investigate the effects of trial employment based on pre and post-treatment outcomes for a subset of individuals that appear across the stages. This allows us to see the comparative effect of internships by gender for the very same set of individuals, or what would 24 have occurred absent the trial. Out of the136 men and 60 women with offers from intern employers, 130 men and 55 women reported salaries prior to the MBA. The distribution of these individuals’ prior MBA salaries and the distribution of their salaries after internships are shown in Figure 4. An absolute improvement in salaries across the pre and post-treatment conditions are likely attributable to the MBA; by assessing the relative conditions we net out these effects. Figure 4 indicates that prior to the internship and MBA men’s salaries are higher than women’s across almost the entire distribution. For example, the 50th percentile and 80th percentile salary for men prior to the MBA is $74,500 and $100,000, respectively. These same percentiles are $70,000 and $80,000 for women (ratios of 0.94 and 0.80, respectively). The offers received from employer where at internship occurred at the same percentile for the exact same set of individuals is $110,000 and $125,000 for men, and $108,000 and $125,000 for women (0.98 and 1.0, respectively). Interestingly, there are no salary differences or women’s salaries are higher than men’s from internship employers except in the 37th -50th and 55th -69th percentile range. [INSERT FIGURE 4 HERE] Alternative explanations We have argued that internships provide individuals a period of extended visibility in organizations prior to hiring and salary-setting decisions, and that this has a differential impact of the salaries of women versus men. Evidence in the cross-section and across stages strongly supports this claim. Nonetheless, we explore two alternative explanations for our findings: omitted heterogeneity in organizations and negotiations by candidates. It is possible that organizations using internships are more equitable than organizations that do not. That is, perhaps organizations know that internships provide some advantages to 25 women. In our interviews with 20 line and HR managers not a single interviewee stated any specific recruiting aims associated with their organizations’ internship programs (diversity or otherwise). Nonetheless, if having an internship programs is linked to some aspect of organizations related to equity, then the effect of internships on the improvement of women’s salaries may be spurious. It would not be that internships counteract differential evaluation and lead to salary improvement: if these organizations have more equitable pay policies this would naturally boost women’s salaries. To consider this possibility we code a dummy variable, equal to 1 if an organization has an internship program, else 0. Information about organizations’ internship programs were coded based on data we had from the CDO, company websites, and related websites such as vault.com. We include this dummy variable to proxy for unobserved heterogeneity across organizations that may lead to a spurious increase in women’s wages. 12 Including this variable in our models did not change the results. This suggests, inclusive of accounting for the ways organizations differ, the relative importance of internships as a source of salary offers for women remain. Additionally, we consider an alternative explanation that women are better at negotiating salary increases at places where they have completed internships versus places where they have not. It is possible that men are good negotiators across job sources, but women are only good at negotiating offers within organizations where internships occurred. To assess this, we examine data that we collected as a part of the survey. For every offer respondents accepted we asked, “Did you negotiate or try to negotiate about ANYTHING with your employer?” We coded each of these 549 responses across all offers received to determine which respondents successfully negotiated an increase in base salary. Overall, 10% of women and 16% of men negotiated 12 We know the identity of the organizations only for those offers that respondents accepted. 26 successfully with an employer on some facet of their offer (salary, relocation, tuition, vacation time). Figure 5 summarizes the negotiation outcomes of men and women. Of those that negotiated a base salary increase, they were much more likely to do so outside of places where internships occurred, rather than with an internship employer. Successful negotiations in base salary increases occurred between individuals and firms outside of the internship employer 71% of the time for men, and 85% of the time for women. More specifically, there were only two women (out of 140) that indicated they successfully negotiated a salary increase with their internship employer. In sum, women in this study did not earn higher salaries from their internship employer due to salary negotiations. [INSERT FIGURE 5 HERE] A within firm analysis In a final set of regression analyses we examine how internships influence salary offers that come from the same organization. We suggested above that internships could operate by improving the wages for women relative for men, but this could occur because women earn more working for the same organizations as men, or because they work for a different set of organizations. To assess this, we run additional analyses with employer fixed effects and show these results in Table 8. Here, the dependent variable is the salary received for the accepted job offer, not max offer (employer information is only available for the accepted offer). The sample size is smaller than in the previous models because only one offer was accepted per person, and not every respondent specified the name of their employer. Model 14 shows that inclusion of 27 firm-fixed effects leads the gender main effect to disappear. That is, there is some element of sorting of individuals across firms that leads to a gender effect in the baseline models. Once individuals are compared within the same firm men and women do not receive significantly different offers. Yet, we can also see why men’s and women’s salaries do not differ significantly. In Model 15 we include the interaction between the female dichotomous variable and internships and find the positive interaction effect remains. This indicates that within organizations individuals are hired through different methods, and the reason women do not receive significantly different salaries from men is there is a leveling effect through internships. To see this graphically, in Figure 6 we show the three the largest employers in our context that had varied methods of hiring. In these three firms we observe the salaries that men and women received from different sources. In support of our predictions, in each of these firms women with prior internship experience in the organization received higher offers than women that were hired outside of internships. [INSERT FIGURE 6 HERE] To gain further insight into the leveling effect we interviewed HR managers and line managers about internships. As stated previously, none of the managers interviewed for this study indicated that they use internships with the intention of assessing the quality of women specifically. Managers did convey, however, that internships are used to assess individuals on characteristics that tend to be linked to masculine characteristics. For example, when asked what her company looks for during internships, one HR executive replied: 28 “I don’t think we look for anything different than any other company. We need strategic thinkers. It doesn’t matter what your role is. . .HR or manufacturing. We have a strategic way of doing business. . We are financially driven, but we tend to be more strategic thinkers. For me first and foremost I look for people that can be strategic. I look for people that can run with the best of them so to speak. You cannot be intimidated by authority. You can’t be. . . you have to run with the best of them is the way I say it, and not everybody can do that.” The general sentiment expressed by this HR executive, that individuals in this setting are expected to “run with the best of them”, underscores the specific nature of these professional jobs, and that these jobs include a set of expected behaviors around competition, authority, and leadership. The internship yields the chance for all individuals to demonstrate these characteristics. 13 Where is inequality being generated? Our analyses suggest that a narrowing of salaries after internships. For women and men that complete internships and receive offers from their employers, there is no statistically significant difference in the salaries that they receive. But, women’s initial salary offers are still only 95% of what men are offered. To understand why, we further investigate the salary offers that professionals receive when they do not receive offers from their internship employer. Men that did not receive an offer from their internship employer (either because they did not have an internship or did not receive an offer) had an average maximum offer of $109,899. This amounted to a $1,703 increase in salary versus the full-time offer from an internship employer. Meanwhile, women that did not receive an offer from their internship employer (either because they did not have an internship or did not receive an offer) had an average maximum offer of $102,165, or made significantly less than men that did not have offers from internship employers. Among those who did not do internships are sponsored students that may have 13 In addition to interviews with managers, we conducted interviews with MBA interns. They stated they had ample opportunity to interact with employees during internships, including at networking events, alumni meetings, and their end-of-summer presentations. 29 received full-time offers from their employers. Excluding those with sponsors, the average maximum salaries are even lower for women, $99,438, while they are $109,913 for nonsponsored men. We assess the salary offers of those individuals that did complete internships but did not receive offers. For those individuals that did complete internships and did not receive offers from their internship employer, men received maximum offers of $109,904 while women received maximum offers of $96,730. When men and women receive offers from organizations where they have had internships, the gap in salaries is virtually non-existent. However, it seems that while failed internships do not have any penalties for men they carry penalties for women. Discussion and Conclusion While there have been a great number of studies documenting that women start out earning less than men within organizations, the demand-side contributions to initial inequality in wages are not yet clear. At the organization-labor market interface it is hard to disentangle explanations of differential evaluation and treatment of men and women from more rational explanations for wage disparity. In this paper we contribute to literature on inequality, organizations and labor markets by presenting a new framework to addresses this issue. In our trial approach we can avoid the problem that organizations may always know more about candidates than researchers, by investigating the outcomes of individuals when organizations ‘hire twice’. The contributions of this approach are not limited to a specific mechanism per se but can be extended to address issues that persist in a diverse set of literatures on hiring such as statistical discrimination (Altonji and Pierret, 2001) and human capital (Tomaskovic-Skaggs, 2002; Fernandez-Mateo, 2009). 30 Further, we contribute to literature on inequality, organizations, and labor markets by investigating a practice through which inequality is lessened. Using detailed data on several hundred professionals we document that internships have a leveling effect. Further, we were able, within the limits of our research design to suggest a demand-side mechanism leading to this reduction. Internships are useful because they provide professionals extended visibility as they complete tasks within organizations. These internships showcase, in particular, soft-skills that may lead to women’s salaries being lower in traditional hiring processes. This is an important finding not only because of its theoretical contributions, but also because of the prevalence with which internships are used to hire professionals. In our setting internships are nearly as common as other methods of job finding, such as formal hiring, and they are more than twice as common as more well-studied methods such as referrals. The referrals literature has largely outlined disadvantages to the referrals practice for women and minorities (Fernandez and Fernandez-Mateo 2006; Reskin and Padavic, 1994; Korenman and Turner, 1996; Moore, 1990; Reskin, McBrier, and Kmec, 1999; Rubineau and Fernandez 2013), because networks that provide information about prospective candidates may not be equally available to all groups. Here, in contrast we find a lessening of salary disadvantages for women due to internships. Our findings are consistent research on social contact (e.g. Allport, 1950) and research that has found workplaces that promote contact in teams may provide benefits to disadvantaged groups because it allows them to come into contact with powerful others (Kalev, 2009). In the case of internships, individuals from traditionally disadvantages groups benefit because this provides a chance for individuals to visibly demonstrate skills and receive resources (Burt, 1992; Baron and Pfeffer, 1994; Podolny and Baron, 1997; Sparrowe and Liden, 2005; Castilla, 2011; Briscoe and Kellogg, 2011). 31 While this study makes a substantial contribution, future work should proceed on several fronts. Our chosen context limits the generalizability of our findings. However, similar methods of matching individuals to employers exist in other professions, including engineering and law. It would be useful to investigate what, if any, effect internships have on wage inequality in these professions. In addition, it would be useful to understand more directly how organizations behave when hiring through internships. Using available data we were able to rule out unobserved heterogeneity in organizations as an explanation for our leveling effect. This does not preclude, however, that within organizations managers use hiring practices for different objectives. Future work should examine the ways in which practices may be used by managers. In closing, much is known about new employment relationships, and how the externalization of the employment relationship affects individuals and organizations (Bidwell, Briscoe, Fernandez-Mateo, and Sterling, 2013). Trial employment represents a fairly new way that firms temporarily externalize employment. As scholars of organizations, labor markets, and inequality it is necessary to understand the outcomes of this externalization on individuals and organizations and its unintended consequences (Baron, 2000). Here, we find that unintended consequences need not always lead to inequality, suggesting we must continue to investigate the complex set of interactions between individuals, organizations, and markets. 32 REFERENCES Allport, G. W. 1954. The Nature of Prejudice. Reading, Mass.: Addison-Wesley. Altonji, J. G., & Blank, R. M. 1999. Race and gender in the labor market. Handbook of labor economics, 3: 3143-3259. Altonji, J. G., & Pierret, C. R. 2001. Employer learning and statistical discrimination. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 116(1): 313-350. Barbulescu, R., & Bidwell, M. 2013. Do women choose different jobs from men? Mechanisms of application segregation in the market for managerial workers. Organization Science, 24(3): 737-756. Barnett, W. P., Baron, J. N., & Stuart, T. E. 2000. Avenues of Attainment: Occupational Demography and Organizational Careers in the California Civil Service. American Journal of Sociology 106 88–144. Baron, J. N. 1984. Organizational perspectives on stratification. Annual Review of Sociology, 10: 37-69. Baron, J. N., & Kreps, D. M. 1999. Strategic human resources: Frameworks for general managers. New York: John Wiley & Sons. Baron, J. N., and J. Pfeffer. 1994. The social psychology of organizations and inequality. Social Psychology Quarterly 57(3):190-209. Baron, J. N. 2000. Comment to Cappelli, P.: Market-Mediated Employment; The Historical Context. Pp. 90–101 in The New Relationship: Human Capital in the American Corporation, edited by Margaret M. Blair and Thomas A. Kochan. Washington, D.C.: Brookings Institution Press. Barron, J.M., J. Bishop, and W. C. Dunkelberg. 1985. Employer search: The interviewing and hiring of new employees. Review of Economics & Statistics 67(1):43. Becker, G. 1975. Human Capital. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Becker, G. 1993. Nobel lecture: The economic way of looking at behavior. Journal of political economy: 385-409. Beenen, G., & Rousseau, D. M. 2010. Getting the most from MBA internships: Promoting intern learning and job acceptance. Human Resource Management, 1: 3-22. Bertrand, M. & Mullainathan, S. 2004. Are Emily and Greg more employable than Lakisha and Jamal? A field experiment on labor market discrimination. The American Economic Review, 94(4), pp. 991-1013 33 Bertrand, M., C. Goldin, & Katz, L. F. 2010. Dynamics of the gender gap for young professionals in the financial and corporate sectors. American Economic Journal: Applied Economics (2010): 228-255. Bidwell, M., Briscoe, F., Fernandez-Mateo, I., & Sterling, A. 2013. The employment relationship and inequality: How and why changes in employment practices are reshaping rewards in organizations. The Academy of Management Annals, 7(1): 61-121. Bielby, W. T. 2000. Minimizing workplace gender and racial bias. Contemporary Sociology: 120-129. Bielby, W. T., & Baron, J. N. 1986. Men and women at work: Sex segregation and statistical discrimination. American Journal of Sociology: 759-799. Bills D. 2003. Credentials, Signals, and Screens: Explaining the Relationship between Schooling and Job Assignment. Review of Educational Research. Booth, A. & Leigh, A. 2010. Do Employers Discriminate by Gender? A Field Experiment in Female-Dominated Occupations. Economics Letters 107 (2): 236–38. Briscoe, F. & Kellogg, K. 2011. The Initial Assignment Effect: Local Employer Practices and Positive Career Outcomes for Work-Family Program Users. American Sociological Review 76(2):291-319. Buchmann, C., DiPrete, T. A., & McDaniel, A. 2008. Gender inequalities in education. Annual Review of Sociology, 34: 319-337. Burt, R. S. 1992. Structural holes: The social structure of competition. Cambrige, MA: Harvard University Press. Cappelli, P. 1999. The new deal at work: managing the market-driven workforce. Boston: Harvard Business School Press. Castilla, E. J. 2008. Gender, Race, and Meritocracy in Organizational Careers. American Journal of Sociology, 113(6): 1479-1526. Castilla, E. J. 2011. Bringing Managers Back In: Managerial Influences on Workplace Inequality. American Sociological Review, 76(5): 667-694. Chatman, J. A. 1991. Matching People and Organizations: Selection and Socialization in Public Accounting Firms. Administrative Science Quarterly, 36(3): 459-484. Cohen, P.N., and M. L. Huffman. 2007. Working for the woman? Female managers and the gender wage gap. American Sociological Review 72.5: 681-704 34 Correll, S. J. 2001. Gender and the Career Choice Process: The Role of Biased Self‐ Assessments. American Journal of Sociology, 106(6): 1691-1730. Correll, S. J., & Benard, S. 2006. Biased estimators? Comparing status and statistical theories of gender discrimination. Advances in group processes, 23: 89-116. Davis-Blake, A., & Uzzi, B. 1993. Determinants of Employment Externalization: A Study of Temporary Workers and Independent Contractors. Administrative Science Quarterly 38(2):195-223. Dencker, J. C. 2008. Corporate restructuring and sex differences in managerial promotion. American Sociological Review, 73(3): 455-476. Diprete, T. A., & Eirich, G. M. 2006. Cumulative advantage as a mechanism for inequality: A review of theoretical and empirical developments. Annual Review of Sociology, 32: 271297. Dixon, J., & Seron, C. 1995. Stratification in the legal profession: Sex, sector, and salary. Law & Society Review, 29: 381-412. Elliott, J. R. and R. A. Smith. 2004. Race, Gender, and Workplace Power. American Sociological Review 69(3): 365-386. Elman, C., & O’Rand, M. 2004. The Race Is to the Swift: Socioeconomic Origins, Adult Education, and Wage Attainment1. American Journal of Sociology, 110(1): 123-160. England, P. 1992. Comparable worth: Theories and evidence. New York: Aldine De Gruyter. England, P., Herbert, M. S., Kilbourne, B. S., Reid, L. L., & Megdal, L. M. 1994. The gendered valuation of occupations and skills: Earnings in 1980 census occupations. Social Forces, 73(1): 65-100. Fernandez-Mateo, I. 2009. Cumulative Gender Disadvantage in Contract Employment. American Journal of Sociology, 114(4): 871-923. Fernandez, R. M., & Fernandez-Mateo, I. 2006. Networks, Race, and Hiring. American Sociological Review, 71: 42-71. Fernandez, R. M., & Greenberg, J. 2013. Race, Network Hiring, and Statistical Discrimination. Research in the Sociology of Work, 24: 81-102. Fernandez, R. M., & Mors, M. L. 2008. Competing for jobs: Labor queues and gender sorting in the hiring process. Social Science Research, 37(4): 1061-1080. Gerhart, B. 1990. Gender differences in current and starting salaries: The role of performance, college major, and job title. Industrial and Labor relations review: 418-433. 35 Granovetter, M. S. 1981. Toward a sociological theory of income difference. In I. Berg (Ed.), Sociological Perspectives on Labor Markets: 11-47. New York: Academic Press. Hagan, J., & Kay, F. 1995. Gender in practice: A study of lawyers' lives: Oxford University Press New York. Heckman, J. J. 1976. The common structure of statistical models of truncation, sample selection and limited dependent variables and a simple estimator for such models, Annals of Economic and Social Measurement, Volume 5, number 4: 475-492: NBER. Heckman, J.J. & Siegelman, P. 1993. The Urban Institute audit studies: Their methods and findings. Heilman, M. E. 1995. Sex stereotypes and their effects in the workplace: What we know and what we don't know. Journal of Social Behavior & Personality. Heilman, M. E., & Eagly, A. H. 2008. Gender stereotypes are alive, well, and busy producing workplace discrimination. Industrial and Organizational Psychology, 1(4): 393-398. Heilman, M. E., & Haynes, M. C. 2005. No credit where credit is due: Attributional rationalization of women's success in male-female teams. Journal of Applied Psychology, 90(5): 905-916. Heilman, M. E., Wallen, A. S., Fuchs, D., & Tamkins, M. M. 2004. Penalties for success: reactions to women who succeed at male gender-typed tasks. Journal of Applied Psychology, 89(3): 416. Huang, W. R. 1996. Gender differences in the earnings of lawyers. Columbia Journal of Law and Social Problems, 30: 267-311. Hultin, M., & Szulkin, R. 2003. Mechanisms of inequality. Unequal access to organizational power and the gender wage gap. European Sociological Review, 19(2), 143-159. Jacobs, J. A. 1992. Women's entry into management: Trends in earnings, authority, and values among salaried managers. Administrative Science Quarterly, 282-301. Jovanovic, B. 1979. Job matching and the theory of turnover. The Journal of Political Economy, 87(5): 972. Kalev, A. 2009. Cracking the Glass Cages? Restructuring and Ascriptive Inequality at Work. American Journal of Sociology, 114(6): 1591-1643. Kalleberg, A. L. 2000. Nonstandard employment relations: Part-time, temporary and contract work. Annual Review of Sociology 26: 341-365. 36 Kalleberg, A. L., Reynolds, J., & Marsden, P. V. 2003. Externalizing employment: flexible staffing arrangements in US organizations. Social Science Research, 32: 525-552. Korenman, S., & Turner, S. C. 1996. Employment contracts and minority-white wage differences. Industrial Relations, 35: 106-122. Lazear, E. P. 1999. Personnel economics: past lessons and future directions. Journal of Labor Economics 199-236. Leahey, E. 2007. Not by productivity alone: How visibility and specialization contribute to academic earnings. American Sociological Review, 72: 533-561. Leicht, K. T. 2008. Broken down by race and gender? Sociological explanations of new sources of earnings inequality. Annual Review of Sociology, 34: 237-255. Lerner, J. S., & Tetlock, P. E. 1999. Accounting for the effects of accountability. Psychological Bulletin, 125(2): 255-275. Madden, J. F. 2012. Performance-Support Bias and the Gender Pay Gap among Stockbrokers. Gender & Society, 26(3): 488-518. Moore, G. 1990. Determinants of men's and women's networks. American Sociological Review, 55: 726-735. Morgan, L. A. 1998. Glass-ceiling effect or cohort effect? A longitudinal study of the gender earnings gap for engineers, 1982 to 1989. American Sociological Review (1998): 479493. Moss, P., & Tilly, C. 2001. Stories employers tell. New York: Russell Sage. Nelson, R. L., & Bridges, W. P. 1999. Legalizing gender inequality: Courts, markets and unequal pay for women in America: Cambridge University Press. Neumark, D. 1996. Sex Discrimination in Restaurant Hiring: An Audit Study. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 11(3): 915-941 Neumark, D. 2012. Detecting discrimination in audit and correspondence studies. Journal of Human Resources 47: 1128-1157. Neumark, D., Bank, R. J. & Van Nort, K.D.. 1996. Sex Discrimination in Restaurant Hiring: An Audit Study. The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 111 (3): 915–41 Olson, J. E., Frieze, I. H., & Good, D. C. 1987. The effects of job type and industry on the income of male and female MBAs. Journal of Human Resources, 22(4): 532-541. Padavic, I., & Reskin, B. F. 2002. Women and men at work: Pine Forge Press. 37 Pager, D. 2007. The use of field experiments for studies of employment discrimination: Contributions, critiques, and directions for the future. The Annals of the American Academy of Political and Social Science, 609: 104-133. Penner, A. M. 2008. Race and gender differences in wages: The role of occupational sorting at the point of hire. The Sociological Quarterly, 49(3): 597-614. Petersen, T., & Morgan, L. A. 1995. Separate and unequal: Occupation-establishment sex segregation and the gender wage gap. American Journal of Sociology: 329-365. Petersen, T., & Saporta, I. 2004. The Opportunity Structure for Discrimination1. American Journal of Sociology, 109(4): 852-901. Pfeffer, J. 1997. Problems and Prospects in New Directions for Organization Theory, Oxford University Press. Pierce, J. 1995. Gender Trials: Emotional Lives in Contemporary Law Firms. University of California Press. Podolny, J. M., and J. N. Baron. 1997. Resources and relationships: Social networks and mobility in the workplace. American Sociological Review, 62(5):673-93. Riach, P. A., & Rich, J. 1987. Testing for sexual discrimination in the labor market. Australian Economic Papers, 26 (49): 165–78. Reskin, B., & McBrier, D. 2000. Why not ascription? Organizations' employment of male and female managers. American Sociological Review, 65(2): 210-233. Reskin, B. F., McBrier, D. B., & Kmec, J. A. 1999. The Determinants and Consequences of Workplace Sex and Race Composition. Annual Review of Sociology, 25: 335-361. Reskin, B. F., & Roos, P. A. 1990. Job Queues, Gender Queues: Explaining Women’s Inroads Into Male Occupations. Philadelphia: Temple University Press. Reskin, B. F., & Padavic, I. 1994. Men and women at work: Thousand Oaks, CA: Pine Forge Press. Reskin, B. & McBrier, D. 2000. Why not ascription? Organizations' employment of male and female managers. American Sociological Review, 65(2):210-33. Ridgeway, C. 1997. Interaction and the conservation of gender inequality: Considering employment. American Sociological Review, 62(2): 218-235. Rissing, B. & Castilla, E. 2014. House of Green Cards: Statistical or Preference-based Inequality in the Employment of Foreign Nationals. Forthcoming in American Sociological Review. 38 Rivera, L. 2011. Ivies, Extracurriculars, and Exclusion: Elite Employers' Use of Educational Credentials. Research in Social Stratification and Mobility, 29: 71-90. Sorensen, J. 2007. Organizational Diversity, Labor Markets, and Wage Inequality. American Behavioral Scientist, 50: 659-676. Sorensen, J. & Sorenson, O. 2007. Corporate demography and income inequality. American Sociological Review 72: 766-783. Stainback, K., Tomaskovic-Devey, D., & Skaggs, S. 2010. Organizational Approaches to Inequality: Inertia, Relative Power, and Environments. Annual Review of Sociology, 36(1): 225-247. Stolzenberg, Ross M. 1978. Bringing the boss back in: Employer size, employee schooling, and socioeconomic achievement. American Sociological Review: 813-828. Tomaskovic-Devey, D. 1993. Gender & racial inequality at work: The sources and consequences of job segregation, Cornell University Press. Tomaskovic-Devey, D., Zimmer, C., Stainback, K., Robinson, C., Taylor, T., & McTague, T. 2006. Documenting desegregation: Segregation in American workplaces by race, ethnicity, and sex, 1966–2003. American Sociological Review, 71(4): 565-588. Tomaskovic‐Devey, D., & Skaggs, S. 2002. Sex Segregation, Labor Process Organization, and Gender Earnings Inequality. American Journal of Sociology, 108: 102-128. Tosi, H. L., & Einbender, S. W. 1985. The effects of the type and amount of information in sex discrimination research: A meta-analysis. Academy of Management Journal, 28(3): 712723. Weinberger, C. J. 2011. In search of the glass ceiling: Gender and earnings growth among US college graduates in the 1990s. Industrial and Labor Relations Review: 949-980. 39 Table 1. Source of Full-Time Offers for Men and Women Men Women Internship* 30.4% 29.7% Formal 35.0% 36.9% Informal 12.3% 16.2% Other 22.3% 17.2% *Source of maximum offers for all respondents reporting at least one full-time job offer (N= 350) 40 Table 2. Offers and Salaries for Domestic and Non-Domestic Professionals Domestic International *p < 0.01 Offer Received 0.64* 0.44 StD 0.48 0.50 41 Average Max Salary $110,715 $111,301 StD $17,769 $35,551 Table 3. Descriptive Statistics Mean (1) Maximum Offer (2) Female (3) GPA (4) GMAT (5) Previous Salary (6) Exp1 (>1 yrs, <3 ys) (7) Exp2 (> 3 yrs, <5 yrs) (8) Exp3 (>5 yrs) (9) Sponsored (10) Finance (11) Consulting (12) General Management (13) Age (14) White (15) Black (16) Hispanic (17) Asian N = 350, *p < 0.05 $110,929 0.31 4.61 711 StD $24,582 0.22 41.96 $27,345 0.40 0.49 0.17 0.16 0.20 0.39 0.06 27.68 0.46 0.02 0.04 0.19 1.00 0.46 -0.13* $74,995 0.42 (1) 0.37 0.49 0.36 0.24 2.46 0.50 0.15 0.20 0.39 1.00 0.13* -0.06 -0.05 0.11* 0.05 0.22* -0.05 0.10 0.07 0.40 -0.11* 0.49 (2) 0.22* 0.35* 0.02 0.05 -0.10 0.00 1.00 0.05 (5) 1.00 -0.08 -0.20* (6) 1.00 0.07 -0.14* -0.38* (7) 1.00 -0.03 -0.01 0.32* -0.37* -0.70* 0.01 0.17* 0.19* -0.03 0.00 0.21* 0.14* 0.08 -0.01 0.05 -0.07 0.04 0.00 -0.08 -0.18* -0.20* -0.03 -0.06 0.07 -0.13* -0.02 0.10 (4) -0.10 -0.07 -0.02 1.00 -0.08 -0.04 0.06 (3) -0.08 -0.04 -0.05 -0.01 0.01 -0.07 -0.20* -0.03 -0.12* 0.03 0.06 0.02 0.02 -0.04 0.04 -0.05 0.05 0.03 -0.05 -0.04 0.05 0.02 (8) 1.00 0.00 0.08 -0.13* -0.21* -0.06 -0.02 -0.08 42 0.05 0.07 1.00 -0.02 -0.11* -0.41* -0.09 0.15* -0.08 -0.05 (11) 1.00 0.67* 0.04 (10) 0.05 0.03 -0.20* 0.33* -0.45* -0.30* 0.05 (9) 0.10 0.01 1.00 -0.04 -0.08 0.00 0.14* -0.24* 0.12* 0.00 -0.04 -0.01 -0.07 0.06 0.11* 0.00 0.11* 1.00 0.03 0.04 0.03 (12) -0.08 0.02 0.04 0.00 (13) 1.00 -0.04 (14) 1.00 0.00 -0.14* -0.04 -0.14* -0.04 -0.38* (15) 1.00 -0.03 -0.07 (16) 1.00 -0.10 (17) 1.00 Table 4. Maximum Salary Offer Men Women *p < 0.05 N 241 109 Average Max Offer $113,147* $106,023 StDev $25,914 $20,617 Table 5. OLS Regressions of Maximum Salary Offers Female GPA (1) -7272.3 ** (2515.0) GMAT (2) -6992.7 ** (2608.4) -5851.9 * -0.61 -23.4 (34.2) (33.4) Exp1 (>1 yrs, <3 ys) (5194.3) 0.15 ** (0.05) 13132.8 (19254.5) Exp2 (> 3 yrs, <5 yrs) 12050.8 (19301.1) Exp3 (>5 yrs) 14684.6 (19553.0) Sponsored -6270.3 ** (2333.9) 10914.7* * (5405.3) (4) (2505.6) 12583.1* * -1.74 Previous Salary (3) Finance 7374.8 (4864.4) (29.9) 0.16 ** (0.05) 12183.7 (17046.4) 10632.2 (17033.0) 12804.9 (17253.0) 4263.1 (2369.7) -2813.8 (4219.4) Consulting 10375.0 *** (2236.1) General Management -2001.6 (3442.9) Age White N -2443 7217.6 (4886.7) -25.2 (32.3) 0.18 ** (0.1) 12872.5 (18325.9) 12906.1 (18321.7) 17851.6 (19043.2) 4868.3 * (2397.0) -2788.9 (4173.2) 10619.3 *** (2279.2) -2326.3 (3480.1) -1050.9 (761.4) (2875.1) -5763.4 (5763.1) Hispanic Constant -6390.3 ** -1750.8 Black Asian (5) -1058 (5090.8) 113186.5 *** (1585.1) 371 56367.1 (36081.6) 371 38464.9 (38118.6) 371 67481.6 * (33550.4) 371 Clustered standard errors, ***p< 0.001, **p< 0.01, *p < 0.05, two-tailed tests 44 -3062.7 (3611.2) 95427.7 * (46496.8) 371 Table 6. The Effect of Job Source on Salary Female GPA GMAT Previous Salary Exp1 (>1 yrs, <3 ys) Exp2 (> 3 yrs, <5 yrs) Exp3 (>5 yrs) Sponsored Finance Consulting General Management Age White Black Hispanic Asian Formal Informal (6) -6460.0 ** (2436.9) 7369.4 (4888.8) -26.3 (32.1) 0.18 *** (0.05) 12983.9 (17968.7) 12761.9 (17982.2) 17821.7 Constant N (2333.2) 6323.6 (4766.6) -25.4 (32.2) 0.18 *** (0.05) 12567.9 (18672.5) 11708.5 (18674.8) 16901.3 (8) -6370.4 ** (2427.5) 6643.1 (4855.1) -28.1 (31.5) 0.19 *** (0.05) 11781.2 (18284.1) 12264.3 (18301.8) 16934.5 (9) -5954.0 ** (2285.3) 6224.1 (4748.5) -25.6 (29.3) 0.18 *** (0.05) 12407.8 (18715.6) 11655.7 (18780.3) 16791.4 (10) -8873.1 ** (2909.4) 6575.9 (4673.9) -22.4 (28.8) 0.18 *** (0.05) 12370.3 (19338.6) 11655.2 (19409.6) 17101.6 (18705.5) (19289.0) (19101.5) (19558.4) (20202.7) -2661.4 -2449.8 -3157.4 -2521.6 -2660.2 4431.4 (2353.1) (4162.7) 10320.9 *** (2301.9) -2470.2 4141.2 (2320.3) (4152.3) 9807.3 *** (2176.0) -1869.0 5320.3* (2418.1) (4302.5) 10719.6 *** (2238.6) -2263.6 4281.7 (2309.8) (4374.5) 9877.3 *** (2216.2) -1835.6 3832.4 (2411.0) (4346.9) 10187.0 *** (2214.1) -1374.7 (3471.6) (3587.0) (3496.0) (3556.8) (3581.8) -1684.5 -812.1 -1709.3 -821.5 -958.8 -1058.4 (758.6) (2892.7) -6022.9 (5733.6) -1344.8 (5031.7) -3335.1 (3574.1) 1947.6 (1816.6) Internship Internship x Female (7) -5968.3 * 95288.5 * (46457.7) 371 -1192.9 (760.6) (2769.6) -6341.1 (6135.7) -191.3 (4834.9) -4099.3 (3596.4) -13184.6 *** (3156.9) 106486.0 * (47396.6) 371 Clustered standard errors, ***p < 0.001, **p < 0.01, *p < 0.05 45 -1071.2 (754.4) (2888.9) -5398.2 (5932.1) -640.2 (5148.4) -3057.0 (3605.9) 3366.0 (2328.1) 100272.3 * (45014.5) 371 -1193.7 (757.4) (2757.0) -6244.8 (6248.1) -87.0 (4790.9) -4045.6 -1216.9 (768.1) (2752.4) -5999.2 (6269.5) -22.4 (4935.6) -4121.9 (3427.1) (3435.0) -13150.2 * -12799.8 * (4750.1) (5107.3) -359.1 (4115.8) (5279.0) 432.8 107105.6 * (45203.5) 371 -246.0 (4109.1) (5231.4) -2423.2 9856.9* (4083.4) 104364.2 * (45199.0) 371 Table 7. Heckman Selection Model of Salary Offers Female GPA GMAT Previous Salary Exp1 (>1 yrs, <3 ys) Exp2 (> 3 yrs, <5 yrs) Exp3 (>5 yrs) Sponsored Finance Consulting General Management Age White Black Hispanic Asian Formal (11) -8857.3 (2845.45) -1306.9 (756.81) 0.17 (0.05) 19804.7 (14187.62) 18778.0 (14097.29) 22967.8 (14649.18) 9341.7 (3692.41) -2689.9 (3336.22) 11938.9 (2795.68) -476.8 (5234.35) 13230.9* (6172.13) -34.4 (33.47) -1129.8 (2849.71) -3356.3 (7721.00) 8.5 (6200.52) -1838.0 (3494.16) Informal Internship Internship x Female Constant N 70710.0 (38573.61) 427 **p < 0.01, *p < 0.05, † p < 0.1 (12) -5915.3 (2641.49) -1189.0 (692.29) ** 0.18 (0.05) 12307.5 (13425.23) 11570.2 (13325.82) 16718.5 (13816.59) * 4204.4 (3454.74) -2522.4 (3423.26) *** 9875.1 (2791.34) -1836.2 (5141.37) 6111.0 (5818.65) -25.5 (30.76) -823.2 (2729.66) -6246.2 (7784.68) -89.6 (6111.57) -4045.6 (3433.56) -359.1 (3232.02) -13147.7 (4067.92) 434.1 (3325.01) ** (13) -8828.4 ** (3087.71) -1211.1 (689.31) ** 0.18 ** (0.05) 12249.6 (13365.22) 11552.4 (13266.79) 17014.0 (13756.87) 3739.2 (3444.46) -2661.3 (3409.33) *** 10184.5 (2784.59) -1375.1 (5125.57) 6440.2 (5789.94) -22.2 (30.67) -960.9 (2718.95) -6000.6 (7752.22) -25.5 (6085.28) -4121.9 (3418.99) -246.0 (3218.66) ** -12796.7 ** (4055.03) -2423.4 (3672.42) * 9862.9 † (5486.10) 107547.7 ** 104894.0 ** (36165.45) (36024.20) 427 427 46 Table 8. Regression Models of Accepted Salary Offers Female GPA GMAT Previous Salary Exp1 (>1 yrs, <3 ys) Exp2 (> 3 yrs, <5 yrs) Exp3 (>5 yrs) Sponsored Finance Consulting General Management Age White Black Hispanic Asian Formal Informal Internship Internship x Female Constant Firm Fixed Effects N (14) 627.6 (1795.3) 3101.6 (3604.6) 11.0 (20.8) 0.098 ** (0.03) 13938.1 (10446.0) 10431.6 (10328.2) 11993.4 (10646.4) -3361.4 (2656.8) -9785.7 * (4325.7) -6018.0 (6554.5) -8533.9 * (3815.1) -573.0 (459.1) -1504.8 (1869.6) -5938.9 (6347.7) 2952.8 (4223.0) -3872.0 (2151.0) (15) -3303.3 (2423.5) 4497.5 (3620.9) 7.9 (20.9) 0.10 (0.03) 14924.9 (10402.2) 11794.1 (10285.6) 13345.9 (10631.4) -2199.4 (2751.4) -10286.4 (4376.0) -5230.3 (6611.2) -8875.6 (3870.8) -713.4 (475.3) -1639.2 (1859.1) -6000.5 (6384.8) 3417.0 (4215.6) -3935.7 (2143.6) 1577.6 (3351.9) 120.8 (4918.7) 1407.4 (3551.4) 8025.2 (3493.4) 91188.4 *** 88046 (24797.2) (24977.3) ***p < 0.001, **p < 0.01, *p < 0.05 Yes 318 *** * * * *** Yes 318 47 Figure 1. Reasons Individuals Select an Internship Offer 30.0 25.0 Percent 20.0 Women 15.0 Men 10.0 5.0 0.0 Growth Potential Industry Job Content Job Function Location Note: Respondents are from the 2010 cohort and completed internships in 2009. N=285 48 Figure 2. Job Source by Gender 40.0 35.0 Proportion 30.0 25.0 Men Women 20.0 15.0 10.0 5.0 0.0 Internship Formal Job Source 49 Informal Figure 3. Comparison of Salary Offers Across Stages Pre-Treatment 1 (Prior to MBA) Women/Men: Pre-Treatment 2 (Internship) Women/Men: 181 women, 418 men 152 women, 297 men $68,685/$75,560 = 90.9% $76,272/$83,676 = 91.1% Intern Employer: (Received Offer) Women/Men: $108,600/$108,196 = 100.3% N=60 women, 136 men Non-Intern Employer Women/Men: (Max Offer) $102,165/$109,899 = 93.0% N=87 women, 181 men 50 Post-Treatment (Max Offer) Women/Men: $106,258/$112,075 = 95% 147 women, 317 men Figure 4. Percentile Distribution of Salaries $160,000 Men's Salaries $140,000 $120,000 Equity Line $100,000 Prior Salaries $80,000 Full-Time Salaries After Internship $60,000 $40,000 $70,000 $90,000 Women's Salaries 51 $110,000 $130,000 Figure 5. Comparison of Negotiations by Source 350 300 Frequency 250 200 Men Women 150 100 50 0 Total Negotiated, Yes 52 Negotiated, No Internship Negotiated, Internship Figure 6. Salary Offers across Different Methods of Hiring 125 Men, Intern Starting Salary (1000s) 120 Men, NI 115 Women, Intern Women, NI 110 105 100 Firm A Firm B Firm C Note: Salary levels are shown for three firms for 65 offers, NI = Non-Internship 53