A Summary of and Reaction to Professor Randall S. Thomas’s “What Should We Do About Multijurisdictional Litigation in M&A Deals?” Daniel Waxman May 2, 2014 Abstract Multijurisdictional deal litigation is not a recent phenomenon; it has influenced forum selection in M&A cases since the 1970s. However, the changing landscape of M&A litigation in recent years has resulted in an increased number of cases filed in multiple jurisdictions. This increased frequency, combined with the decreasing quality of complaints, has resulted in an unjustified increase in litigation and settlement costs for defendant-corporations. This paper dissects Randall S. Thomas’s 2013 article, “What Should We Do About Multijurisditional Litigation in M&A Deals?,” published in the Vanderbilt Law Review. Thomas’s article explores the causes and consequences of and proposes solutions to this recent trend. According to Thomas, two potential solutions exist to remedy the recent increase in multijurisdictional deal litigation. The first is the defendant-corporation’s adoption of a forum selection clause, effectively allowing the corporation to select the forum in which to litigate the deal challenge. However, issues exist as to the clause’s enforceability and whether plaintiff’s attorneys can circumvent it. The second potential solution is a tweaked version of the current system of judicial comity, allowing judges from the various forums in which the litigation is filed to discuss and decide which forum is most appropriate. This solution is not without its own problems, including potential disagreement among judges and the absence of an effective policing mechanism. Introduction a. Paper Outline This paper summarizes the potential causes for the increase in multijurisdictional litigation, and supports Thomas’s finding that the cause may be a combination of multiple factors. It then assesses the costs and benefits of multijurisdictional litigation, and ends with a discussion of proposed policy responses including forum-selection clauses and comity (legal reciprocity). b. The Driving Force: Agency Cost or Plaintiff’s Bar As described by Thomas, Multijurisdictional M&A litigation is “the latest battleground” in the battle between investors and companies concerning representative litigation claims, the merits of such claims and who the true beneficiaries are. Investors argue that direct and derivative law suits are necessary to efficiently monitor management behavior, while companies respond that the plaintiffs’ bar is the driving force behind such claims “as agency costs in contingency fee suits make the lawyer the real party in interest.” c. Paving the Path: Civil Procedure The existing federal rules of civil procedure create the potential for multijurisdictional litigation in M&A deals. For example, according to Thomas: “Shareholders that wish to challenge the proposed terms of an M&A transaction can sue in either a state or federal court located in either the target company's state of incorporation or the location of the company's headquarters (assuming the defendants have the necessary presence in the jurisdiction).” Though plaintiff shareholders may bring the action in either of the two jurisdictions mentioned above, the Internal Affairs Doctrine continues to govern the controlling law (assuming a state cause of action). Therefore, while a lawsuit challenging a Delaware corporation transaction may be filed in the location of the company’s headquarters, Delaware corporate law remains controlling. However, hundreds of cases each year may be brought as federal securities class actions, in which case federal law controls: This begs the question, why file in a different jurisdiction only to have the same law applied? One response Thomas offers is that Delaware courts are relatively skeptical of M&A deal challenges alleging disclosure violations, making it more difficult for plaintiffs to have their day in court. This explanation may also explain the recent “upsurge in multijurisdictional litigation,” considering the comparable upsurge in disclosure-based complaints. d. Recent Trends, Their Effects, and Potential Responses i. Trends In his article, Thomas points out that “[s]ince the end of the financial crisis, . . . the number of jurisdictions in which shareholders attack each transaction,” and “the percentage of large deals that have been challenged in multiple jurisdictions” have increased. For example, from 2005 to 2011, the percent of large deals challenged in multiple jurisdictions rose from 38.7% to 94.2%. ii. Effects Thomas’s article presents multiple views concerning the costs and benefits of multijurisdictional litigation. For example, “[t]he defense bar argues that these suits have vastly increased the transaction costs of completing deals without producing any offsetting benefits,” while others argue that such costs are minimal and provide investors the benefit of choice of forum. In a 2012 article in the Northwestern University Law Review, Professors Thomas and Thompson argued that although multijurisdictional litigation increases costs, the cost increases are modest given that (1) “not much discovery is taken in most deal cases and few pretrial dispositive motions are filed and briefed,” (2) “only one preliminary injunction motion is scheduled per transaction,” and (3) although “more than one court must be involved in every case, . . . judges are not being asked to decide weighty issues, . . . but rather to manage some preliminary discovery motion practice . . . .” iii. Responses A. Two Primary Responses: Forum Selection Clauses and Judicial Comity. Thomas’s article proposes two potential responses to the recent increase in multijurisdictional litigation. The first is supported by the defense bar and its academic supporters. This response, according to Thomas, is to completely “eliminate the shareholders’ choice of forum,” which can be done by mandated litigation in the state of incorporation, or allowing the target’s board to choose the litigation venue. The second potential response is supported by “judges, academics, and investors who believe the current system of judicial comity is appropriate,” though some tweaks may be needed. These responses are discussed in greater detail in Section 3 below. B. Two Secondary Responses: Dismissing Weak Actions and Limiting Fees in Disclosure Benefits Cases. Thomas suggests two additional responses to the increase in multijurisdictional litigation: First, assuming the increase in disclosure-based settlements is an indication that the quality of M&A suits is decreasing, “courts in all jurisdictions should . . . dismiss[] . . . weak shareholder class actions and derivative suits, particularly those that allege only disclosure violations in arm’s length acquisitions.” Second, Thomas suggests that if companies are in fact correct that the plaintiffs’ bar is the cause of this increase in multijurisdictional litigation, “judges should not hesitate to cut or deny fees in disclosure-based settlements where they find that the resultant change to the disclosures is of little value to investors.” Such an approach could dissuade plaintiff’s attorneys—arguably the primary beneficiary of such suits—to waste the court’s time with litigation that may result in no real benefit to the ostensible plaintiffs. According to Thomas, disclosures are the “most common non-monetary result of shareholder litigation,” and should the court determine that such disclosures provided “important” information to shareholders, there is still a “wide variance among those benefits that are considered material.” In fact, the Delaware Court of Chancery has stated that “it will grant ‘minimal fees for minimal benefits and major fees for major results.’” Professor Davidoff of Ohio State University College of Law suggests that increased disclosures to shareholders should “produce new and unfavorable information about the merger and therefore reduce the percentage of shares voted in favor of the deal.” However, a forthcoming study to be published in the Texas Law Review conducted by Steven M. Davidoff, et al., concludes that there is “no significant evidence that disclosure-only settlements affect shareholder voting” and suggests that “courts should reject disclosure settlements as a basis for attorney fee awards.” However, the recognition that additional disclosures create value for shareholders provides an incentive to plaintiff’s attorneys to take on disclosure-only cases. In fact, during summer 2013, I was researching what our adversary’s fees were likely to be in the In re Google Shareholder Litigation case my firm was settling. The more we searched, the more “therapeutic benefit” cases (providing the shareholder plaintiffs non-monetary benefits) we came across relative to monetary benefit cases. Thus, therapeutic benefit cases comprise a large portion of attorney’s fee cases in Delaware corporate law relative to monetary benefit cases. Therefore, either dismissing a larger portion of these solely therapeutic cases, or at least providing increased certainty as to the amount of fees that will be awarded (at a rate much lower than the current rate) could be sufficient to deter such claims. 1. The Problem: Recent Increase in Multijurisdictional Litigation and DisclosureBased Settlements—A History of Class Actions This section includes a brief overview of the history of M&A litigation and concludes with a discussion of the benefits and drawbacks of multijurisdictional litigation. In the 1980s, takeovers began to accelerate as corporate conglomerates were broken up by raiders convinced that the value of the separate parts was greater than the whole. In the 1990s, multijurisdictional litigation existed in only a small number of cases and a relatively large percent of deals resulted in quantifiable monetary benefits to shareholders. From 2007 to 2012, the number of deals decreased while the number of cases involving multijurisdictional litigation increased, and many cases resulted in disclosure settlements. a. The 1980s Takeover Wave: A Response to Over-Conglomeration This era represents the “Golden Age” of shareholder litigation, and is characterized by a sharp increase in hostile takeovers due to the realization that conglomeration is not quite as profitable as managers once presumed: As Thomas suggests, “[t]hese deals frequently spurred both the target and bidder to file suits.” Even in this era the litigation was multijurisdictional. An excerpt from Thomas’s article: Bidders would ask the courts to strike down the target's defenses under state law and would challenge the accuracy of the target company's disclosures under federal law. If the target was a Delaware corporation, the bidder would routinely file in the Delaware Chancery Court as quickly as possible to fix the forum that would determine what defenses the target could use and how it could use them in responding to the unsolicited takeover proposal. Targets would respond as quickly as possible by filing their own suit in their hometown state court. They would ask the court to permit the use of their defenses as they pleased or try to impede the bid in a variety of ways, such as alleging that the bidder had violated federal securities laws. The target's hope was that the judge would be more sympathetic to its situation given the large number of local workers that it employed. While costly and time-consuming (due to a “flurry of jurisdictional motions”), this “blatant forum shopping” described above was commonplace in such litigation, and seen as necessary given the “high stakes” associated with the privilege of litigating the case in a given party’s preferred forum. While shareholders filed class actions in the 1980s, the real drama lied in the suit between the bidder and target. However, Thomas suggests that the shareholder class action “assume[d] greater prominence” after the Delaware Supreme Court held in Time Warner that “Paramount’s tender offer was reasonably perceived by Time’s board to pose a threat to Time and that the Time board's ‘response’ to that threat was, under the circumstances, reasonable and proportionate.” According to Thomas, this holding essentially allows a “target unbridled discretion to use a poison pill, resulting in the near demise of the hostile tender offer and paving the way for shareholder litigation to assume greater prominence.” b. 1993–2001: Friendly Mergers and the Baseline Measure of M&A Litigation “The 1990s brought new waves of friendly mergers,” and the booming stock market only added to the frenzy by facilitating stock-for-stock transactions: The Time Warner case mentioned above and the friendly nature of most 1990s mergers resulted in a drastic decline in bidder-target litigation, and Thomas notes that “shareholder representative actions filled the void.” Such class actions generally resulted in substantive, quantifiable results. For example, Thomas’s article suggests that “they made it harder for bidders to complete deals but had a positive effect on premiums in completed deals. About one-third of these cases settled, and in about 40% of those settlements, investors received an increase in the deal consideration.” According to Thomas, this era provides the “baseline measure” of M&A deal litigation. While a large proportion of M&A deals in the late 90s resulted in some form of litigation, Thomas suggests that “there was little multijurisdictional litigation,” and “representative suits had an economically beneficial impact for shareholders. Settlements occurred regularly, frequently increasing the deal price paid to target company shareholders. Shareholder litigation, in other words, was a useful mechanism for policing the agency costs of management.” c. 2007–2012: The Financial Crisis As evidenced by the graph below, the drying up of the credit markets during the 2007– 2008 global financial crisis resulted in a drop in M&A deals in 2008 and again in 2009, followed by a leveling off in 2010 where the number of deals has remained steady at around 42 thousand throughout 2011 and 2012. Thomas proposes that such a drop can be viewed as a product of the 2007 financial crisis in combination with the “Delaware Chancery Court's decision in Air Products & Chemicals, Inc. v. Airgas, Inc. and the Delaware Supreme Court's ruling in Versata Enterprises v. Selectica, Inc.,” making hostile takeovers more difficult by sanctioning target company defenses including the combination of a poison pill and classified board. In addition to decreasing the number and value of M&A deal transactions, Thomas suggests that the financial crisis and legal landscape of the mid-to-late 2000s also resulted in three “undesirable shifts in representative shareholder litigation.” First, though the number of post-crisis M&A deals has decreased, the total number of attacked deals has stayed constant, and as a result the percentage of deals being challenged is much greater now than in the pre financial crisis era. Professor Thomas makes the argument that the static number of challenges throughout the depressed M&A environment is evidence of the plaintiffs’ bar’s influence on deal litigation, given that the bar has “a fixed amount of litigation capacity . . . and therefore continuing to file roughly the same number of cases.” To illustrate: Second, though the number of M&A deals decreased during the 2007–2012 era, there was also a “sharp uptick in multijurisdictional litigation.” For example, from the year 2000 to 2010, the percentage of deals targeted by multijurisdictional cases increased from 3.3% to 47.6%. See the following graphic summarizing the number of cases subject to multiple jurisdictions from 2007 through 2013: Number of Filing Jurisdictions: Finally, Professor Thomas notes that “[s]ettlement patterns appear to have changed as well.” For example, of the cases settled in 1999 and 2000, 42% resulted in increased consideration for shareholders and only 18.5% involved disclosure claims, however in as early as 2005 “disclosure-based settlements constituted about 63.9% of all settlements; by 2011, that number rose to 79.5%.” Such a drastic shift in settlement benefits is concerning given that, as Thomas points out, “the resultant change to the disclosures is of little value to investors,” while plaintiff’s attorneys still receive, on average, between $400,000 and $575,000 for such settlements. I see this as a major incentive for plaintiff’s attorneys to continue bringing cases, regardless of the actual benefits to shareholders, so long as they continue to receive fee awards. d. The Arguments For and Against Restricting Choice of Forum i. Argument For: Multijurisdictional Litigation is an Abusive ForumShopping Technique Thomas points out that during the M&A “Golden Age” of the late 1970s and 80s, forum shopping was seen as simple zealous advocacy necessary in M&A litigation utilized by firms representing both plaintiffs and defendants. However, Thomas continues, “the defense bar now represents only defendant-corporations” and, “[a]s a result,” such firms and their corporate clients now argue that “multijurisdictional litigation is an abusive forum-shopping technique.” Therefore, the defense bar advocates for the adoption of forum-selection provisions which, in its view, would remedy such abusive forum-shopping, but would also effectively “reverse the forum shopping in their clients’ own favor.” ii. Argument Against: The Existing System of Comity is Sufficient Thomas’s article explains that our existing system of federalism has resulted in and “fostered the horizontal interaction of sister state courts as well as the vertical back and forth between state and federal courts.” Such a long-standing, successful system should not be overturned without “careful consideration,” as this state of frequent multijurisdictional litigation and disclosure settlements may be just another “passing fad.” Before proposing solutions to the “problem” of multijurisdictional litigation, it is important to discuss whether a solution is needed by assessing the reason for its recent increase in frequency and its costs and benefits. 2. The Causes, Costs, and Benefits of Multijurisdictional Litigation Multijurisdictional litigation has burdened M&A transactions since the mid-1970s. However, before analyzing “solutions” to the “problem” of increased multijurisdictional litigation, it is important to determine the reasons why this increase has occurred as well as its costs and benefits. According to Thomas’s article, the recent increase in multijurisdictional litigation can be attributed to the legal landscape condoning it, plaintiff’s firms being incentivized to bring such claims, non-Delaware courts’ willingness and desire to accept such cases, and the desirability of non-Delaware court procedures. Further, Thomas suggests that multijurisdictional litigation per se is not all bad. For example, it conforms to traditional rules, so that leaving it in place does not shock the current system. It also preserves states’ abilities to govern corporations operating within their borders and keeps Delaware in check by allowing other states to influence corporations and the corporate legal landscape. However, the costs are substantial and include increased settlements and attorney’s fees due to many courts’ willingness to accept cases that would otherwise be rejected in Delaware; an unjustified increase in the use of judicial resources; plaintiffs firms filing premature complaints to substantiate their claim to the lead plaintiff designation; and courts accepting cases solely on the basis that if the case is dismissed it may be accepted in a different jurisdiction. a. The Cause of the Recent Increase in Multijurisdictional Litigation is Fourfold i. The Legal Landscape: Matsushita Sanctions Multijurisdictional Litigation Thomas suggests that Matsushita Electric Industrial Co. v. Epstein, a United States Supreme Court case decided in 1996, “allows plaintiffs that have been left out of a deal litigation in a first court (often Delaware) to file suit in a second court (federal or another state) in order to try and gain control over the entire litigation.” The effect of the above rule shifts the power structure between defense and plaintiff firms in favor of defense firms. For example, once a case is filed in Delaware, a second plaintiff’s firm may file in a different jurisdiction and threaten to settle the case and release all claims, including the case that was filed first. To that end, Thomas suggests that “[d]efendants may run a reverse auction, in which competing plaintiffs’ counsel offer to settle their suits at the lowest price.” I see Thomas’s “reverse auction” effect of Matsushita having multiple effects. First, as Thomas suggests, it will likely reduce the value of the suit for the plaintiff’s firms. This will in turn create a disincentive for plaintiff’s firms to put in the extra work to file the initial suit given the possibility of a filing in a different jurisdiction. Therefore, the initial filing will likely be less detailed. To that end, it puts much of the bargaining power in the hands of defense firms who are now able to pit multiple plaintiff firms against each other to lower the settlement price. ii. Newer and Smaller Plaintiffs’ Law Firms Have Incentives to Bring These Cases First, as stated in Section a above, multijurisdictional litigation is a disincentive for a larger, more established law firm to expend time, money, and other resources bringing a claim, when it can be taken over by a filing in another jurisdiction. The flipside to this argument is that Matsushita is an incentive for smaller, less-known firms to file on a case already pending in a corporation’s state of incorporation (usually Delaware), should that corporation have its headquarters in the smaller firm’s state. Thomas indicates that if a smaller firm can “establish [itself] as lead counsel in an action in any one of these jurisdictions, [it] will have substantial leverage to get at least part of any attorneys’ fee award paid in a global settlement of all the competing cases.” iii. The Market for Corporate M&A Cases First, it is necessary to determine whether courts, notably the Delaware Chancery Court, desire to retain or increase the number of M&A cases filed in their jurisdiction. Given Delaware’s prominence in all matters corporate, it may not seem necessary for the Delaware courts to vie for as many M&A cases as possible; after all, Thomas suggests that “their dockets are very busy, and none of the judges seem to be lacking for things to do.” However, Thomas further suggests that the Delaware courts may be “concerned that the state will lose companies, a significant concern in a state where corporate fees account for 15% to 20% of the state’s budget.” The fact that “Delaware courts have awarded fees that are on average $400,000 to $500,000 higher than other courts” evidences Delaware’s desire to retain M&A cases, or simply represents Delaware’s acceptance of only the most meritorious cases (evidenced by Delaware judges “publicly disparag[ing] the quality of many of the cases being filed”). The Chancery Court’s ability to distinguish the meritorious claims and dispose of others will likely lead to the strongest cases being initially filed in Delaware where the judges are “experienced and knowledgeable” and will “issue[] predictable and speedy decisions.” Delaware’s expertise also incentivizes plaintiffs to bring weaker claims in alternative jurisdictions; non-Delaware judges are more likely to consider negative consequences of a specific transaction in that court’s jurisdiction (such as mass job losses and other economic harm) than the relatively objective Delaware courts. iv. Variances in Court Procedures According to Thomas, there are additional procedural variances between the Delaware courts and those in other areas of the country that may detract from a plaintiff’s willingness to file an M&A case in Delaware. For example, some states may “move forward without waiting on the delivery of proxy statements,” while other courts may be less reluctant to “enjoin a transaction in which no other bidder has come forward,” and finally “the Delaware Chancery Court does not permit juries.” Each of the above factors may have contributed in whole or in part to the rise in multijurisdictional litigation, but to proffer a compelling solution, one must be clear that there is a problem, so the paper now turns to the costs and benefits. b. The Benefits and Costs of Multijurisdictional Litigation Similar to the causes of multijurisdictional litigation, the costs and benefits are multifactorial and cumulative, however it is difficult to quantify, without additional research, which are most substantial. i. The Benefits: Conforms to Traditional Rules, Preserves State’s Ability to Govern its Corporations, Keeps Delaware in Check The first benefit offered by Thomas’s article is that the current system conforms to the status quo in our legal system. Absent an extraordinary exception to this time-tested system, it may be best to leave well enough alone. The second benefit suggested by Thomas is that the United States corporate landscape allows states to influence the corporations that reside within its borders. For example, as stated by Professor Alan R. Palmiter in his Corporations E&E (seventh edition), the Internal Affairs Doctrine requires state courts “to accept the corporate law rules of the incorporating state, even when those rules are different or inconsistent with rules of the forum state.” While this provides the governing law for corporations incorporated under its laws, the state has little ability to affect the laws by which foreign corporations merely operating within the state abide. Therefore, multijurisdictional litigation, assuming it provides for increased litigation in the states in which a corporation is doing business, may provide an additional means for the courts of a given state to regulate corporations operating within that state’s boundaries. Finally, in conjunction with the previous point, multijurisdictional litigation not only allows courts to adjudicate the behavior of foreign corporations operating within their borders, but would also reduce Delaware’s virtual monopoly of corporate law. According to Thomas, it “gives other states’ courts a channel to articulate their state’s interest in these cases and thereby influence corporate law.” ii. The Costs: Increased Settlements, Attorney’s Fees, Judicial Resources, Hasty Filings, and Inter-Court Competition. A. Settlement and Attorney’s Fees While there has been little empirical research on the direct costs of multijurisdictional litigation on defendant corporations, Professor Thomas argues that any cost increase due to attorney’s fees and settlements is likely minimal. For example, of the 124 deals over $100 million in 2010, over 28% were dismissed without settlement; however, the impact of multijurisdictional litigation on the cases that do settle is unclear. Thomas further argues that while multijurisdictional litigation may create more settlements if courts in states other than Delaware are less likely to dismiss a case, such settlements are not likely to result in any direct costs to the defendant corporations, as “these settlements involve increased disclosure to the class of affected shareholders, and not increased consideration.” Thomas further claims that it is unlikely that defendant corporations will incur any substantial increase in attorney’s fees due to multijurisdictional litigation. First, deal litigation is characterized by few significant motions, little discovery, and most cases are resolved quickly. Second, as stated, when cases are filed in multiple jurisdictions, it allows defense counsel to “run a reverse auction,” essentially forcing plaintiff’s firms in different jurisdictions to bid each other down. Third, “most multijurisdictional cases are only litigated in one forum because the judges and attorneys from each court agree on which court should hear the case.” Finally, “only one preliminary injunction hearing needs to be scheduled per transaction.” Therefore, Thomas concludes, while defense costs may increase slightly, they are likely immaterial and difficult to quantify. However, former Chancellor and current Chief Justice of the Delaware Supreme Court Leo Strine argues that the costs of attorney’s fees from settled cases are more substantial than Thomas suggests. For example, Strine argues that plaintiffs “attack third-party merger transactions regardless of whether any conflict of interest is involved, and propose settlements that, as we shall soon see, provide monetary benefits to the plaintiffs’ lawyers, not the class.” Further, such attorney’s fees are substantial, while the benefits provided by the litigation to the plaintiff shareholders are not: [G]rowth in the frequency of deal litigation does not seem to be matched by growth in recoveries for those whose interests are to be represented in such litigation. To the contrary, the recent evidence . . . demonstrates the predominance of deal litigation settlements involving payment of attorney’s fees to plaintiffs’ counsel, but no payment to class members. We acknowledge that in some circumstances supplemental disclosure or other non-monetary consideration can justify a settlement in which plaintiffs’ counsel earns a fee, but the absence of any monetary consideration in 84% of deal litigation settlements, together with the increase in the volume of such litigation, suggests that less salutary considerations may be at work, and that there is a systemic failure endangering the ability of representative shareholder litigation to produce net benefits to investors. Strine likens disclosure cases to medical malpractice cases, asking whether “it would be acceptable for 84% of medical malpractice suits to be settled with plaintiffs’ lawyers succeeding in obtaining only additional information about what the physician did wrong, but not getting a monetary award for their clients and still getting a fee for their victory.” Finally, while Thomas argues that multiple jurisdictions favor defendants because it empowers them to conduct a reverse auction effectively decreasing the settlement price, Strine sees it differently: [F]ilings by multiple plaintiffs' law firms in multiple forums can be viewed as cooperative, as well as competitive, because the resulting additional defense costs and uncertainties about which court will hear the case, and how it will decide it, increase the pressure on defendants interested in global resolution of litigation to pay larger overall attorney's fees than might be paid if litigation were confined to a single forum. B. Judicial Resources Intuitively, Thomas suggests that the more jurisdictions a case is filed in, the more effort courts, judges, court staff, etc. must expend to resolve the case. However, as stated in the previous Section, Thomas points out that that M&A deal litigation requires relatively little court effort, “so courts will probably expend relatively few resources on this litigation,” and the courts outside Delaware assume these cases voluntarily. Another cost of multijurisdictional litigation purported by Thomas is an increased number of frivolous claims. Regardless of the materiality of the incremental costs within a given deal litigation, increasing the total number of cases may incur a substantial cost on defendant corporations. In fact, Thomas points out that “a common refrain from the defense bar is that all M&A deal litigation is frivolous.” (emphasis added). Given the Court of Chancery’s disdain for and ability to detect frivolous deal litigation, it may behoove a plaintiff’s firm to file a weaker case in a different jurisdiction. In addition, recent “settlement percentages in Delaware have gone from 48.7% of all M&A class actions filed in 2005 to 76.9% of all such cases in 2012,” and “in 2005, disclosure-based settlements constituted 67% of all settlements in deal litigation, but . . . by 2011, this figure had increased to 84% of all settlements.” This is not to say that all disclosure-based claims are frivolous, though according to Thomas, in many cases “the resultant change to the disclosures is of little value to investors.” The disclosure settlement is an indication of the poor quality of most M&A cases filed in the recent merger wave, and many commentators blame the decreasing quality on multijurisdictional litigation given that many cases are filed in jurisdictions more sympathetic to weak deal cases than Delaware. According to Leo Strine, “[c]orporations incorporated in many states now appear to suffer material costs in litigation over multiple jurisdictions, which results in payment of attorneys’ fees but no benefit for shareholders.” The following chart summarizes the disparity in recent years between cases that have been settled or dismissed and those that have gone to judgment: Further, Strine and his co-authors continue, multijurisdictional litigation leads to “unnecessary expedited proceedings in weak cases.” Generally, the defendants defending a case brought in the corporation’s state of incorporation “would be inclined to oppose plaintiffs’ request for expedited proceedings, and the court would be inclined to deny that request.” However, when an additional case is filed in a corporation’s state of operation or principle place of business and “in the absence of reasonable certainty that the court in that other forum would abstain from exercising jurisdiction, the defendants have little practical choice but to agree to and actively support expedition” resulting in increased litigation costs. C. Hasty Filings The issue here stems from the fact that, according to Thomas, courts tend to award lead counsel position to, or at least consider when awarding the position, which plaintiff’s firm filed first. This incentivizes plaintiff’s firms to hurriedly throw together a complaint, file, and then sit back and determine whether there is a meritorious claim somewhere behind the haphazard complaint. Thomas’s suggested response, already adopted in Delaware, is to simply “give preference to well-researched cases over poorly drafted ones.” Strine and his co-authors mention that “[a]nother foreseeable result [of hasty filings] is the imposition on corporate defendants of the costs of addressing and dismissing inadequately supported derivative complaints, costs that are ultimately borne by investors.” D. Inter-Court Competition Finally, Thomas suggests that when courts compete to hear these deal cases, “[p]laintiffs’ counsel has incentives to push for class certification and lead counsel designation,” and a “court that is competing to keep these cases may, in order to keep the case, be tempted to move too quickly to resolve these important procedural questions.” Furthermore, Thomas continues, a given court may refuse to reject an otherwise meritless claim if it suspects a plaintiff firm may file in a different court that would be more willing to accept the case. The result of such reluctant acceptance is that the corporation must settle a case that would otherwise have been dismissed, again providing a benefit to the plaintiff’s firm and nothing to the shareholders. c. Potential Solutions to the Disclosure-Based Settlement Issue Many problems associated with multijurisdictional litigation described above stem from the fact that the only benefit provided to shareholders is additional information, while plaintiff’s firms are making away with attorney’s fees based on the court’s often nebulous quantification of such therapeutic benefits. However, Thomas suggests two ways for courts to efficiently remedy this issue. First, “routinely den[ying] plaintiffs’ expedited-discovery requests when the case appears frivolous . . . ‘erases plaintiffs’ primary leverage to force pre-closing settlements’ and thus reduces the risk of an injunction.” Second, courts could grant motions to dismiss when the case appears frivolous. Thomas also cautions readers concerning two problems with these potential solutions. First, multijurisdictional litigation incentivizes defendants to support motions to expedite for fear of losing the case to a competing jurisdiction. Second, it is important to realize that, though it seems most disclosure-based cases are relatively meritless, some result in important benefits for plaintiffs. For example, in In re Del Monte, the initial claims were largely disclosure-based, but the additional information received by the plaintiffs “revealed that the board’s investment banker had ‘secretly and selfishly manipulated the sale process to engineer a transaction that would permit [it] to obtain lucrative buy-side financing fees.’” Therefore, “we must take care to avoid throwing the baby out with the bath water” by ensuring that a claim is in fact frivolous before treating it in the manner the solutions above suggest. 3. Potential Policy Solutions to the Costs Imposed by Multijurisdictional Litigation Professor Thomas’s article focuses on two potential policy responses to remedy the increased costs to defendant corporations caused by multijurisdictional litigation: Forumselection clauses and improved comity. Forum-selection clauses may help to remedy the issue by providing, in the corporation’s bylaws or charter, that “all shareholder suits [are] to be heard in the Delaware Chancery Court or give the defendant-company’s board of directors the option” to choose its preferred forum. Improved comity would provide for the judges who receive the cases to discuss and “resolve amongst themselves which single court ought to decide all of the cases arising out of the transaction.” a. Forum-Selection Clauses Thomas suggests that implanting a forum-selection clause in a corporation’s charter or bylaws “limit[s] the jurisdictions in which shareholders can pursue representative litigation.” This is perhaps the easiest, least expensive, and most practical solution for corporations themselves to not only solve the problem of increased costs resulting from plaintiffs filing cases in multiple forums, but also to provide the defendant-corporation its forum of choice. As suggested by Vice Chancellor Laster in Revlon, “if boards of directors and stockholders believe that a particular forum would provide an efficient and value-promoting locus for dispute resolution, then corporations are free to respond with charter provisions selecting an exclusive forum for intra-entity disputes.” However, despite its apparent ease and practicality, Thomas notes that “only a small number of firms have followed this advice,” and warns that widespread adoption of this solution creates a potential for defendant corporations to essentially bribe Delaware into becoming more management friendly by threatening to commence litigation elsewhere. i. Advantages to Forum-Selection Clauses A. Delaware Law Interpreted by Delaware Courts The most obvious and important advantage to forum selection clauses cited by Thomas is that, assuming most litigation will occur in Delaware as a result, the Delaware Chancery Court and Delaware Supreme Court remain the principal interpreters of the vast body of case law the Delaware courts have developed over hundreds of years. The Delaware Chancery Court is world-renowned for its ability to efficiently churn out difficult corporate law cases. Given the Chancery Court’s expertise and the complexity of many corporate law concepts, Thomas notes that “Delaware judges and lawyers often complain that other jurisdictions do a poor job of applying Delaware corporate law’s highly nuanced fiduciary principles because they are unfamiliar with those principles and have few opportunities to learn about them.” Therefore, Delaware courts and defendant corporations see forum-selection clauses as a way to not only reduce the costs associated with multijurisdictional litigation, but also to provide more certainty to the application of the Delaware legal principles, further reducing the costs of such litigation. To be sure, the legal certainty provided by the body of case law created by the Court of Chancery is a major advantage of incorporation in the state. To allow courts unfamiliar with the nuances of such laws to decide cases that would otherwise be resolved in Delaware reduces such certainty and increases not only the cost of litigation, but also the cost of questionable corporate decisions-making. Thomas agrees: “When other judges [outside of Delaware] are faced with these cases, it may lead to a wider variation of results, so that some bad cases may suddenly take on great value.” B. The Forum-Selection Clauses are Seemingly Enforceable Thomas notes that a corporation’s charter is “claimed to be [a] contract[], and forum selection provisions, in general, are permissible as a matter of contract law, so these particular types of clauses must also be enforceable.” Furthermore, former Chancellor Strine recently held that “a forum selection clause adopted by a board with the authority to adopt bylaws is valid and enforceable under Delaware law to the same extent as other contractual forum selection clauses.” However, it is still unclear whether the corporate board’s fiduciary obligations underpinning the corporate charter have an effect on the clause’s enforceability. C. Forum-Selection Clauses are Implemented by Corporations One huge advantage to forum-selection clauses not mentioned in Thomas’s article is that they are implemented by the very institutions adversely affected by the recent spike in multijurisdictional litigation. To the extent that the clauses are deemed valid and enforceable, corporations’ incentives are aligned with implementing these clauses to reduce the increased costs associated with such litigation. This benefit is in relation to utilizing judicial comity as a solution (discussed below). While judicial comity relies on judges’ efforts to create a solution that has minimal effect on them or their courts (and may even be harmful considering the jurisdiction has more control over the operation of foreign corporations within its borders given the increase in multijurisdictional litigation), forum-selection clauses can be implemented by corporations without relying on any outside actors (assuming their validity). ii. Disadvantages to Forum-Selection Clauses A. Backlash From Other States, Regulators and Lawyers Delaware is the pinnacle of U.S. corporate law, and as Thomas notes, a “strong push by Delaware for such clauses [essentially ensuring litigation in Delaware for deal cases arising out of the public companies incorporated in the state] may spark a backlash from other states, federal regulators, and plaintiffs’ lawyers.” Such a backlash, suggests Thomas, may have negative consequences for Delaware in the future. For example, if jurisdictions outside Delaware “refuse to hear cases involving Delaware corporations, . . . [it may] discourage companies from initially incorporating in Delaware.” While this argument seems logical, I do not see much of a threat to Delaware in this regard. First, as stated earlier, states other than Delaware have an interest in hearing cases regarding foreign corporations operating within their borders. This suggested boycott by outside states over one clause in a generally long and complex corporate charter seems infeasible. Further, should the boycott occur, I do not anticipate it would have much effect on the number of corporations incorporating in Delaware. Corporations incorporate in Delaware for many reasons, including its superior business courts, sophisticated bar, the Delaware General Corporate Law statute, efficient case management, and vast body of case law. I have doubts that other states’ refusals to hear cases regarding Delaware corporations would affect the number of businesses incorporating in Delaware given most corporations’ desire to litigate in Delaware. B. Potential Constitutional and Federalism Issues Our federal society allows plaintiffs to select in which forum to bring a lawsuit. As Thomas notes, “citizens invoke the general jurisdiction of state courts to sue defendants over whom that court has personal jurisdiction,” and federal courts use diversity jurisdiction “to avoid a perceived hometown bias.” Thus, allowing corporations to insert such clauses into their bylaws or charter essentially circumvents our current federal system of forum selection, which strikes a balance between which party has influence over the eventual forum selection. Thomas notes that it would essentially “permit defendants to funnel all cases into sympathetic state courts in the state of the corporation’s headquarters,” and further that refusing plaintiffs an opportunity to choose the forum location and further limiting the case to state court deprives the plaintiff “access to federal courts as a response to possible home-court discrimination.” C. Plaintiffs’ Lawyers Will Attempt to Circumvent Forum-Selection Clauses Thomas suggests that if this proposal were implemented, “plaintiffs’ lawyers would undoubtedly look for ways around these forum-selection clauses, perhaps by choosing to file alternative claims in other states’ courts or purely federal claims in the federal courts.” This would complicate the relatively standard nature of deal litigation, and further increase costs by forcing litigation over collateral issues such as whether “the clauses impinge on shareholders’ fundamental right to enforce directors’ and officers’ fiduciary duties.” Further, widespread adoption of forum-selection clauses and plaintiff’s attorneys’ desire to circumvent them may lead to a disruption of Delaware’s corporate law prominence. For example, Thomas warns that should the circuit courts disagree as to whether Delaware should have the ability to allow corporations to force M&A litigation in its own state, the “U.S. Supreme Court could get involved, with unpredictable consequences for Delaware’s continued quasi-monopoly in corporate law.” D. Substantive Invalidity under Corporate Law The forum-selection clauses, though seemingly valid under applicable contract law, may be subject to certain corporate law challenges. First, Chancellor Laster of the Delaware Chancery Court has advocated for such clauses as a solution to the problem of multijurisdictional deal litigation. However Thomas notes that Laster “expressly referred to action by both ‘directors and shareholders’ in adopting ‘charter’ provisions.” This suggests that, absent express shareholder approval of the provision, courts may find that a restriction on plaintiff shareholders’ ability to bring a case in their forum of choice is invalid. It also decreases the solution’s desirability in the eyes of management, as one major benefit of this solution is that it is quick and relatively painless. However, Thomas notes that if shareholder approval is required for the clause to be valid, the board would have to present the clause to the shareholders in a proposed charter amendment and risk “the potential embarrassment of having their shareholders vote [it] down.” Professor Thomas cites Galaviz v. Berg to support the proposition that the “contract analogy is unsupported because the directors’ bylaw lacked the requisite mutual consent.” While this case “does not[] decide whether the adoption of [the company’s] venue bylaw was within the directors’ powers as a matter of Delaware law,” it does hold that the company “failed to show that its bylaw is effective under federal law to limit these plaintiffs’ right to bring these claims in this Court.” The Galaviz court reasoned that “the venue provision was unilaterally adopted by the directors who are defendants in this action, after the majority of the purported wrongdoing is alleged to have occurred, and without the consent of existing shareholders who acquired their shares when no such bylaw was in effect,” and proceeded to deny the defendant-corporation’s motion to dismiss for improper venue. However, the court did mention that “parties may enter into contracts—including those where elements of adhesion exist—that contain legally enforceable forum selection clauses,” therefore retaining the possible of validity of shareholderapproved forum-selection clauses. Thus, this case is evidence that plaintiffs may be able to find ways to circumvent the effect of unilaterally-adopted forum selection clauses, at least when the provision is adopted unilaterally by the board of directors. Though it seems shareholder-approved charter provisions provide the mutual consent needed to validate a forum selection provision, shareholders still face massive collective action problems. For example, “[w]hile a shareholder vote provides some protection to investors, . . . shareholder approval of charter amendments does not necessarily mean the amendments increase shareholder wealth.” Even with organizations like ISS providing assistance and advice to the shareholders as a group, collective action issues may still plague the shareholder voice. E. Lock-in Effect Finally, single-forum forum-selection clauses effectively “lock in” the litigation forum. Thus, while Thomas notes that Delaware “currently do[es] an excellent job balancing investor and management interests, this could change, leaving shareholders without effective recourse for management wrongdoing.” Furthermore, Thomas notes that multi-forum forum-selection clauses that allow management the choice of multiple forums have two problems. First, they effectively do nothing more than allow forum shopping by defendants. “Why should we privilege defendants to choose the forum for shareholder litigation rather than plaintiffs?” Second, they allow for the possibility that defendant-corporations “hold up” the Delaware courts, essentially bargaining for more favorable outcomes in return for more suits brought in the state. b. Comity—Tweaking the Current System A second potential solution proposed by Thomas to the problems associated with multijurisdictional litigation is to tweak the current system of judicial comity. The Delaware Chancery Court, as the primary court in many multijurisdictional deal cases, already has experience with this solution. As Thomas notes: Chancellor William Chandler of the Delaware Chancery Court developed a practice in multijurisdictional deal litigation of contacting the other judge(s) in courts with pending litigation from the same transaction to discuss which forum was the most appropriate for the litigation to proceed. If practiced effectively by judges and agreed to by counsel, multijurisdictional cases can be litigated in one forum. The appeal of this system is that judges can, pursuant to certain factors, decide between themselves which forum is most appropriate to hold the litigation. Such factors may include “their courts’ docket backlog, their subject matter expertise, the relative quality of the cases filed, the attorneys’ ability to effectively pursue the litigation, and their jurisdiction’s interest in the defendant-corporation’s affairs.” An additional factor mentioned earlier in this paper is a court’s interest in interpreting its own state’s law. For example, a novel issue or a point of corporate law that is relatively unsettled in Delaware may be better handled by the Court of Chancery as to provide guidance to other courts attempting to interpret Delaware law. i. Problems with Judicial Comity Before a system of judicial comity is broadly utilized, Thomas suggests that it is important to consider two issues: First, the success of this approach requires the voluntary participation by the judges in each form in which the litigation has been filed. A specific judge’s personal or situational motives could play a part in derailing the cooperation needed to make this solution work effectively. Thomas notes that “if a particular judge wants to preside over a highprofile case,” it may “result in diverting cases inefficiently.” He further warns that even if judges attempt to bring the litigation in the most beneficial forum, they may not agree on the application of the factors or which forum is ultimately best, and “there is no surefire policing mechanism.” These are important considerations, given that judges from different jurisdictions have different backgrounds and are influenced by sometimes conflicting incentives. While Thomas pays this issue lip service, I view it as the largest potential roadblock to an otherwise simple and costeffective solution. I am not sure whether specific action can be taken to reduce the risk that judicial opposition derails this solution, but I am convinced it is comity’s principal hurdle. Second, Delaware has a unique interest in interpreting its own laws. As Thomas notes, the rest of the country (and world) look to Delaware for the cutting edge in corporate law, and that gives Delaware a legitimate interest “in the consistency of its law, which may suffer injury if other states’ courts take license with it.” This can be used as leverage to convince non-Delaware judges to allow the litigation to proceed in Delaware. In fact, Leo Strine has weighed in in favor of judicial comity, but advocates for the application of a “rebuttable presumption that the litigation should proceed in the courts of” the state whose law is to be applied unless “compelling circumstances relating to other parties’ interests or some supervening public interest may justify” allowing the case to proceed in a sister jurisdiction. Strine justifies his position in favor of the rebuttable presumption by arguing that it, inter alia, “promotes the growth of precedent to guide future transactions, . . . enhances judicial accountability, . . . and ensure[s] that corporate representative litigation better serves the interests of stockholders.” Of course, competing with Delaware’s interest in its law’s consistency is the interest of sister states in governing the actions of foreign corporations operating within their borders. Finding a balance between these competing interests may be easier said than done when judges begin discussing and applying the above comity factors. ii. Benefits of Judicial Comity The most notable benefits of judicial comity indicated by Thomas are its “relatively lowcost, easily reversible policy approach that does not require any remarkable changes to the current system.” Further, if a majority of the judges involved in such litigation are able to effectively collaborate and efficiently ascertain the most appropriate jurisdiction to host the litigation, the problems associated with multijurisdictional litigation will largely subside. This approach does not require much in terms of fixed costs up front, it can be easily reversed, and it is simple. Therefore, despite its potential difficulties, Professor Thomas suggests that it is “likely the best solution.” Thomas looks to an article written by Griffith and Lahav in the Vanderbilt Law Review for suggestions concerning how to improve the current system. These suggestions include increasing the accessibility of the Delaware Court of Chancery’s decisions, having the defendants in each case provide notice to each judge concerning the multijurisdictional nature of the litigation “since defendants are in the best position ‘to provide the judges in each jurisdiction with a copy of the related complaint filed elsewhere,’” and “creating a means for sister states to formally certify questions to the Delaware Chancery Court.” Therefore, while forum-selection clauses are a potential solution to the problems and increased costs associated with multijurisdictional litigation, Thomas suggests that the current system of judicial comity, with a few tweaks, may be the most practical and effective solution. Though I agree that this solution, if implemented carefully, can provide a cost-effective solution to the problem, I argue that its hurdles may prevent such flawless implementation. For example, judges will have to objectively and consistently apply the comity factors and disregard large incentives to hear the case in their own jurisdiction, while forum selection clauses are implemented by the very corporations incentivized to do so. Conclusion Thomas’s article effectively outlines current trends in multijurisdictional M&A litigation: Although data quantifying the costs associated with such litigation is scarce, it is likely that plaintiffs challenging the same transaction in multiple forums increases the defendantcorporation’s costs of defending such claims. What data we have suggests that although the number of cases being challenged has remained stagnant, the number deals have decreased indicating a higher percent of deals being challenged. This trend may be a result of the fixed capacity of the plaintiffs’ bar and has resulted recently in an increased percentage of disclosure violation complaints. This shift is an indication that the quality of suits filed by the plaintiff’s bar is in decline, and Delaware’s hard-nose approach to handling such cases may be a cause of the recent increase in multijurisdictional litigation. Thomas then discusses two potential solutions to this trend: Forum-selection clauses and comity. Forum selection clauses allow the defendant-corporation to select the litigation venue, essentially shifting the plaintiff’s ability to forum shop to the defendants. While this solution may be accepted widely in the future, it is plagued by enforceability issues and a slow adoption rate. Judicial comity, as Thomas suggests, may be a more practical and efficient approach to address the issue. It would be relatively inexpensive to implement and would avoid most of the incremental costs associated with filings in multiple jurisdictions. Slight tweaks may be needed to avoid issues such as judges disagreeing about the appropriate venue and the inconsistent application of Delaware law, but if properly implemented comity is an effective and efficient solution. However, I anticipate that comity will be more difficult than suggested to implement given the conflicting incentives imposed on judges of different states. Therefore, I suggest focusing on forum-selection clauses as an ultimate solution, given its apparent validity in corporate charters and that corporations themselves have an incentive to correct the recent trend toward increased disclosure-based complaints and settlements.