FRANCE Incentives for indefinite employment Statements and Comments Radu VRANCEANU ESSEC Business School 1. The principle of “increasing flexibility at the margin” and the emergence of “dual” labour markets” in South European countries. After a long period of disappointing performances in Continental European labour markets, in 1994, the OECD Jobs Strategy called firmly for increasing flexibility as a central element of the employment enhancing policy. In particular, it was agreed that high employment protection as delivered by regular open-ended labour contracts, while having an ambiguous effect on total unemployment, leads to high long term unemployment, and adversely affects productivity, output and welfare. In practice, the strategy of reducing dismissal costs relative to open-ended contracts proved to be hard to implement, due to strong political opposition by the majority of employees and trade unions. To bypass this difficulty, several governments decided to increase labour market flexibility at the margin, by creating or extending the category of employees subject to fixed-term contracts, which firms can fire with small separation costs. As employment protection for the open-ended contracts was basically kept unchanged, a dual labour market emerged in South European countries, with highly protected workers covered by open-ended contracts on the one hand, and much less protected workers, covered by temporary contracts, on the other hand. In general economists were critical about the welfare implications of these dual labour markets. They put forward a mixed impact on the global efficiency of the labour market and strong negative distributional effects (Blanchard and Landier, 2002; Blanchard and Tirole, 2004; Boeri and Garibaldi, 2005; OECD, 2006). As pointed out by Luis Toharia in his Discussion Paper, the Spanish experience is representative of an extreme outcome of the “liberalization at the margin” principle. Subject to very high and persistent unemployment, Spain began this liberalization process in the mid-eighties, well before the other countries, by authorizing the widespread recourse to temporary contracts. Hence, in the late nineties the number of temporary contracts represented more than 30% of total employment (by far the highest ratio in Europe). In the interval, the unemployment rate declined sharply, to reach 9.2% in 2005, slightly higher than the EU15 average (of 7.9%). In the late nineties, the proliferation of fixed-term contracts began to worry Spanish policymakers. Hence several labour policy reforms were implemented in 1997, 2001, and 2006, with the aim of providing additional incentives for firms to hire people under open-ended contracts rather than temporary (fixed-term) contracts, and to convert existing fixed-term contracts into open-ended contracts. The fiscal incentives for firms to shift to open-ended contracts were accompanied by a reduction of the protection provided by this type of contracts: severance payments were reduced from 45 to 33 days per year of employment, but still remain very high according to international comparisons. The juridical dispute resolution mechanism was also simplified. Luis Toharia points 16-17 November 2006 Peer Review Incentives for indefinite employment, Madrid 39 FRANCE out that reforms adopted in 1997 and 2001 do not seem to be very effective in curbing the rise in fixed-term contracts. When it comes to evaluate the virtues of such a reform, and the usefulness of transferring it to other countries, one should firstly proceed to an overall analysis of the macroeconomic consequences of the full package of Employment Protection Legislation (EPL), including the protection of regular workers against dismissal, specific requirements for collective dismissal, regulation of temporary forms of employment, as well as the interaction between the EPL and the unemployment protection system. 2. EPL and the performance of the French labour market 2.1 A brief outlook of the French labour market performance In the last few years, the overall economic performance of the French economy was relatively positive (growth in France outpaced the EU average, French labour productivity is very high, the country attracted substantial amounts of FDI, the fiscal position improved, many French companies are world leaders in their markets). Yet the labour market situation contrasts sharply with this globally reassuring picture. According to the Eurostat statistical database, in the last ten years (1996-2005), employment growth in France exceeded 2% only in one year, compared to Spain where employment growth fell below 2% only in one year. The French unemployment rate in 2005 was as high as 9.7%. Quite worrisome, the share of long-term unemployed persons in total unemployment is very high, equal to 41.2% (as compared to 24,5% in Spain). Another major challenge for the French policymakers is the rising number of unemployed youth (below 25 years old). Youth unemployment rate reached 23% in 2005 (compared to 19,7% in Spain and 16.8% in the EU15), despite the high level of qualification (82.8 percent of the population between 20 and 24 years old obtained a secondary education degree, compared to 61,3% in Spain, and 74.1 in the EU15). One usual suspect for this poor performance of the French labour market is the high level of EPL strictness in France, ranked 6th in 2003 of the 28 countries belonging to the OECD (OECD, 2006). 2.2 Types of labour contracts in France, and the extent of the dual labour market There are two main types of labour contracts in France: the regular open-ended contract (contrat à durée indéterminée, or CDI) and the fixed-term contract (contrat à durée déterminée, or CDD). Temporary help agencies may hire people under special temporary contracts; there is also a special apprenticeship contract. When flexibility is interpreted as the ability of the employer to fire an employee at one moment in time, the overall dismissal cost is the good measure of the protection granted to the employee. This cost is in general a random variable, because, at the moment when the firm decides to fire a worker, it does not know whether the worker will sue for abusive dismissal, and if he goes to court, whether labour judges will sit with the worker or with the firm. 16-17 November 2006 Peer Review Incentives for indefinite employment, Madrid 40 FRANCE In general the firm must pay a severance indemnity, depending on the type of contract (CDI or CDD), the motive of the dismissal, and the decision of the judge. The French law distinguishes between economic motives, where separation occurs basically because the firm strives to maintain its competitive edge, and personal motives, because the worker’s capabilities or behaviour do not match the firm’s needs; one particular personal motive is the serious professional fault, where the worker commits a serious abuse (in this case, there is no severance payment). Notice that the law provides no formal definition for the personal motive (the cause must be “real and serious”), and what can be accepted or not as a valid motive emerged from juridical practice over time.16 Economic motives are defined in more specific terms, which all may be related one way or another to the firm’s financial solvency. In addition, firms with over 50 employees cannot fire more than 10 persons if they do not demonstrate before the Labour Public Authority that they did all they could in order to prevent the dismissals. Referring to the typical open-ended contract (CDI), severance payments are rather small, between 1/10th to 1/6th of the monthly wage per year of experience when the dismissal occurs for personal motives, and the double for economic motives. This severance payment is much lower than in Spain (33 days per year of experience). Yet the full expected firing cost is much bigger, since often labour judges rule that the motive is not valid; in this case, they would ask the firm to pay large severance payment (for unfair dismissal) of at least six months of salary. In some cases, the judge may rule to reintegrate the employee. The firm must then pay the fine and the wage over the whole not worked period. In 2004, 26% of the workers fired for a personal motive went to courts (in general, they dispute the motive of the dismissal). In 64.5% of the cases, the outcome was favourable to the employees (Munoz-Perez and Severin, 2005). Given this overall context, in many instances firms try to avoid the trial and agree to pay a negotiated amount to the employee in exchange for his resignation. This compensation may be quite large, since the employee’s bargaining threat point is given by the discounted future costs of keeping him on the payroll. Given these large implicit firing costs, French open-ended contracts come with a substantial degree of job protection. Over time, it became more and more difficult to fire someone for economic motives. Actually, the number of lay-offs for personal motives increased by 40% between 2001 and 2003 (Lagrenne and Leroux, 2006). Probably firms tend to invoke faked personal motives, while the true motive is economic (Cahuc and Kramarz, 2004). The fixed-term contract is also subject to these constrains during its validity period, but the firm may not renew it at its term without having to justify its decision. It just has to pay a severance indemnity of 10% of the cumulated compensation. Hence, natural contract termination seems to be a way to avoid the high dismissal cost specific to open-ended contracts. However, the recourse to fixed-tem contracts is highly restricted in France. Firms cannot hire temporary workers for permanent tasks; one person cannot be hired for more than 18th months under such a contract; if the worker is kept employed after this period, his contract automatically becomes open-ended. As a consequence, the proportion of workers hired under fixed-term contracts in France has never reached the substantial amount recorded in Spain. The share of genuine CDD contracts in the total stock of employment fluctuated between 4% and 6% between 1990 and 2002, and the total share of temporary contracts (CDD, plus interimary and apprenticeship contracts) never exceeded 12% of total employment (Amira and De Stefano, 2005). 16 See also Blanchard and Tirole (2004), Pigoni and Zuary (2003), Cahuc and Kramarz (2004). 16-17 November 2006 Peer Review Incentives for indefinite employment, Madrid 41 FRANCE Given these low ratios, and worried because of the resilience of unemployment despite the sustained output growth, in 2005 the French government took the rather opposite direction as compared to Spain, and tried to further enhance the flexibility of the labour market at the margin. 2.3. The new initiatives: “long live the CNE, rest in peace the CPE” In August 2005, the government created a new form of contract which could be offered by small size firms (below 20 employees) for new hires, called contrat nouvelle embauche (CNE). The innovation is that during the first two years, the contract can be cancelled without any justification, and the decision of the firm cannot be challenged in courts. For every dismissed worker the employer must pay severance payments of 8% of the gross cumulated compensation, and pay an additional 2% to the state agency that runs the unemployment benefit system. At the end of the second year, if not interrupted, the contracts become automatically of the open-ended type. More than one year later, 10% of the new hires by small firms were signed under the new contract (Junod et al. 2006). In the Spring of 2006, the Parliament passed a law that created a similar contract for job seekers below 25 irrespective of the firms’ size, contrat première embauche (CPE). Student associations argued that such a law is discriminatory, since it aims at providing the youth with “precarious” jobs. Many universities went on strike. After one month of strong social unrest, the law was withdrawn. Probably those who could benefit from the measure were not the university graduates, but the low skilled young persons. Yet this failed attempt showed once again how difficult it can be in France to implement measures with specific target groups. 3. The way ahead: towards the single labour contract While the idea of liberalizing the labour market at the margin as a way of increasing employment received a wide political support in France and other countries where the majority of workers is subject to high protection contracts, many French labour economists express a very sceptical view on the virtues of such a trend. Building on stylized models of the Continental European economy (developed in the Mortensen-Pissarides matching framework), they show that such a measure would lead to excessive polarization between protected and unprotected workers, with adverse effects on morale, productivity, growth and equity.17 These economists argue that the performance of the labour market would be largely improved if the existing two types of contracts (CDI – CDD) is replaced by a single type of contract, designed such as to promote the main goals of labour policy: 18 Forster employment and reduce the unemployment rate; Protect employees against excessive income volatility, in particular by supporting income during short spells of unemployment; Grant firms enough flexibility to adjust to fluctuations in real activity. 17 See Cahuc and Postel Vinay, 2002 ; Cahuc and Carcillo, 2006; L’Haridon and Malherbet, 2006. 18 The main lines of this reform were firstly sketched in a report to the Ministry of Labour by Cahuc and Kramarz (2004). 16-17 November 2006 Peer Review Incentives for indefinite employment, Madrid 42 FRANCE Under such a policy, emphasis is set on income protection and not on job protection. For the new unified contract, direct firing costs would increase, as firms would be asked to pay a tax for each dismissed worker. This tax would increase resources of the unemployment benefit system. Such a tax might help internalizing social costs of unemployment, as required by Blanchard and Tirole (2004). In turn, the employee could no longer challenge in courts the firm’s decision, except for outrageous abuses (discrimination, harassment), as is now the case with the CNE. The reform would thus remove the possibility for judges to second guess the firm’s decision, would eliminate large trial costs and the uncertainty related to a firm’s decision to fire a worker.19 The idea of the single contract has already caught the attention of the political leaders in France and might come into the public debate during the Presidential campaign of 2007. Probably the reform cannot succeed if the majority of insiders get slightly worse-off, even if the global gains are positive (the unemployed and temporary workers would largely benefit, as well as firms). Hence, to make the reform politically acceptable, firms should concede some wage increases to workers under the old open-ended contracts in order to compensate them for the bygone security. The feasibility of the reform should also be weighed in keeping with cultural barriers in France and the ability to reform an extremely imbricate Labour Law. One obstacle seems to be the OIT Convention 158/1982, ratified by France in 1989. This convention, signed in 2006 by 32 countries (most of them from the developing world), requires that the firing motive should be valid. Yet the Convention takes a relatively flexible position, since it only defines (art. 5) motives that are not valid (cannot fire a pregnant women, a worker’s representative, the person who criticize the hierarchy, ban all forms of discrimination,…). Hence, the single contract may well be consistent with a loose interpretation of the Convention. Other alternative would be to withdraw from this agreement, in keeping with the art. 17. As an upshot of all these, the challenge for both France and Spain, and for the other countries featuring a dual labour market, is not how to reduce the frequency of fixed-term contracts while maintaining the excessively high job protection specific to the regular open-ended contract, but how to make the latter much more flexible, and universal. 19 Austrian experience, as presented by independent expert Helmut Mahringer at this Peer Review, is extremely instructive. 16-17 November 2006 Peer Review Incentives for indefinite employment, Madrid 43 FRANCE References Amira, Selma and Gilbert De Stefano, 2005, Contrats à durée déterminée, intérim, apprentissage, contrats aidés, DARES, Premières Syntèses Informations, Avril, 14, 2. Blanchard, Olivier and Augustin Landier, 2002, The Perverse Effects of Partial Labour Market Reform: Fixed-term Contracts in France, Economic Journal, 112, pp. F214-F244. Blanchard, Olivier and Jean Tirole, 2004, Redesigning the Employment Protection System, De Economist, 152, 1, pp. 1-20. Boeri, Tito and Pietro Gariabldi, 2005, Two Tier Reforms of Employment Pprotection: a Honeymoon Effect?, mimeo, Bocconi University, Milan. Cahuc, Pierre and Stéphane Carcillo, 2006, Que peut-on attendre des contrats nouvelle embauche et première embauche ?, Revue Francaise d'Economie, 21, pp. 37-86. Cahuc, Pierre and Francis Kramarz, 2004, De la précarité, à la mobilité: vers une sécurité sociale professionnelle, Rapport au Ministre d’Etat, Ministre de l’Economie, des Finances et de l’Industrie et au Ministre de l’Emploi, du Travail et de la Cohésion Sociale, www.ladocumentationfrancaise.fr/ rapports-publics/ 054000092/index.shtml. Cahuc, Pierre and Fabien Postel-Vinay, 2002, Temporary Jobs, Employment Protection and Labor Market Perfomance, Labor Economics, 9, 1, pp. 63-91. Junod, Bérengère, Christine Lagrenne, Claude Minni, Laure Berne, 2006, Le contrat nouvelles embauches, DARES, Premières Synthèses Informations, Juin, 25, 4. Lagrenne, Christine and Marine Le Roux, Les licenciements en 2003, DARES, Premières Synthèses Informations, Mars, 11, 1. L’Haridon Olivier and Franck Malherbet, 2006, Employment Protection Reform in Search Economies, IZA Discussion Paper 2304. Munoz Perez, Brigitte and Evelyne Severin, 2005, Le droit de travail en perspective contentieuse 1993-2004, Ministère de la Justice, DACS 2005-2, Novembre. Pigoni, Maria-Theresa and Patrick Zouary, 2003, Les nouveaux usages du licenciement pour motif personnel, DARES, Premières Synthèses Informations, Juillet, 28, 2. OECD, 2006, General Policies to Improve Employment Opportunities for All, Chapter 3, OECD Employment Outlook, 2006, OECD, Paris. 16-17 November 2006 Peer Review Incentives for indefinite employment, Madrid 44