Analysis of Affordability of Cost Recovery: Communal and Network Energy Services September 30, 1998 By Clare T. Romanik The Urban Institute under contract to The World Bank EXECUTIVE SUMMARY The following analysis compares the housing-utility burden of Russian households under the current (1996) subsidized rate scheme with the burden they would experience under a rate scheme that would cover the full cost of providing the same services. Special attention is given to the relative impact of the new scheme on households in different expenditure categories and on households living in urban and rural areas. In this analysis, households are grouped into quintiles based on total expenditures, which serve as a proxy for income. The analysis uses a sample of households that is 68 percent urban, 6 percent PGT (poselok gorodskogo typa), and 26 percent rural (using GOSKOMSTAT settlement type definitions). Rural households comprise a disproportionate share (33 percent) of the households in the lowest quintile. In addition, households in the lowest quintile are much more likely to be one-to-two member households, to be composed of pensioners without working age adults, and to occupy more space per capita than households in the higher expenditure quintiles. By Western standards, housing and utility charges in Russia are very low— households in the highest expenditure quintile on average spend more money on alcohol and tobacco than on all housing-related costs. The mean combined housing-utility charge for the sample is 97 thousand rubles (19 US dollars at an exchange rate of 5000 rubles to $1); at full-cost recovery levels, the mean charge is 285 thousand rubles ($57). “Standard” units in the sample (with district heat and hot water, gas stove, central water and sewerage and telephone connections), were on average 49 square meters—one square meter larger than the overall sample mean; their higher mean charge of 371 thousand rubles ($74) reflects greater amenities. The analysis defines the housing-utility cost burden to be housing and utility charges as a share of total expenditures, and then uses this measure to illustrate how burdens increase with the introduction of full-cost recovery measures. A household paying out 20 to 29 percent of its expenditures on housing and utility services has a moderate burden; one paying 30 percent or more has a high burden. With full-cost recovery tariffs and no income growth, nearly all (97 percent) of the households in the lowest expenditure quintile have moderate or high burdens while only a few (8 percent) of the households in the highest expenditure quintile fall into this category. The share of the overall population with moderate or high burdens increases from 12 to 54 percent when tariffs increase to full-cost recovery levels. We can put the latter figures into perspective by comparing them with figures for the United States: according to the American Housing Survey for the United States in 1995, 54 percent of U.S. households had moderate or high burdens. However, the figures for Russia are not directly comparable because they overstate the housing-utility burden. The Russian sample comprises owners occupying their own unit and public renters paying below-market rent, and the market value of their housing is not counted as income. To assist households facing a moderate or high housing-utility burden, municipalities will have to set aside funds for housing allowances, distributed on a means-tested basis. i Despite the higher costs associated with operating a housing allowance program, raising tariffs to full-cost recovery levels will help municipalities balance their budgets. At 1996 tariffs, a municipality must provide an average annual effective subsidy of 2.6 million rubles ($513) per household because of low tariffs, housing benefits and housing allowances, and non-collection (arrears). If tariffs increase to full-cost recovery levels with zero income growth and the same levels of energy consumption, a municipality will still have to provide an average annual subsidy of 1.1 million rubles ($225) per household because of increased participation in the housing allowance program and continuing non-collection. However, this means that a municipality will be subsidizing only one-third of housing-utility costs (referred to as the subsidy burden of the municipality), as opposed to subsidizing threequarters of the costs under the current rate scheme. For a municipality with 50,000 households, the savings from lower subsidies annually amounts to 72.2 billion rubles ($14.4 million). Sensitivity analysis was performed to see how assumptions about income growth and energy conservation affect the housing-utility burdens faced by households and municipal subsidies. With 3 percent annual growth in real income from 1996 to 2003, the share of households with moderate or high burdens drops from 54 to 44 percent and the municipality’s subsidy burden drops from 33 to 28 percent. Assuming a modest decline in energy demand due to low-cost investments in energy conservation measures causes the share of households with moderate or high burdens to fall from 54 to 49 percent and the municipality’s subsidy burden to decrease from 33 to 30 percent of costs. Access to utility services is weakly correlated with expenditures, but strongly correlated with settlement type. Services like district heat, centrally-supplied hot water, and sewerage are available to most urban households; few rural households have this access to these services. The majority of rural households have to use coal for heating, bottled gas and coal for hot water, and bottled gas for cooking. At current tariffs, coal is the most expensive form of heating; however, cost recovery levels of coal are currently twice those for district heat and gas boiler heating on average. Reliance on fuels that already have higher cost recovery levels, helps explain why rural households experience smaller payment increases under a full-cost recovery scenario—both in terms of absolute and percentage increases. If rates are brought up to full-cost recovery levels, the average total housing-utility charge for rural households increases from 95 to 214 thousand rubles; the average total charge for urban households increases from 100 to 316 thousand rubles. Compared to households in the highest quintile, households in the lowest quintile experience similar smaller increases in total charges when housing-utility charges are brought up to full-cost recovery levels. The average charge for households in the lowest quintile increases from 69 to 195 thousand rubles; the average charge for households in the highest quintile increases from 128 to 397 thousand rubles. Households in higher quintiles will tend to have a greater increase because they typically occupy larger units and have more family members (both factors affecting housing and utility charges). ii Thirty percent of households in the sample reported that they had arrears in housing or utility bills. Since the incidence of arrears varies little by income, it indicates a serious problem of enforcement as opposed to a problem of households not having the ability to pay. Although the incidence of arrears does not vary much by settlement type, it can vary a lot for individual oblasts, krais, and cities. For example, default rates range from 8 percent in Moscow City to 71 percent in Kurgan, indicating real differences in the efforts or ability to control this problem. The average cumulative household arrearage (among those households in arrears) also varies by individual oblasts, krais, and cities, ranging from 15 to 450 thousand rubles ($3-90). Cumulative arrears are particularly high in PGT (about 400 thousand rubles per household on average), and are lowest in rural areas (about 186 thousand rubles per household on average). iii DESCRIPTION OF THE SAMPLE This analysis uses data from Round 7 of the RLMS (Russian Longitudinal Monitoring Survey), which was conducted in the last quarter of 1996.1 The original Round 7 sample had 3562 household records. After cleaning the data for this analysis, 2990 records remained. The original RLMS sample was designed to be representative of the population of the Russian Federation. The resulting sample after cleaning should also be representative of this population, except for the exclusion of households renting their units at market value.2 Using GOSKOMSTAT settlement type definitions, the resulting sample is 68% urban, 6% PGT (poselok gorodskogo typa), and 26% rural. The reader should carefully interpret statistics presented for PGT because of the relatively small number of cases in the PGT category. Household size does not vary by settlement type, having a median value of three persons for all settlement types. This is not a poverty study. Specialists in poverty studies measure current consumption because they are trying to assess the household’s welfare. Knowing that income will vary over a lifetime, the household saves. When current resources fall, the household may rely on savings to continue its habitual level of consumption. This is known as consumption smoothing. A poverty study would not consider money invested or put in savings because the household is, in effect, setting aside the money for future consumption. 1 In Round 7 of the RLMS, 77 percent of the interviews were held in October, 23 percent in November, and less than one percent in December 1996. See Poverty in Russia: Public Policy and Private Responses, (ed. Jeni Klugman), Washington, DC, The World Bank for a detailed description of the RLMS. 2 Annex 1 includes a detailed description of the process of cleaning the data and imputing unit characteristics. Cases were removed if they did not have pertinent information on expenditures, utility connections, or unit type, and this information could not be imputed. Also, all households renting on the secondary market (as opposed to renting from municipalities and enterprises) were excluded. Households that split were not included, because it could not be determined whether the new households resided in separate units or in the same housing unit. 1 This study measures income (including from past savings) because it is the current resources of the household that determine its ability to pay for housing and utility services. Household expenditures are used as a proxy for household income because of the problem of underreported income in surveys.3 For the sample as a whole, the average reported total expenditures is 50 percent more than the average reported total income. The variance between reported expenditures and income grows with wealth: average reported total expenditures for the highest expenditure quintile is twice the reported income; in the lowest expenditure quintile there is little difference between the reported figures. Questions on both income and expenditures were quite thorough in the RLMS.4 This together with the anonymity of the survey may have encouraged some households to reveal more income than they would to the government. The mean monthly income reported in the RLMS (1,192 thousand rubles) is 34 percent higher than the official mean monthly income (892 thousand rubles) for September 1997, nearly a year later. In addition to reported expenditures, total household expenditures include an imputed value for food produced and either consumed or given away by the household (imputed by the Carolina Population Center of the University of North Carolina, responsible for designing the RLMS) as well as an imputed value for housing and utility charges (imputed as part of this report). Households reported what they had paid in the past 30 days for housing and communal services; however, in this time they might have paid none of what they owed for that month, some of what they owed, exactly what they owed, or what they owed for that month plus past arrears. Thirty percent of the households reported that they were in arrears. In addition to arrears, many households were eligible for housing benefits because they were veterans, disabled or had an occupation designated as special. Other households were also participants in the new housing allowances program which targets subsidies to low-income households whose housing-utility burden is more than a certain percent of total income. Finally, some households might be paying up past arrears or building a stock of coal or firewood for the whole winter. Thus the reported value often does not correspond to the family’s usual housing-related liabilities. Table 1 compares imputed monthly housing and utility charges with those reported in the RLMS.5 Since most households spend a relatively small share of their budget on 3 For a discussion of problems encountered in measuring income with households surveys in Russia, see Poverty in Russia: Public Policy and Private Responses. One serious problem with measuring income in Russia is the common delay of salary payments. 4 Although the RLMS was quite thorough in its questions, it is very difficult to obtain the monetary value of many in-kind benefits that employees receive. For example, respondents were asked if they had received goods and services from their place of work. However, it is unlikely that respondents would cite benefits such as free lunches, subsidized food in schools and kindergartens managed by enterprises, and subsidized vacations. 5 The reported charges had three components: (1) a question on all charges for housing and communal services; (2) a question on purchases of coal, firewood, peat, kerosene; and (3) a question on purchases of bottled gas. The households were to report expenditures within the past 30 days. However, the 2 housing and utility charges, the imputation process does not greatly affect total expenditures. Annex 2 provides more information on the imputation process and a comparison of total expenditures based on the imputed and reported charges. Table 1 Comparison of Reported and Imputed Monthly Housing and Utility Charges, per Household (1996 Thousand Rubles) Methods for Estimating Housing and Utility Charges Reported total rent and utility expenditures Reported total rent and utility expenditures with 0 values excluded Imputed total rent and utility expenditures Minimum Value Median Value Mean Value Maximum Value 0.0 47.5 71.1 1,170.0 0.8 75.0 97.8 1,170.0 15.1 88.2 97.2 377.9 Table 2 shows that the mean monthly total expenditure level of the sample is 1,797 thousand rubles (1996 rubles). At an exchange rate of 5000 rubles to one US dollar this is $359. The median for the sample 1,152 thousand rubles, or $230. The mean expenditure level for rural households is below the sample average because they are overrepresented in the lowest quintile and underrepresented in the highest quintile. Although rural households make up 26 percent of the sample, they represent 33 percent of the households in the lowest expenditure quintile and only 17 percent of the households in the highest expenditure quintile. The opposite is true of urban households which are overrepresented in the highest quintile and underrepresented in the lowest quintile. The expenditure disparity among all households is high: the mean expenditure level of the lowest quintile (331 thousand rubles) is only 7 percent of the mean expenditure level of the highest quintile (4,912 thousand rubles). Table 2 Total Monthly Household Expenditures By Settlement Type (1996 Thousand Rubles) latter two categories are generally ‘lumpy’ purchases (purchased less frequently than on a monthly basis) so some households would report an amount much larger than that needed for one month, while others would report zero spending. These values were adjusted to a third of the reported amount to compensate. 3 All Households N = 2990 Urban N = 2024 PGT N = 188 Rural N = 778 All Households mean median 1,796.6 1,152.4 1,948.5 1,227.1 1,605.1 1,090.7 1,447.8 974.1 By Expenditure Quintile (mean) Lowest 2 3 4 Highest 331.0 727.2 1,161.9 1,851.2 4,912.0 335.4 725.9 1,167.3 1,870.2 5,041.7 336.2 737.6 1,180.3 1,823.6 4,238.6 321.8 728.0 1,142.5 1,809.2 4,573.9 Households in different expenditure quintiles tend to have different demographic characteristics. (See Table 3.) About 28 percent of all households in the sample could be called “pensioner” households. A pensioner household is defined here as a household with no working age adults (in a few cases, these households might include children under 18 years of age). Pensioner households make up 59 percent of the households in the lowest quintile and only 7 percent of the households in the highest quintile. Another difference concerns household size. Households in the lowest quintile on average have fewer than two household members, while the higher quintiles on average have more than three household members. This is to be expected, since a household’s income and expenditures should increase as it includes more working age adults. Table 3 Pensioner Households and Average Household Size by Expenditure Quintile Pensioner Households as a Percentage of all Households Average Household Size All Households 28 2.8 By Expenditure Quintile Lowest 2 3 4 Highest 59 32 25 17 7 1.9 2.5 2.9 3.3 3.5 Although households in the higher quintiles tend to have larger apartments, they tend to have less space per capita than households in the lower quintiles. (See Table 4.) The latter is true even for households that occupy only part of an apartment or house (the living space of these households, however, varies little by expenditure quintile).6 Table 3 6 The 10 percent of dwellings that were part of a house or apartment were much smaller on average 4 largely explains this counterintuitive result. Households in the lowest quintile tend to have fewer members and are more likely to be pensioners. Pensioners may reside in a unit that used to be occupied by themselves and their children who have since then moved into their own unit. This finding is counter to the approach of a poverty study which would rate these pensioners as not poor because their per capita consumption of housing, at least, is relatively high. From the perspective of housing reform, however, this finding is important because pensioners with relatively large apartments and relatively low income are facing a very real problem with respect to space-based fees that should be understood by policy makers. Table 4 Total Space and Space Per Capita by Expenditure Quintile and by Type of Space (Square Meters) Separate Apartment or House (Total Space) N = 2696 Part of Apartment or House (Living Space Occupied by Household) N = 294 Per Capita Total Total Per Capita All Households 50 22 32 14 By Expenditure Quintile Lowest 2 3 4 Highest 43 48 51 54 55 29 24 21 19 18 26 33 32 35 33 16 15 12 14 11 Table 5 describes the sample in terms of ownership and housing type. The sample contains 62 percent privatized, private, or cooperative housing units and 38 percent publicly-owned units. A large share (71 percent) of the units in the rural areas are private single-family houses. In urban areas, the housing units are overwhelmingly (88 percent) apartments, but are almost equally split between private (52 percent) and publicly-owned (48 percent) dwellings. Table 5 Distribution of Ownership and Unit Type of Housing Units, By Settlement Type All Households N = 2990 Privatized, Private or 61.8 Urban N = 2024 PGT N = 188 52.4 (32 square meters) than separate houses and apartments (50 square meters). 5 68.6 Rural N = 778 84.4 Table 5 Distribution of Ownership and Unit Type of Housing Units, By Settlement Type All Households N = 2990 Urban N = 2024 PGT N = 188 Rural N = 778 Cooperative Apartments Single Family Houses 33.0 28.8 41.1 11.4 26.1 42.6 13.6 70.8 Publicly-Owned 38.2 47.6 31.4 15.6 36.4 1.9 47.1 0.5 29.3 2.1 10.2 5.4 Apartments Single Family Houses UTILITY SERVICES AND CHARGES This analysis focuses on the utility component of housing-related costs. Table 6 shows that utility connections vary heavily by settlement type: for example, only 10 percent of rural households enjoy utility-supplied hot water, while 75 percent of urban households have this service. Central (district) heating is supplied to most (89 percent) urban households, but only to 21 percent of rural households. Because of these differences in utility connections, households from different settlement types are likely to be affected differently by a rise in utility tariffs. Table 6 Percent of Households with Utility Connections By Settlement Type Utility Service All Households N = 2990 Urban N = 2024 PGT N = 188 Rural N = 778 Central Heating 70 89 66 21 Network Gas 63 73 92 27 Hot Water 57 75 52 10 Central Water 76 90 81 39 Sewerage 66 87 47 17 Telephone 44 51 53 24 Table 7 shows that, in most cases, households in the highest quintile are more likely to have a utility connection than households in the lowest quintile. However, the relationship between wealth and utility connections is not as strong as the relationship between settlement type and utility connections. Network gas is the one utility service that does not appear to be related to income. This is because many households in the higher 6 quintiles have units equipped with electric stoves and thus have no need for gas connections. The weak correlation between income and access to utilities results from the past practice of administrative allocation of housing and the persistence of underdeveloped housing markets. Table 7 Percent of Households with Utility Connections, By Settlement Type and Expenditure Quintile Utility Service and Expenditure Quintile All Households N = 2990 Urban N = 2024 PGT N = 188 Rural N = 778 Central Heating Lowest 2 3 4 Highest 61 69 67 70 81 82 90 87 90 93 54 62 56 74 89 23 19 18 21 27 Network Gas Lowest 2 3 4 Highest 62 63 66 63 60 76 77 76 76 64 92 92 95 94 86 29 22 31 24 30 Hot Water Lowest 2 3 4 Highest 44 53 55 59 72 65 73 70 79 84 31 41 63 65 64 8 7 11 8 20 Central Water Lowest 2 3 4 Highest 64 76 77 77 87 80 91 91 92 95 62 77 93 81 92 34 36 36 41 51 Sewerage Lowest 2 3 4 Highest 56 65 65 68 77 79 89 85 88 92 31 38 51 58 61 19 14 15 18 19 Telephone Connection Lowest 2 3 32 43 43 39 50 49 33 44 63 19 26 23 7 Table 7 Percent of Households with Utility Connections, By Settlement Type and Expenditure Quintile Utility Service and Expenditure Quintile 4 Highest All Households N = 2990 46 58 Urban N = 2024 52 64 PGT N = 188 71 56 Rural N = 778 25 33 To highlight the potential impact of reforms, it is useful to compare how much households relying on a particular fuel were expected to pay based on 1996 charges, with how much they would be paying if they were charged at full-cost recovery levels.7 (See Table 8.) The utility charges in Table 8 are broken down by fuel type to show how households are obtaining heating, cooking, and hot water services. The lowest cost recovery levels, and thus the greatest jump in charges, are for gas space heat and services typically supplied by the municipality: district heating, hot water connections, central water, and sewerage. Under the 1996 rate scheme, the combined average charges for district heat and hot water are the same as the combined average charges for heat and hot water fueled by network gas—46 thousand rubles, or 9 US dollars. When rates are raised to cover the full cost of providing these services, however, the combined average district heat and hot water charges become greater—159 thousand rubles ($32), as opposed to 144 thousand rubles ($29). Households without network gas and district heat must use coal, bottled gas or some other means for obtaining heat and hot water.8 Households using coal for heating and bottled gas for hot water begin by paying the most at 69 thousand rubles ($14), but end up paying the least at full-cost recovery levels, roughly 107 thousand rubles ($22). No matter which fuel type, heating charges are a household’s largest payment both under 1996 charges and at full-cost recovery levels.9 7 As with estimating the current housing and utility costs, the estimates for full cost recovery depended on the type of service, fuel and unit type. Data on cost recovery levels for communal services were taken from Form 22 of the Department of Housing and Communal Services. Cost recovery levels for gas and coal were calculated using 1996 prices and unsubsidized prices. Full information is provided in Annex 3. 8 The RLMS did not explicitly ask households what fuel they used for heating; however, it did ask households if they had a connection to the district heating network or the natural gas network. It also asked if the household had purchase firewood, coal, peat, or kerosene (and in a separate question, bottled gas) within the past 30 days. Combining this information, we categorized households accordingly using “coal-heating” as a catch-all for households without district heat or network gas. 9 Annex 4 has more information on the breakdown of the housing-utility bill by type of unit and ownership of unit. Again, regardless of the breakdown, heating charges represent the largest share of a household’s housing-utility bill. 8 Table 8 Imputed Monthly Utility Charges by Fuel and Utility Connection (1996 Rubles) Mean Value of Imputed Charge (1996 Rubles) Utility Connection and Fuel Type At Full Cost Recovery Levels 1996 Charges Ratio of Average 1996 Charge to Average Full Cost Recovery Charge (%) Percent of Households With Connection Heat 27,134.9 41,826.0 60,541.3 91,782.2 131,501.6 96,436.9 30 32 63 69.8 8.6 21.6 3,155.4 7,766.4 10,008.4 7,507.8 9,708.0 22,388.7 42 80 45 60.8 21.5 17.7 18,751.9 4,545.8 8,400.9 (accounted for in heat) 66,911.6 12,086.3 10,501.1 (accounted for in heat) 28 38 80 -- 56.6 19.1 20.2 4.1 Central Water/Sewerage Central Water & Sewerage Only Central Water Only Sewerage Neither 13,519.6 7,521.5 2,891.3 0.0 46,627.1 23,262.6 13,068.6 0.0 29 32 22 -- 65.6 10.5 0.7 23.2 Telephone With Connection No Connection 15,752.1 0.0 26,253.5 0.0 60 -- 44.3 55.7 Electricity (Except for Cooking) 14,445.7 33,209.4 44 100.0 Central (District) Heating Gas Boiler Heating Coal Heating Cooking Network Gas Bottled Gas Electric Stove Hot Water Hot Water Connection Gas Boiler (Network Gas) Gas Boiler (Bottled Gas) Coal or Other In 1996, property taxes and payments for capital repair were practically non-existent. (See Table 9.) Tenants of publicly-owned apartments made one kvarplata payment which included a nominal rent component. Since 1997, many jurisdictions have instituted separate capital repair and rent payments, in addition to a maintenance fee. Here, we assume that rent for tenants of publicly-owned apartments will be equal to the property tax instituted for owners.10 Thus, future rent and property tax are presented as one category 10 This assumption reflects the principles of the current housing policy by the Government of Russia. 9 here. Also, the average future maintenance fee was calculated for all apartment units, without regard to tenure. Table 9 Imputed Monthly Housing Charges by Ownership and Unit Type (1996 Rubles)a Mean Value of Imputed Charge (1996 Rubles) Ownership - Unit Type Category Maintenance Publicly-Owned Apartment (APT) Privatized or Cooperative APT Single Family Housing (SFH) 1996 Charges At Full Cost Recovery Levels Percent of Households in Each Category (included in kvarplata) 15,604.9 0 53,146.1 53,146.1 0 36.4 33.0 30.6 18,308.2 4,542.9 0 0 0 0 36.4 1.9 61.7 0 0 0 0 5,073.4 7,480.5 9,653.7 11,426.0 27.9 18.2 40.7 13.2 0 0 0 0 6,595.4 12,155.9 15,445.9 18,281.6 27.9 18.2 40.7 13.2 Kvarplata Publicly-Owned APT Publicly-Owned SFH Private Housing Property Tax or Rent SFH without network gas or without district heat APT without network gas or without district heat Housing with network gas and district heat Housing with network gas and district heat in a large city Capital Repair SFH without network gas or without district heat APT without network gas or without district heat Housing with network gas and district heat Housing with network gas and district heat in a large city Notes: a In the future, the kvarplata paid by renters of state-owned units will be divided into a rent payment and a maintenance payment. The rent payment should be comparable to the property tax charged to owners of privatized units. Maintenance payments should be the same regardless of ownership of the unit. Having both network gas and central heating connections is used as a proxy for housing with modern amenities. Since rural households often do not have access to district heat, network gas, and centrally-supplied hot water, they more heavily rely on coal for heating, bottled gas for cooking, and bottled gas or coal for hot water. The high costs of coal heating relative to 10 district heating (at 1996 rates) help drive up the housing and utility charges of rural households.11 It is not surprising then, that rural households are expected to pay almost as much as urban households for housing and utility services (see Table 10). It is important to note that while expected to pay nearly as much as urban households, rural households generally do not have access to many important services, such as centrally-supplied hot water and sewerage. Table 10 Imputed Monthly Utility Charges and their Distribution by Settlement Type: At 1996 Rates (Mean Value in 1996 Thousand Rubles or Percent Distribution) All Households N = 2990 Housing or Utility Service Urban N = 2024 PGT N = 188 Rural N = 778 Charge Share (%) Charge Share (%) Charge Share (%) Charge Share (%) Heat Cooking Hot Water Water/ Sewerage Telephone Electricity Rent /Maintenance 35.6 5.4 13.2 9.7 7.0 14.4 11.9 37 6 13 9 7 17 11 29.9 5.0 15.3 11.8 8.2 14.1 15.3 31 5 14 11 8 16 14 28.3 2.8 10.4 8.7 6.7 16.2 8.9 36 4 11 9 8 23 9 52.3 6.9 8.3 4.5 3.8 15.0 3.8 53 8 9 4 3 19 4 Total 97.2 100 99.5 100 82.1 100 94.6 100 A rural household’s relatively high housing and utility costs at the 1996 rates, even in the absence of many services, partly reflects the relatively high cost recovery levels of the main fuels on which they rely: coal and bottled gas. This means that when charges are brought up to full-cost recovery levels the average rural household is now in a better situation than its urban counterpart. Table 11 shows that the mean housing-utility charge of rural households (215 thousand rubles) at full cost recovery rates is only about two-thirds that of urban households (316 thousand rubles). 11 Other explanations for why heating is such a large share of a rural household’s housing costs include: (1) Many rural households do not have access to and thus, do not pay for sewerage or even central water; (2) There are more houses than apartments in rural areas which means no maintenance costs as well as more total space to heat; (3) Under the calculation method used here, the costs of providing hot water with coal was included in heating charges. (Eleven percent of the rural households were assumed to be using coal for heating water. See Annex 5 for a complete breakdown of utility services by fuel and settlement type.) 11 Table 11 Imputed Monthly Utility Charges and their Distribution by Settlement Type: At Full Cost Recovery (Mean Value in 1996 Thousand Rubles or Percent Distribution) a All Households N = 2990 Housing or Utility Service Heat Cooking Hot Water Water/ Sewerage Telephone Electricity Maintenance Rent / Property Tax Capital Repair Total Urban N = 2024 PGT N = 188 Rural N = 778 Charge Share (%) Charge Share (%) Charge Share (%) Charge Share (%) 96.2 10.6 42.3 33.1 11.6 33.2 36.8 8.2 12.8 37 4 12 10 4 14 11 3 5 93.9 10.6 53.2 40.9 13.7 32.8 14.2 47.8 9.0 31 4 15 12 4 12 5 14 3 79.7 8.1 31.6 27.1 11.1 34.0 13.2 26.0 8.5 36 4 12 10 5 16 6 9 4 106.2 11.2 16.6 14.5 6.4 34.0 8.8 10.9 6.2 51 6 7 5 3 18 4 4 3 284.9 100 316.1 100 239.3 100 214.7 100 Notes: a The average unit in the sample has 48 square meters, 2.8 occupants, and an average cost per square meter of 6,190 rubles. In the entire sample, 70% has central heat, 61% gas stove, 57% hot water connection, 66% both central water and sewerage and 44% telephone. “Standard” units in the sample, having all of the abovementioned amenities, make up 24% of the sample. On average, they have 49 square meters, 2.8 occupants and an average cost per square meter of 7,807 rubles. The mean charge for standard units in the sample is 371,226 rubles, which is 30 percent more than the mean charge of the average unit in the sample. ARREARS Before considering raising tariffs, it is also important to analyze why there are arrears in housing and utility bills. From Table 12, it appears that poor enforcement is a major cause of high arrears. Thirty percent of households reported that they had arrears in housing or utility bills.12 The incidence of arrears among households in the highest expenditure quintile, who clearly have the means to pay, is only slightly lower (27 percent) than that of all households. The region with the lowest rate of reported arrears is Moscow City with 8 percent. The city of Kurgan has the highest rate of reported arrears at an astounding 71 percent. The fact that in Kurgan the cost of housing and utility services is high in relation to income level may help explain the city’s high arrears rate. 12 The terminology in the RLMS was, “Do you have unpaid housing bills?” which was preceded by the question, “Have you paid for housing and communal services in the past 30 days?” A third question asked 12 The incidence of arrears is lowest in rural areas, although still high at around 25 percent of the households in each expenditure category. It may be difficult, however, to define arrears in rural areas. Although 25 percent of rural households reported that they housing bills that they had not paid, 51 percent of rural households reported they had not paid a regular housing and communal services bill in the prior thirty days. Even when the purchase of coal, peat, kerosene, firewood, or bottled gas is taken into account, 32 percent of the rural households reported no housing related expenditures in the previous thirty days. Rural households may not report housing-related expenditures if they receive the goods and services through a barter arrangement between their employer and the utility company. For example, an agricultural employee may receive very little cash, but their employer might arrange for their utility payments to be paid through a barter arrangement with the utility service provider. Table 12 Monthly Incidence of Arrears and Cumulative Arrearage in Housing and Utility Bills (Percent of Households in Each Expenditure Quintile, 1996 Thousand Rubles) All Households N = 2990 Urban N = 2024 PGT N = 188 Rural N = 778 Incidence for All Households 30 31 42 25 Incidence by Expenditure Quintile Lowest 2 3 4 Highest 33 32 31 29 27 35 34 32 30 26 49 56 42 32 25 26 20 25 26 28 250.2 247.6 393.9 185.7 Average cumulative arrearage (among households in arrears) It is important to know not only the incidence of arrears, but the amount of arrears. If a household reported that it had unpaid housing or utility bills, the RLMS asked how much the family owed. The mean cumulative arrearage of households is 250 thousand rubles, while the median is 128 thousand rubles. The mean cumulative arrearage in PGT is particularly high, at close to 400 thousand rubles. As with the incidence of arrears, cumulative arrearage varies widely for different oblasts, krais, and cities. The place with the lowest average arrearage, 15 thousand rubles, is the settlement of Betlutsa in respondents how much they owed. Judging from the rather high amounts reported in response to the third question, it is most likely that households interpreted this as cumulative arrears. 13 Kalushskaya oblast. In contrast, the city Surgut in Khanty Mansiiskiy AO, Tiumenskaya oblast, and the settlement Zalokokuazhe in Kabardino-Balkariia have the highest cumulative arrearage, averaging nearly 450 thousand rubles for the households reporting to be in arrears. The latter also had the second highest incidence of arrears at 59 percent. The areas with the highest average cumulative arrearage are not the poorest. The average total expenditures for Kabardino-Balkariia (2,530 rubles) is well above the sample mean, and the average for Khanty Mansiiskiy (6,842 rubles) is the highest in the sample. In both of these locations the cost of housing and utility services in relation to income level is lower than it is in Betlutsa, which has the lowest cumulative arrears in the sample. ANALYSIS OF HOUSING-UTILITY BURDEN In most countries, food and housing dominate a household’s expenditures. In Russia, food is clearly a household’s most significant expenditure; housing-related costs do not represent a significant expenditure, except for households in the lowest quintile. Table 13 shows that for households in each of the three highest expenditure quintiles, the average housing- utility burden (combined housing and utility charges as share of total expenditures) is less than 10 percent. Households in the second lowest expenditure quintile on average have a housing-utility burden of 12 percent, while the lowest quintile has an average housing-utility burden of 25 percent.13 Having to spend little on housing, the wealthier households devote a small portion of their income to investment and a large portion to other items, including the purchase of durables. Note that when a household devotes income to investment and purchase of durables, they are not fully consuming their income today, but are setting aside income for future consumption. For the poorer households, investment is practically non-existent. This may reflect in part different demographic characteristics of the quintiles. Younger wealthier families are establishing their households and saving for retirement. Pensioners may have less need for durables or savings. However, it also signifies a continuing trend of income disparity. 13 Note that the imputed housing and utility charges and the resulting housing-utility burdens do not reflect the fact that many households pay little or none of the prescribed charge because they are recipients of housing benefits or housing allowances or they simply do not pay and are in arrears. Thus, actual housingutility burdens will be considerably lower and even zero for many households. By calculating what the housing-utility burden would be without these programs and arrears, we can compare the relative change in housing-utility burden as a result of policy changes. Later on, we will take into account these programs as well as arrears in determining the impact of these policy changes on municipal budgets. 14 The very low share of expenditures spent on housing by wealthier households reflects the low dispersion of housing and utility charges even as income disparity has grown immensely. Under market pricing, it is normal for wealthier households to have lower housing-utility burdens than poorer households; however, the particularly low burdens of Russian households in the highest expenditure quintile is an artifact of universallysubsidized rent and utility services. Table 13 Average Share of Monthly Household Budget By Category and Expenditure Quintile (Mean Percent Value) Expenditure Quintile All Households N = 2990 Urban N = 2024 PGT N = 188 Rural N = 778 Food a All Quintiles Lowest 2 3 4 Highest 60.0 61.4 67.2 65.8 60.5 45.1 59.0 63.0 66.4 65.5 59.8 42.8 59.4 63.8 67.7 65.7 50.7 45.8 62.8 57.9 68.9 66.7 64.0 55.1 Housing & Utility Charges b All Quintiles Lowest 2 3 4 Highest 10.8 24.8 11.8 8.3 6.0 3.3 10.1 23.2 11.8 8.2 6.0 3.4 9.6 22.2 8.7 7.8 5.0 3.2 13.2 28.3 12.8 8.6 6.0 3.2 Alcohol and Tobacco c All Quintiles Lowest 2 3 4 Highest 3.5 2.8 3.6 3.7 3.6 3.7 3.7 3.1 3.9 3.8 3.7 3.9 2.8 1.7 2.2 2.6 4.4 3.5 3.0 2.2 3.2 3.5 3.4 2.8 Investment d All Quintiles Lowest 2 3 4 Highest 2.9 0.9 1.4 1.8 4.0 6.7 3.2 0.8 1.5 2.1 4.0 6.7 2.8 0.9 2.0 1.5 0.8 8.9 2.4 0.9 1.1 1.1 4.4 5.8 Other Items e All Quintiles 22.7 24.1 25.4 18.6 15 Table 13 Average Share of Monthly Household Budget By Category and Expenditure Quintile (Mean Percent Value) Expenditure Quintile Lowest 2 3 4 Highest All Households N = 2990 10.2 16.0 20.4 26.0 41.1 Urban N = 2024 9.9 16.5 20.3 26.5 43.1 PGT N = 188 11.3 19.3 22.5 39.2 38.5 Rural N = 778 10.6 14.0 20.1 22.2 33.1 Notes: a Food includes food produced and either consumed or given away by the family. b Housing and utility charges were imputed based on local tariffs, norms and household and dwelling characteristics. The imputation includes the purchase of coal or bottled gas. c Alcohol and tobacco expenditures are probably underestimated because of the difficulty of separating them from food purchases. d Investment expenditures include cash savings, deposits, investments in securities, and loans to others. e Other items include, among others, the purchase of durables in the last three months, adjusted to obtain a monthly figure. By including per capita expenditures, Table 14 shows that the major difference in the housing-utility charges of households in the lowest and highest expenditure quintiles is a result of household size. In other words, unlike in market economies, in Russia there is no correlation between income and housing-related expenditures. In fact, households in the lowest quintile on average spend slightly more per capita than their counterparts in the highest quintile. (This can be explained by the fact that they occupy more space per capita, shown in Table 4.) Without having to spend more on housing and utility services on a per capita basis, households in the highest quintile in total still manage to spend more than 7 times the amount spent by households in the lowest quintile on a per capita basis. To illustrate just how little households in the highest quintile are spending on housing and utility charges, compare the average amount they spend on housing, 128 thousand rubles, with the average amount they spend on alcohol and tobacco, 159 thousand rubles. The average amount households in the highest quintile spend on non-food items (the categories “alcohol and tobacco” and “other items” from Table 14) is 20 times the average amount they spend on housing and utility charges. Table 14 Average Monthly Household Expenditures by Category and Expenditure Quintile (Mean Value in 1996 Thousand Rubles) All Households N = 2990 Expenditure Quintile Per Capita Expenditures Household Expenditures 16 Urban N = 2024 PGT N = 188 Rural N = 778 Household Expenditures Table 14 Average Monthly Household Expenditures by Category and Expenditure Quintile (Mean Value in 1996 Thousand Rubles) All Households N = 2990 Expenditure Quintile Urban N = 2024 PGT N = 188 Rural N = 778 Per Capita Expenditures Household Expenditures 224.1 367.7 494.6 699.2 1,710.4 331.0 727.2 1,161.9 1,851.2 4,912.0 335.4 735.9 1,167.3 1,870.2 5,041.7 336.2 737.6 1,180.3 1,823.6 4,238.6 321.8 728.0 1,142.5 1,809.2 4,573.9 146.9 252.8 330.5 415.1 598.6 211.6 488.7 763.7 1,115.0 1,847.4 218.6 482.2 764.6 1,111.4 1,785.0 226.0 504.0 775.2 922.4 1,764.4 195.7 501.2 757.9 1,160.5 2,151.1 44.9 39.9 37.4 38.0 40.6 69.3 84.7 95.0 108.6 128.1 66.3 84.1 94.8 110.7 133.5 56.8 62.7 89.5 90.3 114.8 77.5 91.3 97.1 106.8 109.2 5.8 12.1 18.0 26.4 56.0 9.4 25.9 42.7 67.9 159.0 11.3 28.2 44.8 69.8 171.0 5.7 13.4 29.8 83.7 138.6 6.4 22.8 40.6 60.1 112.8 Investment Lowest 2 3 4 Highest 2.8 5.4 11.2 33.1 155.9 3.3 10.5 21.4 74.0 412.1 3.1 10.8 25.2 75.7 406.3 4.2 16.5 16.5 14.4 580.6 3.3 8.2 12.8 81.0 379.4 Other Items Lowest 2 3 4 23.8 57.5 97.5 186.6 37.4 117.4 239.2 485.7 36.0 120.5 237.9 502.6 43.5 13.9 269.3 712.9 38.8 104.7 234.1 400.8 All Expenditures Lowest 2 3 4 Highest Household Expenditures Food Lowest 2 3 4 Highest Housing & Utility Charges Lowest 2 3 4 Highest Alcohol and Tobacco Lowest 2 3 4 Highest 17 Table 14 Average Monthly Household Expenditures by Category and Expenditure Quintile (Mean Value in 1996 Thousand Rubles) All Households N = 2990 Expenditure Quintile Highest Urban N = 2024 Per Capita Expenditures Household Expenditures 859.4 2,365.3 PGT N = 188 Rural N = 778 Household Expenditures 2,545.8 1,640.3 1,821.4 At 1996 tariffs and expenditure levels, housing-utility burdens are not very high for most households. The mean housing-utility burden for households in the sample is 10.8 percent and the median value is 7.5 percent. Rural households have slightly lower total charges than urban households (See Table 10), but their mean housing-utility burden is higher, 13.2 percent compared to 10.1 percent, because of their lower incomes. Nearly 64 percent of the sample has very low housing-utility burdens (defined as less than 10 percent of their household budgets). Five percent has high housing-utility burdens (defined as greater than or equal to 30 percent of their household budgets) and another 7 percent has moderate housing-utility burdens of 20 to 29 percent of their budgets. By administratively allocating housing and charging low fees for rent and utility services, the government historically has allowed low-income households to occupy relatively large units. As shown in Table 4 above, low-income households often have more space per capita than wealthier households. Since it is the space variable that determines a household’s largest utility payment—heating—this partially explains the relatively high housing-utility burden faced by low-income households. (See Table 15.) Low rent and utility charges do not provide an impetus for a household to find a smaller unit if it becomes smaller (e.g., children moving out). Table 15 October 1996 Housing-Utility Burden Housing-Utility Burden as Percent of Total Expenditures Very Low 0 - 9% All Households Low 10-14% Low to Moderate 15-19% Moderate 20-29% Total High 30+% 63.6 16.8 7.7 6.5 5.4 100.0 Lowest 10.9 20.1 18.4 24.2 26.4 100.0 2 41.0 35.6 15.9 6.9 0.7 100.0 3 73.1 21.9 3.8 1.2 -- 100.0 Expenditure Quintile 18 Table 15 October 1996 Housing-Utility Burden Housing-Utility Burden as Percent of Total Expenditures Total High 30+% Moderate 20-29% -- -- 100.0 4 94.0 5.5 Low to Moderate 15-19% 0.5 Highest 99.2 0.8 -- -- -- 100.0 Urban 65.2 17.4 7.6 6.0 3.8 100.0 PGT 71.3 17.6 2.7 4.3 4.3 100.0 Rural 57.7 15.0 9.3 8.1 9.9 100.0 Very Low 0 - 9% Low 10-14% Settlement Type If we hold total expenditures at the same level and allow housing-related costs to rise to their full-cost recovery levels, the mean housing-utility burden of the sample rises to 31.1 percent, with a median value of 21.9 percent. The median housing-utility burden in the United States for 1995 was also 22 percent.14 The distributions of housing-utility burden at full-cost recovery (Table 16) differ dramatically from those computed using 1996 tariffs (Table 15). Now only 16 percent of the households has a very low burden. Over half of the sample (54 percent) has moderate or high housing-utility burdens. As expected, the incidence of moderate or high housing-utility burdens varies heavily by income. Almost all (97 percent) of the households in the lowest expenditure quintile fall in this category, but less than 10 percent of the households in the highest quintile do. Burden also varies by settlement type. The percent of urban households with moderate or high housing-utility burdens increases by more than 5 times—from 10 percent to 57 percent. The percent of rural households with moderate or high housing-utility burdens increases less than 3 times: from 18 percent to 50 percent. This reflects the relatively high current costs that rural households incur. Table 16 Housing-Utility Burden at Full Cost Recovery Housing-Utility Burden, as Percent of 1996 Total Expenditures 14 The source for the US figures is the American Housing Survey for the United States in 1995, issued April 1997, by the U.S. Department of Commerce and the U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development. 19 Low 10-14% Very Low 0 - 9% All Households Low to Moderate 15-19% Moderate 20-29% High 30+% Total 16.4 15.1 14.3 19.6 34.6 100.0 0 0.8 1.8 10.2 87.1 100.0 2 0.8 4.7 13.0 29.3 52.2 100.0 3 4.5 17.9 23.1 30.3 24.2 100.0 4 20.9 27.3 21.6 21.7 8.5 100.0 Highest 55.5 24.9 12.0 6.5 1.0 100.0 Urban 15.1 14.2 14.3 19.3 37.2 100.0 PGT 15.4 17.6 17.0 23.9 26.1 100.0 Rural 19.9 17.0 13.6 19.4 30.1 100.0 Expenditure Quintile Lowest Settlement Type Table 17 summarizes how the distribution of households across housing-utility burden categories changes as tariffs increase and compares this with the distribution of housingutility burden in the United States in 1995. The share of households with a very low housing burden starts out at 64 percent at 1996 rates. It decreases to 26 percent at a 75 percent cost recovery level, and further decreases to 16 percent at full-cost recovery. The share of households with a high burden begins at a small 5 percent at 1996 rates, and increases to 22 percent at the 75 percent cost recovery level, and to 35 percent at full-cost recovery.15 The U.S. distribution is closest to the Russian distribution at full-cost recovery levels—in both 54 percent of households has moderate or high housing-utility burdens. Table 17 Comparison of Housing-Utility Burden Levels at 1996 Charges, 75% Cost Recovery and Full Cost Recovery in Russia, with 1995 Housing-Utility Burden Levels in the United States Housing-Utility Burden, as Percent of 1996 Total Expenditures Very Low 0 - 9% Low 10-14% 15 Low to Moderate 15-19% Moderat e 20-29% High 30+% Total Note that unit size varies little with burden levels. At 1996 charges, the mean total space occupied by households with the lowest burden is 49 square meters and the space occupied by those with the highest burden is 45 square meters; at full-cost recovery, households with the lowest burden occupied 46 square meters on average and those with the highest burden occupied 48 square meters. 20 Table 17 Comparison of Housing-Utility Burden Levels at 1996 Charges, 75% Cost Recovery and Full Cost Recovery in Russia, with 1995 Housing-Utility Burden Levels in the United States Housing-Utility Burden, as Percent of 1996 Total Expenditures Very Low 0 - 9% 63.6 Low 10-14% 16.8 Low to Moderate 15-19% 7.7 Moderat e 20-29% 6.5 75% Full Cost Recovery 26.4 19.4 13.7 Full Cost Recovery 16.4 15.1 United States 14.7 15.2 1996 Charges (33% Full Cost Recovery) High 30+% Total 5.4 100.0 18.1 22.4 100.0 14.3 19.6 34.6 100.0 15.9 23.2 31.1 100.0 Source for U.S. figures: American Housing Survey for the United States in 1995, issued April 1997 by the U.S. Department of Commerce and the U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development. Note that the distribution excludes 2 percent of the sample which reported zero or negative income as well as 4 percent of the sample which reported no cash rent. Including these would add to the “very low” and “high” categories. Housing-utility burden is calculated as monthly housing costs (rent, mortgages, utilities, etc.) as percent of current income. Although housing-utility burdens experience great shifts with the imposition of greater cost recovery, in absolute monetary terms, the increases in charges appear to be less dramatic. Table 18 compares the 1996 imputed charges and corresponding burden levels with the charges and burden levels at 75 percent cost recovery and at full-cost recovery levels. The mean imputed 1996 housing-utility charge for the sample is 97 thousand rubles ($19). At 75 percent cost recovery, the mean charge increases to 214 thousand rubles ($43) and at full cost recovery, the mean charge is 285 thousand rubles ($57).16 With such a low initial level of charges, it is not surprising to see the average housing-utility burden double under 75 percent cost recovery and triple under full cost recovery. It is also important to remember that these burden measures assume that real incomes do not grow and that no one implements technological or institutional energy conservation measures. In the following sections on sensitivity analysis, we will see that these factors greatly affect burden levels. Table 18 Comparison of Average Monthly Housing-Utility Charges (1996 Thousand Rubles) and Average Burden Levels (Percent) Under the 1996 Rate Scheme, 75 Percent Cost Recovery and Full Cost Recovery, by Expenditure Quintile and by Settlement Type 16 Note that for 24 percent of the sample occupying “standard” units (i.e, receiving the following services: district heat and hot water, gas stove, central water and sewerage and telephone) the mean charge is higher at 371 thousand rubles, or $74. The average size of these units was 49 square meters. 21 Housing-Utility Burden (Percent) Housing-Utility Charges (1996 Thousand Rubles) At 1996 Rates All Households At 75% Cost Recovery At Full Cost Recovery At 1996 Charges At 75% Cost Recovery Charges At FullCost Charges 97.1 213.7 284.9 10.8 23.3 31.1 Lowest 69.3 146.4 195.2 24.8 52.8 70.4 2 84.7 181.2 241.6 11.8 25.3 33.7 3 95.0 205.9 274.6 8.3 17.9 23.9 4 108.6 237.4 316.5 6.0 13.0 17.3 Highest 128.1 297.5 396.7 3.4 7.7 10.3 Urban 99.5 237.1 316.1 10.1 23.9 31.8 PGT 82.1 179.5 239.3 9.6 21.3 28.4 Rural 94.6 161.0 214.7 13.2 22.5 30.0 Expenditure Quintile Settlement Type SENSITIVITY ANALYSIS: REAL INCOME GROWTH Until now, our estimates assumed that there would be no real income growth while housing and utility charges increased to full-cost recovery levels. The following sensitivity analysis explores the effect of real income growth on housing-utility burden levels. Scenario 1 assumes that there will be 3 percent per annum real income growth, which cumulatively represents a 23 percent increase from 1996 to 2003. Scenario 2 assumes 6 percent per annum real income growth, cumulatively a 50 percent increase over that period. Under these two scenarios, the mean monthly total expenditure level of the sample increases from 1.8 million rubles to 2.2 million rubles and 2.7 million (1996) rubles, respectively. The housing-burden calculations are quite sensitive to assumptions of income growth. With no income growth, the mean housing-burden level is 31 percent. With 3 percent per annum growth, the mean housing-utility burden level drops to 25 percent and with 6 percent per annum growth, it drops to 21 percent. Table 19 shows that with 6 percent per annum growth in real income, the share of households facing a high housing-utility burden is cut roughly in half from 35 to 18 percent. At the same time, the share of households with very low housing-utility burdens doubles from 16 to 32 percent. There are only small changes in 22 the shares of households with low, low-to-moderate, or moderate housing-utility burdens. Table 19 Comparison of Housing-Utility Burden Levels at Full Cost Recovery with No Income Growth, Three Percent Annum Growth and Six Percent Annum Growth From 1996 to 2003 Housing-Utility Burden, as Percent of 1996 Total Expenditures Very Low 0 - 9% Low 10-14% Low to Moderate 15-19 Moderate 20-29% High 30+% Total No Income Growth 16.4 15.1 14.3 19.6 34.6 100.0 Three Percent Annum Growth 23.2 18.1 14.8 18.0 25.9 100.0 Six Percent Annum Growth 31.5 19.8 14.1 16.4 18.3 100.0 SENSITIVITY ANALYSIS: REDUCTION IN HOUSEHOLD ENERGY CONSUMPTION There are two potential sources of demand reduction which are likely to mitigate what households will have to pay in the future for communal and network energy services. The first is proper billing of consumption; the second is through investment in energy efficient equipment and measures to reduce energy losses. Proper Billing. There are two issues here: proper billing of energy produced for residential use overall, and proper billing of energy consumption by individual households. To achieve the latter would require metering in individual units, which does not exist at present, with the exception of electricity consumption. With meters installed and charges tied to actual usage, overall energy consumption would probably decrease as many households would downwardly adjust their consumption and save money where they could not before. Other households would be charged more to reflect their above-average usage. However, meters may not produce much overall savings in the short-run (i.e., 7 years) because of the high fixed costs involved in installation. We did not include a switch to billing by metering in our scenarios because of the long payback periods for investments in meter installation. In the absence of individual metering systems, distributors of gas, district heat and hot water will continue to rely on “consumption norms” to charge a household for the services provided according to the size of the unit or the size of the household. While the norms cannot match any particular household’s actual usage, they are intended to approximate overall usage across a population so the distributor can recover his costs. There is some evidence, however, that these norms overestimate usage overall, and thus, on average, 23 charge households too much for these services at any given rate. For example, gas consumption norms for cooking range from 7 to 15 cubic meters/person/month. In meter testing programs in Vladimir and Volgograd, actual consumption was 7 to 8 cubic meters/person/ month— significantly higher than consumption in France and Germany, but lower than what many Russian households are charged. Similar situations exist with consumption norms for gas water heating, gas space heating, district space heat, and district hot water heating.17 We examined a scenario in which gas consumption norms were adjusted to more realistically reflect actual consumption (i.e. 8 and 14 cubic meters/person/month for cooking and water heating, respectively, and 4, 5, and 6 cubic meters/square meter/month for heating in the south, central, and northern regions, respectively). In addition, consumption norms for district heat and hot water were reduced by a flat 10 percent to reflect the possible impact of more accurate recording of usage. The joint effect of improving the measurement of these services is a 6 percent decrease in imputed full costs on average from 285 thousand rubles to 268 thousand rubles (1996 rubles). Energy Conservation Measures. Even with adequate billing arrangements, household consumption of gas, district heat, and hot water in Russia will be higher than in most countries with comparable climates because of relatively inefficient energy use. Many factors have contributed to this inefficiency, including: (a) the structure of the existing housing stock and networks which have been built under improper pricing signals; (b) lack of access to new, more efficient technologies; and © lack of sufficient funds to finance energy efficient investments at either the supply or consumer level. A potential source of reducing heat costs is improved regulation and increased competition. At the same time, introducing competition in one area, could have undesired effects in another area. For example, a combined heat and power producer wanting to reduce heat charges in face of competition, might increase its electricity tariffs to compensate. Other results may not produce short-run savings. For instance, if households are given the opportunity to choose other heat producers, they may shift to building-level boilers rather than relying on over-extended central heating systems. This might lead to a cost increase in the early years because of the capital costs involved in such a shift. For these reasons, the sensitivity analysis does not consider regulation and competition as a likely source of much savings in the short-run. Other ways to reduce heat costs include more efficient production technologies and 17 Annex 6 compares the 1996 range of consumption norms for gas, district heat and hot water with estimated average actual usage, based on meter testing programs or consumption levels in countries with comparable climates. 24 improved heating efficiency of apartments. A modest degree of cost reduction at the producer level could be accomplished through high rate-of-return, low-cost investments (e.g., automated controls, heat meters at the intake from the heat supplier, leak detection programs, etc.). Demonstrations projects of building retrofits in the former Soviet Union countries have recorded energy savings of up to 30 percent. Complete retrofits may decrease the short-run marginal cost of supply, but not the total cost because of high investment requirements and long payback periods. However, partial retrofits (e.g., window weather-stripping, heat balancing, building-level heat control, etc.) have achieved energy savings of up to 20 percent with considerably shorter payback periods. Given that savings of 5 to 15 percent seem to be achievable for relatively minor levels of investment on both the residential and producer side, the sensitivity analysis examined the impact of a 10 percent reduction in energy consumption (over and above the savings achieved through improved measurement). The cumulative effect of improved measurement and low-cost energy conservation measures is an 8 percent decrease from 285 thousand to 262 thousand rubles (1996 rubles). Table 20 shows that with proper measurement and energy conservation measures, the share of households facing a high housing-utility burden is reduced from 35 to 30 percent. The share of households with very low housing-utility burdens increases from 16 to 20 percent. Again, there is little change in the share of households with low, low-tomoderate, or moderate housing-utility burdens. Compared to the effect of increasing incomes, the decrease in burden is less dramatic. The potential impact of these measures, however, is somewhat constrained because they only affect some of the services provided. The cost of other services, such as maintenance, telephone, and electricity are not reduced. Table 20 Comparison of Housing-Utility Burden Levels at Full Costs: Demand Reductions through Proper Billing Arrangements and Energy Conservation Measures Housing-Utility Burden, as Percent of 1996 Total Expenditures Very Low 0 - 9% Low 10-14% Low to Moderate 15-19% Moderate 20-29% High >= 30% Total Ceteris Paribus 16.4 15.1 14.3 19.6 34.6 100.0 Proper Billing Arrangements 18.7 15.0 15.6 18.5 32.2 100.0 Energy Conservation Measures & Proper Billing Arrangements 19.8 15.8 15.1 19.0 30.4 100.0 These are only a sample of the most important factors that will influence future 25 housing burden. Other related effects include expected growth in availability of telephones and corresponding costs; additional salary growth in the public sector (e.g., military) which will happen in response to and simultaneously with elimination of existing housing benefits; potential growth in a number of market renters (as part of growing labor mobility) which will face a much higher level of total housing-related costs. IMPACT ON MUNICIPAL BUDGETS As the level of government responsible for providing most of the current housingrelated subsidies, municipalities and other local governments stand to benefit the most from an increase in tariffs to full-cost recovery levels. Every municipality knows, however, that when it increases tariffs, it will not receive a full payment from every household. Even at the low 1996 rates, many households did not pay the prescribed tariff because they received housing benefits or housing allowances, or simply refused to pay and were in arrears. Thus, the estimated collection has three components: Collection Estimate = Amount Billed to Unsubsidized Population + Amount Billed to Subsidized Population - Arrears Likewise, the difference between the amount collected and the total costs to provide these services represents a combined direct and indirect subsidy from the municipality to households. The subsidy burden is the share of total costs borne by the municipality. Subsidy Burden = (Total Housing and Utility Costs - Collection Estimate) / Total Housing and Utility Costs According to estimates by the Institute for Urban Economics (IUE) in Moscow, 30 to 35 percent of households received housing benefits in the end of 1996 and they were billed, on average, 55 percent of the unsubsidized rate. Distribution of housing benefits is category based, that is, it depends on the person’s status (e.g., veteran), occupation (e.g., teacher or military) or perhaps, physical disability. Depending on their category, recipients of housing benefits might be liable for only 50 or 70 percent or, in some cases, none of the prescribed charges for their unit. Also according to IUE, 6 to 7 percent of households received housing allowances during this period and they were billed for approximately 75 percent of the unsubsidized rate. Distribution of payments in the housing-allowance program is means-based. Eligibility and the size of the subsidy is based on the family’s housing needs and their ability to pay. In 1996, participation in the housing allowance program was below estimated eligibility for four reasons: (1) some households had to choose between housing benefits and housing allowances and chose the former; (2) some housing allowance offices demonstrated poor performance, including information campaign activities; (3) some eligible households decided not to pay at all and are in the category of households with arrears; (4) some 26 households with a small expected allowance do not apply.18 In the future, the housing benefits program will gradually be replaced by the housing allowance program. Many of the households receiving housing benefits will be eligible for housing allowances. To estimate how much a municipality might collect if it increased tariffs to full cost recovery levels, we first had to estimate how many households would qualify for a housing allowance (assuming that housing benefits programs no longer exist). The eligibility rules for housing allowance programs vary throughout the country, but for our analysis, we assumed that a household would be eligible for an allowance if its housing and utility charges totaled more than 20 percent of its household income.19 That is, the household would pay the portion of the bill that is equal to 20 percent of its income; the municipality would not bill them for the remaining portion. In this sense, the municipality is billing the household for services at some rate below full cost recovery. Under the 75 percent cost recovery rate scheme and expenditure levels the same as in late 1996, we estimate that 41 percent of the households would be eligible for housing allowances. With the full cost recovery rate scheme and expenditure levels again held constant, we estimated that 54 percent of the households would be eligible for housing allowances. These estimates were used to calculate a weighted average of the charges to be billed to the population. (See Table 21.) Table 21 Share of Households Receiving Subsidies and Estimated Charges Population Category Mean Charge per Population Category (Rubles) Population share (%) Weighted Charge (Billed) per Population Category At October 1996 Tariffs Unsubsidized Population a Housing Allowance Recipients 64 97.2 62.2 6 72.9 4.4 18 A thorough description of early experience with the housing allowance program in Russia can be found in the article, “Monitoring Russia’s Experience with Housing Allowances,” by Raymond J. Struyk, Alexander S. Puzanov, and Lisa A. Lee, in Urban Studies, Vol. 34, No. 11, 1789-1818, 1997. 19 According to the Federal Concept for Housing and Communal Reform, the federal standard for housing allowance eligibility under full-cost recovery (to be achieved by the year 2003) is 25 percent. Thus, the 20 percent rule used throughout this paper should overestimate the subsidy burden of a municipality. 27 Housing Benefits Recipients 30 Total 53.4 100 16.0 82.6 At 75 Percent Cost Recovery Tariffs Unsubsidized Population 59 213.7 127.1 Housing Allowance Recipients b 41 139.0 56.3 Total 100 183.4 At Full Cost Recovery Tariffs Unsubsidized Population 46 284.9 131.1 Housing Allowance Recipients b 54 169.3 91.4 Total 100 222.5 Notes: a This is really a misnomer because the 1996 tariffs represent large subsidies in themselves since they are much below cost. For the sake of consistency, we use the term “unsubsidized” for the households who are not receiving special housing benefits or housing allowances. b The assumption is that the housing benefits program is phased out. Many of the households currently receiving housing benefits would be eligible for housing allowances, particularly if housing and utility rates were increased. The reader should be aware that the figures in Table 21 represent an upper limit of housing allowance eligibility. The estimates in Table 21 assumed that the municipality would pay the difference between actual costs and the share paid by the household (set at 20 percent of the household’s income). In practice, each local government operating a housing allowance program sets a “maximum social rent” according to family size. The municipality is responsible for the difference between the maximum social rent and the share paid by household. (When actual costs are below the maximum social rent, the housing allowance is based on actual costs.) The degree to which the figures above overstate housing allowance eligibility depends on actual maximum social rents employed by local governments. These can vary a lot. If we assume a maximum social rent based on 20 square meters per household member, then under the 75 percent cost recovery rate scheme the share of households eligible for housing allowances falls from 41 to 36 percent. Under the full-cost recovery rate scheme, the share falls from 54 to 49 percent. In addition to reducing the number of households eligible for housing allowances, the use of a maximum social rent also reduces the municipality’s subsidy to households that are still eligible. The combined effect is that perhaps one quarter of all households will experience moderate or high burdens, even though they are recipients of housing allowances. Out of their own pockets, fifteen percent of all households will pay 21 to 29 percent, 5 percent will pay 30 to 39 percent, and another 5 percent of the households will pay more than 40 percent of their total expenditures on housing-related costs (according to estimates based 28 on the rule of 20 square meters per capita). The other option facing these households is to relocate. It was also necessary to calculate current arrears to have an assumption for future arrears. Table 22 shows how we estimated monthly (as opposed to cumulative) arrears to be 14 percent of the amount billed to households. Monthly arrears are defined as the difference between the average amount billed and the average amount collected (that is, the amount that households reported paying in the RLMS). As was illustrated in Table 21, the average amount billed depends on the share of households receiving housing benefits and allowances and the average amount billed to these households. Table 22 Calculation of Arrears Estimate Value (1996 Thousand Rubles or Percent) Total Billed in 1996 (weighted average of charges from the table above) 82.6 Mean Housing-Utility Payments, as reported in the RLMS survey 71.1 Arrears Estimate (weighted per household charge) 11.5 Arrears as Percent of Total Billed 14% Returning to the assumptions behind the estimates laid out in Table 21, we estimated the net impact of an increase in tariffs on a municipality, given the fact that it will collect more fees from some households, but have to provide greater subsidies to other households. Table 23 shows the subsidy level per 100,000 households, the subsidy burden (as percent of total housing and utility costs), and the savings to a municipality under a variety of scenarios. The share of households eligible for housing allowances changes with each scenario depending on the number of households facing a moderate or high housing-utility burden, and the severity of their burden.20 In all scenarios (including the 1996 rate scheme), the arrears are assumed to be 14 percent of the total amount billed to households.21 At 1996 tariffs, a municipality of 100,000 households annually collects approximately 20 We assume here that 100 percent of the eligible households will participate in the housing allowance program, even though experience shows that the number of participants is always smaller than the eligible population. 21 With higher charges, there will be more incentive for households not to pay their housing and utility bills. We assume that the household’s incentive not to pay, however, will be counteracted by the municipality’s greater efforts at enforcement, thus maintaining monthly arrears at approximately 14 percent. 29 85.3 billion rubles ($17.1 million), which means that it must subsidize 75 percent of all housing-related costs—257 billion rubles ($51.3 million)— through low rates, program benefits and non-collection (arrears). When unsubsidized households are charged rates corresponding to 75 percent of cost recovery levels, the same municipality might expect to provide housing allowances to 41 percent of the households and, including the cost of arrears, subsidize 45 percent of the full cost of the services provided. However, it would save 104 billion rubles ($20.8 million) compared to the 1996 rate scheme. When unsubsidized households are charged the full cost of providing the services, the municipality would provide housing allowances to 54 percent of the households, but subsidize only 33 percent of all housing-related costs. All together, it would annually collect approximately 230 billion rubles ($45.9 million), and provide a subsidy of 112 billion rubles ($22.5 million) through housing allowance program benefits and non-collection (arrears). The difference in subsidy from the 1996 rate scheme annually amounts to 144 billion rubles ($28.9 million). The municipality’s subsidy burden and its savings compared to the 1996 rate scheme would improve even more if there were either income growth or reduced household consumption of energy. If there was 3 percent annum income growth, then the municipality could expect that its subsidy burden would decrease, perhaps to 28 percent of total housing-related costs. If households reduce their energy consumption, even if there is no income growth, then total costs of providing the services would fall while households would pick up more of the tab. The municipality would subsidize 30 percent of total housing-related costs, and save 163 billion rubles ($32.6 million) compared to what it must pay out under the 1996 rate scheme. Table 23 Housing-Utility Subsidy Burden of a Municipality with 100,000 Households, By Scenario (Million US Dollars: 5000 Rubles = $1) Annual Subsidy, per 100,000 Households Subsidy as % of Total Housing-Utility Costs Savings to Municipality, Compared to the 1996 Rate Scheme 1996 Rate Scheme 51.3 75% ---- 75 Percent Cost Recovery 30.5 45% 20.8 Full-Cost Recovery 22.5 33% 28.9 Scenario Income Growth Scenarios (With Full-Cost Recovery Tariffs) Three Percent Annum Growth 19.2 28% 32.1 Six Percent Annum Growth 16.4 24% 35.0 Reduced Household Consumption Scenarios (With No Income Growth) 30 Table 23 Housing-Utility Subsidy Burden of a Municipality with 100,000 Households, By Scenario (Million US Dollars: 5000 Rubles = $1) Annual Subsidy, per 100,000 Households Subsidy as % of Total Housing-Utility Costs Savings to Municipality, Compared to the 1996 Rate Scheme Proper Billing 20.1 31% 31.2 Energy Conservation Measures & Proper Billing 18.7 30% 32.6 Scenario This analysis is not intended to be predictive, i.e., it does not try to predict what the world will look like in a future point in time. Instead, it provides an estimate of the upper limit of a municipality’s subsidy burden under a variety of scenarios. Actual costs to the municipality will depend on 1) housing allowance participation rates; 2) the program’s administrative costs; and, 3) the municipality’s success in enforcing collection and reducing arrears. We have no way of knowing what actual housing allowance participation rates will be under different rate schemes; we can only estimate eligibility. Actual participation will be influenced by the local administration’s outreach efforts, the degree of difficulty in applying for assistance, the expected benefit level, and cultural factors such as attitude towards receiving government assistance and even fear of government intrusion. The greater the increase in burden, the more likely that a household will participate. For the above-mentioned reasons it is not possible to extrapolate participation rates from experience in other countries, except to say that the number of participants is always smaller than the eligible population. Under the full cost recovery rate scheme, we estimate that 54 percent of households would be eligible to receive a housing allowance. Even with participation rates much below eligibility rates this would represent a significant increase from the 6 percent participation rate in 1996. During the process of German reintegration, East German households experienced great increases in their rent. By the end of 1992, 2 million East German households—30 percent of all East German households— participated in a housing allowance program. (The housing allowance program existed in West Germany since 1955; during the same period, 6 percent of West German households, 1.8 million, were also participating in the program.) This share of East German participants dropped to 1.4 million households (or about 20 percent) by the end of 1993 as real income increased.22 Analysis of housing allowance participation rates and the accompanying 22 Material taken from Wohngeld and Mietenbericht, 1993, Bundesministerium fur Raumordnung Bauwesen und Stadtebau, 1994 and personal conversation with Dr. Dick and Dr. Volker, as reported in 31 administrative costs in Russia is beyond the scope of this analysis. Housing Allowance Design: An Evaluation for Slovakia, by M. Mikelsons, et.al, The Urban Institute, 1996. The reader is referred to the Urban Institute report’s annex, “Other Country Experience with a Consumer-Based Housing Subsidy,” for a summary of experience throughout the world. 32 ANNEX 1 FURTHER DESCRIPTION OF THE SAMPLE Table 1 - Annex 1 Process Followed in Excluding Records from the Sample Number of Records Excluded Percent of All Records in Original Sample Market Renters 181 5.18 Dormitory Occupants 151 4.24 20 0.56 Zero Value on Total Household Expenditures 4 0.11 Zero Value on Number of Household Members 1 0.03 Missing Value on Hot Water 18 0.51 Missing Value on Network Gas 36 1.01 Missing Value on Both Living Space and Total Space 47 1.32 2 0.06 112 3.14 Total Cases Remaining 2990 83.94 Original RLMS Sample 3562 100.00 Reason for Exclusion Missing Values on Housing Type (own residence, market rent or dormitory) Missing Value on Unit Type (Separate Apartment or House or Part of Apartment or House) Split Households 33 Table 2 - Annex 1 Process Followed in Imputing Housing Characteristics Variable with Imputed Values Imputation Method Total Space 1,2 Living Space 1,2 Connection to Central Heating 1 Connection to Central Water Supply 1 Connection to Central Sewerage 1 Telephone Connection 1,3 Unit is Private or Privatized 1,3 Unit is Separate or Part of Larger Unit 1 Ownership of Building 1 • Imputation method (1) involved replacing missing values from Round 7 of the RLMS with Round 6 values. • Imputation method (2) was used after imputation method (1) for computing total or living space for cases that still had missing information for one, but not both types of space information. For cases in which only one space value was missing, the missing value was imputed based on the existing value times the median total space / living space ratio for that unit type (separate apartment, part of an apartment, separate house, part of house). • Imputation method (3) was used after imputation method (1) for cases that still had missing information. Two cases with missing information on telephone connection were assumed to not have telephone service. Two cases (apartment dwellers) were assumed to have non-privatized units. Two cases (in separate houses) were assumed to have private units. 34 ANNEX 2 JUSTIFICATION FOR IMPUTING HOUSING AND UTILITY CHARGES In one question of the RLMS survey, respondents were asked how much they had paid for all housing and communal services (maintenance and utilities) in the past 30 days. For several reasons the reported value may not correspond to the family’s usual housingrelated liabilities. Most significantly, these include arrears: 30 percent of the households reported that they had unpaid housing and utility bills. In addition to arrears, many households were eligible for housing benefits because they were veterans, disabled or had an occupation designated as special. Finally, some households were also participants in the new housing allowances program which targets subsidies to low-income households whose housing-utility burden is more than a certain percent of total income. It is not possible to tell from responses to the RLMS questionnaire whether a household received benefits or allowances or both. In the past 30 days, a household might have paid none of what they owed for that month, some of what they owed, exactly what they owed, or what they owed for that month plus past arrears. Thus, the payment often will not correspond to the housing and utility services consumed by the household. To create a variable that reflects the value of the housing and utility services enjoyed by a household (whether or not they are actually paying for these services), required using unit and household characteristics reported in the RLMS. The following table presents the algorithms for imputing housing and utility charges. Table 1 - Annex 2 Algorithms for Calculating Housing and Utility Charges Service Unit Characteristics Calculation Approach Rent - Non-privatized apartment Kvarplata tariff * unit size Maintenance Non-privatized single family dwelling 100 Rubles * unit size Privatized apartment Maintenance tariff * unit size Privatized single family dwelling 0 If central heating connection Heat tariff * unit size If no central heating connection, but have gas connection Gas price per m3 * norm usage of m3 per month per m2 of space * unit size If no central heating connection and no gas connection, assumed coal heating Coal price per ton (minimum 150,000 R) * norm usage of tons per month * unit size Heating 35 Table 1 - Annex 2 Algorithms for Calculating Housing and Utility Charges Service Cooking Hot Water Water Sewerage Telephone Electricity Unit Characteristics If network gas connection Calculation Approach Gas tariff * household size If no gas connection, but household uses gas stove Bottled gas price per liter * .09 liters per person * household size (maximum 4) If household uses electric stove Electricity tariff per kWt * 40 kWt * household size (maximum 3) If hot water connection Hot water tariff * household size If no hot water connection, but have gas connection Gas price per m3 * norm usage of m3 per month per person * household size If no hot water connection, no network gas connection, but use bottled gas for cooking Bottled gas price per liter * .09 liters per person * household size If neither hot water nor gas connection 0 (Costs assumed to be accounted for under heating) If both cold water and sewerage connection Water-sewerage tariff * household size If only cold water connection 3/5 * Water-sewerage tariff * household size If only sewerage connection 2/5 * Water-sewerage tariff * household size If neither connection 0 If telephone connection Local service flat fee If no telephone connection 0 All households assumed to have electricity service Electricity tariff per kWt * 200 kWt if household has 5 or more members; else tariff per kWt * (100 + 25 * (household size - 1)) Notes: 1) Unit size is defined as total space for households that live in separate apartments or houses and as living space for households that live in parts of apartments or houses. 2) All tariffs and prices used for imputing charges were regionally-based. In most cases this meant at the city or oblast level. The norm usage levels for gas also vary by region. 36 Note that the imputed charges still do not correspond to the full value of these services, since in 1996 they were still provided at subsidized rates for all households. Even when utility and maintenance services are increased to full cost recovery levels, rent for state-owned housing will still probably lag behind market levels. This means that those households will continue to consume much more housing than will be reflected in their expenditures. The low share of the household budget spent on housing and utility services means that altering the estimate for these charges does not greatly affect the distribution of households by total expenditures. In the following table, records with the same column and row number are households that did not shift expenditure deciles after the imputation of housing and utility charges. These represent 84 percent of the sample. Another 15 percent of the households in the sample shifted one decile, either higher or lower, because of the imputed charges. Less than one percent of the households shifted more than one decile as a result of the imputation. In all of the latter cases, households that were in a higher expenditure decile based on reported payments, were recategorized in a lower decile based on imputed charges. A household might report a housing-utility payment much higher than its regular monthly housing-utility bill if it is paying up arrears and/or building a stock of coal or firewood for the whole winter. Table 2 - Annex 2 Shift of Households Among Expenditures Deciles after Imputation of Housing-Utility Charges (Count of Records) Expenditure Decile with Imputed Housing-Utility Charges 1 (Lowest) 2 1 272 27 2 27 230 42 3 40 223 36 4 2 29 226 42 5 4 34 232 29 6 1 3 24 250 21 1 19 254 25 1 23 259 16 1 15 279 Expenditure Decile with Reported Charges 3 4 5 7 8 9 37 6 7 8 9 10 (High -est) 4 10 4 295 Note: The reported charges had three components: 1) a question on all charges for housing and communal services; 2) a question on purchase of coal, firewood, peat, kerosene; 3) a question on purchase of bottled gas. The households were to report expenditures within the past 30 days. However, the latter two categories are generally ‘lumpy’ purchases (purchased less frequently than on a monthly basis) so households would report an amount much larger than that needed for one month. These values were adjusted to a third of the reported amount to compensate. 38 ANNEX 3 CALCULATION OF FUTURE HOUSING AND UTILITY CHARGES As with estimating the current housing and utility costs, the estimates for full cost recovery depended on the type of service, fuel and unit type. Data on cost recovery for communal services (maintenance, central heat, hot water, central water and sewerage) were provided by the Form 22 of the Department of Housing and Communal Services. In the regions in the sample, the cost recovery levels for communal services ranged from 17 to 40 percent (as of August 1997). Over half of the regions in the sample had cost recovery levels between 25 and 35 percent for communal services. Electric cost recovery levels were taken from information provided by individual Energos (electric power plants). These ranged from 19 to 61 percent. Cost recovery levels for delivery of natural gas were calculated using the November 1996 subsidized price for residential users and the price for unsubsidized (industrial) users. In the sample, gas cost recovery levels ranged from 15 to 100 percent, with a relatively even and wide dispersion. Likewise, cost recovery levels for coal were calculated based on the 1996 price and an estimate of the full price. (The estimated full price was 200 thousand rubles per ton in coal-producing regions and 350 thousand rubles in all other regions. The telephone cost recovery level was assumed to be 60 percent and the bottled gas cost recovery level 80 percent. Table 1 - Annex 3 Algorithms for Calculating Housing and Utility Charges Service Unit Characteristics Calculation Approach Rent Property Tax Single family dwelling without gas or central heating 100 Rubles* unit size Apartment without gas or central heating 160 Rubles * unit size Single family dwelling with both gas and central heating 200 Rubles * unit size Apartment with both gas and central heating 250 Rubles * unit size Apartment (1996 maintenance tariff / cost recovery level for communal services ) * unit size House 0 Single family dwelling without gas or central heating 130 * unit size Maintenance Capital Repair 39 Table 1 - Annex 3 Algorithms for Calculating Housing and Utility Charges Service Heating Cooking Hot Water Water Sewerage Unit Characteristics Calculation Approach Apartment without gas or central heating 260 * unit size Single family dwelling with both gas and central heating 320 * unit size Apartment with both gas and central heating 400 * unit size If central heating connection 1996 charge / cost recovery level for communal services If no central heating connection, but have gas connection 1996 charge / gas cost recovery level If no central heating connection and no gas connection, assumed coal heating Coal price at full cost recovery per ton * norm usage of tons per month * unit size If network gas connection 1996 charge / gas cost recovery level If no gas connection, but household uses gas stove 1996 bottled gas charge / 0.80 If household uses electric stove 1996 electricity for stove charge / electricity cost recovery level If hot water connection 1996 hot water charge / cost recovery level for communal services If no hot water connection, but have gas connection 1996 charge / gas cost recovery level If no hot water connection, no network gas connection, but use bottled gas for cooking 1996 bottled gas charge / 0.80 If neither hot water nor gas connection 0 (Costs assumed to be accounted for under heating) If both cold water and sewerage connection 1996 water-sewerage charge / cost recovery level for communal services If only cold water connection 1996 water charge / cost recovery level for communal services If only sewerage connection 1996 sewerage charge / cost recovery level for communal services If neither connection 0 40 Table 1 - Annex 3 Algorithms for Calculating Housing and Utility Charges Service Unit Characteristics Calculation Approach Telephone If telephone connection 1996 telephone charge / 0.60 If no telephone connection 0 All households assumed to have electricity service 1996 electricity charge / electricity cost recovery level Electricity 41 ANNEX 4 DISTRIBUTION OF HOUSING AND UTILITY CHARGES BY TYPE AND OWNERSHIP OF UNIT For households in single-family houses, heat and electricity represent nearly threequarters of their monthly housing and utility charges. For apartment dwellers, heat still sticks out as a high cost, but there are also other important components such as hot water, cold water and maintenance charges. Similar patterns occur between private and publiclyowned dwelling because the large majority of single-family houses are privately owned. Table 1 - Annex 4 Distribution of (Full-Cost Recovery) Housing and Utility Charges By Type and Ownership of Unit Type of Unit House Housing or Utility Service Heat Cooking Hot Water Cold Water/Sewerage Telephone Electricity Maintenance Rent / Property Tax Capital Repair Total Ownership of Unit Apartment Privatized or Cooperative 54 6 6 4 3 19 0 3 4 29 3 15 12 5 12 16 3 5 41 4 11 8 4 15 9 3 5 29 4 15 13 4 13 15 3 5 100 100 100 100 42 PubliclyOwned ANNEX 5 DISTRIBUTION OF FUEL TYPES USED BY UTILITY SERVICE AND SETTLEMENT TYPE Not having access to district heat, centrally-supplied hot water, or network gas, the majority of rural households have to use coal (or furnace oil or firewood) for heating, bottled gas and coal for hot water, and bottled gas for cooking. The following table shows the breakdown of fuel types used by utility service and settlement type. The fuel type used was determined by the algorithms found in Table 1 - Annex 2. Table 1 - Annex 5 Distribution of Fuel Types Used by Utility Service and Settlement Type Rural N = 778 PGT N = 188 All Households N = 2990 Urban N = 2024 70 9 22 89 5 6 66 29 5 21 13 66 Cooking Network Gas Bottled Gas Electric Stove 61 22 18 71 8 21 92 4 4 27 61 12 Hot Water Hot Water Connection Gas Boiler (Network Gas) Gas Boiler (Bottled Gas) Coal or Other 57 19 20 4 75 17 7 1 52 40 4 4 10 20 59 11 Central Water/Sewerage Central Water & Sewerage Only Central Water Only Sewerage Neither 66 11 1 23 86 4 1 9 47 34 0 19 17 22 <1 61 Telephone With Connection No Connection 44 56 51 49 53 47 24 76 100 100 100 100 Expenditure Decile Heat Central (District) Heating Gas Boiler Heating Coal Heating Electricity 43 ANNEX 6 COMPARISON OF 1996 CONSUMPTION NORMS WITH ESTIMATED AVERAGE ACTUAL USAGE At present, only a few households have meters to record actual energy consumption, with the exception of electricity consumption, which is generally metered. In most households, consumption of gas, district heat, and hot water is estimated based on “consumption norms”. Given that the norms are adjusted to ensure that system losses fall within allowed parameters, many households are paying for significantly more energy than they are actually consuming. Gas consumption levels and, therefore, gas norms, vary by type of use and between regions. Gas consumption norms for cooking range from 7 to 15 cubic meters/person/month. In meter testing programs in Vladimir and Volgograd, actual consumption has been found to be on the order of 7 to 8 cubic meters/person/month— lower than the consumption norms in many regions. Gas consumption norms for water heating range from 12 to 25 cubic meters/person/month. Actual consumption in France and Germany is around 14 cubic meters/person/month. Allowing for the relatively low efficiency of water heaters, the actual consumption on average is probably relatively close to the billing norms. However, in some areas, where the norms are particularly high, there appears to be significant overbilling. Consumption norms for gas heating also appear high relative to expected actual consumption. Based on conservative estimates of energy consumption and conversion efficiency, (25 Mcal/square meter/month and 60% conversion efficiency), gas consumption for space heating should be on the order of 5 cubic meters/square meter/month. This could vary by plus or minus 25 percent in the northern and southern regions, respectively. While the consumption norms in the major centers are close to these levels, in outlying regions the norms range from 7 to 14 cubic meters/square meter/month. With respect to district heating and hot water supply, only limited information has been collected on actual heat consumption and hence on the error level incorporated into the consumption norms. Early indications are, however, that overbilling is less significant for heat/hot water than for gas supply, and that part of the overbilling for heat may be offset by under-billing for hot water. We examined a scenario in which gas consumption was adjusted to more realistically reflect actual consumption (i.e. 8 and 14 cubic meters/person/month for cooking and water heating, respectively, and 4, 5, and 6 cubic meters/square meter/month for heating in the south, central, and northern regions, respectively). In addition, consumption norms for district heat and hot water were reduced by a flat 10 percent to reflect the possible impact of more accurate recording of usage. 44 ANNEX 7 ANOTHER VIEW OF HOUSING-UTILITY BURDEN In our analysis, estimates of housing-utility burden have used total expenditures as a proxy for income. While this is useful for understanding the relative impact of a policy change, this approach overestimates the impact on the population as a whole. The reason is that the total expenditures includes an imputed value for housing and utility charges at their subsidized rates. This underestimates a household’s income in the sense of their well-being because the value of the services they are consuming is much greater than represented by the subsidized rates. What would happen to the current and full-cost housing burdens if the monthly market rent value of the dwelling was included as part of the household’s income?23 To illustrate the effect of including the market rent value of the household’s dwelling, we will use an example from Moscow. Table 1 shows the mean 1996 and full-cost housingutility charges for Moscow as well as the mean total expenditures, market rent unit value, and an income estimate including this market rental unit value. The mean market rent value for a Moscow housing unit was calculated from Wave 4 of the Moscow Longitudinal Housing Survey which was conducted in December 1995 (roughly one year before the RLMS). In the MLHS twelve households reported paying market rent for their unit, with rents ranging from $200 to $400. Table 1 - Annex 7 Income Estimate That Includes Market Rent Value of Housing Unit: Illustrative Example of Moscow City (Mean Values) Input into Housing Burden Calculation Ruble Value (1996 Thousand Rubles) Dollar Value (Rubles / 5000) 1996 Charges 113.2 $22.6 Full-Cost Charges 563.4 $112.7 Total Expenditures 2,956.3 $591.3 Market Rental Value of Dwelling (1995) 1,237.5 $247.5 23 It is common practice in expenditure surveys to impute a rental value for owners occupying their own units. In essence, the owners are paying rent to themselves. To understand the potential income represented by the unit, consider the case when the owner rents out his property and moves in with family members for free. 45 Income Proxy (Total Expenditures + Imputed Market Rent Value of Dwelling) 4193.8 $838.8 Note: Both household incomes (expenditures) and market rents are higher in Moscow than in most of Russia. The housing burden drops considerably when the household’s income is upwardly revised to reflect their unit’s market value. Instead of a 1996 housing burden of 6 percent, the households have a burden of 4 percent. Under the full-cost recovery scenario, the median burden of Moscow households decreases from 32 to 17 percent. This simple example illustrates that the true income of Russian households includes the value of their housing for which they either pay nominal rent or receive free because they have privatized the unit. Table 2 - Annex 7 Revised Estimates of Housing-Utility Burden Taking Into Account the Market Value of Dwelling Consumed by Household: Illustrative Example of Moscow City (Median Values of Percents) Level of Housing-Utility Charges Based on Total Expenditures Based on Income Estimate with Market Value of Dwelling Housing-Utility Burden Based on Current Charges and Total Expenditures 6 4 Housing-Utility Burden Based on Full-Cost Charges and Total Expenditures 32 17 46 References Klugman, Jeni, ed. Poverty in Russia: Public Policy and Private Responses, Washington, DC, The World Bank. Martinot, Eric. Investments to Improve the Energy Efficiency of Existing Residential Buildings in Countries of the Former Soviet Union. The World Bank, 1997. Mikelsons, Maris, et. al. Housing Allowance Design: An Evaluation for Slovakia, The Urban Institute, 1996. Struyk, R., A. Puzanov, and L. Lee. “Monitoring Russia’s Experience with Housing Allowances,” in Urban Studies, Vol. 34, No. 11, 1789-1818, 1997. U.S. Department of Commerce and the U.S. Department of Housing and Urban Development. American Housing Survey for the United States in 1995. Issued April 1997. 48 ANNEX 8 TARIFF INFORMATION USED FOR IMPUTING HOUSING AND UTILITY CHARGES Oblast or City St Petersburg Moscow City Moscow Oblast Syktyvkar Leningrad Oblast Smolensk Rzhev Tula Kaluga Nizhniy Novgorod Cheboksary Penza Lipetsk Tambov Kazan Saratov Saratov Volgograd Nalchik Rostov-na-Donu Krasnodar Stavropol Chelyabinsk Kurgan Izhevsk Orsk Perm Miass Tomsk Surgut Biusk Krasnoyarsk Vladivostok Blagoveschensk 1996 District 1996 Hot 1996 Central Heat Tariff /sq Water Tariff / Water-Sewerage 1996 Kvarplata m person Tariff / person Tariff / sq m 335 3,012 9,860 400 492 9,138 6,968 310 650 7,579 7,776 404 777 14,625 5,175 542 600 8,000 5,000 373 304 5,390 1,296 141 432 3,240 2,380 160 291 4,254 2,768 139 350 4,000 3,000 150 480 5,064 3,496 543 350 4,500 400 77 450 2,079 1,594 103 276 6,905 5,263 369 300 3,500 2,000 168 300 1,200 2,084 990 305 3,185 2,934 45 305 3,185 2,934 45 300 4,000 1,500 197 200 4,000 1,900 166 450 6,500 6,000 202 550 9,075 6,090 300 500 5,000 6,000 276 810 10,875 2,844 668 1,166 5,618 5,864 175 420 4,000 1,120 366 763 4,881 6,337 420 397 4,500 3,044 252 831 10,983 10,085 322 700 4,320 5,050 300 865 5,760 14,870 1,490 840 9,820 3,400 214 644 8,366 3,636 555 1,576 10,508 2,736 385 1,000 11,000 6,000 450 46 1996 Maintenance Tariff / sq m 368 310 404 375 373 129 160 139 107 543 77 100 336 96 900 45 45 176 166 200 300 276 625 158 366 400 156 315 154 1,200 214 555 385 450 Cost Recovery Level for Communal 1996 Coal 1996 Bottled Services Price / ton Gas Price / liter 35% 150,000 40,000 17% 166,300 . 35% 166,300 21,000 25% 266,000 12,495 30% 150,000 40,000 25% 150,000 32,000 30% 150,000 20,000 20% 150,000 15,225 30% 150,000 31,500 25% 350,000 30,000 30% 180,400 27,300 25% 150,000 29,400 40% 348,300 26,000 25% 584,500 48,300 40% 162,000 25,200 25% 250,000 21,000 25% 250,000 21,000 30% 585,000 21,000 30% 150,000 20,000 40% 150,000 22,000 30% 150,000 20,000 40% 345,000 20,000 30% 150,000 50,000 35% 161,300 25,000 30% 250,000 43,800 40% 150,000 25,000 30% 150,000 6,300 30% 150,000 50,000 30% 203,600 40,000 35% 240,100 40,000 30% 162,800 40,000 40% 150,000 44,100 35% 150,000 46,200 35% 242,400 72,000 ANNEX 8 TARIFF INFORMATION USED FOR IMPUTING HOUSING AND UTILITY CHARGES Oblast or City St Petersburg Moscow City Moscow Oblast Syktyvkar Leningrad Oblast Smolensk Rzhev Tula Kaluga Nizhniy Novgorod Cheboksary Penza Lipetsk Tambov Kazan Saratov Saratov Volgograd Nalchik Rostov-na-Donu Krasnodar Stavropol Chelyabinsk Kurgan Izhevsk Orsk Perm Miass Tomsk Surgut Biusk Krasnoyarsk Vladivostok Blagoveschensk 1996 Flat Telephone Tariff 28,000 12,000 10,500 24,000 20,000 14,000 12,000 10,000 12,000 18,000 12,544 13,500 10,000 10,000 15,000 14,000 14,000 11,000 10,000 12,000 12,500 8,000 10,000 20,000 15,000 20,000 20,000 22,000 18,000 28,000 16,000 24,000 20,000 30,000 1996 Network Gas Tariff / person (for stove use) 1,000 470 325 953 1,545 1,100 1,200 1,350 2,033 1,350 900 800 2,475 1,200 1,000 891 891 940 850 1,440 960 640 1,827 1,400 592 1,280 1,920 1,827 1,200 1,200 2,200 2,000 2,000 2,000 Consumption Norm for Gas Hot Water (cubic meter / 12.9 12.5 13.1 18.8 10.0 12.0 12.0 13.0 19.8 15.0 20.0 10.0 15.0 13.0 12.5 15.0 15.0 12.0 15.0 16.0 25.0 25.0 14.7 13.0 15.8 15.0 15.0 14.7 12.5 13.0 14.0 25.0 25.0 25.0 Consumption Norm for Gas 1996 Heat (cubic 1996 Gas Tariff Gas Cost Electricity Electricity Cost meter / sq m) /cubic meter Recovery Level Tariff /kWh Recovery Level 4.1 145 55% 10,000 43% 7.6 57 21% 13,000 49% 4.5 41 15% 13,000 49% 12.0 75 31% 18,400 61% 4.5 150 56% 10,000 43% 7.0 110 41% 8,000 34% 7.0 150 56% 6,000 30% 7.5 193 73% 5,000 27% 6.3 231 87% 10,000 35% 4.3 169 65% 8,000 49% 8.0 90 34% 7,000 56% 7.5 80 31% 9,000 50% 7.0 309 100% 3,700 19% 14.0 120 45% 6,000 30% 8.5 83 32% 12,000 38% 7.0 59 23% 9,000 38% 7.0 59 23% 9,000 38% 7.0 118 44% 9,000 45% 55% 12.0 85 31% 15,000 6.2 111 41% 8,000 50% 13.0 74 27% 12,000 50% 13.0 49 18% 10,000 45% 5.5 174 68% 8,000 32% 8.0 200 78% 12,000 43% 8.3 74 29% 8,500 43% 7.0 128 53% 8,000 41% 7.0 192 75% 10,000 38% 5.5 174 68% 8,000 32% 10.1 145 56% 10,000 43% 7.3 171 77% 8,000 43% 8.6 220 83% 7,500 37% 13.0 154 69% 8,400 54% 13.0 154 64% 15,000 50% 13.0 154 60% 15,000 50% 47