(21/6/16) IDARI COURSE OUTLINE – ECONOMICS OF CONVENTIONS The conventional fabric of markets Frédéric Morand (frederic.morand@nuigalway.ie) 14 July 2003 Markets belong to the most prodigious constructions of humanity. They allow us to exchange with others without necessarily speaking to them or even without meeting them. Markets obey conventional judgments. Our desire to hold money as store of wealth, for example, is a barometer of the degree of distrust of our own calculations and conventions concerning the future (Keynes 1937). Trust in money is just but one of the many conventions governing our economies. Conventions can be briefly defined as a regularity in behaviour, commonly agreed to within a group, and which specifies behaviour in a particular recurrent situation (Schotter 1981). A protection against uncertainty (‘This apple has an organic label: it has not been sprayed’), conventions make interpersonal relations possible. This protection, however, is never absolutely guaranteed (‘Is this organic label reliable?’): conventions are subject to lock-in effects, conflicts, and change, with determining consequences on the sustainability of markets. Conventions play a fundamental socio-economic role. How to make a sound use of such an essential resource? This module (5 x 2 hours) offers an introduction to the understanding of conventions, starting from their adoption through learning and innovation (§1). It exposes some of the difficulties facing economic theory when attempting to address social interaction (§2). The example of trust will be taken as an illustration (§3). The French Conventions Theory provides a perspective that may help overcoming the previous difficulties (§4). An original model of learning as a change of conventions will be discussed (§5). 1. Why does learning matter to transition economies? Transition to market economy requires change in mental models. Hagedorn, 2000; What to learn? Evaluating the Privatization Experience in Transition, Understanding Transition of Central and Eastern European Agriculture. Institutional Change and Economic Performance in a Comparative Perspective: Berlin, 10 (November 2-4). Bromley, 2000; A most difficult passage: The economic Transition in Central and Eastern Europe and the Former Soviet Union, KATO Symposium, Understanding Transition of Central and Eastern European Agriculture. Institutional Change and Economic Performance in a Comparative Perspective: Berlin, 37 (2-4 November). 1 (21/6/16) 2. How to understand learning? A theoretical gap in Economics: learning is more than ‘choosing rationally’ (and intentionally). North, 2000; Understanding institutions; in C. Ménard, Institutions, Contracts and Organizations. Perspectives from New Institutional Economics, Edward Elgar: Cheltenham (UK) and Northampton (MA, USA), 7:10. Thaler, 2000; From Homo Economicus to Homo Sapiens, Journal of Economic Perspectives; Vol. 14, 133-141 (Winter). 3. Trust and interest in market mediations There are mediations between collectives and individuals. What are they? How to analyse them? Credibility and trust, as a particular interaction structure, will be analysed Kreps, 1995; Corporate culture and economic theory; in K. A. Shepsle and J. E. Alt, Perspectives on positive political economy, Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, 90-143. Williamson, 1993; Calculativeness, Trust, and Economic Organization, Journal of Law & Economics; Vol. 36, 453-486 (April). 4. Beyond the ‘pure market logic’ in Economics Towards an economic theory of institutions. Rule and market are not necessarily conflicting in economic analysis. Favereau, 2001; Theory of information: from bounded rationality to interpretive reason; in P. Petit, Economics and Information, Kluwer: Dordrecht, 93:120. Thévenot, 2001; Conventions of co-ordination and the framing of uncertainty; in E. Fullbrook, Intersubjectivity in Economics, Routledge: London. 5. Analysing learning through conventions and routines Limits, perspectives and applications of an original learning model where learning binds agents and structure together in a transformative process between explicit and tacit information. 6. Indicative further readings Akerlof, 1970; The market for "lemons": quality uncertainty and the market mechanism, Quarterly Journal of Economics; Vol. 84, 488:500. Arrow, 1974; The Limits of Organization, W. W. Norton & Co: New York and London. Invisible institutions (p. 23:26) 2 (21/6/16) Arrow, Bolin, Costanza, Dasgupta, Folke, Holling, Jansson, Levin, Mäler, Perrings and Pimentel, 1995; Economic Growth, Carrying Capacity, and the Environment, Science; Vol. 268, 520:521. Arthur, 2000; Cognition: the Black Box of Economics; in D. Colander, The Complexity Vision and the Teaching of Economics, Edward Elgar Publishers, Northampton (Mass.), Chapt.3, 7 p.. Bikhchandani, Hirshleifer and Welch, 1992; A Theory of Fads, Fashion, Custom, and Cultural Change as Informational Cascades, Journal of Political Economy; Vol. 100, 992-1026. Bowles and Gintis, 2000; Walrasian economics in retrospect., The Quarterly Journal of Economics; Vol. 115, 1411-1439 (Nov 2000). Bowles, 1998; Endogenous Preferences: The Cultural Consequences of Markets and other Economic Institutions, Journal of Economic Literature; Vol. 36, 75:111 (March). Boyer and Orléan, 1992; How do conventions evolve?, Journal of Evolutionary Economics; Vol. 2, 165:177. Bromley, 2000; Can Agriculture Become an Environmental Asset?, World Economics; Vol. 1, 127-139 (July-September). Granovetter, 1978; Threshold Models of Collective Behavior, American Journal of Sociology; Vol. 83, 1420:1443. Hodgson, 1993; Optimization and Evolution; in G. Hodgson, Economics and Evolution. Bringing Life Back into Economics, Polity Press and Blackwell Publishers: Cambridge UK, 197:213. chap. 13: Panglossian dialogue Juma, 2002; The global sustainability challenge: from agreement to action, International Journal of Global Environmental Issues; Vol. 2, 1-14. Keynes, 1937; The General Theory of Employment, Quarterly Journal of Economics; Vol. 51, 209:223. Porter and van der Linde, 1995; Toward a New Conception of the EnvironmentCompetitiveness Relationship, Journal of Economic Perspectives; Vol. 9, 97:118. Schotter, 1981; The Economic Theory of Social Institutions, Cambridge University Press: Cambridge. Simon, 1976; From Substantive to Procedural Rationality; in S. Latsis, Method and Appraisal in Economics, Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, 129:148. Stiglitz, 1999; Whither Reform? Ten Years of the Transition, Annual Bank Conference on Development Economics: Washington, 32 (28-30 April). Thévenot, 1999; Pragmatic regimes governing the engagement with the world; in K. Knorr-Cetina, T. Schatzki and V. Savigny Eike, The practice Turn in Contemporary Theory, Routledge: London. Tversky and Kahneman, 1982; Judgments of and by Representativeness; in D. Kahneman, P. Slovic and A. Tversky, Judgment under Uncertainty: Heuristics and Biases, Cambridge University Press: Cambridge, 84:93. Vatn and Bromley, 1997; Externalities - A Market Model Failure, Environmental and Resource Economics; Vol. 9, 135-151. 3