Choice and Happiness in South Africa Andrea Szabó Gergely Ujhelyi Department of Economics Department of Economics University of Houston University of Houston aszabo2@uh.edu gujhelyi@uh.edu December 8, 2015 Abstract Do people choose what makes them feel happy or do they pursue other goals instead? Benjamin, He¤etz, Kimball, and Rees-Jones (2012) present a methodology to study this question and provide results for US samples. We replicate their methodology in a sample taken from low-income South African townships. We …nd that in this sample people almost always choose what makes them feel happy. In addition, respondents perceive little con‡ict between own happiness and other relevant determinants of choice such as sense of purpose and family happiness. 1 Introduction There are well-documented cases where people’s choices do not appear to maximize their happiness. For example, those who choose to work longer hours are less happy than others (Di Tella and MacCulloch, 2008), and having children does not seem to make people happier (Hansen, 2012; Stanca, 2012). Benjamin, He¤etz, Kimball, and Rees-Jones (2012), BHKR from now on, examine this question directly and report that in hypothetical choice situations between 5 and 38 percent of respondents say that they would choose the option that would make them less happy. At least some of the time, for at least some measures, people’s choices appear to have goals other than increased happiness.1 Direct evidence on the extent to which happiness guides choices is scarce and no study that we know of has been conducted outside of the richest countries.2 This is an important gap because understanding what contributes to happiness is particularly important for public policy (Layard, 2006; Loewenstein and Ubel, 2008). For example, policy experiments advocated in developing countries are often based on the notion that self-control problems, lack of information, or other constraints prevent people from making “optimal”choices. At the same time, we seem to know little about the objectives that people seek when making these choices. Is the pursuit of happiness equally important among the poor and the rich? We use the methodology proposed by BHKR to study people’s choices and happiness in a low income population in a group of South African townships near Pretoria. We confront survey respondents with hypothetical choice scenarios, for example, would they choose to travel to an important social event (a friend’s wedding), or would they rather save the time and money and stay at home? Would they choose a job with a higher salary where they would make less than others at the …rm, or one with a lower salary where they would make more than others? Then, we ask them which choice would make them happier or help them ful…ll some of their other goals in life, such as their family’s happiness, good health, or a sense of purpose.3 1 BHKR show that there are di¤erences between measures, e.g., between those capturing people’s life satisfaction, happiness with life as a whole, or their current feelings of happiness (see also Diener et al., 2010 and Deaton et al., 2010). As described below, our main measure asks about feelings of happiness immediately after making a choice. BHKR found this type of measure to be the least predictive of choice. 2 While the literature on the economics of happiness has traditionally focused on OECD countries, the number of studies conducted in developing countries has grown in recent years. Examples include Ravallion and Lokshin (2002), Kingdon and Knight (2007), Appleton and Song (2008), Deaton et al. (2010), Fontaine and Yamada (2014), and Stillman et al. (2015). Our work di¤ers from these studies by focusing on the relationship between choice and happiness rather than on the determinants of happiness. 3 In the psychology literature, studies using similar methods include Tversky and Gri¢ n (1991) and Hsee et al. (2003). In economics, see also Benjamin et al. (2014). One may object to this methodology, e.g., on the grounds that respondents may have di¢ culty predicting how they would feel in a choice situation. In this paper, we simply accept the methodology at face value and study whether it yields di¤erent results in 2 We have three main results. First, we …nd that respondents mostly choose the option that makes them feel happier. Across all scenarios, choice and happiness coincide in 87 percent of the cases, with little variance between scenarios. It is noteworthy that our questions explicitly ask about a¤ect (feelings of happiness) rather than judgement (life satisfaction). The former is typically viewed as a weaker predictor of choices, which makes the concordance between choice and happiness in our sample particularly salient. As we emphasize below, while our procedures are similar, our sample di¤ers from BHKR’s in many dimensions (income, education, language, etc.) and one must therefore be cautious in drawing comparisons. Subject to these caveats, in this South African sample happiness seems to predict choices more than it did in the US. Second, like BHKR we identify certain goals, notably achieving a sense of purpose and family happiness, which are strong determinants of choices apart from happiness. Interestingly, in previous surveys respondents in the US and elsewhere rated these same goals as being highly important (Ry¤, 1989; Diener and Oishi, 2004). The principal goals driving choices in our low-income South African sample are similar to those identi…ed as important elsewhere in the world. Our third result resolves the tension between the …rst two set of …ndings, that happiness is important and that, at the same time, other goals are also important. In general, respondents in our study perceive little con‡ict between happiness and other goals. People in our sample tend to view choices that make them happy as also contributing to their other goals in life. This di¤ers somewhat from the US results and suggests that, in our context, it is possible for people to simultaneously achieve happiness and other goals. We also show that individual characteristics, such as marital status or the number of children in the household, a¤ect the extent to which these various objectives can be reconciled. In the rest of the paper, Section 2 describes our research design, Section 3 presents the results, and Section 4 compares our results to BHKR’s. Section 5 discusses robustness and Section 6 concludes. 2 2.1 Research design Study environment We conducted our surveys in a group of townships about an hour’s drive north of Pretoria (Mabopane, Ga-Rankuwa, and Winterveldt). The setting is typical of peri-urban areas in many African countries, featuring a combination of informal shacks, (single-family) governour context. 3 ment housing, and some larger single-family homes. Most of the infrastructure is relatively well-developed (all households have running water, there is a large number of paved roads). The average household size in our sample is slightly above 4, with one member employed. Average monthly household income reported in our survey is around 6000 Rand ( 600 USD), and two-thirds of the respondents completed high school. These …gures are close to those reported by the South African statistical agency for the average Black household in the country.4 While there are clearly many dimensions in which our setting di¤ers from BHKR’s (see Section 4) we believe comparing results from the two studies can provide at least suggestive comparisons between samples from a developed and a developing country. 2.2 Survey design The starting point for our design was BHKR’s “Cornell study,”because this is the only one allowing for an analysis of which life goals besides happiness a¤ect choices. We presented respondents with 8 hypothetical choice scenarios, 7 of which were directly adapted from BHKR, adjusting for the South African context.5 For example, in one scenario we asked participants to imagine choosing between a job that pays R6000 (about $600) a month and allows 7.5 hours of sleep each day and one that pays R10,000 (about $1000) but only allows 6 hours of sleep. The same question appears in BHKR with income …gures of $80,000 per year for 7.5 hours of sleep or $140,000 per year for 6 hours of sleep. For scenarios involving money, we chose the monetary …gures to be comparable round …gures to those in BHKR, adjusting for income di¤erences. In the above scenario, the R6000 …gure is slightly higher than the average household income reported by our respondents, and it is 60% of the alternative choice being o¤ered. In some cases, adjustments were necessary for the social and economic context. For example, we replaced traveling home for Thanksgiving by plane with traveling to a friend’s wedding by bus. Like BHKR, we also included a scenario where choice and happiness was predictable in order to test the validity of the methodology. This involved a choice between an apple or an orange, where BHKR predicted and found very few reversals and a particularly large e¤ect of happiness on choice (as it turns out, in South Africa this scenario is a useful test on the methodology for reasons very di¤erent from the US, see Section 3.1). Finally, we included an 8th scenario involving a choice between luxury consumption (buying a nicer meal than usual) and paying down debt, because we thought this was a particularly realistic choice situation in our setting. The full list of choice scenarios is given 4 Average monthly income: R 5,803, household size: 3.98, unemployment rate: 40%. Source: Statistics South Africa (http://beta2.statssa.gov.za/) 5 We took 6 scenarios (BHKR’s 1, 3, 5, 6, 8, and 10) from the Cornell study. These include the only scenario asked in the CNSS study and two of the scenarios in the Denver study. We added a 7th scenario (BHKR’s 13) that only appeared in the Denver study. 4 in the Appendix. After each scenario, we asked the respondents which option they think they would choose. We also asked them how each option would make them feel in terms of a variety of possible goals including their own subjective well-being (SWB), their family’s happiness, their health, their social life, etc. Speci…cally, we asked “Between these two options, in the few minutes immediately after making the choice, which option do you think would make you feel better in terms of... your own happiness / your family’s happiness / etc.”Note that in this formulation our measure of SWB explicitly asks about instantaneous feelings of happiness. We are not measuring more evaluative notions like life satisfaction. Responses were on a 6-point scale for choices (1 = De…nitely choose option 1, 2 = Probably choose option 1, ..., 6 = De…nitely choose option 2) and on a 7-point scale for happiness and other goals (1 = Option 1 would de…nitely feel better, ..., 4 = No di¤erence, ..., 7 = Option 2 would de…nitely feel better). Importantly, as in BHKR’s Cornell study, the scale for happiness and other life goals includes a “No di¤erence” option. To facilitate at least suggestive comparisons to the CNSS and Denver studies, we also included another version of the happiness question: “If you were limited to these two options, which do you think would make you feel happier?”This was a stand-alone question (without the other life goals), did not specify “in the few minutes immediately after making the choice,” and the response scale did not allow for an indi¤erence option (it used the same 6-point scale as the choice question). In some of the analysis below, we collapse the choice question to a binary variable indicating which option the respondent would be more likely to choose. Similarly, we sometimes collapse the SWB question using a binary variable to represent which option would more likely make the individual happier (excluding responses indicating indi¤erence). Each respondent was randomly given one of four di¤erent versions of the questionnaire. The questions asked were always the same, but the versions di¤ered in the order in which speci…c questions or scenarios were presented. In the robustness analysis of section 5 below we compare the di¤erent versions to check for questionnaire e¤ects. As part of the survey, we also collected various socio-economic characteristics of the respondents, including age, education, marital status, household size, and income, among others. We present more details on these variables in Section 3.3 below. 2.3 Sampling and implementation We randomly sampled 1000 households from the full list of residential addresses in the townships of Mabopane, Ga-Rankuwa, and Winterveldt. The original sampling was done for 5 a project on residential water consumption (Szabó and Ujhelyi, 2015), and we included our choice scenarios at the end of the last survey for that project. All households were surveyed in February 2013. Our surveyors visited each address and interviewed an adult member of the household.6 Surveys were conducted face to face at the respondent’s home. Our surveyors received special training for this project; they are local residents employed by a survey and market research company with extensive experience working in the area. Questionnaires were available in both English and the local language (Setswana). 34 households could not be located or refused to participate, resulting in a sample size of 966. Histograms of our raw data on the answers to the choice, SWB and other life goal questions appear in the Appendix. 3 3.1 Results Choice-SWB reversals Table 1 shows the distribution of answers to the choice and SWB questions using binary measures. Each column corresponds to a di¤erent scenario. The …rst four cells in each column are restricted to respondents who did not view the two options as providing the same level of SWB and the fraction of respondents stating indi¤erence is shown in the …fth row of the table. For example, the …rst cell in the …rst column reveals that 15 percent of non-indi¤erent respondents would choose a job with more sleep and less pay and say that this option would make them happier. Similarly, the second cell shows that 72 percent would choose the job with less sleep and more pay and would feel happier with this option. Of particular interest are the 3rd and 4th rows: these show the fraction of respondents exhibiting a “choice-SWB reversal.”In the third cell of the …rst column, 7 percent of respondents would choose more sleep but think that the job with more income would make them happier, and 5 percent exhibit a reversal in the opposite direction. In our sample, people mostly choose the option that makes them happier. Across all scenarios, choice and happiness coincide in 87 percent of the cases. The fraction of choicehappiness concordance for individual scenarios falls in a tight range: between 84 and 90 percent. These numbers are remarkably large, especially since we explicitly ask about a¤ect (feelings of happiness), which BHKR found to be less predictive of choice than more evaluative notions of happiness (e.g., life satisfaction). In this South African sample, choices are highly correlated with instantaneous feelings of happiness. 6 More impersonal survey methods, such as phone surveys or self-administered questionnaires would not have been practical in our context. 6 7 10.98 4.75 1.35 0.0000 947 5.47 1.14 0.1455 950 34.21 72.21 7.26 Money versus Time % 50.05 Sleep versus Income % 15.05 1.14 0.0000 947 4.22 9.29 75.29 Friends versus Income % 11.19 3.21 0.0901 934 5.68 7.82 45.12 Friends/Family versus Money % 41.37 1.24 0.0001 948 4.96 10.13 57.28 Fun versus Debt % 27.64 2.08 1.0000 939 4.9 4.79 23.43 Money versus Time, v. 2 % 66.88 0.93 0.0057 953 3.78 6.82 20.36 Abs. Inc. versus rel. inc. % 69.05 4.25 0.0000 921 3.37 11.62 37.13 Apple versus Orange % 47.88 Notes: For each scenario, the …rst four rows present the distribution of responses among those who did not indicate indi¤erence for the SWB question. The fraction of indi¤erent SWB responses is indicated in the …fth row. The Liddell test tests the hypothesis that the average choice response is equal to the average SWB response for paired data. The text of each scenario appears in the Appendix. Higher SWB: Option 1 Chosen: Option 1 Higher SWB: Option 2 Chosen: Option 2 Higher SWB: Option 2 Chosen: Option 1 Higher SWB: Option 1 Chosen: Option 2 Indi¤erence for SWB p-value of Liddell Exact Test N Choice scenario Table 1: Choice and SWB responses across scenarios One scenario that requires some discussion is the “test” scenario involving a choice between two free snacks, an apple or an orange. BHKR included this question because response patterns are predictable (in the US context, one would expect few reversals), thus providing a check on the methodology. In the South African case we …nd that this scenario yields one of the largest fraction of reversals (15 percent). It turns out that, in this context, these patterns also provide support for the methodology. As we became aware after the conclusion of our survey, there exists in South Africa a powerful urban legend about somebody handing out free oranges infected with HIV. This conspiracy theory, going back to the 1990s, was documented to be part of the local culture as recently as 2011 (Sivela, 2012). Such beliefs mean that this choice scenario should involve trade-o¤s between own happiness (a taste for a fruit) and other goals, health in particular, especially for those who like oranges. Indeed, we …nd that while our respondents were evenly split between assigning higher SWB to apples or oranges, this scenario yielded the largest di¤erence in reversals. 24 percent of those preferring oranges based on SWB said that they would choose an apple, while only 7 percent of those preferring apples would choose an orange. Below, we also …nd direct evidence that concerns about health and romantic life were strong determinants of choice in this scenario. In the South African context, these patterns make perfect sense and are exactly what one would expect in the presence of beliefs about HIV infected oranges.7 3.2 Determinants of choice What other factors besides own happiness explain choices, and how strong is own happiness as a determinant of choice relative to these? Table 2 presents regressions of choice on own happiness and other factors. For OLS regressions, all variables are demeaned at the scenario level to control for di¤erences across scenarios. In column 1, we see that 49 percent of the variation in choice is explained by own happiness alone. This con…rms the strong association between choice and happiness documented in the previous section. The next column excludes own happiness but includes the other 11 goals. This results in an R2 similar to the …rst column: excluding own happiness, other factors are also important determinants of choices. The largest coe¢ cients are on family happiness and sense of purpose: these goals are highly correlated with choices in our sample. The …nding that choices closely re‡ect family happiness and sense of purpose echoes the 7 Another noteworthy feature of Table 1 is that respondents always prefer more money, both in terms of choice and SWB. For example, in the …rst column, 78% would choose more income and less sleep and 79% predict that more income would yield higher SWB. We observe a similar pattern in the remaining scenarios: respondents prefer to save money rather than time, earn more rather than live among friends, save money rather than go to a wedding, get money now rather than later, and have a higher absolute income rather than a higher relative income. This is of course what one would expect given the low incomes in the sample. 8 results from a series of interviews reported by Clark (2003) who collected what people in two South African townships thought to be important aspects of a “good life.” The top four aspects mentioned were having a job, housing, an education, and adequate income. In our context these are likely to increase one’s sense of purpose (interpreted as “knowing what to do”). The …fth most important aspect mentioned was a good family (respondents explained that this was valued because of the support it provided in times of need). It is also noteworthy that these same aspects are also typically rated as being highly important in surveys in other countries (e.g., Ry¤, 1989; Diener and Oishi, 2004). We …nd that the goals rated as important in the US and elsewhere are also highly correlated with choices in our low-income South African sample. The third column of Table 2 includes all 12 goals. This results in little change in explanatory power but large drops in individual coe¢ cients compared to the …rst two columns. This pattern indicates the presence of multicollinearity: it suggests that respondents tend to view choices that are more conducive to one goal (e.g., own happiness) as useful for the attainment of other goals as well. We con…rm this directly in Table 3 where we regress the score on own happiness on the other 11 goals. Across all scenarios, these goals explain 86 percent of the variation in which option makes a person happier. For the individual scenarios, this R2 is always above 80 percent. In our sample, respondents appear to perceive little con‡ict between SWB and other goals in life. 9 Table 2: Regressions of choice on SWB and other goals OLS Own happniess 0.569*** (0.007) Family happiness Health Life’s level of romance Social life Control over your life Life’s level of spirituality Life’s level of fun Social status Life’s nonboringness Physical comfort Sense of purpose Observations (pseudo) R2 7451 0.4867 0.250*** (0.024) 0.090*** (0.024) -0.013 (0.023) 0.032 (0.023) 0.036* (0.021) -0.042** (0.020) 0.031 (0.020) 0.029 (0.023) -0.066*** (0.022) 0.023 (0.025) 0.260*** (0.022) 7451 0.4899 0.312*** (0.024) 0.136*** (0.025) 0.028 (0.024) -0.028 (0.022) -0.005 (0.022) 0.011 (0.021) -0.059*** (0.019) 0.040** (0.019) 0.010 (0.023) -0.048** (0.022) 0.020 (0.024) 0.197*** (0.022) 7451 0.5104 Ordered Probit 0.247*** (0.019) 0.111*** (0.020) 0.018 (0.020) -0.018 (0.019) -0.009 (0.019) 0.002 (0.019) -0.071*** (0.018) 0.025 (0.018) 0.011 (0.020) -0.081*** (0.020) 0.003 (0.021) 0.191*** (0.019) 7451 0.2392 Probit 0.195*** (0.021) 0.173*** (0.023) 0.014 (0.024) 0.017 (0.024) -0.041* (0.024) 0.041* (0.023) -0.102*** (0.024) 0.090*** (0.022) -0.002 (0.026) -0.009 (0.026) 0.029 (0.027) 0.107*** (0.022) 7451 0.4907 Notes: The dependent variable is choice on a 6-point scale for OLS and Ordered Probit, and on a binary scale for Probit. All independent variables are on a 7-point scale. Variables are demeaned at the scenario level for the OLS regressions. Ordered Probit and Probit regressions include scenario …xed e¤ects. Robust standard errors in parentheses. ***, **, * denote signi…cance at the 1, 5, and 10 percent, respectively. 10 11 All scenarios pooled 0.368*** (0.025) 0.200*** (0.022) 0.050** (0.024) 0.122*** (0.023) 0.078*** (0.020) 0.052*** (0.018) -0.026 (0.016) 0.062*** (0.021) -0.059*** (0.018) 0.009 (0.022) 0.201*** (0.021) 7473 0.860 Sleep versus Income 0.399*** (0.063) 0.162*** (0.051) 0.084 (0.057) 0.049 (0.053) 0.086* (0.051) 0.001 (0.042) -0.030 (0.037) 0.000 (0.044) -0.035 (0.043) 0.068 (0.047) 0.259*** (0.048) 937 0.855 Money versus Time 0.332*** (0.060) 0.210*** (0.054) 0.127* (0.065) 0.121** (0.053) 0.170*** (0.052) 0.038 (0.045) -0.100** (0.043) 0.070 (0.058) -0.085** (0.041) -0.029 (0.059) 0.204*** (0.054) 939 0.896 Friends versus Income 0.191*** (0.064) 0.296*** (0.063) 0.038 (0.062) 0.013 (0.052) 0.159*** (0.051) 0.031 (0.044) 0.015 (0.048) 0.046 (0.057) -0.080* (0.047) 0.024 (0.055) 0.295*** (0.060) 934 0.821 Friends/Family versus Money 0.466*** (0.060) 0.222*** (0.052) 0.048 (0.060) 0.036 (0.053) 0.064 (0.045) 0.067* (0.037) -0.065** (0.029) 0.118*** (0.045) -0.034 (0.045) 0.023 (0.052) 0.139*** (0.047) 933 0.896 Fun versus Debt 0.362*** (0.071) 0.314*** (0.064) 0.104 (0.074) 0.134** (0.064) -0.007 (0.054) 0.057 (0.042) -0.032 (0.040) -0.009 (0.055) -0.048 (0.047) 0.026 (0.068) 0.135** (0.053) 931 0.875 Money versus Time, v. 2 0.380*** (0.066) 0.213*** (0.059) 0.068 (0.051) 0.046 (0.049) 0.018 (0.049) -0.027 (0.039) 0.032 (0.042) 0.095* (0.050) 0.006 (0.043) -0.005 (0.056) 0.234*** (0.048) 932 0.877 Abs. Inc. versus Rel. inc. 0.412*** (0.075) 0.231*** (0.063) -0.045 (0.061) 0.344*** (0.080) -0.034 (0.049) -0.052 (0.051) -0.001 (0.045) 0.082 (0.066) 0.004 (0.046) -0.028 (0.057) 0.141*** (0.047) 931 0.897 Apple versus Orange 0.340*** (0.071) 0.115** (0.056) -0.040 (0.071) 0.195*** (0.071) 0.080 (0.072) 0.292*** (0.073) 0.040 (0.074) 0.039 (0.071) -0.112 (0.070) 0.022 (0.088) 0.099 (0.073) 936 0.801 Notes: Happiness regressed on other goals. All variables are on a 7-point scale and demeaned at the scenario level. Robust standard errors in parentheses. ***, **, * denote signi…cance at the 1, 5, and 10 percent, respectively. Observations R2 Sense of purpose Physical comfort Life’s nonboringness Social status Life’s level of fun Life’s level of spirituality Control over your life Social life Life’s level of romance Health Family happiness Choice scenario Table 3: The correlation between happiness and other life goals 3.3 3.3.1 Heterogeneity Heterogeneity between scenarios To explore the heterogeneity of our …ndings across scenarios further, Table 4 presents regressions similar to those in Table 2 separately by scenario (the …rst column reproduces column 3 from Table 2 for comparison). For each scenario, choice is …rst regressed on SWB and then we add the other life goals. The table presents the latter regressions, and indicates the change in R2 as the 11 life goals are added. We note that the incremental R2 is highest for decisions that are most realistic in the context of the study (being asked to contribute time vs. money at a child’s school, spending a small unexpected bonus on having fun vs. ful…lling a debt obligation, choosing between an apple and an orange). These scenarios, which are the closest to decisions respondents may face in everyday life, are most a¤ected by additional life goals besides happiness. Interestingly, this is exactly what BHKR …nd in the US, where decisions deemed most relevant for respondents also resulted in the highest incremental R2 : Recall that the decision making process in the apple vs. orange scenario is partially predictable due to the urban legend about oranges infected with HIV. Indeed, we see that health considerations are particularly important determinants of choice in this scenario, as is respondents’concern about their romantic life. 12 13 All scenarios pooled 0.312*** (0.024) 0.136*** (0.025) 0.028 (0.024) -0.028 (0.022) -0.005 (0.022) 0.011 (0.021) -0.059*** (0.019) 0.040** (0.019) 0.010 (0.023) -0.048** (0.022) 0.020 (0.024) 0.197*** (0.022) 7451 0.510 0.034 Sleep versus Income 0.308*** (0.066) 0.113 (0.070) -0.012 (0.054) 0.021 (0.057) 0.068 (0.062) 0.004 (0.056) -0.039 (0.050) -0.068 (0.047) 0.022 (0.058) 0.007 (0.060) 0.018 (0.060) 0.092* (0.055) 935 0.408 0.001 Money versus Time 0.287*** (0.069) 0.029 (0.063) -0.032 (0.070) -0.019 (0.063) 0.014 (0.061) -0.090 (0.061) -0.069 (0.052) 0.158*** (0.059) 0.011 (0.065) -0.174*** (0.059) -0.015 (0.075) 0.443*** (0.067) 937 0.486 0.056 Friends versus Income 0.300*** (0.072) 0.113* (0.066) 0.066 (0.060) -0.101 (0.062) 0.019 (0.051) -0.063 (0.056) -0.012 (0.050) 0.086* (0.051) -0.050 (0.066) -0.114* (0.059) 0.029 (0.064) 0.229*** (0.063) 929 0.365 0.036 Friends/Family versus Money 0.278*** (0.068) 0.193*** (0.073) -0.002 (0.076) 0.075 (0.065) -0.026 (0.065) 0.097* (0.057) -0.153*** (0.054) 0.018 (0.042) 0.086 (0.062) -0.120* (0.069) 0.068 (0.065) 0.146** (0.066) 932 0.581 0.039 Fun versus Debt 0.348*** (0.066) 0.221*** (0.073) -0.082 (0.066) -0.100 (0.067) 0.013 (0.065) 0.072 (0.058) -0.096* (0.056) -0.037 (0.059) 0.091 (0.060) -0.034 (0.064) 0.009 (0.067) 0.209*** (0.061) 926 0.530 0.050 Money versus Time, v. 2 0.304*** (0.066) 0.268*** (0.065) -0.067 (0.057) -0.019 (0.053) 0.034 (0.046) 0.058 (0.048) -0.094** (0.043) 0.055 (0.046) -0.048 (0.053) -0.019 (0.051) 0.015 (0.053) 0.211*** (0.052) 929 0.633 0.037 Abs. Inc. versus Rel. inc. 0.352*** (0.072) 0.136* (0.081) 0.007 (0.071) -0.008 (0.061) -0.037 (0.062) -0.009 (0.057) -0.071 (0.054) 0.098* (0.054) 0.085 (0.061) -0.101* (0.058) 0.015 (0.066) 0.184*** (0.060) 930 0.603 0.042 Apple versus Orange 0.298*** (0.058) 0.047 (0.067) 0.171*** (0.058) -0.169** (0.067) -0.038 (0.073) -0.057 (0.064) 0.081 (0.072) 0.112 (0.076) -0.108 (0.079) 0.156** (0.074) 0.056 (0.079) 0.092 (0.064) 933 0.513 0.069 Notes: OLS regressions. The dependent variable is choice on a 6-point scale and all independent variables are on a 7-point scale. Variables are demeaned at the scenario level. Incremental R2 is the change in the R2 of the regression as the 11 goals other than own happiness are added. Robust standard errors in parentheses. ***, **, * denote signi…cance at the 1, 5, and 10 percent, respectively Observations R2 Incremental R2 Sense of purpose Physical comfort Life’s nonboringness Social status Life’s level of fun Life’s level of spirituality Control over your life Social life Life’s level of romance Health Family happiness Own happniess Choice scenario Table 4: Regressions of choice on happiness and other goals, by scenario 3.3.2 Heterogeneity between individuals Which respondents are more likely to exhibit choice-SWB reversals and which ones tend to choose what makes them happy? In Table 5 we look at this question by regressing the incidence of reversals on various individual characteristics of the respondents. These were collected as part of the survey, and include the respondent’s gender, age, marital status, household size (adults and children), highest level of education, and household income. For the latter, we have 143 missing values. To maximize the number of observations and limit measurement error, we use observed income and ownership of various household appliances to predict household income (in logs), and use these predicted values for the entire sample.8 In the …rst column of Table 5, our dependent variable is the number of scenarios in which the respondent exhibited a reversal. In the remaining columns, the dependent variable is 1 if the respondent exhibited a reversal in the given scenario, and 0 otherwise. In all regressions, respondents who indicated indi¤erence in the SWB question are coded as missing. The regressions in Table 5 are estimated with OLS. For the individual scenarios, Table 12 in the Appendix presents similar results from Probit regressions. The regressions in this table tend to paint a consistent picture: the same types of respondents are likely to exhibit reversals in all scenarios. We …nd that choice-SWB reversals are signi…cantly less likely among men, older respondents, widowers, and those with fewer children. Given our earlier results, these patterns make perfect sense. As we saw in Section 3.2, one’s family’s happiness was one of the strongest correlates of choice apart from SWB. Thus, we would expect respondents for whom family is more important to exhibit more reversals, and respondents for whom family carries less weight to more often base their choices on own happiness. This is exactly what we …nd: older men, widowers, and those with fewer children are likely to attach less importance to family, and they are particularly likely to choose what makes them personally happy. 8 Predicted income is based on the regression ln(Y + 1) = X + " where Y is reported income in Rand, and X includes ownership of the following: hot running water, TV, DVD player, car, cellphone, refrigerator. 14 15 -0.238** (0.116) -0.014** (0.006) 0.119 (0.448) -0.391** (0.163) 0.045 (0.144) 0.028 (0.044) 0.103** (0.044) 0.325 (0.203) -0.158 (0.205) -0.222 (0.607) 0.088 (0.189) 818 Male Sleep versus Income -0.054** (0.022) -0.001 (0.001) -0.032 (0.061) -0.103*** (0.030) 0.017 (0.028) -0.005 (0.009) 0.002 (0.007) 0.028 (0.048) -0.038 (0.049) -0.158 (0.118) 0.058 (0.037) 939 Money versus Time -0.049** (0.024) -0.001 (0.001) -0.031 (0.070) -0.075* (0.043) -0.012 (0.029) -0.001 (0.010) 0.012 (0.009) 0.100* (0.051) -0.015 (0.051) -0.071 (0.126) 0.017 (0.040) 937 Friends versus Income -0.081*** (0.022) -0.002* (0.001) -0.062 (0.062) -0.120*** (0.034) -0.032 (0.028) 0.007 (0.009) -0.004 (0.008) 0.103** (0.043) -0.012 (0.044) 0.058 (0.118) -0.012 (0.037) 936 Friends/Family versus Money -0.036 (0.023) -0.002* (0.001) -0.013 (0.061) -0.002 (0.043) 0.015 (0.027) 0.012 (0.010) 0.015* (0.009) 0.046 (0.049) -0.010 (0.050) -0.059 (0.124) 0.029 (0.039) 924 Fun versus Debt -0.020 (0.024) -0.004*** (0.001) -0.034 (0.059) -0.117*** (0.033) -0.018 (0.029) 0.010 (0.010) 0.031*** (0.010) -0.012 (0.056) -0.095* (0.056) -0.106 (0.154) 0.041 (0.047) 937 Money versus Time, v. 2 -0.002 (0.020) -0.003*** (0.001) 0.021 (0.055) 0.022 (0.036) -0.003 (0.024) -0.006 (0.007) 0.014** (0.006) 0.033 (0.027) 0.006 (0.029) -0.244* (0.130) 0.083** (0.040) 928 Abs. Inc. versus Rel. inc. -0.010 (0.020) -0.003** (0.001) -0.028 (0.048) -0.061** (0.030) -0.000 (0.025) -0.002 (0.007) 0.016** (0.007) 0.026 (0.040) -0.036 (0.041) 0.065 (0.084) -0.016 (0.027) 942 Apple versus Orange 0.007 (0.024) -0.003*** (0.001) 0.075 (0.076) -0.056 (0.040) 0.009 (0.029) -0.010 (0.009) 0.022*** (0.009) 0.060 (0.050) -0.004 (0.052) -0.279* (0.150) 0.076* (0.045) 911 Notes: OLS regressions. In the …rst column, the dependent variable is a respondent’s total number of choice-SWB reversals; in the other columns it is an indicator equal to 1 if the respondent exhibited a reversal in the given scenario. ‘Primary school’is 1 if the respondent’s highest level of completed education is primary school; ‘High school’is 1 if it is high school or above. Income is measured in logs and predicted based on ownership of household appliances as described in the text. All regressions include a constant. Robust standard errors in parentheses. ***,**,* denote signi…cance at the 1, 5, and 10 percent, respectively. Observations Income squared Income High school Primary school Number of children Number of adults in the HH Single Widowed Divorced Age Total reversal Choice scenario Table 5: Reversals and respondent characteristics 4 Comparison with BHKR How do our …ndings compare to BHKR’s? Before turning to this issue, we must discuss two basic questions: what to compare, and how to interpret the comparisons. 4.1 What to compare? BHKR analyze 29 survey versions across 3 samples, using two di¤erent survey methods. Reproducing this rich design was not possible in our context. An immediate implication is that not every result in BHKR will have a meaningful counterpart in our study. Because we believe that studying other correlates of choices besides happiness is important, the starting point for our design was the only study that allowed for this, BHKR’s Cornell study. As described in Section 2, most choice scenarios, the wording of our main happiness question, and the response scale were all based on this study. It is plausible that these design choices could matter for the results. First, recall that the SWB question included the option for respondents to indicate that they were indi¤erent (and indi¤erent respondents were excluded when computing the fraction of SWB-choice reversals / concordances). This can potentially a¤ect the results through framing e¤ects, or because indi¤erent respondents are forced to indicate either a reversal or a concordance when the indi¤erence option is not present. Our results below show that, within our sample, we get fewer reversals when the indi¤erence option is not included. Second, in the Cornell study the SWB question asked exclusively about “happiness:” happiness with life as a whole and immediately felt own happiness. Apart from these two questions, the Denver study also contained a question on “life satisfaction.” In the Cornell study, there was no signi…cant di¤erence in the explanatory power of the two happiness measures for choices. By contrast in the Denver study life satisfaction had a signi…cantly higher explanatory power for choice than immediately felt own happiness, while happiness with life as a whole did not result in statistically signi…cant di¤erences compared to either of the other two measures. The CNSS study only asked about happiness with life as a whole. Whether or not these di¤erences in design caused the Cornell results to be di¤erent from BHKR’s other two studies cannot be formally established. Because BHKR observe considerably more reversals in the Cornell sample than in the other two samples (BHKR, p2093-4), this suggests that design features could be important. We conclude that the safest comparison of our …ndings described above is with the Cornell results. It is of course always possible to …nd dimensions in which our study is closer to one of the other BHKR samples (see below). To allow some comparison of our results to the other two studies our surveys also included a version of the SWB question that did not allow for 16 indi¤erence, was asked as a stand-alone question without other life goals, and did not refer to immediately felt happiness (asked about “happiness” rather than “happiness in the few minutes immediately after making the choice”). We use these results (shown in Table 11 below) when comparing our …ndings to BHKR’s Denver or CNSS study. 4.2 How to interpret the comparisons? BHKR’s study and ours obviously di¤er in the country where the study is located, but there are many other di¤erences. These include observable sample characteristics like income, education, and age (especially relative to the Cornell sample). They are also likely to include various unobservable characteristics stemming from random sampling vs. convenience sampling (in the case of the Denver and Cornell studies). For example, it could be that subjects who are willing to …ll out a self-administered questionnaire are more or less likely to exhibit reversals than those who don’t. There is a di¤erence in language and culture, perhaps including how people think of “happiness.”9 There are also several di¤erences in design: we use a subset of the BHKR scenarios adapted to the local context, and face-to-face interviews instead of self-administered or telephone questionnaires. The latter is relevant if respondents are more likely to admit to choice-SWB reversals in impersonal, self-administered surveys than face-to-face to an interviewer.10 In theory, any of these di¤erences could impact the …ndings, and we cannot formally test whether they do. In fact, BHKR themselves …nd substantial di¤erences between their various studies. Thus, one should not attribute the di¤erences in results to any one particular factor. Finally, we should mention that there are legitimate questions one may raise regarding external validity. For example, …nding that our respondents exhibit more SWB-choice reversals in the scenarios in our survey does not rule out the existence of scenarios which we did not consider that could yield fewer reversals in our sample than in BHKR. 9 While we have no direct evidence of this, our …eldworkers and translators assured us that the word “happiness” (lethabo) is interpreted similarly in English and Setswana. We are aware of one paper in psychology studying whether various measures of well-being make sense in Setswana and whether they yield comparable scales to their English counterpart. That paper concludes that they do (Wissing et al., 2010). 10 This possibility is mitigated by the signi…cant experience of our surveyors. Our …eldworkers are members of the local community who regularly conduct surveys on topics much more sensitive than ours in this population, including projects on health or sexual behavior. They are trained to overcome issues of trust and respondent bias in these delicate situations. 17 0 .2 Density .4 .6 Figure 1: Number of reversals across respondents 0 2 4 Number of reversals 6 8 Notes: The graph shows the histogram of the number of scenarios for which a respondent exhibited a choice-SWB reversal. 4.3 Comparing the …ndings Subject to the caveats above, we now discuss how our results compare to those found in BHKR’s US samples. 4.3.1 Cornell study Choice-SWB reversals. The comparison of reversals with BHKR’s Cornell study is summarized in Table 6. In BHKR, the fraction of responses where choice and happiness coincided was 77 percent, with a range of 62-84 percent across scenarios.11 This is signi…cantly smaller than the 87 percent, with a range of 84-90, reported in our Table 1. People in our sample appear to choose what makes them happy more than they do in the Cornell study.12 This conclusion is con…rmed by looking at the distribution of reversals. In the Cornell study, 82 percent of the subjects had a reversal in at least one scenario (see BHKR’s Web Appendix, p43). The corresponding fraction in our sample is 38 percent (Figure 1 shows the histogram of the number of reversals across individuals in our sample). One obvious di¤erence with the Cornell sample is that our respondents are older on average. In the Appendix, we calculate Table 1 for respondents under the age of 30, and …nd very similar results to those shown here, with an average concordance of 86% and a range of 83-89% across scenarios (third column of Table 6). 11 BHKR, Table 2, excluding the Apple vs. Orange scenario that was designed to generate no reversals. Including that scenario yields an average of concordance of 78%. 12 This conclusion is una¤ected by excluding the scenario with the largest fraction of reversals from the Cornell study, or by excluding/including the Apple vs. Orange test scenario in both studies. 18 Table 6: Comparison with BHKR’s Cornell study BHKR: Cornell SWB question In the few minutes immediately after making the choice, which option do you think would make you feel better in terms of your own happiness? Taking all things together, which option do you think would make your life as a whole better in terms of your own happiness? yes 9 333-409 South Africa (Table 1) South Africa, under 30 only (Table 10) Between these two options, in the few minutes immediately after making the choice, which option do you think would make you feel better in terms of your own happiness? Indi¤erence allowed yes yes Number of scenarios 7 7 Number of observa921-953 109-114 tions Frequency of reversals 16-38 10-16 11-17 (%) Average frequency of 23 13 14 reversals (%) 21 Average frequency of reversals without Interest vs. Career (%) Average frequency of 22 13 15 reversals including Apple vs. Orange (%) Notes: BHKR’s Cornell study summarized based on Table 2 in BHKR (2012). Number of observations and Frequency of reversals are per scenario. Interest vs. Career is the scenario in BHKR yielding the largest fraction of reversals. 19 Determinants of choice. Turning to the various determinants of choices (Table 2), our …ndings show some di¤erences compared to those observed for the US (BHKR, Table 3). First, the R2 of the univariate regression of choice on happiness is smaller in the BHKR study (38% vs. 49%). This con…rms the stronger association between happiness and choice documented in the previous section. Second, and more importantly, in BHKR the explanatory power of SWB for choice changed little when other factors were included in the regression. This indicates that the correlation between the various life goals is smaller in their sample. This can be con…rmed directly by regressing own happiness on other goals in the BHKR data: for all scenarios pooled, this yields an R2 of 0.27, compared to 0.86 in the …rst column of our Table 3. Among our respondents happiness and other life goals seem to be more closely aligned than in BHKR’s sample. In everyday life, people’s choices are more likely to maximize their subjective well-being when other goals are not in con‡ict with it. Therefore, to the extent that our …ndings generalize to a su¢ ciently large set of actual choices faced in everyday life, we expect people in South Africa to exhibit higher levels of happiness than in the US. We can test for this directly using the BHKR data and our study. In both surveys respondents were asked, separately from the choice scenarios, to rate their actual level of happiness, as well as how they felt in terms of their other goals.13 Table 7 presents the average ratings in the South African and US samples on a 1-10 scale (1=bad, 10=good). As can be seen, in spite of their very di¤erent circumstances, people in South Africa report signi…cantly higher levels of subjective well-being (“Own happiness”). This makes sense if, compared to the US, trade-o¤s between the various life goals in this population are less of a constraint to the maximization of subjective well-being. Heterogeneity. As already mentioned above, both in BHKR and our study SWB seems to be a stronger determinant of choices in scenarios that are closest to decisions respondents are likely to actually face. In terms of heterogeneity across individuals, BHKR do not …nd individual characteristics to be important determinants of reversals, with the exception that black respondents in the Cornell sample are signi…cantly more likely to exhibit reversals. By contrast, in Table 5 we found several characteristics that were associated with reversals. However, these …ndings are not easily comparable because (i) our sample has no variation in respondents’race (everyone is black), and (ii) BHKR’s regressions do not include some of the characteristics which we found to be signi…cant (marital status and number of children). 13 “Thinking about how you felt today, how would you rate ... your own happiness / your family’s happiness / etc.” 20 Table 7: How respondents currently feel about their various life goals in South Africa vs. the US Own happniess Family happiness Health Life’s level of romance Social life Control over your life Life’s level of spirituality Life’s level of fun Social status Life’s nonboringness Physical comfort Sense of purpose South Africa N Mean 961 8.414 (0.062) 961 7.946 (0.068) 961 7.580 (0.072) 961 7.006 (0.079) 961 7.061 (0.070) 961 7.532 (0.068) 961 7.615 (0.068) 961 7.010 (0.072) 961 7.066 (0.075) 962 7.058 (0.078) 962 7.707 (0.071) 961 8.301 (0.066) Cornell N Mean 415 7.636 (0.073) 415 7.455 (0.082) 414 7.860 (0.083) 415 6.101 (0.124) 414 7.292 (0.087) 414 7.254 (0.088) 413 6.015 (0.118) 413 7.249 (0.087) 414 7.072 (0.085) 414 7.147 (0.091) 413 7.659 (0.077) 415 7.520 (0.090) Di¤erence p-value 0.0000 0.0000 0.0220 0.0000 0.0572 0.0198 0.0000 0.0534 0.9624 0.5019 0.6882 0.0000 Notes: Each goal was rated on a 10 point scale. The …rst two columns refer to our South African data, the following two to the comparable US survey in BHKR (Cornell sample). The US data is available at http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.102.5.2083. Standard errors in parentheses. The last column is the p-value for the equality-of-means t-test. 21 4.3.2 Denver and CNSS studies As discussed above, BHKR’s Denver and CNSS studies have fewer elements in common with our design. One potentially important di¤erence is that the happiness question in these samples did not allow respondents to indicate indi¤erence. Thus, in these studies indi¤erent respondents were forced to indicate either a choice-SWB reversal or a concordance (or say that they don’t know or leave the question blank). To obtain at least suggestive comparisons, we also included a happiness question without the indi¤erence option in our survey. As in the Denver and CNSS studies, this was included as a stand-alone question not grouped together with the other 11 life goals. Responses were on a 6-point scale which we transform to a binary scale as above.14 Our …ndings for this question are in Table 11 in the Appendix. Compared to the results in Table 1 where indi¤erence was allowed, we now …nd more concordance in every scenario. The average concordance is 93 percent with a range of 90-94 percent across scenarios. This mirrors BHKR’s …ndings, who see more concordance in the Denver and CNSS studies than in the Cornell sample where indi¤erence was allowed. Our …ndings suggest that removing the indi¤erence option in the happiness question may force some respondents to indicate concordance. The comparison with the Denver and CNSS studies is summarized in Tables 8 and 9. Comparing the Denver and CNSS results to our no-indi¤erence results, we again …nd more concordance in the South African sample. Combining all treatments in the Denver study, the average choice-SWB concordance was 85 percent (calculated from BHKR, Table 2).15 The CNSS study included a single scenario (Sleep vs. Income), with a concordance of 92 percent. In our sample, the concordance for this scenario was 95 percent - a small, but statistically signi…cant di¤erence. Qualitatively, these results show a similar pattern to the Cornell study: respondents in our survey appear to choose what makes them happy more often than they did in BHKR. 5 Robustness Following BHKR, we checked the robustness of our …ndings to three types of questionnaire e¤ects (cf. BHKR, Section IV). Detailed tables for this section are in the Appendix. First, as in BHKR’s Denver study, we wanted to check whether respondent fatigue may have resulted 14 This is the same scale that was used in the Denver study. In the CNSS study, the scale was binary. Recall that the Denver study includes a life satisfaction question which BHKR found to yield signi…cantly more concordance than the felt happiness question. Excluding the life satisfaction question yields 83% concordance in the Denver sample (calculated from BHKR’s data posted at http://dx.doi.org/10.1257/aer.102.5.2083). 15 22 Table 8: Comparison with BHKR’s Denver study SWB question BHKR: Denver South Africa (Table 11) Which do you think would make you more satis…ed with life, all things considered? Taking all things together, which do you think would give you a happier life as a whole? During a typical week, which do you think would make you feel happier? No 6 420-425 10-19 15 Which do you think would make you feel happier? Indi¤erence allowed No Number of scenarios 7 Number of observations 961-965 Frequency of reversals (%) 5-9 Average frequency of re7 versals (%) 7 Average frequency of reversals including Apple vs. Orange (%) 17 Average frequency of reversals excluding life satisfaction question (%) Notes: BHKR’s Denver study summarized based on Table 2 in BHKR (2012). Number of observations and Frequency of reversals are per scenario. The last row reports average reversals in the Denver study excluding respondents who were asked the …rst version of the SWB question. Table 9: Comparison with BHKR’s CNSS study BHKR: CNSS SWB question South Africa (Table 11, column 1) Which do you think would give you a happier life as a whole? No 1 (Sleep vs. income) 972 8 Which do you think would make you feel happier? Indi¤erence allowed No Number of scenarios 1 (Sleep vs. income) Number of observations 961 Frequency of reversals (%) 5 p-value for equal reversals 0.01 Notes: BHKR’s CNSS study summarized based on Table 2 in BHKR (2012). The last row reports a t-test for the hypothesis that the frequency of reversals in the two studies is the same. 23 in scenario-order e¤ects. To this end, we reversed the order of the scenarios and checked whether choices were a¤ected. We …nd that average choices in the reversed questionnaires are not statistically di¤erent for 7 out of the 8 scenarios, whether we measure choice on a binary scale or on the 6 point scale. We can also compare respondents’choices for scenarios that were asked in the …rst half of the survey vs. for scenarios asked later. We …nd a small tendency for respondents to favor option 2 more for scenarios asked later: 50% vs. 53% (p = 0:06). We …nd a similar tendency for SWB (55% vs. 57%) but this di¤erence is not statistically signi…cant (p = 0:21). Overall these order e¤ects are even smaller than those found in BHKR, perhaps re‡ecting the fact that respondent fatigue was less prevalent in our surveyor-administered surveys. Like in BHKR, order e¤ects did not a¤ect the frequency of choice-SWB reversals: we …nd reversals in 8% of cases regardless of scenario order (p = 0:91). Second, in one version of the questionnaire we reversed the presentation of the various life goals, so that the own happiness question came last. This is to make sure that life goals introduced earlier were not mechanically more correlated with choices. Regressing choice on happiness and the 11 other life goals for these observations yields similar results to those seen above. Own happiness is highly correlated with choice when entered on its own, but its coe¢ cient drops dramatically without a large change in the R2 of the regression when the other variables are entered as well. This again indicates a strong correlation between the respondents’ various life goals in this sample. Like BHKR, we do see a change in the magnitude of some of the individual coe¢ cients depending on the order in which life goals were listed. However, this does not tend to a¤ect which life goals are statistically signi…cant in explaining choices. Finally, in one version of the questionnaire, we asked the stand-alone SWB question before the choice question. Thus, we prompted respondents to think about happiness before thinking about choice. We wanted to know if this could a¤ect how respondents would choose and whether they would exhibit a choice-SWB reversals. We did not …nd this to be the case. In most cases, the fraction of respondents choosing one option over the other did not change by more than one or two percentage points when the SWB question was asked …rst. We only …nd a statistically signi…cant di¤erence in 1 out of 8 scenarios.16 Similarly, there was no signi…cant di¤erence in the average number of reversals exhibited by a respondent.17 16 For the Fun vs. Debt scenario the 5 percentage point di¤erence in the fraction of responses is only marginally insigni…cant, with a p-value of 0.15. 17 BHKR perform this robustness check in their Cornell study where the SWB response scale includes the indi¤erence option. Since our stand-alone SWB question did not include indi¤erence, the two robustness checks are not directly comparable. In general, neither BHKR nor we …nd evidence that asking about SWB before or after asking about choice has large e¤ects on the results. 24 6 Discussion We investigated happiness and other determinants of choices in a developing country. We presented respondents in South African townships with hypothetical choice scenarios and asked about their choices as well as which option they would prefer along a variety of dimensions. We found that people mostly choose what makes them feel happy. In addition, respondents perceive little con‡ict between happiness and other important determinants of choice such as sense of purpose and family happiness. The …ndings show some di¤erences relative to those found by BHKR in US samples, suggesting that there might be relevant di¤erences between developed and developing countries. More broadly, our results highlight a potentially important dimension of heterogeneity: not only can people have di¤erent goals when making choices, they can also di¤er in the degree to which these various goals are in con‡ict with each-other. A possible interpretation of our …ndings is suggested by the literature on hedonic adaptation (Frederick and Loewenstein, 1999; Loewenstein and Ubel, 2008). It is well documented that people’s hedonic experiences adapt to changing life circumstances, such as increased income or disability. Some of this adaptation is passive, embodied in the basis of comparison (as when the sick experience life’s “little pleasures”more intensively than the healthy). However, adaptation can also be active, embodied in the choices that people make. For example, time-use studies show that one’s circumstances a¤ect day-to-day activities and the resulting ‡ow of happy experiences (Krueger et al., 2009; Knabe et al., 2009).18 Development economists have also noted that such adaptation may be important: “These three men all lived in small houses without water or sanitation. They struggled to …nd work, and to give their children a good education. But they all had a television, a parabolic antenna, a DVD player, and a cell phone. Generally, it is clear that things that make life less boring are a priority for the poor.” (Banerjee and Du‡o, 2011, p36). The pronounced happiness-seeking behavior we observe in the South African sample may re‡ect adaptation to life among the poor. The lack of ample resources to improve one’s life may be compensated, to some extent, by attaching a higher weight to happiness in decision making. 18 Similarly, Maslow’s (1943) concept of a hierarchy of needs would suggest that the goals people seek adapt to their circumstances, with higher level goals (e.g., self-ful…lment) becoming more desirable as lower level goals (e.g., physical safety) are attained. 25 Social status Nonboringness Comfort Purpose .3 .1 .2 .3 .1 .2 .3 .1 .2 .3 .1 .2 .3 .4 .1 .2 .3 .4 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 .3 5 .2 4 .1 3 0 2 .4 1 0 .1 .2 .3 7 .3 6 .2 5 .1 4 0 3 .3 2 .2 1 .1 7 0 6 .3 5 .2 4 .1 3 0 2 0 .05 .1 .15 .2 .25 1 0 .05 .1 .15 .2 .25 26 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 0 .05 .1 .15 .2 3 0 .05 .1 .15 .2 .25 2 0 .05 .1 .15 .2 1 0 .05 .1 .15 .2 0 .1 .2 .3 6 0 .05 .1 .15 .2 5 0 .05 .1 .15 .2 4 0 .05 .1 .15 .2 3 0 .05 .1 .15 .2 2 0 .05 .1 .15 .2 1 0 .05 .1 .15 .2 0 .1 .2 .3 .4 .5 .2 .3 0 .1 .2 .3 0 .1 .2 .3 .4 .5 0 .1 .2 .3 .4 .5 .1 .2 .3 .4 .1 Fun versus Debt 0 .05 .1 .15 .2 .25 0 .1 .2 .3 .4 5 0 .1 .2 .3 .4 4 0 .1 .2 .3 .4 3 0 .1 .2 .3 .4 2 .1 .2 .3 .4 1 0 7 .3 6 .2 5 .1 4 0 3 .3 2 .2 1 .1 7 0 6 .3 5 .2 4 .1 3 0 2 .3 1 .2 6 .1 5 0 4 .3 3 .2 2 .1 1 0 0 .1 .2 .3 .4 .5 0 0 Friends versus Money 0 .1 .2 .3 .4 .4 1 .1 .2 .3 7 0 6 .4 5 0 .1 .2 .3 4 .3 3 .2 2 .1 1 0 7 .3 6 .2 5 .1 4 0 3 .3 2 .2 1 .1 7 0 6 0 .05 .1 .15 .2 .25 5 0 .05 .1 .15 .2 .25 4 .3 3 .2 2 .1 1 0 6 0 .05 .1 .15 .2 .25 5 .3 4 .2 3 .1 2 0 1 .1 .2 .3 .4 .1 .2 .3 .4 .3 Friends versus Income 0 0 6 0 .05 .1 .15 .2 .25 5 0 .05 .1 .15 .2 4 .3 3 .2 .3 2 .1 .2 1 0 .1 .2 Time .1 .2 .3 .4 0 .1 0 .1 .2 .3 .4 .5 0 0 .1 .2 .3 .4 .5 Money versus 0 0 .05 .1 .15 .2 .25 3 0 .05 .1 .15 .2 .25 2 0 .05 .1 .15 .2 1 0 .05 .1 .15 .2 6 0 .05 .1 .15 .2 5 0 .05 .1 .15 .2 4 0 .05 .1 .15 .2 .25 3 0 .05 .1 .15 .2 .3 2 0 .05 .1 .15 .2 .2 1 0 .05 .1 .15 .2 .1 0 .1 .2 .3 .4 .5 0 0 .1 .2 .3 .4 .5 Sleep versus Income 0 .05 .1 .15 .2 .25 .4 2 .1 .2 .3 1 0 7 .4 6 .2 .3 5 0 .1 4 .3 3 .2 2 .1 1 0 7 .3 .4 6 0 .1 .2 5 .3 4 .2 3 .1 2 0 1 .3 .4 7 .1 .2 6 0 5 .3 4 .2 3 .1 2 0 0 .05 .1 .15 .2 .25 0 1 .4 0 .05 .1 .15 .2 .25 0 .1 .2 .3 6 .2 .3 0 .05 .1 .15 .2 .25 0 5 0 .1 0 .05 .1 .15 .2 .25 0 4 0 .05 .1 .15 .2 .25 0 .05 .1 .15 .2 0 3 .3 .4 0 .05 .1 .15 .2 0 2 0 .1 .2 0 .05 .1 .15 .2 0 .05 .1 .15 .2 .25 1 0 .1 .2 .3 .4 0 .05 .1 .15 .2 .2 Fun .1 Spirituality 0 .05 .1 .15 .2 .25 0 Control 0 .05 .1 .15 .2 .25 Social life 0 .05 .1 .15 .2 .3 Romance .2 Health .1 Family happiness 0 .05 .1 .15 .2 .25 0 Own happiness .1 .2 .3 .4 Choice 0 7 Appendix Figure 2: Histograms of choice, SWB and other life goals, by scenario Money versus Time, v2 Abs. Inc. versus Rel. Inc. 1 2 3 4 5 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 Apple versus Orange 6 1 2 3 4 5 6 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 27 10.53 5.26 0 0.2379 114 5.31 0 0.6072 113 32.46 69.91 7.96 Money versus Time % 61.75 Sleep versus Income % 16.81 0 0.5811 114 4.39 7.02 74.56 Friends versus Income % 14.04 1.75 1.0000 112 6.25 7.14 28.57 Friends/Family versus Money % 58.04 0.88 0.3593 113 6.19 10.62 45.13 Fun versus Duty % 38.05 3.51 1.0000 109 5.50 6.42 33.03 Money versus Time, v. 2 % 55.05 0.88 0.3323 113 5.31 9.73 12.39 Abs. Inc. versus rel. inc. % 72.57 2.63 0.0015 111 2.70 16.22 33.33 Apple versus Orange % 47.75 Notes: For each scenario, the …rst four rows present the distribution of responses among those who did not indicate indi¤erence for the SWB question. The fraction of indi¤erent SWB responses is indicated in the …fth row. The Liddell test tests the hypothesis that the average choice response is equal to the average SWB response for paired data. The text of each scenario appears in the Appendix. Higher SWB: Option 1 Chosen: Option 1 Higher SWB: Option 2 Chosen: Option 2 Higher SWB: Option 2 Chosen: Option 1 Higher SWB: Option 1 Chosen: Option 2 Indi¤erence for SWB p-value of Liddell Exact Test N Choice scenario Table 10: Choice and SWB responses across scenarios among respondents under the age of 30 28 Money versus Time % 56.22 35.37 4.88 3.53 0.1821 964 Sleep versus Income % 18.42 76.69 4.16 0.73 0.0000 961 0.0000 960 0.94 3.96 78.02 Friends versus Income % 17.08 0.0001 965 2.38 6.01 48.6 Friends/Family versus Money % 43.01 0.0000 961 1.87 6.87 60.25 Fun versus Debt % 31.01 0.0000 961 0.94 4.68 27.16 Money versus Time, v. 2 % 67.22 0.0000 963 1.04 4.47 22.95 Abs. Inc. versus rel. inc. % 71.55 0.0000 962 2.39 7.59 37.73 Apple versus Orange % 52.29 Notes: The table presents the distribution of choice and SWB responses on a binary scale using the stand-alone SWB question. Responses were on a 6-point scale with no allowance for indi¤erence. The Liddell test tests the hypothesis that the average choice response is equal to the average SWB response for paired data. The text of each scenario appears in the Appendix. Higher SWB: Option 1 Chosen: Option 1 Higher SWB: Option 2 Chosen: Option 2 Higher SWB: Option 2 Chosen: Option 1 Higher SWB: Option 1 Chosen: Option 2 p-value of Liddell Exact Test N Choice scenario Table 11: Choice and SWB responses across scenarios, stand-alone SWB question 29 Sleep versus Income -0.278** (0.114) -0.004 (0.005) -0.151 (0.338) -0.721** (0.327) 0.088 (0.131) -0.017 (0.050) 0.010 (0.037) 0.132 (0.271) -0.205 (0.278) -0.811 (0.601) 0.300 (0.187) 939 Money versus Time -0.216** (0.107) -0.005 (0.005) -0.104 (0.321) -0.354 (0.236) -0.040 (0.123) -0.005 (0.046) 0.053 (0.036) 0.433 (0.264) -0.040 (0.271) -0.279 (0.554) 0.064 (0.175) 937 Friends versus Income -0.425*** (0.116) -0.010* (0.005) -0.279 (0.346) -0.835** (0.341) -0.157 (0.132) 0.044 (0.048) -0.016 (0.038) 0.587* (0.312) 0.040 (0.326) 0.481 (0.707) -0.110 (0.215) 936 Friends/Family versus Money -0.177 (0.109) -0.009* (0.005) -0.087 (0.330) -0.035 (0.219) 0.044 (0.126) 0.054 (0.046) 0.062* (0.036) 0.220 (0.264) -0.030 (0.274) -0.177 (0.623) 0.105 (0.192) 924 Fun versus Debt -0.102 (0.108) -0.018*** (0.005) -0.191 (0.335) -0.920*** (0.334) -0.105 (0.126) 0.045 (0.046) 0.127*** (0.036) -0.069 (0.264) -0.454* (0.272) -0.449 (0.694) 0.185 (0.211) 937 Money versus Time, v. 2 -0.030 (0.119) -0.021*** (0.006) 0.125 (0.325) 0.153 (0.241) -0.028 (0.148) -0.049 (0.049) 0.087** (0.037) 0.338 (0.299) 0.178 (0.309) -1.514** (0.698) 0.515** (0.214) 928 Abs. Inc. versus Rel. inc. -0.067 (0.116) -0.015** (0.006) -0.204 (0.365) -0.580* (0.326) -0.008 (0.138) -0.015 (0.047) 0.091** (0.038) 0.200 (0.308) -0.144 (0.316) 0.577 (0.624) -0.145 (0.192) 942 Apple versus Orange 0.019 (0.107) -0.013*** (0.005) 0.313 (0.281) -0.349 (0.279) 0.034 (0.124) -0.047 (0.045) 0.101*** (0.036) 0.338 (0.295) 0.067 (0.307) -1.149* (0.595) 0.312* (0.185) 911 Notes: The dependent variable is an indicator equal to 1 if the respondent exhibited a reversal in the given scenario. ‘Primary school’is 1 if the respondent’s highest level of completed education is primary school; ‘High school’is 1 if it is high school or above. Income is measured in logs and predicted based on ownership of household appliances as described in the text. All regressions include a constant. Robust standard errors in parentheses. ***,**,* denote signi…cance at the 1, 5, and 10 percent, respectively. Observations Income squared Income High school Primary school Number of children Number of adults in the HH Single Widowed Divorced Age Male Choice scenario Table 12: Reversals and respondent characteristics, probit regressions Table 13: Robustness: Choices with reordered scenarios Scenario Sleep vs. Income Money vs. Time Friends vs. Income Friends/Family vs. Money Fun vs. Debt Money vs. Time, v.2 Abs. Inc. vs. Rel. Inc. Apple vs. Orange Average choice (binary) All Scenarios reordered 1.77 1.77 1.39 1.46 1.79 1.77 1.51 1.49 1.62 1.62 1.28 1.25 1.24 1.21 1.40 1.37 Di¤erence p-value 0.95 0.03 0.49 0.50 0.92 0.31 0.33 0.44 Average choice (6-point) All Scenarios reordered 4.73 4.84 3.20 3.46 4.81 4.79 3.63 3.59 4.04 4.04 2.46 2.33 2.43 2.28 3.14 3.07 Di¤erence p-value 0.39 0.06 0.86 0.80 1.00 0.32 0.26 0.64 Notes: For each scenario, the table displays the average responses to the choice questions for all observations as well as for observations where the order of the scenarios was reversed. The p-value is for the equality-of-means t-test. 30 Table 14: Robustness: Regressions of choice on SWB and other goals, with goals reordered Own happniess (1) 0.501*** (0.015) Family happiness Health Life’s level of romance Social life Control over your life Life’s level of spirituality Life’s level of fun Social status Life’s nonboringness Physical comfort Sense of purpose Observations R2 1886 0.3987 (2) 0.177*** (0.046) 0.078* (0.046) 0.037 (0.046) 0.026 (0.045) -0.013 (0.040) -0.055 (0.039) 0.027 (0.043) 0.095** (0.045) -0.190*** (0.041) 0.006 (0.054) 0.359*** (0.045) 1886 0.4547 (3) 0.165*** (0.053) 0.107** (0.054) 0.040 (0.046) 0.019 (0.047) 0.011 (0.045) -0.027 (0.040) -0.054 (0.038) 0.023 (0.042) 0.080* (0.047) -0.190*** (0.041) 0.020 (0.054) 0.341*** (0.045) 1886 0.4594 Notes: OLS regressions for observations where the presentation of the various life goals was reversed for each scenario. The dependent variable is choice on a 6-point scale, all independent variables are on a 7-point scale. Variables are demeaned at the scenario level. Robust standard errors in parentheses. ***, **, * denote signi…cance at the 1, 5, and 10 percent, respectively. 31 Table 15: Robustness: Choices with reordered choice and SWB questions Scenario Sleep vs. Income Money vs. Time Friends vs. Income Friends/Family vs. Money Fun vs. Debt Money vs. Time, v.2 Abs. Inc. vs. Rel. Inc. Apple vs. Orange Average choice (binary) SWB All before choice 1.77 1.80 1.39 1.39 1.79 1.85 1.51 1.49 1.62 1.67 1.28 1.29 1.24 1.24 1.40 1.42 Di¤erence p-value 0.37 0.95 0.05 0.54 0.15 0.90 0.98 0.53 Average choice (6-point) SWB All before choice 4.73 4.63 3.20 3.13 4.81 4.89 3.63 3.40 4.04 4.12 2.46 2.41 2.43 2.29 3.14 3.10 Di¤erence p-value 0.40 0.63 0.52 0.11 0.58 0.71 0.29 0.77 Notes: For each scenario, the table displays the average responses to the choice questions for all observations as well as for observations where the stand-alone SWB question was asked …rst. The p-value is for the equality-of-means t-test. 32 7.1 Choice scenarios in the survey Scenario 1: Sleep vs. Income Suppose that you have to decide between two new jobs. The jobs are exactly the same in almost every way, but have di¤erent work hours and pay di¤erent amounts. Option 1: A job paying R 6,000 per month. The hours for this job are reasonable, and you would be able to get about 7.5 hours of sleep on the average work night. Option 2: A job paying R 10,000 per month. However, this job requires you to go to work at unusual hours, and you would only be able to sleep around 6 hours on the average work night. Scenario 2: Money vs. Time Imagine that the school your child goes to (suppose you have one), implements a “student activity fee”of R 60 per week to help pay for maintenance of facilities and cleaning. However, the school allows you to not pay the fee if instead you put in 2 hours of work a week at the school helping with minor repairs or cleaning. You face two options: Option 1: Spend 2 hours each week with school service. Option 2: Pay R 60 each week. Scenario 3: Friends vs. Income Imagine that you have been reassigned at your job, and will be moved to a new location. There are two o¢ ces where you could request to work. One o¢ ce is in the town where many of your friends happen to be live, and pays 4800. The other o¢ ce is in a town where you don’t know anyone, and pays R 6600. Your job will be exactly the same at either o¢ ce. You must decide between the following two options: Option 1: Make R 4800 and move to the town where your friends are. Option 2: Make R 6600 and move to a town where you don’t know anyone. Scenario 4: Friends/Family vs. Money Imagine that one of your closest friends moved to a di¤erent city three years ago. You recently received an invitation to his/her wedding where many of your mutual friends will attend. You face two options. Would you choose to go to the wedding if you had to buy a R 700 round-trip bus ticket and travel 8 hours each way to get there? Option 1: Go the wedding, which requires a R 700 round trip bus ticket. Option 2: Miss the wedding, but save the money. Scenario 5: Fun vs. Debt Suppose this month you received an extra R 150 in your paycheck. 33 Option 1: I would use the money to treat myself and my family to a nicer meal than usual. Option 2: I would save the money and pay o¤ my utility bill balance or other debt. Scenario 6: Money vs. Time, version 2 Suppose your employer wants to give you a bonus. Option 1: R 300 now. Option 2: R 350 in three months. Scenario 7: Absolute Income vs. Relative Income Say you are considering a new job, and have o¤ers from two companies. Even though all aspects of the two jobs are identical, employees’ salaries are di¤erent across the two companies. Everyone in each company knows the other employees’ salaries. You must choose one of the two companies, which means you must decide between the following two options: Option 1: Your monthly income is R 15,000, while on average others at your level earn R 17,500. Option 2: Your monthly income is R 14,000 while on average others at your level earn R 11,500. Scenario 8: Apple vs. Orange Suppose you are checking out a new supermarket that just opened near where you live. As you walk by the fresh fruit display, you are o¤ered your choice of a free snack: Option 1: A freshly sliced apple. Option 2: A freshly sliced orange. The following pictures illustrate the presentation of the scenarios in the survey. 34 35 36 References [1] Appleton, S., and L. Song (2008): “Life satisfaction in urban China: Components and determinants,”World Development 36, 2325-2340. [2] Banerjee, A.V., and E. Du‡o (2011): Poor Economics, New York, NY: Public A¤airs. [3] Benjamin, D.J., O. He¤etz, M.S. Kimball, and A. Rees-Jones (2012): “What Do You Think Would Make You Happier? What Do You Think You Would Choose?”American Economic Review 102(5), 2083–2110. [4] Benjamin, D.J., O. He¤etz, M.S. Kimball, and N. Szembrot (2014). “Beyond Happiness and Satisfaction: Toward Well-Being Indices Based on Stated Preference.” American Economic Review, 104(9), 2698-2735. [5] Clark, D.A. (2003): “Concepts and Perceptions of Human Well-being: Some Evidence from South Africa,”Oxford Development Studies 31(2), 173-196. [6] Deaton, A., J. Fortson, and R. Tortora (2010): “Life (evaluation), HIV/AIDS, and death in Africa,”in: E. Diener, D. Kahneman, and J. F., Helliwell (eds.): International di¤erences in well-being, pp. 105-136, Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press. [7] Di Tella, R., and R. MacCulloch (2008): “Gross national happiness as an answer to the Easterlin Paradox?”Journal of Development Economics 86, 22–42. [8] Diener, E., and S. Oishi (2004): “Are Scandinavians Happier Than Asians? Issues in Comparing Nations on Subjective Well-Being,”in: F. Columbus (ed.): Asian Economic and Political Issues, Vol 10, Hauppauge, NY: Nova Science Publishers. [9] Diener, E., D. Kahneman, W. Tov, and R. Arora (2010): “Income’s association with judgments of life versus feelings,” in: E. Diener, D. Kahneman, and J. F., Helliwell (eds.): International di¤erences in well-being, pp. 3-15, Oxford, UK: Oxford University Press. [10] Frederick, S. and G. Loewenstein (1999): “Hedonic Adaptation,”in: D. Kahneman, E. Diener, and N. Schwarz (eds.): Well Being: The Foundations of Hedonic Psychology, p302-329, New York, NY: Russell Sage Foundation Press. [11] Fontaine, X., and K. Yamada (2014): “Caste Comparisons in India: Evidence From Subjective Well-Being Data,”World Development 64, 407–419. 37 [12] Hansen, T. (2012): “Parenthood and Happiness: a Review of Folk Theories Versus Empirical Evidence,”Social Indicators Research 108, 29–64. [13] Hsee, C.K., J. Zhang, F. Yu, and Y. Xi (2003): “Lay Rationalism and Inconsistency Between Predicted Experience and Decision,” Journal of Behavioral Decision Making 16(4), 257–72. [14] Kingdon, G., and J. Knight (2007): “Community, comparisons and subjective well-being in a divided society,”Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization 64, 69-90. [15] Knabe, A., S. Ratzel, R. Schob, and J. Weimann (2009): “Dissatis…ed with life but having a good day: Time-use and well-being of the unemployed,” Economic Journal 120, September, 867–889. [16] Krueger, A.B., D. Kahneman, C. Fischler, D. Schkade, N. Schwarz, and A.A. Stone (2009): “Time Use and Subjective Well-Being in France and the U.S.”Social Indicators Research 93(1), 7-18. [17] Layard, R. (2006): “Happiness and public policy: A challenge to the profession,” Economic Journal 116, March, C24–C33. [18] Loewenstein, G., and P.A. Ubel (2008): “Hedonic adaptation and the role of decision and experience utility in public policy,”Journal of Public Economics 92, 1795–1810. [19] Maslow, A.H. (1943): “A theory of human motivation,” Psychological Review 50, 370396. [20] Ravallion, M., and M. Lokshin (2002): “Self-rated economic welfare in Russia,” European Economic Review 46(8), 1453-1473. [21] Ry¤, C.D. (1989): Happiness is everything, or is it? Explorations on the meaning of psychological well-being,” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology 37(6), 10691081. [22] Sivela, J. (2012): “Infected Condoms and Pin-Pricked Oranges: An Ethnographic Study of AIDS Legends in Two Townships in Cape Town,”Cultural Analysis 11, 45-66. [23] Stanca, L. (2012): “Su¤er the little children: Measuring the e¤ects of parenthood on well-being worldwide,”Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization 81, 742–750. 38 [24] Stillman, S., J. Gibson, D. McKenzie, and H. Rohorua (2015): “Miserable Migrants? Natural Experiment Evidence on International Migration and Objective and Subjective Well-Being,”World Development 65, 79–93. [25] Szabó, A., and G. Ujhelyi (2015): “Reducing nonpayment for public utilities: Experimental evidence from South Africa,”Journal of Development Economics, 117, 20-31. [26] Tversky, A., and D. Gri¢ n (1991): “Endowment and contrast in judgments of wellbeing,” in: F. Strack, M. Argyle, and N. Schwarz (eds.): Subjective Well-Being, p101118, Oxford, UK: Pergamon Press. [27] Wissing, M.P., S.M. Thekiso, R. Stapelberg, L. Van Quickelberge, P. Choabi, C. Moroeng, A. Nienaber, Q.M. Temane, and H.H. Vorster (2010): “Validation of three Setswana measures for psychological wellbeing,” South African Journal of Industrial Psychology 36(2), 1-8. 39