Using“Piece‐RateEquivalents”andRelativePayoffsto ExploreGenderDifferencesintheWillingnesstoCompete JohnIfcher SantaClaraUniversity 500ElCaminoReal SantaClara,CA95053 jifcher@scu.edu 408‐554‐5579 HomaZarghamee BarnardCollege ColumbiaUniversity NewYork,NY10027 hzargham@barnard.edu 212‐854‐8946 Preliminarydraft:November21,2013 Pleasedonotcitewithoutpermissionfromtheauthors. JELclassificationcodes:C91,J16,J24 Keywords:Competitiveness;GenderDifferences;RelativePayoff;Piece‐Rate Equivalent Acknowledgements MurielNiederleandLiseVesterlundwerekindenoughtosharetheirz‐Tree programwithus.LaraMoultonandMarianneFaragprovidedexcellentresearch assistance.FinancialsupportfromtheLeaveySchoolofBusinessatSantaClara Universityisgratefullyacknowledged. Abstract Laboratoryexperimentshavedemonstratedthatmenaresignificantlymorewilling tocompetethanwomengivenabinarychoicebetweenaPiece‐Rate(PR)and Winner‐Take‐All(WTA)paymentinstereotypically‐maletasks.Thisdifferenceis ascribedtovariantoverconfidenceandpreferenceforcompetition,andisbelieved tohaveaprofoundimpactonthemarketforhighly‐competitivejobs,wherewomen areunderrepresented.Inthispaper,wedevelopanewinstrumenttomeasurethe willingnesstocompetebyofferingsubjectsaseriesofPRpaymentsrangingfrom0 to100percentoftheWTApayment,whichenableustoidentifythePRequivalentof a$2.00WTApayment;thatis,thevalueofthe$2.00WTApayment.Wefindthat womenvalueWTApaymentssignificantlylessthanmen,about$0.28less;andthat womenrequireapremium(relativetomen)ofabout40percenttocompete.Our newinstrumentismoresensitivethanthetraditionalbinary‐choiceinstrument,as itclassifiesthewillingnesstocompeteinto21categories.Thisenableustoidentify relationshipsthatarenotidentifiableusingthebinary‐choiceinstrument.For example,wefindthatsubjectswhoarethemostwillingtocompetealsohavehigh abilityonaverage;andthatthereisapositiverelationshipbetweenthewillingness tocompeteandGPAformen(notforwomen),andapositiverelationshipbetween thewillingnesstocompeteandtakingSTEMcoursesforwomen(notformen). 1.Introduction Laboratoryexperimentshavedemonstratedthatmenaresignificantlymorewilling tocompeteinastereotypically‐maletaskthanarewomen(Niederle&Vesterlund (NV),2011).Thisgenderdifferenceisascribedtovariantbeliefsaboutrelative performanceandpreferencesforcompetition(bygender).1Thegenderdifferencein thewillingnesstocompeteisbelievedtohaveaprofoundimpactonthelabor market,especiallyinthemarketforthemostcompetitiveandlucrativejobs,where womenareunderrepresented.Forexample,womenheld2.5percentofthefive highestpaidjobsatU.S.firmsbetween1992and1997(Bertrand&Hallock,2001). Thisdisparitypersistseveninthefaceoffemaleeducationalgainsandgreater governmentguaranteesagainstgenderdiscrimination(Goldin,Katz,&Kuziemko, 2006).NV(2011)assertthatthegenderdifferenceinthewillingnesstocompete impliesthatwomenenter—andconsequentlywin—fewercompetitions,andthus, mayhelpexplainwomen’sunderwhelmingperformanceinmale‐dominatedfields. Importantly,thisiscostlynotonlyforwomenwhomaynotadvanceinlucrative, male‐dominatedfields,butalsoforsocietyasthebestjobcandidatemaynotbe matchedwithajob. Twoimportantquestionsfollow(NV,2011).First,whatincentivescouldchangethe situation?Second,doesnatureornurtureexplainthegenderdifference? Researchershavebeguntoexaminethefirstquestion.Forexample,Niederle,Segal, andVesterlund(2013)investigatetheimpactofaffirmativeactionintheNV(2007) setting.Theyfindthathavingaquotaforwomenincreaseswomen’swillingnessto compete,especiallyamonghigh‐abilitywomen.BalafoutasandSutter(2010)find thatprovidingwomenwithahandicapalsogeneratesareductioninthegender differenceinthewillingnesstocompete(theyalsoreplicateNV’squotafinding). Competinginteamshasalsobeenshowntoreducethegenderdifferenceinthe willingnesstocompete(e.g.,Dargnies,2009;Healy&Pate,2011).Finally,Gupta, PoulsenandVilleval(2013)showthatwomenaremorewillingtocompetein single‐sexcompetitionsthaninmixed‐sexcompetitions. Thispaper’sfirstcontributionistoconsideradifferentincentivethatcouldreduce thegenderdifferenceinthewillingnesstocompete:financialincentives.Specifically, weattempttoidentifythe“relativepayoff”—WTApaymenttoPRpayment—thatis 1NV(2007)spawnedaseriesoflaboratoryexperimentsthattesttherobustnessandlimitsoftheir seminalfinding:menaresignificantlymorewillingtocompeteinamathtaskthanarewomen.For example,researchershaveconductedlaboratoryexperimentsthat(a)manipulatesubjects’beliefsby providingsubjectswithfeedbackregardingtheirrelativeperformance(e.g.,Cason,Masters,& Sheremeta,2010;Wozniak,Harbaugh&Mayr,2009)andusingtasksthatarenotstereotypically‐ male(e.g.,Grosse&Riener,2010;Kamas&Preston,2009;Wozniaketal.,2009);(b)explicitlycontrol forriskpreferences(e.g.,Casonet.al.,2010;Wozniaketal.,2009);and(c)employproportional winner‐take‐allpayments(e.g.,Casonet.al.,2010).Whilethisbodyofresearchhasillustrated circumstancesunderwhichNV(2007)doesnothold,themainfinding(thatmenaresignificantly morewillingtocompeteinstereotypically‐maletasksthanarewomen)hasbeenreplicated repeatedly(seeNV(2011)forathoroughreviewoftheliterature). necessaryforasubjecttocompete.Todoso,weoffersubjectsaseriesofchoices betweenPiece‐Rate(PR)payments—rangingfrom0to100percentoftheWinner‐ Take‐All(WTA)payment—andaWTApayment.Wefindthatwomenrequirea significantlygreaterrelativepayofftocompete,about40percentmore,thanmenon average.IntheU.S.,incontrast,womenarebelievedtobepaidless(notmore)than menforsimilarjobs(Bertrand&Hallock,2001).Thus,itshouldcomeasnosurprise thatwomenareunderrepresentedinthemostcompetitive,male‐dominatedjobs. Moreover,ourfindingsuggeststhatifwomenreceivedasalarypremium(relativeto men)thattheirunder‐representationinsuchjobsmightbereduced. Thispaper’ssecondcontributionistodevelopaninstrumentthatenablesusto measurethestrengthofasubject’swillingnesstocompetealongacontinuumand alsoataseriesofrelativepayoffs.Incontrast,thetraditionalbinary‐choice instrumentprovidesresearcherswithasingledatapointregardingthesubject’s willingnesstocompete.Consequently,weareabletodemonstratethatNV(2007) holdsforallPRpaymentsbetween5and70percentoftheWTApayment.Further, weareabletoidentifyrelationshipsbetweenthewillingnesstocompeteandother variablesthatarenotidentifiableusingthetraditionalbinary‐choiceinstrument. Forexample,wefindthatsubjectswhoarethemostwillingtocompetealsohave highabilityonaverage. Thispaper’sthirdcontributionistoexploretherelationshipbetweenthe willingnesstocompete—usingournewinstrument—andacademicperformance, enrollmentinScience,Technology,Engineering,andMath(STEM)courses,and participationinvarsityathletics.Wefindthatthereisapositiverelationship betweenthewillingnesstocompeteandGPAformen,butnotforwomen;andthat thereisapositiverelationshipbetweenthewillingnesstocompeteandtakingSTEM courseforwomen,butnotformen.KamasandPreston(2012)findnogender differenceinthewillingnesstocompetebetweenmaleandfemaleSTEMmajors. OurresultsuggestsanexplanationforKamasandPreston’sresult.Wefinda positiverelationshipforwomen(butnotformen)betweenthenumberofSTEM coursesawomentakesandherwillingnesstocompete.GiventhatSTEMmajors takemoreSTEMcoursesthannon‐STEMmajors,femaleSTEMmajorsshouldbe morewillingtocompetethanfemalenon‐STEMmajors;andthus,femaleSTEM majorsmaybemoresimilartomenintheirwillingnesstocompetethanfemalenon‐ STEMmajors.Finally,wefindthatfemalevarsitycollegeathletesaremorewillingto competethanwomenwhoarenotvarsitycollegeathletes. Theseresultsareimportantforatleasttworeasons.First,ithasbeensuggestedthat theunderrepresentationofwomeninSTEMfieldsmayhelpexplainwhywomenare paidlessthanmenonaverage.Ourfindingsuggeststhatwomenwhoareless willingtocompetearelesslikelytotakeSTEMcourses,andpresumablyenterSTEM fields.Itisimportanttonote,however,thatouranalysisisunabletodemonstratea causallink.Thus,thisevidenceismerelysuggestive.Forexample,incontrast,our resultmightimplythatwomenwhotakemoreSTEMcoursesbecomemorewilling tocompete.ThisisimportantasitaddressesthesecondofNVquestions:Does natureornurtureexplainthegenderdifference?Ourresultregardingfemalevarsity collegeathletesisalsosuggestiveofthesamerelationship:Womenwhoparticipate incollegevarsityathleticsbecomemorewillingtocompete.Again,wehavenot demonstratedacausallink,andthus,ourresultcouldimplythatwomenwhoare morewillingtocompetealsoparticipateincollegevarsityathletics. Therestofthepaperunfoldsarefollows.Section2describedtheexperimental design.Sections3and4presentsanddiscusstheresults,respectively. 2.ExperimentalDesign Inbrief,ourexperimentalprocedurewasasfollows(additionaldetailsareprovided below).(1)Subjectsreadandsignedtheinformedconsentform.(2)Subjects completedfourtasksinwhichtheyaddedfivetwo‐digitnumbersforfiveminutes. EachtaskwasincentivizedwitheitheraPiece‐Rate(PR)orWinner‐Take‐All(WTA) payment.Intwoofthefourtaskssubjectshadtochoosebetweenthetwopayment schemes.(3)Subjectscompletedafifthtask,inwhichtheychosebetweenvarious payment‐schemesforthefirsttaskretrospectively.(4)Subjectsevaluatedtheir performanceonthefirstfourtasks.(5)Subjectscompletedfiveadditionaltasksthat arepartofaseparatestudyanddiscussedinIfcherandZarghamee(2013).(6) Subjectscompletedariskpreferencetask.(7)Subjectsansweredquestions regardingdemographicandothercharacteristics.(8)Subjectsreceivedtheir paymentandexitedtheexperimentalsession.Experimentalsessionslasted approximately90minutes.Subjectsreceivedaminimumpaymentof$18andan averageof$30fortheirparticipation.Theexperimentwasprogrammedand conductedwiththesoftwarez‐Tree(Fischbacher2007);NVgraciouslyprovided theirz‐Treeprogram,whichwemodifiedforthisstudy.Allinstructionswereread aloudbytheexperimenterandareincludedinAppendixA.2 2.1.Subjects ThelaboratoryexperimentwasconductedatSantaClaraUniversityinthefallof 2012.One‐hundredandeightundergraduatestudents(58male,50female)were recruitedfromcoursesthatallundergraduatestudentsarerequiredtotake.These courseswerechoseninanattempttoensurethatthesamplewasrepresentativeof theundergraduatestudentbody.Prospectivesubjectsweretoldthatparticipation inthestudywouldtakeabout90minutesandthattheywouldbepaidfortheir participation,withanaveragepaymentof$32andaminimumpaymentof$16. 2.2.Tasks1,2,and3 ThisexperimentbuildsuponNV(2007)andthefirstthreetasksreplicatethosein NV(2007).Subjectshadfiveminutestoperformsummations;eachsummationwas 2Weranthreepilotsessionswith36subjectsinthesummerof2012.Thepilotsessionsdidnot includethefiveadditionaltasksthataredescribedinitem(5)above. offiverandomlychosen,two‐digitnumbersdisplayedhorizontallyacrossa computerscreen.Subjectsweregivenapenandscrappapertouseduringthe session;subjectswerenotallowedtousecalculators.Immediatelyaftersubjects submittedananswer,theprograminformedthemiftheiranswerwascorrect, displayedthenumberofcorrectandincorrectanswerssubmittedbythesubject duringthetasksofar,andpresentedanewsummationproblem.Afterfiveminutes, thetaskendedandsubjectscouldnotsubmitadditionalanswers.Subjectsreceived nofeedbackfromtheprogramorexperimenterregardingtheperformanceofother subjectsintheirsession. Thepaymentschemeforthefirstthreetasksvaried.Beforecompletingeachtask, subjectsreceiveddetailedinstructionsregardingthetaskandpaymentscheme(all instructionswerereadaloudbytheexperimenter).Thepaymentschemefortask1 wasa$0.50PRpaymentpercorrectanswer.Thepaymentschemefortask2wasa WTApaymentandthusdependedonperformancerelativetoothergroupmembers. Thesubjectwhosubmittedthemostcorrectanswerswithineachgroupoffour subjectsreceived$2.00percorrectanswer;theotherthreegroupmembers receivednopayment.Tiesweresettledrandomlybythecomputer. Theinstructionsexplicitlystatedthatasubject’sgroupincludedthosethreeother subjectssittinginthesame(front‐to‐back)rowasthesubject;thatis,thosesubjects sittingimmediatelyinfrontofand/orbehindthesubject.Whensubjectsarrivedfor theirsession,theexperimenterassignedsubjectstoseatsbysimplystating,for example,“Pleasesitinseat10.”Theorderinwhichseatswereassignedwasnot systematicexceptthattheexperimenterattemptedtoseattwofemaleandtwomale subjectsineachrow.Lastly,therewasnoexplicitmentionofthegroups’gender balance,however,subjectscouldobservetheothersubjectsintheirgroupand session.Ofthe27groupsintheexperiment,24hadtwomaleandtwofemale subjects,twohadthreemaleandonefemalesubject,andonehadfourmale subjects.Allresultsreportedbelowarerobusttodroppingthethreegroupsthat haveanunequalnumberofmaleandfemalesubjects. Thepaymentschemefortask3wasdeterminedbythesubject’schoicebetweenthe $0.50PRandthe$2.00WTApaymentusedintasks1and2,respectively.The instructionsexplicitlystatedthatifsubjectschoosethe$2.00WTApayment,then theirperformanceintask3wouldbecomparedtotheirgroup‐mates’performance intask2.Asintask2,tiesweresettledrandomlybythecomputer. 2.3.Tasks4and5 Task4usedthesamesummationtaskastasks1through3buthadadifferent paymentscheme.Inanattempttomorefullyunderstandsubjects’preferences betweenPRandWTApayments,weofferedsubjectsaseriesofchoicesbetween variousPRpayments,rangingfrom$0.00to$2.00,anda$2.00WTApayment.All choiceswerepresentedverticallyonasinglescreen.Thefirstchoicewasbetweena $0.00PRpaymentanda$2.00WTApayment.Thenextchoicewasbetweena$0.10 PRpaymentanda$2.00WTApayment.Thereafter,thePRpaymentincreasedin $0.10incrementsuntilitreached$2.00(seeFigure1forascreenshotofthisseries ofchoices).Wewouldexpectsubjectstochoosethe$2.00WTApaymentwhenthe alternativeisa$0.00PRpayment;conversely,wewouldexpectsubjectstochoose the$2.00PRpaymentwhenthealternativeisa$2.00WTApayment. Weattempttoidentifythestrengthofeachsubject’spreferenceforaPRpayment relativetoaWTApaymentbyobservingherswitchpoint:theminimumPRpayment thesubjectpreferredtoa$2.00WTApayment.Switchpointsrepresentthe“PR equivalentofthe$2.00WTApayment”—hereafterdenotedsimply“PR‐equivalent.” Further,weexaminethedistributionofPR‐equivalentstodeterminethemeanand medianPR‐equivalentaswellasthePR‐equivalentCDF. Task5usesthesamepaymentschemeastask4.However,intask5subjectsare choosingbetweenvariousPRpayments,rangingfrom$0.00to$2.00,anda$2.00 WTApaymentfortheirandtheirgroup‐mate’sperformanceintask1.Subjectswere remindedhowmanyquestionstheyansweredcorrectlyintask1,butagainreceived noinformationregardinghowothersubjectsinthesessiondid.AsinNV(2007), task5isincludedinthisstudyinanattempttoruleoutriskandfeedbackaversion asanexplanationforgenderdifferencesintherelativepreferenceforPRpayments. 2.4.Beliefsregardingrankintasks1through4 Subjectswereaskedtorankthemselvesrelativetotheirgroup‐matesintermsofthe numberofquestionstheyansweredcorrectlyintasks1through4:1stbest,2ndbest, 3rdbest,or4thbest(i.e.,worst).Subjectswereinformedthattheywouldbepaidan additional$1foreachtaskinwhichtheyrankedthemselvescorrectly.Thensubjects completedfiveadditionaltasks,6through10,whichusedthesamepayment schemesastasks1through5,respectively,butusedarandomtaskinplaceofthe summationtask.Tasks6through10arenotconsideredinthestudyandarepartof aseparatestudydiscussedinIfcherandZarghamee(2013).3 2.5.Task11 Task11wasastandardrisk‐preferencemeasure(Holt&Laury,2002).Subjects chosebetweenaseriesoffixedpayments,rangingfrom$0.00to$10.00,anda lotterywitha50%chanceofa$10paymentanda50%chanceofa$0payment.All choiceswerepresentedverticallyonasinglescreen.Thefirstchoicewasbetweena $0.00fixedpaymentandthelottery.Thenextchoicewasbetweena$1.00fixed 3InIfcherandZarghamee(2013)wenotonlyexploresubjects’willingnesstocompeteinarandom taskbutalsoinvestigateordereffects.Thus,100subjectscompletedtasks6through10firstand tasks1through5second.Asweareprimarilyfocusedonthenewinstrumentinthispaperandthere isevidenceofsubstantialordereffects,wedonotincludethe100subjectswhocompletedthe randomtasksfirstandthesummationtaskssecondintheanalysisinthispaper. paymentandthelottery.Thereafter,thefixedpaymentcontinuedtoincreasein $1.00incrementsuntilitreached$10.00. 2.6.Questionnaire Subjectscompletedaquestionnairethatincludedquestionsregardingtheir demographicandothercharacteristics,forexample,dateofbirth,gender,race, familybackground,personalitycharacteristics,andsubjectivewell‐being.In addition,thequestionnaireincludedquestionsregardingtheirpastandcurrent participationincompetitivesports,whichenabledustoexaminewhethersuch participationiscorrelatedwiththerelativepreferenceforaPRpayment.Wealso askedforsubjects’permissiontodownloadtheirtranscriptandincorporatetheir choiceofmajorsandcoursestaken(aswellastheircoursegrades)intoour analyticaldatabase;allsubjectsgaveuspermissiontodoso.Thiswasdoneto examinewhetherthelikelihoodofpursuingSTEM(Science,Technology, Engineering,andMath)majorsandcoursesiscorrelatedwiththerelative preferenceforaPRpayment. 2.7.Payments Subjectsweregivendetailedinstructionsregardingthecalculationoftheir payment;again,allinstructionswerereadaloudbytheexperimenter.Subject‐ paymentsincluded:a$5.00show‐upfee;$11.00forcompletingtheeleventasks;a $1.00paymentforcorrectlyindicatingtheirrankintasks1,2,3,or4(andtasks6,7, 8,or9);andapaymentbasedontwooftheelevencompletedtasks.Todetermine whichtwotaskswouldbepaid,twonumbers,betweenoneandeleven,were randomlychosen(withoutreplacement)usingabingospinnerafterallsubjectshad completedthequestionnaire.Iftasks4or5(or9or10)werechosen,thenoneof the21PRpaymentswasrandomlychosen,againusingthebingospinner.Iftask11 waschosen,thenoneofthe11fixedpaymentswasrandomlychosenandthelottery wasimplementedusingthebingospinner.Subjectpaymentswerepaidincash.The paymentwasplacedinanenvelopewithonlythesubjects’identificationnumberon it,andsubjectsreceivedtheirpaymentenvelopesastheyexitedthesession. 3.Results 3.1.ReplicationofmainNV(2007)findings WebeginbyreplicatingNV’smainresults.First,thereisnogenderdifferencein performanceonthesummationtaskinanyofthefourtasks,1through4.For example,intask1menandwomencorrectlyanswer9.6and8.8questions, respectively,onaverage(p=0.40);allp‐valuesreportedinthepaperaretwo‐sided. Onemalesubjectcorrectlyansweredanaverageof49questionspertask;the secondbestperformingsubjectcorrectlyanswered20questionspertask.Ifthebest performingsubjectisdroppedfromthecalculation,thenmenandwomencorrectly answer9.0and8.8questions,respectively,onaverage(p=0.81).4Subjects’ performanceiscorrelatedacrossthetasksforbothgenders(Spearmanrank correlationsrangefromalowof0.52forwomenbetweentasks1and2toahighof 0.84formenbetweentasks3and4).Finally,performanceimprovessignificantly betweentasks1and2;marginallybetweentasks2and3;andinsignificantly betweentasks3and4forbothgenders(men:9.6,10.6,11.4,and11.6;women:8.8, 10.5,11.0,and11.1). Second,comparedtowomen,menaresignificantlymorelikelytochoosethe$2.00 WTApaymentwhenofferedachoicebetweenitandthe$0.50PRpaymentintask3 (0.57versus0.34,p=0.02).Examiningtherelationshipbetweenthechoiceofthe WTApaymentintask3andperformanceontasks1and2,onefindsthat,forboth menandwomen,thosewhochoosetheWTApaymentintask3donotperform significantlybetterintasks1and2thandothosewhochoosethePRpayment(p≥ 0.14forallmeasures)(seeTable1).Formen,theimprovementinperformance betweentask1and2isnotsignificantlydifferentforthosewhochoosetheWTA versusPRpaymentintask3(1.2versus1.0,p=0.83).Forwomen,however,those whochoosetheWTApaymentintask3improvesignificantlymorebetweentasks1 and2thandowomenwhochoosethePRpayment(2.9versus1.0,p=0.03).This resultdivergesfromNV.Lastly,aprobitestimationshowsthatwomenare significantlylesslikelythanaremen(marginaleffect=24percentagepoints)to choosetheWTApayment,controllingfortask‐2performanceandimprovementin performancebetweentasks1and2. 3.2.MeasuringthewillingnesstocompeteusingPR‐equivalents Weidentifythestrengthofeachsubject’srelativepreferenceforaPRpaymentby observingthePR‐paymentequivalentoftheWTApayment(hereafterdenoted“PR‐ equivalent”):theminimumPRpaymentthesubjectchoosesovera$2.00WTA payment.PRpaymentsincreasein$0.10incrementssoasubjectwhoswitchesat the$0.60PRpaymentmighthaveswitchedataPRpaymentbetween$0.51and $0.59aswell.ThegreaterthePR‐equivalent,thegreaterthePRpaymentneedsto be(relativetothe$2.00WTApayment)forasubjecttochoosethePRpayment, implyingastrongerrelativepreferenceforWTApayments.Weinterpretrequiringa greaterPR‐equivalentasindicatingagreaterwillingnesstocompete.Accordingly, weinterpretthewillingnesstocompeteasincreasinginPR‐equivalent. Ofthe108subjectsinthestudy,100haveidentifiablePR‐equivalents.Specifically, 96choosetheWTApaymentwhenthePRpaymentis$0.00,continuetochoosethe WTApaymentuntilauniquePRpaymentatwhichtheychoosethePRpayment,and 4Duringtask2onefemalesubjectraisedherhandandreportedthatshecouldnotenterananswer toasummationquestionintothecomputer.Theexperimenterwalkedovertohercomputerand enteredtheanswerforherwithoutaproblem.Afterthatshedidnotreportanyproblemsentering answersintothecomputer.Theexperimentertoldherthatiftask2wasselectedasthepaymenttask herpaymentwouldbeadjusted.Task2wasnotselectedasapaymenttaskforthesession. thereafterchoosethePRpaymentforallremainingvaluesofthePRpayment.Two subjectsalwayschoosetheWTApaymentforallPRpayments,includingthe$2.00 PRpayment;thesesubjectsarecodedashavinga$2.10PR‐equivalent.Incontrast, twosubjectsalwayschoosethePRpayment,evenwhenitis$0.00;theyarecoded ashavinga$0.00PR‐equivalent.Finally,eightsubjects’PR‐equivalentcannotbe identified,astheirchoicesdonotfollowanyoftheprecedingpatterns.Forexample, someswitchbetweentheWTAandPRpaymentsmorethanonce.Theseeight subjectsaredroppedfromallfurtheranalyses. Figure2illustratesthedistributionoftask‐4PR‐equivalents.ThemeanPR‐ equivalentis$0.81,illustratingthatonaveragesubjectsrequirea$0.81PRpayment toswitchfromthe$2.00WTApaymenttothePRpayment.ThemedianPR‐ equivalentis$0.60.ThemodalPR‐equivalentis$0.50,with20percentofsubjects switchingatthisPRpayment.ThesecondmostcommonPR‐equivalentis$1.00;16 percentofsubjectshavethisPR‐equivalent.Sothedistributionisbi‐modaland subjectsappeartobunchatthe$0.50and$1.00PRpayment.Finally,36percentof subjectshaveaPR‐equivalentof$1.00orgreater. Examiningthedistributionoftask‐4PR‐equivalentsbygender,oneobservesaclear distinctionbetweenthetwodistributions(Fisher’sexacttest:p=0.04)(seeFigure 3).ThemeanandmedianPR‐equivalentsaresignificantlygreaterformenthanfor women,$0.94versus$0.66(p=0.01),and$0.85versus$0.60,respectively.Further, onlyninepercentofmenhaveaPR‐equivalentof$0.50orless;incontrast,28 percentofwomenhaveaPR‐equivalentof$0.50orless.Conversely,whileonlynine percentofwomenhaveaPR‐equivalentof1.50orgreater,thecorrespondingfigure formenis20percent.Regressingtask‐4PR‐equivalentsongender,onefindsthat men’sPR‐equivalentsaresignificantlygreaterthanwomen’s(b=$0.28,p=0.01). Figure4illustratestheCDFofthosewhochoosethePRpaymentovertheWTA paymentforallPRpaymentsbetween$0.00and$2.00bygender.ThefemaleCDFis everywheretotheleftofthemaleCDF.Thisindicatesthatagreaterpercentageof womenchoosethePRpaymentovertheWTApaymentatallPRpayments.Thus, NV’sseminalfindingisnotdependentontherelativepayoffbeingfour($2.00WTA paymentto$0.50PApayment).However,theverticaldistancebetweenthemale andfemaleCDF(thedifferenceinthepercentofmenandwomenthatchoosethePR paymentatagivenPRpayment)issmalleratPRpaymentsnear$0.00and$2.00. EstimatingtheverticaldistancebetweenthemaleandfemaleCDF,weregress subjects’choices(1=WTApaymentand0=PRpayment)forallPRpayments between$0.00and$2.00ongender;weclustertheobservationsbysubject,as subjects’21choicesarenotindependent.Womenare13.5percentagepointsless likelytochoosetheWTApaymentthanaremenacrossallPRpayments(p=0.01); limitingtheanalysistoPRpaymentsbetween$0.50and$1.50,womenare17.5 percentagepointslesslikelythanarementochoosetheWTApayment(p=0.01). Onecancomparesubjects’choicesbetweena$0.50PRand$2.00WTApaymentin task3,wherethechoiceispresentedasinNV(2007),andintask4,whereitis presentedasthesixthof21choices.Althoughthechoiceitselfisthesame,the contextchanges.Intheformer,thechoiceispresentedbyitself.Inthelatter,the choiceispresentedinthecontextofaseriesofbinarychoicesbetweenvariousPR paymentsanda$2.00WTApayment.Theframingappearstohaveanimpacton subjects’choices.Intheformersetting,59percentofmenand35percentofwomen choosetheWTApayment(theseresultsareslightlydifferentthanthosepresented previously,astheeightsubjectswithunidentifiabletask‐4PR‐equivalentsarenot included).Inthelattersetting,thepercentofmenwhochoosetheWTApayment increases10percentagepoints(p=0.17)to69percent;forwomenthepercent increases19percentagepoints(p=0.01)to54percent.Thatwomen’schoicesare moreaffectedisperhapsnotsurprisinggiventhatCrosonandGneezy(2009)find thatwomenaremorecontext‐sensitivethanaremen.Lastly,subjects’task‐3choice ofpaymentscheme(1=WTApaymentand0=PRpayment)ishighlycorrelated withtheirtask‐4PR‐equivalent(Spearmanrankcorrelation=0.61,p=0.00), suggestingthatbothinstrumentsaremeasuringasimilarparameter. ExaminingeachPRpaymentseparately,womenaresignificantlylesslikelyto choosetheWTApaymentthanaremenforallPRpaymentsbetween$0.10and $1.30(p<0.10foreach)exceptthe$0.50PRpayment.Conversely,womenarenot significantlylesslikelytochoosetheWTApaymentthanaremenfornineof21PR payments.ThelackofasignificantgenderdifferencewhenthePRpaymentis$0.00 and$2.00isnotsurprising,asonewouldexpectsubjectstochoosetheWTA paymentintheformerandthePRpaymentinthelatter.Further,thelackofa significantgenderdifferenceatthe$0.50PRpaymentappearstobeidiosyncraticas thereisasignificantgenderdifferenceforneighboringPRpayments.However,the lackofasignificantgenderdifferencewhenthePRpaymentisbetween$1.40and $1.90suggeststhatmenarenotmorelikelytochoosetheWTApaymentwhenthe PRpaymentislarge,thatis,whenthePRpaymentisatleast70percentoftheWTA payment. 3.3.UsingPR‐equivalentstocalculatethe“relativepayoff”ofWTApayments Ithasbeenarguedthatgenderdifferencessuchasthoseobservedinthisandother papersareimportantastheymayexplainthepaucityofwomeninsomehighly competitivejobs(NV,2011).Inotherwords,womenshyawayfrompositionsthat includecompensationschemesthatmimic,insomerespects,WTApayments.PR‐ equivalentsenableustoexaminehowmuchgreateraWTApaymenthastobe relativetoaPRpaymentsothatasubjectchoosestheWTApayment.Specifically, the“relativepayoff”atthePR‐equivalentistheWTApaymentdividedbythePR paymentatthePR‐equivalent.Forexample,ifisasubject’sPR‐equivalentis$0.80, thentherelativepayoffatherPR‐equivalentis2.5(=$2.00WTApayment÷$0.80 PRpayment).Inotherwords,aslongastherelativepayoffisgreaterthan2.5,the subjectwillchoosetheWTApayment;otherwiseshewillchoosethePRpayment. RelativepayoffsatthePR‐equivalentcanrangefromone($2.00PR‐equivalent)to infinity($0.00PR‐equivalent).ThegreatertherelativepayoffatthePR‐equivalent, thegreatertheWTApaymentneedstoberelativetothePRpayment,forasubject tochoosetheWTApayment,implyingaweakerrelativepreferenceforWTA payments.WeinterpretrequiringagreaterrelativepayoffatthePR‐equivalentas indicatingalowerwillingnesstocompete.Accordingly,weinterpretthewillingto competeasdecreasingwiththerelativepayoffatthePR‐equivalent. Nextwerepeattheanalysisaboveusingsubjects’relativepayoffattask‐4PR‐ equivalents.Women,onaverage,choosetheWTApaymentaslongastherelative payoffisgreaterthan3.0(=$2.00WTApayment÷$0.66meanPR‐equivalent).In contrast,men,onaverage,choosetheWTApaymentaslongastherelativepayoffis greaterthan2.1(=$2.00WTApayment÷$0.94meanPR‐equivalent).Thus, comparedtomen,womenrequirea43percentrelativepayoff“premium,”on average,tochoosetheWTApayment.UsingthemedianinsteadofthemeanPR‐ equivalenttheresultissimilar:themajorityofwomenrequirearelativepayoff greaterthan3.3(=$2.00WTApayment÷$0.60medianPR‐equivalent)tochoose theWTApayment.Incontrast,menrequirearelativepayoffgreaterthan2.4(= $2.00WTApayment÷$0.85medianequivalent).Thiscorrespondstowomen requiringa37.5percentrelativepayoff“premium”tochoosetheWTApayment. Theseresultssuggestthat,allelseequal,womenrequireasubstantiallylarger payoff,onaverage,tocompete. Intheirseminalwork,NVoffersubjectsasingle,carefullychosenrelativepayoffof4 (=$2.00WTApayment÷$0.50PRpayment).NVchoosethisrelativepayoffasit ensuresthattheexpectedpayoffisthesameforPRandWTApaymentsifasubject’s chanceofwinningtheWTAtournamentis25percent(therearefoursubjectsin eachgroup).UsingNV’sinstrument,oneisnotabletodeterminehowlargethe relativepayoffneedstobesothatasubjectchoosestheWTApayment,thestrength ofasubject’srelativepreferenceforWTApayments,northerelativepayoff‐ premiumthatisneededsothatwomenareaslikelyasmentochoosetheWTA payment. 3.4.Responsivenessofchoicestorelativepayoff Weexaminetheresponsivenessofsubjects’choicestochangesintherelativepayoff oftheWTApayment.Specifically,weperformaprobitregressionofsubjects’choice ofpaymentscheme(1=WTApaymentand0=PRpayment)onthelogofrelative payoffsintask4.Thechoicebetweena$0.00PRand$2.00WTApaymentsis droppedfromthisanalysisastherelativepayoffwouldbeinfinite(=$2.00÷$0.00). Theobservationsareclusteredbysubject,asthesubjects’20choicesarenot independent.Theresultsindicateahighlysignificantpositiverelationshipbetween thelogoftherelativepayoffandthelikelihoodofchoosingtheWTApayment;that is,thelikelihoodthatsubjectschoosetheWTApaymentoverthePRpayment increasesintherelativepayoff.Themarginaleffectsindicatethatdoublingthe relativepayoffisassociatedwitha45percentincreaseinthelikelihoodofchoosing theWTApayment(p=0.00).Interestingly,thestrongpositiverelationshipissimilar formenandwomen.Interactingthelogoftherelativepayoffswithgenderand addingagenderdummy(1=femaleand0=male)totheregression,wefindthatthe coefficientontheinteractiontermisnotsignificantlydifferentthanzero(p=0.17). Themarginaleffectsimplythatdoublingtherelativepayoffisassociatedwitha58 percent(p=0.00)anda35percent(p=0.00)increaseinthelikelihoodofchoosing theWTApaymentformenandwomen,respectively.Thus,therelationshipbetween therelativepayoffandthelikelihoodofchoosingtheWTApaymentissimilarfor menandwomeneventhoughwomenarelesslikelytochoosetheWTApaymenton average. 3.5.ResponsivenessofPR‐equivalentstoperformance Regressingtask‐4PR‐equivalentsongenderandtask‐3performance,thecoefficient onfemaleisnegativeandstatisticallysignificant(b=‐0.27,p=0.01),indicatingthat aftercontrollingforperformancewomen’smeanPR‐equivalentis$0.27lessthanis men’smeanPR‐equivalent(seeTable2).Ifonedoesnotcontrolfortask‐3 performance,thecoefficientonfemaleisvirtuallyunchanged,b=‐0.28(p=0.01); thus,performancedoesnotexplainthegenderdifferenceinthewillingnessto compete,asmeasuredbyPR‐equivalents. Interestingly,thecoefficientontask‐3performanceispositiveandstatistically significant(b=0.03,p=0.00),indicatingthatforeachadditionalsummation questionasubjectanswerscorrectlyherPR‐equivalentincreasesbyanaverageof $0.03.Wecontrolfortask‐3performancesincesubjectschoosetheirtask‐4PR‐ equivalentbeforecompletingtask4.Specifically,whilechoosingtheirtask‐4PR‐ equivalentsubjects’beliefscouldnothavebeeninfluencedbytheirtask‐4 performance.Thecoefficientsonfemaleandperformancearesimilarif,insteadof controllingfortask‐3performance(whensubjectschosebetweenaWTAandPR payment),wecontrolfortask‐2performance(whenallpaymentswereWTA payments)ortask‐4performance.Finally,controllingforimprovementsin performancebetweentasks1and2,and2and3,doesnotaffecttheresults. TheresultabovedivergesfromNV(2007).NVfindthatsubjects’likelihoodof choosingtheWTApaymentdoesnotincreasewithperformanceaftercontrollingfor genderandimprovementinperformance.Thisraisesthequestionofwhetherour resultsdivergefromNV(2007)becauseourinstrumentisdifferentorbecauseour sampleisdifferent.Toexaminethisquestionweperformaprobitregressionof task‐3choiceofpaymentscheme(1=WTApaymentand0=PRpayment)ontask‐2 performanceandimprovementinperformancebetweentasks1and2;recall,task3 mimicstheNVinstrument.Thecoefficientontask‐2performanceispositivebut insignificant(marginaleffect:b=0.02,p=0.19)(seeColumn4ofTable2).This replicatestheresultinNV(2007)andindicatesthatthereisnotasignificant relationshipbetweenperformanceandthelikelihoodofchoosingtheWTApayment intask3.Thus,ourPR‐equivalentinstrumentappearstobemoresensitivethan NV’s.Specifically,weareabletoconfirmthatthewillingnesstocompete,as measuredbyPR‐equivalents,isincreasinginperformance. Figures5aand5billustratetherelationshipbetweentask‐4PR‐equivalentsand task‐3andtask‐2performance,respectively.Examiningthefiguresclosely,the positiverelationshipbetweenPR‐equivalentsandperformanceismostapparentfor high‐valuePR‐equivalents.Forexample,meantask‐3performanceforsubjectsin thefirstthroughfifthquintileoftask‐4PR‐equivalentsis10.3,10.5,10.4,11.4,and 14.2,respectively;further,meantask‐3performanceforsubjectsinthetenthdecile oftask‐4PR‐equivalentsis17.1.Themeantask‐3performanceofsubjectsinthe fifthquintileandtenthdecileoftask‐4PR‐equivalentsissignificantlygreaterthan themeantask‐3performanceforsubjectsnotinthosegroups(14.2versus10.6,p= 0.01,and17.1versus10.7,p=0.00,respectively).Theresultsaresimilarifweuse task‐2performanceinsteadoftask‐3performance,orifweimposeatopcodeof30 onthesubjectwhoanswered51questionscorrectlyintask3.Thisresultisperhaps notsurprisingastheWTAtournamenthasfourparticipants.Soonlysubjectswho believetheyarethebestintheirgroupshouldhaveelevatedPR‐equivalents.Using NV’sinstrument,thisresultisobscuredassubjectsarenotabletoexpressthe strengthoftheirpreferenceforWTApayments(astheyareabletowithPR‐ equivalents). Interestingly,forbothmenandwomen,thosewithhigh‐valuetask‐4PR‐ equivalents—11menand4womenhavePR‐equivalentsof$1.50orabove—have significantlybettertask‐3performancethandothemenandwomenwithPR‐ equivalentsbelow$1.50(men:15.6versus10.6,p=0.02;andwomen:14.8versus 10.7p=0.03).Thesameresultsareobtainedifoneusestask‐2performance.Thus, somemenandwomenexpressagreaterwillingnesstocompete,asmeasuredby PR‐equivalents,andtheypresumablybelievetheyhaveahighlikelihoodof receivingtheWTApayment.Incontrast,comparingthosewhochoosetheWTA paymenttothosewhochoosethePRpaymentintask3,thedifferenceintask‐2 performanceisnotsignificantlydifferentformennorwomen(men:11.5versus9.9, p=0.38;andwomen:11.7versus9.9,p=0.12). Finally,somequalitativeevidenceregardingtherelationshipbetweenthe willingnesstocompeteandperformancewarrantsmention.Weasksubjectsthe followinginthequestionnairethatisadministeredafteralltasksarecompletedbut beforepayment‐revelation:“Whatfactorsdidyouconsiderinmakingyourchoice betweentheTournamentandPiece‐ratepaymentschemeinTask3?”Thesubject withthebestperformance,averaging49correctanswerspertask,statesthat “BecauseIamsuchabeastataddition,Ipickedtournamentscheme.TheleastIgot was45right.”Healwayschosethe$2.00WTApayment,evenwhenoffereda$2.00 PRpaymentintask4.Thesubjectwiththesecondbestperformance,averaging20 correctanswerspertask,didnotanswertheabovequestion,buthistask‐4PR‐ equivalentis$2.00.SohedoesnotchoosethePRpaymentuntilitisequaltothe WTApayment.Finally,thesubjectwiththethirdbestperformance,averaging18.5 correctanswerspertask,statesthat,“IconsideredmybeliefinhowwellIcanadd andhowwellIdidinthepreviousone.AlsoIconsideredmyprejudgementsonthe otherpeopleinmygroupbasedongender/howfastIheardthemclickinginthe previousones.”Hertask‐4PR‐equivalentis$1.50.Herresponseindicatesthateven thoughsubjectsdonotreceiveformalfeedbackabouttheirrelativeperformance fromtheexperimenter,subjectsmaybeattemptingtodeterminehowwelltheyare doingrelativetoothersubjectsintheirgroupusingauditoryorother environmentalcues.Thus,subjectswithhigh‐valuePR‐equivalentsmaybeawareof theirsuperiorrelativeperformance;andtheirwillingnesstocompete,asmeasured byPR‐equivalents,mightsimplyreflectthattheyknowtheyareadeptatthetask andmaynotrepresentageneralizedpreferenceforcompetition. Insummary,likeNV(2007),wefindevidencethatmenhaveagreaterwillingnessto competethandowomen:men’smeantask‐4PR‐equivalentissignificantlygreater thanwomen’s;andmenaresignificantlymorelikelythanwomentochoosethe $2.00WTApaymentoverthe$0.50PRpaymentintask3.However,unlikeNV (2007),wefindevidencethatawillingnesstocompeteislinkedtosuperior performance:task‐4PR‐equivalentsarepositivelyrelatedtotask‐3performance; andthosewhohaveahigh‐valuetask‐4PR‐equivalentarestrongperformers,on average. 3.6.ResponsivenessofPR‐equivalentstobeliefsaboutperformanceandrisk preferences Malecollegestudentsarebelievedtobemoreoverconfidentthanfemalecollege students(Croson&Gneezy,2009;Ifcher&Zarghamee2013).Inoursample,men’s meantask‐3self‐rank(where1=1stbest,2=2ndbest,3=3rdbest,and4=4thbest) issignificantlyhigherthanwomen’s(1.7versus2.3,p=0.00),eventhoughmen’s meantask‐3performanceisnotsignificantlybetterthanwomen’s(11.4versus11.0, p=0.71).Men’sgreaterwillingnesstocompetecouldsimplybetheresultoftheir greateroverconfidence.Regressingtask‐4PR‐equivalentsongenderandtask‐3self‐ rank,thecoefficientonfemaleisnegativeandsignificant(b=‐0.20,p=0.04), indicatingthataftercontrollingforoverconfidencemenstillhaveagreater willingnesstocompete,asmeasuredbyPR‐equivalents,thandowomen(seeTable 3).Thecoefficientontask‐3self‐rankisnegativeandsignificant(b=‐0.14,p=0.02), indicatingthatthewillingnesstocompeteisincreasingwithself‐rank.Theseresults mirrorresultsinNV(2007). Anotherpotentialexplanationfortheobservedgenderdifferenceinthewillingness tocompeteisvariantriskpreferences.Menarebelievedtobelessriskaversethan arewomen(Croson&Gneezy,2009).Inourstudy,wemeasureriskpreferences usingaHolt‐Laurylottery(task11).Weidentifysubjects’task‐11certainty equivalentusingthesameprocedureasweusetodeterminesubjects’task‐4PR‐ equivalent.Ofthe100subjectswithidentifiabletask‐4PR‐equivalents,99have identifiabletask‐11certaintyequivalents.Thegreaterthetask‐11certainty equivalent,thegreaterthefixedpaymentiswhenthesubjectswitchesfromthe lotterytothefixedpayment,indicatingthesubjectislessriskaverse.Inoursample, themeantask‐11certaintyequivalentismarginallygreaterformenthanitisfor women($5.20versus$4.70,p=0.09),suggestingthatmeninourstudyarelessrisk aversethanarewomen.Regressingtask‐4PR‐equivalentsongenderandtask‐11 certaintyequivalents,thecoefficientonfemaleisnegativeandsignificant(b=‐0.21, p=0.03),indicatingthataftercontrollingforriskpreferences,asmeasuredbytask‐ 11certaintyequivalents,menhaveagreaterwillingnesstocompete,asmeasured bytask‐4PR‐equivalents,thandowomen(seeColumn4ofTable3).Thecoefficient ontask‐11certaintyequivalentsispositiveandsignificant(b=0.14,p=0.00), indicatingthatthewillingnesstocompeteincreasesasriskaversiondecreases. Further,controllingforallthreecovariatesinthesameregression,task‐3 performance,task‐3self‐rank,andtask‐11certaintyequivalents,thecoefficienton femaleremainsnegativeandsignificant(b=‐0.18,p=0.04),indicatingthat,after controllingforperformance,self‐rank,andriskpreferences,menhaveagreater willingnesstocompete,asmeasuredbyPR‐equivalents,thandowomen.Again,this mirrorsNV(2007).Importantly,controllingforself‐rankandriskpreferencesdoes notdiminishtherelationshipbetweenthewillingnesstocompeteandperformance. Thecoefficientontask‐3performanceispositiveandsignificant(b=0.03,p=0.01), indicatingthatthepositiverelationshipbetweenperformanceandwillingnessto competeisnotexplainedbyself‐rankandriskpreferences(seeColumn5ofTable 3).ThisresultagaindivergesfromNV(2007)andraisesthequestionofwhetherthe divergenceisduetothenewinstrumentoradifferentsample.Toexaminethis question,weregresstask‐3choices(NV’sinstrument)ontask‐2performance,task‐2 self‐rank,andtask‐11certaintyequivalents.Thecoefficientontask‐2performance isnotsignificant(b=0.00,p=0.87),indicatingthatwhenusingNV’sinstrumentit appearsthatthereisnorelationshipbetweenperformanceandthewillingnessto compete,asmeasuredbythechoicebetweena$0.50PRpaymentanda$2.00WTA payment(seeTable4).Interestingly,inthisspecification,thecoefficientonfemaleis negativebutnotsignificant(b=‐0.15,p=0.19).ThisalsodivergesfromNV(2007) whereasignificantgenderdifferenceinthewillingnesstocompeteisfoundafter controllingforperformanceandself‐rank.Incontrast,thecoefficientsontask‐2self‐ rankandtask‐11certaintyequivalentaresignificantlyrelatedtothewillingnessto compete(negativelyandpositively,respectively). Finally,repeatingtheaboveregressionformenandwomenseparately,wefindthat therelationshipbetweenthewillingnesstocompeteandperformanceandself‐rank holdformenbutfornotwomen.Formen,thecoefficientontask‐3performanceand ontask‐3self‐rankare0.03(p=0.00)and‐0.14(p=0.06),respectively;theyare 0.02(p=0.69)and0.04(p=0.72)forwomen,respectively(seeColumns6and7of Table3).Incontrast,therelationshipbetweenthewillingnesstocompeteandrisk preferencesissimilarformenandwomen(men:b=0.11,p=0.00,andwomen:b= 0.13,p=0.01).Usingtask‐2performanceandself‐rankinplaceoftask‐3 performanceandself‐rankintheregression,onefindssimilarresultsexceptthat therelationshipbetweenthewillingnesstocompeteandtask‐2self‐rankisnow significantforwomenbutnotmen(men:b=‐0.06,p=0.41,andwomen:b=‐0.30,p =0.00). 3.7.Impactofchoicesonexpectedpayments Toexaminetheimpactofsubjects’choicesontheirpayments,wecalculateeach subject’sexpectedpaymentbasedonherchoicesforeachofthe21offeredPR paymentsintask4.Forexample,ifasubjectchosethe$0.50PRpaymentoverthe $2.00WTApayment,thenherexpectedpaymentwouldbetheproductofthe$0.50 PRpaymentandhertask‐4performance.Incontrast,ifasubjectchosethe$2.00 WTApaymentoverthe$0.50PRpayment,thenherexpectedpaymentwouldbethe productofthe$2.00WTApayment,hertask‐4performance,andtheprobabilityof winningtheWTAtournament,wheretheprobabilityofwinningisimputedusing thedistributionofwinners’task‐2performancewhenallpaymentsareWTA payments.Foreachsubjectwealsocalculatethesubject’smaximumpossible expectedpaymentforeachofthe21offeredPRpayments.Specifically,wecalculate asubject’sexpectedpaymentfromchoosingthePRandWTApayment(asdescribed above),andselectthelargerofthetwo. Theexpectedpaymentsofsubjects’choicesare,onaverage,88percentoftheir maximumpossibleexpectedpayments.Asapercentageofthemaximumpossible expectedpayment,theexpectedpaymentfromsubjects’choicesisgreatestwhen thePRpaymentis$0.00or$2.00,asalmostallsubjectschosetheWTAandPR payment,respectively,therebynearlymaximizingexpectedpayments.Table5 presentstheaveragepercentofthemaximumpossibleexpectedpayment representedbytheexpectedpaymentofsubjects’choices.Asapercentageofthe maximumpossibleexpectedpayment,theexpectedpaymentfromsubjects’choices islowest—74percent—atthe$0.50PRpayment.The$0.50PRpaymentisthe valueatwhichtherelativepayoffofthePRpaymentisthesameasthe unconditionalchanceofwinningtheWTAtournament:one‐quarter.Interestingly, theanalogouscalculationfortask3(when$0.50istheonlyPRpaymentoffered)is 69percent,whichisnotsignificantlydifferent(p‐valueofdifference=0.23). Figures6and7illustratetherelationshipbetweenthepercentofthemaximum possibleexpectedpaymentsandtask‐3performanceandtask‐4PR‐equivalents, respectively.Noclearpatternemergesineitherfigure.Tosystematicallyexamine thisrelationship,weregressthepercentofthemaximumpossibleexpected paymentongender,task‐3performance,task‐3self‐rank,andtask‐11certainty equivalent.Noneofthecoefficientsisstatisticallysignificant.However,dividingthe sampleintolow‐andhigh‐performingsubgroups—subjectswhoperformworse thanandbetterthanthetask‐3median(11summations),respectively—onefinds thatthecoefficientonthetask‐11certaintyequivalentisnegativeandsignificant(b =‐6.45,p=0.04)forthelow‐performingsubgroup,andpositiveandsignificant(b= 2.65,p=0.01)forthehigh‐performingsubgroup(seeTable6).Thisindicatesthat, forlow‐performing(high‐performing)subjects,thepercentofthemaximum possibleexpectedpaymentisincreasing(decreasing)withriskaversion.Inother words,forlow‐performingsubjects,riskaversionispositivelyrelatedtothepercent ofthemaximumpossibleexpectedpaymentrepresentedbytheexpectedpayment ofsubjects’choices.Themagnitudeofthecoefficientislarge:requiringanextra dollartoswitchfromthelotterytothefixedpaymentisassociatedwithalossof 6.45percentagepointsofthemaximumpossibleexpectedpayment.The relationshipistheoppositeforthehigh‐performingsubjects,butthecoefficientis smaller.Thisindicatesthatreducedriskaversionispositivelyrelatedtothepercent ofthemaximumpossibleexpectedpaymentforhigh‐performingsubjects.Itisalso interestingthatthecoefficientonfemaleisnegativeandmarginallysignificant(b=‐ 6.86,p=0.09)forthehigh‐performingsubjectsbutnotforthelow‐performing subjects,suggestingthathigh‐performingfemalesearnalowerpercentageoftheir maximumpossibleexpectedpaymentthandotheirmalecounterparts.Thisgender differenceisnotobservedforthelow‐performingsubjects.Thisresultisinlinewith theNV(2007)resultthathigh‐performingwomenunder‐compete. 3.8.Relationshipbetweentask‐4PR‐equivalentsandSTEMcoursesandGPA Ithasbeensuggestedthatgenderdifferencesinthewillingnesstocompetemay explainthepaucityofwomeninSTEMfields.Toexplorewhetherthisisthecase,we regresstask‐4PR‐equivalentsonthenumberofSTEMcoursessubjectshavetaken; wecontrolfortask‐3performance,task‐3self‐rank,andtask‐11certainty equivalentsineachregressioninthissection.Thecoefficientonthenumberof STEMcoursesispositivebutinsignificant(b=0.10,p=0.21)(seeTable7).The resultschangemarkedly,however,whentheanalysisisrepeatedseparatelyformen andwomen.ThecoefficientonSTEMcoursesispositiveandsignificantforwomen (b=0.03,p=0.01),andnegativeandinsignificantformen(b=‐0.003,p=0.68). Thisindicatesthatwomenwhohaveagreaterwillingnesstocompete,asmeasured bytheirPR‐equivalents,takemoreSTEMcoursesthandowomenwhohavealower willingnesstocompete.Incontrast,formenthereisnorelationshipbetweenthe willingnesstocompeteandSTEMcourseenrollment.Ananalogousregressionthat considerstherelationshipbetweenthewillingnesstocompeteandhavingaSTEM majorfindsasimilarpattern:apositiverelationshipforwomenbutnotformen; however,noneoftheresultsaresignificant. ExaminingtherelationshipbetweenthewillingnesstocompeteandcumulativeGPA onefindstheoppositeresult:thereisapositiveandsignificantrelationshipbetween thetwoformen(b=0.27,p=0.01)butnotforwomen(b=0.15,p=0.55).This indicatesthatmenwhohaveagreaterwilinesstocompetehavehigherGPAsthan menwhohavealowerwillingnesstocompete(seeTable8);thisrelationshipdoes notholdforwomen.Asaspecificationcheck,weincludeSTEMcoursesandGPAas independentvariablesinthesameregression,andtheresultsareunchanged.The juxtapositionofthesetworesultscanleadtosomeinterestingspeculation.For example,formen(butnotforwomen)doingwellacademicallyisdrivenbya willingnesstocompete;andforwomen(butnotmen)takingSTEMcoursesisdriven byawillingnesstocompete.Moreover,therelationshipbetweenthewillingnessto competeandtask‐3performanceholdsformen,butnotwomen.So,perhapsitisnot surprisingthattherelationshipbetweenthewillingnesstocompeteandGPAholds formen,butnotwomen.However,itmustbenotedthattherelationshipsidentified abovearesimplycorrelational,andthus,nocausalinferenceshouldbepresumed. 3.9.Relationshipbetweentask‐4PR‐equivalentsandparticipationinvarsitysports Socialscientistsstudyingthepreferenceforcompetitionhaveponderedwhetherit canbelearned.Inanattempttoexplorethisquestionweasksubjectsabouttheir participationinhighschoolandcollegevarsitysports;whilewecannotidentify causalrelationship,wecanexploretherelationshipbetweenthewillingnessto competeandparticipationinvarsitysports.Wefirstconsiderparticipationin collegevarsitysports.Regressingtask‐4PR‐equivalentsonparticipationincollege varsitysports,wefindthatthecoefficientonparticipationispositiveandsignificant forwomen(b=0.85,p=0.05)butinsignificantformen(b=0.07,p=0.78).This appearstoindicatethatforwomenparticipatingincollegevarsitysportsis positivelyrelatedtoawillingnesstocompete.Themagnitudeoftheeffectis noteworthy,implyingthatparticipationisassociatedwitha$0.85increaseintask‐4 PR‐equivalent.Cautionmustbeusedwheninterpretingthisresultasitisbasedon twofemaleandthreemalecollegevarsityathletes.Further,whethermore competitivewomenparticipateincollegevarsitysportsorwhetherwomenlearnto bemorecompetitivethroughcollegevarsitysportsisnotidentifiableinthisstudy andmustbeexaminedinafutureresearchproject. Examiningtherelationshipbetweenthewillingnesstocompeteandparticipationin highschoolvarsitysports,weregresstask‐4PR‐equivalentsonparticipationinhigh schoolvarsitysports.Wefindthattherelationshipisnegativeandinsignificantfor bothmenandwomen(men:b=‐0.23,p=0.21,andwomen:b=‐0.05,p=0.66).The negative(thoughinsignificant)coefficientmayatfirstappearcurious.However,65 percentofsubjectsarehighschoolvarsityathletes.Thus,collegevarsityathletesare ahighlyselectivegroupandhighschoolvarsityathletesarenot.Thatis,thesetwo subgroupsmaynotbesimilar.Forexample,whilemeantask‐3performancefor varsitycollegeathletesisbetterthanfornon‐athletes(13.6versus11.2,p=0.33), meantask‐3performanceforvarsityhighschoolathletesisworsethanfornon‐ athletes(11.0versus12.1,p=0.31).Onepossibleexplanationforthenegative relationshipbetweenthewillingnesstocompeteandparticipationinhighschool varsityathleticsmightbethatathletesarelessoverconfidentthannon‐athletes. Thatis,highschoolvarsityathletesmightlearntobelessoverconfidentthrough competingandinevitablylosing.Further,wespeculatethatthisshouldbeespecially trueforlow‐performingmen,sincetheycanbethemostoverconfident.Inour samplewefindsupportforthisexplanation:highschoolvarsityathletesrank themselveslowerthannon‐athletes(2.1versus1.8,p=0.15);thereisasimilar patternforthefivecollegevarsityathletes(2.2versus2.0,p=0.59).Furthermore, thedifferenceislargerformen(1.9versus1.2,p=0.01)thanforwomen(2.4versus 2.2,p=0.35),andislargestformenwhosetask‐3performanceisworsethanthe median(2.3versus1.4,p=0.05).Restrictingtheregressiontomenwithtask‐3 performancebelowthemedian,wefindthatthecoefficientonhighschoolvarsity participationisnegativeandmarginallysignificant(b=‐0.47,p=0.08).Again,the magnitudeoftheeffectisnoteworthy,suggestingthatparticipationinhighschool varsityathleticsisassociatedwitha$0.47decreaseintask‐4PR‐equivalentforlow‐ performingmen. Interestingly,therelationshipsidentifiedbetweenthewillingnesstocompeteand STEMcourses,GPA,andvarsitysportsparticipationarenotidentifiableusingtask‐3 choices.Specifically,weconducttheanalogousanalysesexceptwithaprobit regressionusingthetask‐3choiceofpaymentscheme(1=WTApaymentand0= PRpayment)asthedependentvariableandaddingcontrolsfortask‐2performance andself‐rank.Allthecoefficientsofinterestareinsignificant.Thus,thetask‐3 measureisnotsensitiveenoughtoidentifytherelationshipsidentifiedabove. Lastly,thecoefficientsontask‐3performance,task‐3self‐rank,andtask‐11 certaintyequivalentsinthissectionareconsistentwithourpriorresults: performanceispositivelyrelatedtothewillingnesstocompeteformen,andgreater riskaversionisinverselyrelatedtothewillingnesstocompeteformenandwomen. 3.10.Task5 SubjectsretrospectivelychosewhethertheywantedtoapplyaPRpaymentora $2.00WTApaymenttotheirtask‐1performanceforthesame21PRpayments offeredintask4.InNV(2007),ananalogoustaskisusedtoruleoutpotential explanationsfortheobservedgenderdifferenceinthewillingnesstocompete.NV findnosignificantgenderdifferenceinchoicesbetweena$0.50PRanda$2.00WTA paymentwhentheyregresssubjects’retrospectivechoicesongender,task‐1 performance,andtask‐1self‐rank.Theyarguethatthesalientdifferencebetween thetworesultsisthatsubjectscompletethetaskaftermakingtheirchoiceonlyin themainresult.Theyinterpretthisfindingasdemonstratingthattheobserved genderdifferenceinthemainresultisexplainedbyavariantpreferencefor competitionandnotbyotherfactors,forexample,overconfidenceandfeedbackand riskaversion.ReplicatingNV’sexercise,weregresstask‐5PR‐equivalentson gender,task‐1performance,andtask‐1self‐rank.Thecoefficientonfemaleis negativeandmarginallysignificant(b=‐0.14,p=0.07).Thus,thereissome evidencethatthereisagenderdifferencewhenusingretrospectivechoices. However,thecoefficientbecomesinsignificant(b=0.10,p=0.18)ifoneaddstask‐ 11certaintyequivalents(riskaversion)totheregression(seeColumn3ofTable8). NVdidnotmeasuresubjects’riskpreferencesdirectly,sotheycouldnotconductan analogousregression.Thus,wefindsupportthatcompletingthetaskafterchoosing thepaymentschemeisanimportantcontributortosubjects’observedwillingness tocompete. 4.Discussion Wedevelopanewinstrumenttomeasurethewillingnesstocompetebyoffering subjectsaseriesofPRpaymentsrangingfrom0to100percentoftheWTA payment.TheofferedPRpaymentsimplyrelativepayoffs(WTApaymenttoPR payment)rangingfrominfinityto1.Weidentifyeachsubject’sPRequivalentofthe WTApayment.Thatis,thevalueoftheWTApaymenttothesubject.Wefindthat womenvaluethe$2.00WTApaymentsignificantlylessthandomen,about$0.28 less;andthatwomenrequireapremium(relativetomen)ofabout40percentto compete.Giventhisresultandthefactthatwomenarepaidlessthanmenforthe samejobonaverage,itisperhapsnosurprisethatwomenareunderrepresentedin competitive,male‐dominatedfields.Ourresultalsosuggeststhatifwomenwere offeredapremium(relativetomen)forcompetingthatthegenderdifferenceinthe willingnesstocompetemightbeeliminated. WeusethenewinstrumenttodemonstratethatNV’smainresultholdsforPR paymentsbetween5and70percentofthe$2.00WTApayment.Thus,NV’sfinding holdformanyrelativepayoffsandisnotdependentontheratioofthePRpayment totheWTApaymentbeingequaltotheunconditionalchanceofwinningthe tournamentinthebinary‐choiceinstrument.Otherresearchershavedemonstrated thatthereisagenderdifferenceinthewillingnesstocompeteusingproportional tournamentpaymentaswell(e.g.,Casonet.al.,2010). Ourinstrumentismoresensitivethanthebinary‐choiceinstrument,asitclassifies thewillingnesstocompeteinto21categories.Thisenableustoidentify relationshipsbetweenthewillingnesstocompeteandothervariablesthatarenot identifiableifoneusesthebinary‐choiceinstrument.Forexample,wefindthat subjectswhoarethemostwillingtocompetealsohavehighabilityonaverage.This relationshipisnotidentifiableusingthebinary‐choiceinstrument.Itisimportantas itimpliesthatatleastpartiallythewillingnesstocompetemaynotbedependent uponindividual’soverconfidenceandpreferenceforcompetition.Rather,itmaybe taskspecific.Thatis,individualsmaybemorewillingtocompete,notsurprisingly, intasksatwhichtheyareabove‐averageorexceptional.Thisinterpretationis supportedbystudiesthatfindmenarenotmorewillingtocompetethanwomenin stereotypically‐femaletasks(e.g.,Kamas&Preston,2009).Further,asonesubject reportedinthequestionnaire,subjectsarereceivingfeedbackontheirrelative performancebasedonnoisesintheroomandothercues.Outsidethelab, individualspresumablyusevariouscuestohelpdeterminetheirlikelihoodof winningcompetitions.Womenmaybemoresensitivetosuchcues;again,Croson andGneezy(2009)findthatwomenaremorecontext‐sensitivethanmen.Finally, wefindevidencethatthewillingnesstocompeteisdecreasingwithriskaversion. Thus,thewillingnesstocompeteappearstoberelatedtobothperformanceandrisk preferencesinadditiontooverconfidenceandpreferencesforcompetition. Further,wefindapositiverelationshipbetweenthewillingnesstocompeteand GPAformen(notforwomen);apositiverelationshipbetweenthewillingnessto competeandtakingSTEMcoursesforwomen(notformen);andapositive relationshipbetweenwillingnesstocompeteandparticipationinvarsitycollege athleticsforwomen(notformen).Thelattertworesultsmaysuggestthat individualscanlearntoincreasetheirwillingnesstocompete.Thatis,takingSTEM coursesandparticipatinginvarsitycollegesportmayincreasewomen’swillingto compete.However,asweemphasizeinthepaper,ourresearchdesigndoesnot enableustodemonstrateacausalrelationship,andthus,causationcouldruninthe oppositedirection:STEMcoursesandvarsitycollegeathleticsmayattractwomen whoarethemostwillingtocompete.Furtherresearchisneededtoidentifythis potentiallyimportantcausalrelationship,asitwouldhelpexplorewhetherwomen’s willingnesstocompetecanbeaugmented. Finally,giventhansubjects’choicebetweena$0.50PRpaymentanda$2.00WTA paymentareimpactedbythecontextinwhichthechoiceispresented(task3versus task4)suggeststhatsubjectschoicesintask4mightbeimpactedbyquestion‐order andoranchoringeffects.Thus,furtherresearchiswarrantedtodeterminewhether ourfindingsmightbesensitivetotheframingofthequestion. References Balafoutas,L.,andSutter,M.(2010).Gender,CompetitionandtheEfficiencyof PolicyIntervention.IZADiscussionPaperNo.4955. Cason,T.N.,Masters,W.A.,andSheremeta,R.M.(2010).Entryintowinner‐take‐all andproportional‐prizecontests:Anexperimentalstudy.JournalofPublic Economics,94(9),604‐611. Croson,R.,andGneezy,U.(2009).GenderDifferencesinPreferences.Journalof EconomicLiterature,47,448‐74. Dargnies,M.P.(2009).Doesteamcompetitioneliminatethegendergapinentryin competitiveenvironments?CESWorkingPaper2009.06. Fischbacher,U.(2007).z‐Tree:ZurichToolboxforReady‐madeEconomic Experiments.ExperimentalEconomics,10(2),171‐178. Goldin,C.,Katz,L.F.,andKuziemko,I.(2006).TheHomecomingofAmericanCollege Women:TheReversaloftheCollegeGenderGap.TheJournalofEconomic Perspectives,20(4),133‐156. Grosse,N.D.,andRiener,G.(2010)."ExplainingGenderDifferencesin Competitiveness:Gender‐TaskStereotypes."JenaEconomicResearchPapers017. Gupta,N.D.,Poulsen,A.,andVilleval,M.C.(2013).Gendermatchingand competitiveness:experimentalevidence.EconomicInquiry,51(1),816‐835. Healy,A.,andPate,J.(2011).CanTeamsHelptoClosetheGenderCompetitionGap? TheEconomicJournal,121(555),1192‐1204. Holt,C.A.,andLaury,S.K.(2002).Riskaversionandincentiveeffects.American economicreview,92(5),1644‐1655. Ifcher,J.,andZarghamee,H.(2013)AffectandOverconfidence:Laboratory Investigations.SCULeaveySchoolofBusinessResearchPaperNo.11‐02. KamasL.,andPreston,A.(2009).Socialpreferences,competitivenessand compensation:Aretheregenderdifferences?WorkPaper. Kamas,L.,andPreston,A.(2012).Theimportanceofbeingconfident;gender,career choice,andwillingnesstocompete.JournalofEconomicBehavior&Organization, 83(1),82‐97. Niederle,M.,andVesterlund,L.(2007).Dowomenshyawayfromcompetition?Do mencompetetoomuch?TheQuarterlyJournalofEconomics,122(3),1067‐1101. Niederle,M.,andVesterlund,L.(2010).Explainingthegendergapinmathtest scores:Theroleofcompetition.TheJournalofEconomicPerspectives,24(2),129‐ 144. Niederle,M.,andVesterlund,L.(2011).Genderandcompetition.AnnualReviewof Economics,3(1),601‐630. Niederle,M.,Segal,C.,andVesterlund,L.(2013).Howcostlyisdiversity?Affirmative actioninlightofgenderdifferencesincompetitiveness.ManagementScience,59(1), 1‐16. Wozniak,D.,Harbaugh,W.,andMayr,U.(2009).ChoicesaboutCompetition: DifferencesbyGenderandHormonalFluctuations,andtheRoleofRelative PerformanceFeedback.SSRNWorkingPaperNo.1564895. Table1:Task‐1andtask‐2performancebygenderandchoiceoftask‐3paymentscheme Gender Women Men Choice of payment scheme in task 3 PR payment WTA payment p‐value (two‐tail) PR payment WTA payment p‐value (two‐tail) Task 1 8.94 (0.45) 8.65 (0.71) 0.72 Average performance Task 2 9.94 (0.56) 11.53 (1.00) 0.14 8.56 (0.62) 10.39 (1.25) 0.24 9.68 (0.59) 11.36 (1.34) 0.30 Task 2 ‐ Task 1 1.00 (0.42) 2.88 (0.85) 0.03 1.12 (0.39) 0.97 (0.53) 0.83 Observations 33 17 25 33 Table2:Estimatesfromregressingtask‐4PR‐equivalentsongenderandperformance Task‐4 Task‐4 Task‐4 Task‐3 choice PR‐equivalent PR‐equivalent PR‐equivalent of WTA payment (1) (2) (3) (4) Female ‐0.268 (0.097) *** ‐0.276 (0.097) *** ‐0.274 (0.097) *** ‐0.258 (0.098) *** Task‐3 performance 0.031 (0.008) *** 0.032 (0.009) *** Task‐2 performance 0.032 (0.008) *** 0.016 (0.012) Improvement between tasks 1 and 2 0.010 (0.020) 0.000 (0.016) 0.013 (0.022) Improvement between tasks 2 and 3 ‐0.013 (0.021) 100 100 100 Observations 100 Table3:Estimatesfromregressingtask‐4PR‐equivalentsongender,performance,self‐rank,andcertaintyequivalents Task‐4 Task‐4 Task‐4 Task‐4 Task‐4 Male task‐4 Female task‐4 PR‐equivalent PR‐equivalent PR‐equivalent PR‐equivalent PR‐equivalent PR‐equivalent PR‐equivalent (6) (1) (2) (3) (4) (5) (7) Female Task‐3 performance Task‐3 self‐rank Task‐11 (lottery) certainty equivalent Observations ‐0.284 (0.101) *** ‐0.268 (0.097) *** ‐0.197 (0.096) ** 0.031 (0.008) *** ‐0.136 (0.059) ** 100 100 100 ‐0.212 (0.093) ** ‐0.183 (0.088) ** 0.025 (0.009) *** 0.025 (0.006) *** ‐0.037 (0.060) ‐0.137 (0.071) * 0.136 (0.027) *** 0.123 (0.029) *** 0.107 (0.029) *** 53 99 99 0.015 (0.038) 0.038 (0.106) 0.126 (0.046) *** 46 Table4:Estimatesfromregressingtask‐3choiceofpaymentschemeongender,performance,self‐rank,andcertainty equivalents Task‐3 choose WTA payment (1) Female Task‐2 performance Task‐2 self‐rank Task‐11 (lottery) certainty equivalent Observations ‐0.250 (0.098) ** 0.021 (0.012) * 100 Task‐3 choose WTA payment (2) Task‐3 choose WTA payment (3) ‐0.177 (0.107) ‐0.154 (0.115) 0.003 (0.010) 0.002 (0.010) ‐0.199 (0.068) *** ‐0.152 (0.069) ** 0.139 (0.043) *** 99 100 Table5:Averagepercentofthemaximumpossibleexpectedpaymentrepresentedbytheexpectedpaymentofsubjects’ choicesbyPRpayment Percent of maximum $0.00 0.980 (0.141) 0.10 0.783 (0.385) 0.20 0.763 (0.394) 0.30 0.748 (0.402) 0.40 0.762 (0.387) 0.50 0.738 (0.371) 0.60 0.755 (0.344) 0.70 0.741 (0.333) 0.80 0.774 (0.308) 0.90 0.792 (0.294) 1.00 0.809 (0.265) 1.10 0.836 (0.238) 1.20 0.852 (0.226) 1.30 0.868 (0.217) 1.40 0.889 (0.211) 1.50 0.917 (0.174) 1.60 0.942 (0.154) 1.70 0.953 (0.149) 1.80 0.961 (0.147) 1.90 0.968 (0.146) 2.00 0.995 (0.052) Average 0.881 (0.161) Standard deviation in parenthesis PR payment Table6:Estimatesfromregressingpercentofmaximumpossibleexpectedpaymentongender,performance,self‐rank,and certaintyequivalents Task‐3 performance Dependent variable: percent of All worse than maximum possible expected payment (1) median (2) Female ‐1.806 (2.832) ‐0.539 (5.818) Task‐3 performance 0.079 (0.322) 1.923 (1.420) Task‐3 self‐rank 0.613 (2.771) 3.114 (3.982) Task‐11 (lottery) certainty equivalent ‐1.597 (1.624) ‐6.447 (2.955) ** Observations 99 43 Task‐3 performance better than median (3) ‐6.863 (3.910) * 0.057 (0.336) 1.095 (3.256) 2.648 (0.955) *** 44 Table7:EstimatesfromregressingPR‐equivalentsongender,STEMcourses,performance,self‐rank,andcertaintyequivalents All (1) Dependent variable: Task‐4 PR‐equivalent Female STEM courses Task‐3 performance Task‐3 self‐rank Task‐11 certainty equivalent Observations Men (2) ‐0.168 (0.088) * 0.010 (0.008) ‐0.003 (0.007) 0.026 (0.008) *** 0.025 (0.006) *** ‐0.038 (0.058) ‐0.138 (0.070) * 0.124 (0.029) *** 0.106 (0.031) *** 53 99 Women (3) 0.027 (0.009) *** 0.015 (0.036) 0.021 (0.107) 0.118 (0.044) *** 46 Table8:EstimatesfromregressingPR‐equivalentsongender,GPA,performance,self‐rank,andcertaintyequivalents All (1) Dependent variable: Task‐4 PR‐equivalent Female Cumulative GPA Task‐3 performance Task‐3 self‐rank Task‐11 certainty equivalent Observations ‐0.222 (0.088) 0.248 (0.091) 0.022 (0.009) ‐0.027 (0.060) 0.115 (0.029) 99 ** *** ** Men (2) 0.266 (0.094) *** 0.023 (0.007) *** ‐0.113 (0.073) *** 0.104 (0.027) *** 53 Women (3) 0.147 (0.246) 0.015 (0.039) 0.040 (0.109) 0.119 (0.051) ** 46 Figure1:ScreenshotofchoicesbetweenvariousPRpayments,rangingfrom$0.00to$2.00,anda$2.00WTApayment Figure2:Distributionoftask‐4PR‐equivalents 0 5 Fr eq uen cy 10 15 Figure3:Distributionoftask‐4PR‐equivalentsbygender 0 .5 1 1.5 2 Task-4 PR-equivalents ($) Female Male .8 .6 .4 .2 0 % ch o o s e P R p a y m en t 1 Figure4:CDFbygender 0 5 10 15 20 PR payment ($0.10) Females Males Figure5a:Relationshipbetweentask‐4PR‐equivalentsandtask‐3performance Figure5B:Relationshipbetweentask‐4PR‐equivalentsandtask‐2performance Figure6:Relationshipbetweenthepercentofthemaximumpossibleexpectedpaymentsandtask‐3performance Figure7:Relationshipbetweenthepercentofthemaximumpossibleexpectedpaymentsandtask‐4PR‐equivalents