Journal of Research in Peace, Gender and Development Vol. 1(3) pp. 078-090 April 2011 Available online@ http://www.interesjournals.org/JRPGD Copyright ©2011 International Research Journals Review Golden Jubilee of Underdevelopment Elections Matter for Development O. B. C Nwankwo (PhD) Department of Political Science, Anambra State University, Igbariam. Email: nwankwo62@yahoo.com Accepted 05 march, 2011 This paper argues the thesis that the establishment of legitimate public authority through the collective will of the people in a competitive and participative environment creates a more favourable and enabling environment for basic governance capabilities that can guarantee development. Observing that the history of elections in Nigeria is a history of primitive accumulation of votes which made irrelevant the accounting function of election, it argues that this failure of vertical accountability accounts for mediocre development of the country. The converse would have propelled leaders to deliver on their promises through adequate processing of the people’s input into the system, in the expectation of the people’s future support. Development, it continues, demands high valorisation of votes and the higher the value attached to votes in any polity, the higher the level of development. The converse is equally true: underdevelopment in the post independent Nigeria is linked to high de-valorisation of votes which continuously gave rise to unresponsive leaders that have no fear of people’s sanction, that are not bordered by people’s negative votes. Elections thus matter for development! It concludes that Nigeria must re-establish, or in fact establish faith in elections and effective practice of democracy, here understood as the permeation of political participation and competition in the political landscape of the polity. This can be achieved through ensuring that the current electoral reforms and its implementation in 2011 pools have the capacity at least to guarantee high content and psychological values of votes. This two has the capacity to compel the promissory value and through enhancing democracy and governance, and finally compel development. INTRODUCTION This year 2010, 17 African countries are celebrating the golden jubilee of their independence. Nigeria is one of them. As the Union Jack rolled down minutes to midnight th of 30 September 1960 and the Green-White-Green rolled up at that instant, and the floodlights at today’s Tafawa Balewa Square came on signalling a new dawn, it was October 1st 1960. Nigeria became independent from Great Britain. There were hilarious expressions on the faces of many Nigerians as the new national anthem was officially played for the first time and the celebration drums rolled. The driving force of these hilarious expressions was the expectations of a better life for all Nigerians. Our fathers and forefathers hoped that the hitherto siphoned resources of the country by the imperial master would now be invested to the advantage of the people. They knew that Nigeria like any other emerging nation has its problems most significant of which was structural. However, in that hilarious moment the problems were bracketed. They believed that with independence all the country’s problems would gradually disappear. Indeed, within and without, Nigeria at independence with her abundant human and material resources, held lots of promises. To this extent, the expectations of our forebears were not unfounded. However, that independence was a mere act of the parliament, a stroke of the pen that transferred political control and attendant resources from the colonial master to the nationalists. Thereafter, the real struggle began. The nationalists set themselves the task of developing the new nation politically, socially and economically to meet the people’s aspirations. Politically, Nigeria went to independence endowed with representative legislature, political parties, elections and indeed all the trappings of western democratic government. It was indeed to many a model of democratic federalism. In reality, however, it was a fragile achievement that sooner than later became Nwakwo 079 challenged by ethnic tensions, lack of general will among the squabbling and opportunistic representatives of the people, incompetence of democratic leadership among others, which permitted the military to take over power. With the intervention of the military, government became a matter of force and the foundation for perpetual mischief was laid. Coups followed each other and finally culminated in the 30 months civil war that ended in 1970. With the return to civil rule in 1979, the second military incursion in 1983 and the present democratic dispensation that began in 1999, Nigeria at fifty has experienced a total of 28 years of military dictatorship and 22 years of civil rule. How effective the military in its long years of administration of the country has been in the task of meeting the national dreams as anticipated at independence, elicits diverse opinions. Effectiveness is here understood in terms of Government meeting its responsibilities with available resources to the governed, in terms of satisfaction of the basic functions of government by the principal actors, in terms of substantive outcomes (Nwankwo, 2003). To be on the safe side, compared to the quantum of resources and opportunities available to the juntas, they impacted very little on key substantive outcomes especially human development indices. A common feature of all military administrations is that the people cease to live by any common established rule on the basis of which the leaders can be held accountable. As is known, military government with their capacity to change the rule of the game without fear of sanctions is not an accountable government. This paper is therefore, not interested in military administration which it considers ab initio an aberration. However, let us not forget that the foundation of unaccountability was already laid by the politicians and that it was this unaccountability that permitted military incursion in the first instance. The civil political class did everything including manipulation of the constitution to truncate accountability in the face of incompetence of democratic leadership. The resources that were expected to serve the people were privatised to serve individuals in a neo-colonialist garment. This situation which began in the first Republic continued in the Second, the so called Third and the present Fourth Republics even with greater sophistication. As is discussed in this paper, the greatest instrument of accountability in a democratic setting is election. In respect thereto, and to all substantive expectations of the people, the nation has over these past fifty years comparatively retrogressed. In the light of today, empirical evidence suggests that despite all criticisms, the state of the late colonial and early post colonial economies of Nigeria were fairly sufficient as basis for sustained growth and development of the country. This is not withstanding the fact that post colonial leaders were recruited from a weak group: “the petty bureaucratic bourgeoisie which were inexperienced”. Let us also recall, in the words of Nohlen and Nuschler (1993), that it was not until independence was around the corner that African States, nay Nigeria got constitutions they could call their own and then started the real act of democratic governance. The mosaic States which their predecessors few years back managed to control through divide and rule tactic, force and claims to racial superiority, “exclusionary hegemony”(Young, 1994, 218), and that was intolerant of opposition, was at independence expected to be democratically managed through a system that they had not the benefit of experiencing its real working. Williams (1999, 3) opined that “African Governments inherited the institutions through which and the boundaries within which they exercised state authority. They took over or re-established the forms of territorial administration, the decentralised despotism through which their predecessors had exercised power”. In simple terms, they not only had too brief an acquaintance with the virtues of democracy but also lacked the experience and strength of character to cope with the post independent challenges. Having no economic base in society, these leaders “participated in politics only for personal gain. Their loyalties were not to their classes, for they had none, but to their stomachs” (Kasozi, 1994, 10). This is the foundation of the primitive accumulation that is the bane of the politics of today. While these leaders may not have initially adopted brut forces to suppress political opponents as their colonial masters, they manipulated elections, dispensed a wide range of rewards and sanctions to be able to retain their position and keep the masses loyal and subordinated. The distribution of positions in government services and public corporations, issuance of licences for market stalls, permits for agricultural export production, rights to establish enterprises, distribution of scholarships, etc were effectively used to grease machinery for retaining power. In effect, corruption and clientage became embedded in the society with devastating effect on all human development indices. The problem of development from inception can, therefore, and in the words of Chinua Achebe, be said to be linked to leadership (Achebe, 1983). We argue here that the failure not only of democracies but also socio-economic development in post colonial Africa is hinged not only on the failure of leadership but also on the failure of the populace to hold them accountable in and out of government. The later is the problem of followership. The two however are interrelated. No doubt, leadership problematic in Africa, nay Nigeria is an ensemble of multiple factors but we hypothesise that at the root of them all is the failure of vertical accountability that would have made it possible for the people to keep their leaders committed to their promises and to change them when they failed to be responsive to their needs: to change what needed to be changed. It was this that permitted individuals opposed to freedom to resort to violent change through coups that 080 J. Res. Peace Gend. Dev. comparatively worsened the situation. Key instrument in keeping the leaders responsive is vertical accountability through elections. There is, therefore, a nexus between the failure of development and failure of vertical accountability, between development and elections since it is through the elections that the leaders are held accountable to the people. Election therefore matters for development. The Nature of Election By election in this context, we refer to democratic elections as instrument for freely determining access of individuals or groups to decision making roles in a given polity. From a modest definition of democracy as contestation that is open to participation (Dahl, 1971), election occupies a central place in any contemporary democratic system, or as Sartori puts it, “a most essential part of the workings of a political system”. The criterion of contestation which Dahl defined as the extent to which his institutional conditions (see below) are openly available, publicly employed, and fully guaranteed to at least some members of the political system, assumes that significant political decision makers are elected via competition among multiple candidates and or parties. It is this multiplicity of contestants that make possible some meaningful degree of choice. The criterion of participation defined as “the proportion of population entitled to participate on a more or less equal plane in controlling and contesting the conduct of government: to participate, so to speak, in the system of public contestation” (Dahl, 1971, 4), assumes that all adult members of the political community have the right to take part in the political process, most importantly, in the process of electing public officials (Bova 1997, 113). To the extent that part of the adult population is excluded from participation or that individuals or parties are prevented from competing fairly, to such extent can democracy be said to be absent or impaired. Dahl came to these two indicators by isolating the core ideas in the principles embodied in his three assumptions. The first, he noted, is that “a key characteristic of democracy is the continuing responsiveness of the Government to the preferences of its citizens, considered as political equals”. The key phrase thereto is responsiveness on the basis of political equality. The necessary condition for such a continuous responsiveness on the basis of political equality is elaborated in his second assumption, namely, that all full citizens must have the uninterrupted opportunities not only to formulate preferences, but also to signify such preferences to others, and to the government, either acting individually or in an association with others. His third assumption catalogues a number of civil and political liberties such as rights of association, freedom of speech and expression, opposition, etc. that must be guaranteed for the realisation of the necessary condition for the continuing responsiveness. Participation and contestation in an environment conditioned by these institutional requirements is the threshold of democracy. Nohlen (1995) explicitly included in his definition the negative concept of electoral defeat (Abwahl), to emphasis the control or accounting function of democratic elections: vertical accountability. Elected public official that fails to perform, i.e., that fails to be “responsive”, will be removed by the people in any free and fair election. Responsiveness is usually measured in terms of issues of substantive importance to the people, including the “manners and morals, the ways of thinking and feeling” that go with the system. Put in Nigerian parlance, responsiveness is measured in terms of “dividends of democracy”. It is important here to note that participation in the process of selecting public officials formalised in the voting process is but one part of the whole gamut of democratic political participation which connotes ongoing involvement (through various ways and means) in the formulation, approval or implementation of public policies. Examples of such ways and means would include involvement in political campaigns, party meetings, membership of community organisations, joining protests, communicating with legislative representatives, etc. The truth, however, is that these other forms of political participation hardly attract up to a quarter of the adult population. Herein lies the significance of electoral participation, particularly as formalised in the voting process: it is the only form of democratic political participation in which over 50% of the adult populace usually take part. Above all, election embodies the two criteria of participation and contestation, so that the democratic process can be considered to be “indeed encapsulated in elections and electing (Sartori, 1987, 86). Whatever else modern democratic governance may be, it is fundamentally elective. While elections can be applicable to a number of dictatorial polities, the defining characteristics of democratic elections are their freeness and fairness. In fact, free and fair election is one of Dahl’s eight institutional conditions for democracy. A political system is then and only then democratic to the extent that political authority is determined through open, free, fair and competitive election (Nwankwo, 2005). Elections in Nigeria: The Competition and Participation Experience with Indeed for most people, democracy is an abstraction which only assumes concrete dimensions in elections. Thus the history of elections in Nigeria is the history of the nation’s democracy. In other words, participation and competition are the core issues in any democracy. The centrality of election in the evolution of any democracy is hinged on the fact that it embodies the two principles. Beginning with the introductio principle of election, the Nwakwo 081 Table: Composition of the Federal House of Representatives 1954 1954 Members of Representative 92 Members represented the North 42 Members represented the West 42 Members represented the East 6 Members represented Southern Cameroons 2 Members represented Lagos (FCT) Total Membership 184 Table 1: Evolution of Senatorial and Federal Constituencies Year 1954 1957 1960 1964 1979 1989 1999 No. of Senatorial No. of Federal Districts Constituencies 184 52 (+4 senators) 312 40 (+4 senators) 312 52 (+4 senators) 312 95 450 91 593 109 360 Source: Nwankwo, 2003 question of participation in terms of franchise and representation (composition of the legislature) had emerged as salient questions. Thus from that beginning till date one of the principal questions that the nations electoral system had and has continued to face is organising representation. It is a question that deals with creating institutional arrangement that will efficiently and effectively aggregate conflicting interests and beliefs present in the society (Nwankwo, 2003). Districting, a geographical form of representation is an important aspect of the electoral system which address this issue. In other words, the primary unit of representation is in Nigeria is territoriality. At the inception, a deliberative and advisory body which was established in 1917 to become the forerunner of the nation’s legislative assembly had 30 members all of whom were appointed by the Governor. It had 6 'natives' who provided for local political feelings and for the indigenous leaders to develop a sense of identification with the regime and perhaps gain experience in policy making (Price, 1977 p. 18); two Emirs from the North, the Alafin of Oyo and one other member each from Calabar Lagos and Benin-Warri area. The rest members were Europeans. As these were nominated by the governor they could not be said to be representatives of the people of Nigeria. The 1922 constitution laid the foundation for formal democratic participation and competition in 1923. This is to the relative extent, as earlier noted that it introduced the principle of election in filling some of the seats in the legislative council (Hitherto all seats in the council were filled through appointment by the Governor) and created the opportunity for the emergence of political parties. With that, Nigeria blazed the trail to become the first country in black Africa to have elected legislature. By enlarging the size of the house from 30 to 46 and the number of Africans from 6 to 10, the 1922 constitution raised the representative value of the legislature. This trend continued with the 1946 constitution which provided for the direct elections of 4 members of the central legislature (two each from Lagos and Calabar) and the indirect election of 24 others by the newly created regional assemblies. The constitution of 1951 increased the number of indirectly elected members of the central legislature to 136 with further easing of participation in the process (cf. Anyanwu 1999, Nwankwo, 2006, for the Statistics). As can be seen from the above, from the introduction of the principle of election in 1922, there was a gradual increase in the level of participation of Nigerians in governance to independence. The composition of the central legislature in 1954 indicated this trend (see box). In fact by the time of the nation’s independence, the size of the House of representative was further enlarged to 312 members elected for a five year term. Noteworthy is the fact that a total of 167 of these representative came from the North. The creation of the second chamber first at the regional levels and by 1958 at the federal level further enhanced the representation ratio. While the lower house represented the people as individuals, the upper house (the senate) represented the same people as groups: the regions. For the senate 12 members were selected by each of the regional legislatures to represent them at the federal level. Both the Upper and the Lower legislative chambers shared the power to make laws for the country – not withstanding the superiority of the lower house in many respects. For purposes of elections, the country is divided into several territorial units or constituencies which are delimited on the basis of population. Since the introduction of the two chamber legislature in the late 1950s, Nigeria has maintained three main categories of constituencies which are distinguishable by their sizes: senatorial, federal, state constituencies. Senatorial constituencies are used for the election of the members of the upper House of the National Assembly: the Senate. Because the seats in the Upper House are filled on the basis of equality of states, each state of the federation is divided into equal number of senatorial districts. Federal constituencies are used to elect members of the lower House. It is distributed to all the states of the federation on the basis of their population. State constituencies are used to elect members of the state Houses of Assembly. Table 1 shows the historical evolution of senatorial and federal constituencies in Nigeria. Under the current constitution, each state, irrespective of size and population is divided into three senatorial districts. This, as earlier noted is an expression of the political equality of states. The FCT is treated as one senatorial district. Accordingly, Nigeria has today a total of 109 senatorial districts. The constitution also fixed the federal constituencies at 360. (Sec. 47 – 49) 082 J. Res. Peace Gend. Dev. Table 2: Distribution of Constituencies according to States under the 1999 constitution Abia No. of Senatorial Constituencies 3 No. of Federal Constituencie s* 8 Adamawa 3 8 Akwa Ibom 3 10 State Anambra 3 11 Bauchi 3 12 Bayelsa 3 5 Benue 3 11 Borno 3 10 Cross River 3 8 Delta 3 10 Ebonyi 3 6 Edo 3 9 Ekiti 3 6 Enugu 3 8 Gombe 3 6 Imo 3 10 Jigawa 3 11 Kaduna 3 16 Kano 3 24 Katsina 3 15 Kebbi 3 8 Kogi 3 9 Kwara 3 6 Lagos 3 24 Nasarawa 3 8 Niger 3 10 Ogun 3 9 Ondo 3 8 Osun 3 9 Oyo 3 14 Plateau 3 8 Rivers 3 13 Sokoto 3 11 Taraba 3 6 Yobe 3 6 Zamfara 3 7 FCT 1 2 Total 109 360 Source: Nwankwo, 2003 The number of federal constituencies per state has implication for the size of the state House of Assembly who are elected on the basis of state constituencies. The constitution provides for the state constituency to be three or four times the number of the federal constituencies in the state. Table 2 is the distribution of the various constituencies in the states. For the elections of the President or Governor the whole federation or the whole state is counted as one constituency respectively. The boundaries of constituencies are not defined in the constitution. However, the constitution defined the parameters for creating and reviewing them. These include equality or near equality of the number of people and that no constituency should lie between two states. It did not indicate optimal number of people per constituency. The importance of the equality criteria cannot be over emphasised since large inequalities in population will result in inequality in representation. Within the context of the prevailing divisions in the country, and the plural decision rule, delimitation exercise is politically sensitive. Accordingly, the electoral commission - taken to be partisan neutral - is mandated with this task of demarcating the boundaries and reviewing this at least every decade. In addition, such demarcations can only come into force if the two Federal Houses approve it. With the structure of the federation in which states and local Government enclose people with same or almost same identific markers, most of the constituencies have a high degree of homogeneity (In creating states and local Governments, inter-ethnic ties, historical and cultural factors, economic feasibility, etc are basic guiding principles). This is especially the case in the rural areas where over 60% of the voters are living. The overall effect of constituency representation and the rule of drawing the boundaries in such a way that no senatorial district or federal constituency fall within more than one state, is that most if not all ethnic groups can be said to be represented in the national assembly and or in their respective State Houses of Assemblies. An important element of the electoral system of Nigeria is its multiparty basis. The feature is consequent upon the centrality of political parties in the government system of Nigeria. Already, as at the time of the nation’s first national conference, the Ibandan conference of 1949, three political parties had emerged as spokespersons for the three administrative units. As spokespersons for the various units, they came to dominate the political activities in the various units – a factor that came to be the dominant feature of elections in Nigeria (Ekinneh, 1997). In the 1954 election, despite the provision of for direct election into the national legislature, the NPC which controlled the North used indirect election to secure 79 of the total of 92 seats allotted the region. Significantly the AG, the Government party of the West was defeated in her territory by the NCNC to produce a total of 61 seats in the parliament. The two major parties formed a parliamentary coalition. This electoral pattern in which the preponderance of the Northern based NPC in Nwakwo 083 Table 3: Major National Elections in Nigeria Year Type of Election 1959 Parliamentary elections No. of Political Winning Party Parties 4 NPC 1964 Parliamentary election 10 NPC 1992 Parliamentary and 5 presidential elections Parliamentary and 6 presidential elections Parliamentary elections 2 1993 Presidential elections 2 1998 Parliamentary elections Parliamentary and Presidential elections Parliamentary and Presidential elections Parliamentary and Presidential elections 5 SDP SDP (election annulled) Inconclusive 3 PDP Over 30 PDP Over 50 PDP 1979 1983 1999 2003 2007 the national legislature was noticeable and the coalition between the NPC and NCNC continued to independence. In fact in the 1959 elections, the NPC secured 134 seats, NCNC 89, AG 73 while the rest had together 16 seats. Table 3 is a summary of the country’s major national elections. Important to mention is that although the South based AG and NCNC would have coalesced and formed the government, this was not to be because of fundamental difference between the two over the status of Lagos. Important also was the fact that a southern coalition would have marginalised the North and laid the foundation for the disintegration of Nigeria which the NCNC firmly stood for. This fear of Northern marginalisation and consequent withdrawal from the federation receded to the background after the census result of 1964 that gave the North over half of the population of Nigeria, the implication of which was the solidification of Northern dominance of the Federal legislature. This had profound effect on the election of 1964 as the two South based parties formed electoral alliance with minor opposition parties from the North under the aegis of UPGA. NPC aligned with the splinter group of AG (NNA) and NCNC under the aegis of NNDP (Ekinneh, 1997, Ezeani, 1987, Ajibola, 1978). Apart from the multiparty based character, the description of the electoral system highlighted universality of franchise, secrecy of voting, the laws on candidacy (party membership, age, education, etc), the decision rules – Majority/plurality, the autonomy of the electoral authority, the constitutional guarantees of democratic freedoms of association and expression, - the real existence of alternative sources of information, the fact that nobody is under any serious threat not to freely express his or her opinion,- among others (see Nwankwo NPN NPN 2006). These have provided the requisite operational condition for the nation’s electoral processes as to define Nigeria’s system despite problems as democratic. That these variables also confer substantial formal empirical legitimacy on the electoral processes of Nigeria is not debatable. However, the real question is the extent to which they are present in a realistic sense as to guarantee the participative and competitive character of the process. The law on candidacy is a good starting point. Various administrations have over the years tinkered with one aspect or the other of the system as to impair the competitive and participative character of the electoral system. The transition of 1999, because of the crisis situation under which it took place produced fewer restrictions on contestation than those of the previous regimes of Babangida and Abacha. Haggard/Kaufmann (1995, 368) found out that generally “transitions occurring under crisis conditions produce fewer restrictions on contestation”. The transition programmes of Babangida and later Abacha introduced institutional and non institutional restrictions on candidacy (like barring certain cadres of politicians with his new breed philosophy) which impaired democratic character and legitimacy of the elections. This legacy was eliminated in the transition of 1999. Indeed by the second election of 2003 and that of 2007 there were relatively no restriction on participation and competition. Constitutionally, however, all elections in Nigeria have operated on general limitations on candidacy. Currently, electoral candidacy is subject to membership of a political party. It requires that all candidates be nominated by political parties. There are no provisions for independent candidacy by people interested in active politics but who are not interested in belonging to any political party, or even those whose principles and interests are not 084 J. Res. Peace Gend. Dev. articulated in any of the existing parties to stand for elections. The recent debate in the National Assembly to limit the freedom of people from freely forming political parties has been rejected by the Assembly. Limiting candidacy to party membership while at the same time limiting the freedom of individuals to freely form political parties as canvassed by some members would have certainly further excluded a significant number of people from participation. This liberalisation of political parties can therefore be seen as part of the process of improving participation. The age factor is another objective variable of exclusion. Legally, a person at eighteen may belong to a political party, but s/he may not contest any election until s/he is thirty years of age. The third of the categories of the excluded are public servants. This is to the extent that they must resign their jobs in order to contest election. The uncertainty of winning an election and the fear of loosing ones means of existence at the same time forces this category of Nigerians out of electoral contests. They may not even belong to a political party. These limitations, limited the inclusiveness of competition in Nigeria. The exclusion on age and education variables are legitimised by the people as an objective way of eliminating unsuitable candidates. It was found out (2001 survey) that while most Nigerians are for restrictions on the basis of educational variable, they do not support restrictions on the basis of age beyond the level defined by franchise. With over 65% of the population of Nigeria under the age limit of thirty and 25% of this between the ages 18 and 29, with a good number of those above thirty not belonging to any of the existing parties, and finally civil servants, teachers, and the like who, for fear of permanently loosing their means of livelihood desist from contesting, a substantial part of the population have been excluded from active participation in politics through legislation. (see Nwankwo, 2003 for the statistics). However good intentioned these regulations might be, they impaired the principles of inclusive contestation. However, such constitutional limitations are legal as they existed and cannot be considered as impediments to participation in the context of this paper. Generally, Nigeria is not a high achiever in electoral participation. While it may be true according to Beyme (1983, 30), that high electoral participation may not in itself be proof of a well functioning democracy, it definitely increases the legitimacy not just of the electoral but also of the entire political system. It stands as the bedrock of accountability in the polity. Despite extensive educational programmes of the national electoral authorities before each election, despite extensive campaigns mounted by each party, despite the participation of print and electronic media in the process of awakening people’s interest in elections, participation in the registration and voting exercise have varied from one election to another. In 1979 the voter turnout was as low as 25.8% for the national Assembly elections and 35.2% for the presidential elections. In subsequent elections this apathy of voters in Nigeria has not improved significantly. It reached its lowest ebb during the transition under the Abacha regime when about 5% of those registered exercised their voting right in the National Assembly elections (Anyanwu, 1999). The operative phrase above is “those registered”! Fact is that a good number of Nigerians do not take part in the revision of voters register. Indeed, the universality of franchise notwithstanding, the operative franchise of Nigeria is far below the nominal franchise. The nominal franchise is defined as the percentage of the voting population measured against the total population. Operative franchise refers to the percentage of those who actually registered. The percentage of those who registered and voted is defined as effective franchise Available statistics for 1999 showed that effective franchise was low. For the National Assembly Elections, of the 58 Million registered voters only 44% took part in the electoral process. The number was relatively higher in the election of the president confirming the greater importance the people attach to the election. The turnout reached 52%. Compared on state by state basis, electoral turnout in that election reached as low as 20% in Lagos for the National Assembly election and 26% for the presidential elections in FCT and Kano. (INEC Report, 1999) In 2003 and 2007 elections, it declined all the more. The 2007 elections were much more problematic because of the fact that people in most of the constituencies never had the effective opportunity to express their preference. Effective opportunity is used here to refer to absence of widespread arbitrary impediments like wilful intimidation of voters, absence/hoarding of ballot papers, fraud, and similar others that would gravely impair the freeness and fairness of the elections. What emerged from the various electoral tribunals including the latest in Delta State are valid indications of subversions by person/persons in consort with one or the other of the political parties. Indeed, it was the fallouts of the 2007 elections that laid the foundation for the current electoral reforms. We are all living witnesses of the repeat of the same story during the last Governorship election in Anambra State on th February 6 2010 where even the willing voters could not vote. The implication of the general low turnout is that many citizens are in reality disenfranchised. The 2007 elections have gone down in history as Nigeria’s worst competing with the 1964 elections. The greatest significance of the 1964 election in the history of elections in Nigeria was its notoriety for malpractice. Because the stakes were very high for the two major contesting groups, each indulged in questionable electoral practices that shook the nation to its foundation. This theme is better handled separately. Suffice it to note that this charade of an election in addition to other aggravating factors sowed the seed of drift into political Nwakwo 085 chaos that ended the first Republic. Like in the Plato’s allegory of the cave, Nigeria, used to the darkness of unfree and unfair elections was dazed by the candle light of the 1993 election that has been adjudged the most free and fair comparatively. She could not stand the light and so ran back into the cave by annulling that election. Experience wise, Nigeria appears not to have fully learnt the consequences of not allowing free and fair exercise of the people’s power in election, which is instability. In general, absence of free, fair and credible elections for various reasons articulated above, have been the portion of Nigeria since independence. This absence, according to our hypothesis has an intrinsic linkage with the nation’s underdevelopment. Between Development and Underdevelopment Development is here defined as a pattern of social and structured economic transformations which optimises the economic and societal benefits available to the people within a given political community, in this case Nigeria (cf. Goodland/Ledoc, 1987). It reflects significant changes in the society and the economy in such a way as to optimise the level of the benefits to the people, benefits which are reasonably and equitably distributed. Its ultimate objective is the creation of prosperity and a high standard of living in a community. It is a factor of two variables: economic welfare and qualitative social changes which enables the community to undertake sustained growth. Both are the two sides of development problematic. It is important to emphasise that economic welfare is not the same as economic growth. The primary objective of development is the welfare of the people, “the improvement of life for the entire population of a nation” while economic growth is “its principal performance test”. (Goodland/Ledoc, 1987). Although both aspects constitute integral part of development, empirical data indicate no rigid link between them. The operative word here is “rigid link” since both are relevant to each other. Economic performance in terms of growth can diverge widely from human development while relative changes in human development observed in Nigeria since the 1960s did not lead automatically to better economic performance. It is however, not part of this paper to investigate the empirical and logical relationship between them. It suffices for our purpose, to note that both are central to development and vital for its sustainability. Measured in terms of the quality of life and the degree of freedom available to the individual and compared to the quantum of resources available to the country, Nigeria has underdeveloped these fifty years. Underdevelopment is not the opposite of development which is un-development or the absence of development. It suggests rather ongoing and indeed serious exploitation and utilisation of the human and material resources of a given people to the disadvantage of that same people. It is negative development in which vital resources of Nigeria are being utilised to the disadvantage of Nigerians. Underdevelopment is, therefore, a worse situation that non-development. Poor economic performance and poverty in the midst of rich natural and human resources typify Nigeria these past fifty years. After an initial post-colonial growth, the net development indices of the country began declining. This fact is discernible from the Annual Abstract of Statistics of the Federal Office of Statistics. While it may be true that the economy of Nigeria remained vulnerable to changing international markets, and that rising debts limited the scope of action of Governments, corrupt appropriation of limited resources limited equitable distribution and redistribution Accordingly, the development of social resources like education, health services, communication, etc. began to suffer set back. This was in the face of astronomical rises in the population and rural urban migration. The overall effect of all these was that resources could not go round, thus intensifying inequalities not just among individuals but also among different ethnic, regional, and parochial groups. The majority of the people began to depend “on paltry percolation downward of benefits through layered patronage relations” (Williams 2000, 4). New social infrastructure could not be procured, available ones came to be overused, quality of social deliveries – health, education, communication, etc. declined, and like any circular problem, the quantity and quality of input into the productive sector of the economy declined. It is known that socio-economic development changes fundamentally the way individuals and groups relate to the political process. An advanced level of economic development tends to reduce socio-economic inequality and mitigate feelings of relative deprivation and injustices among lower classes. This in turn reduces the likelihood of extremist politics and violent conflicts. That violent conflicts characterise Nigeria’s contemporary polity is a pointer to the quality of life of the ordinary Nigerian as most violent conflicts are contingent on wider social and economic structures arising usually from access and distribution questions. Violent conflicts including armed robbery, kidnapping, and the likes in turn end up critically restricting the degree of freedom available to the individual. Compared with other Third World countries like Brazil that began on almost same footing as Nigeria, Nigeria occupies today the lower rung in the development ladder. While her compatriots in various parts of the world have been able to achieve a measure of development over the last five decades – self-sufficiency in food production, rapid economic growth, improved living standards for the greater majority of their populations, etc. Nigeria has performed abysmally in all these respects. Instead of continued upward trend that was seen during the immediate post-independence, the situation deteriorated and has continued to deteriorate. These facts can be taken from the various reports and 086 J. Res. Peace Gend. Dev. development indicators of the various organs of the United Nations. Much has been written on the causes. Scholars have traced the poor socio-economic performance in Africa to corruption, excessive population growth, ethnic conflicts and consequent political violence, military intervention in politics and governance, incompetent leadership, inappropriate institutional arrangements, competitive disadvantage in the global economy, etc. Discussing generally on Africa, Mbaku (Online, 2000) emphasised poorly designed, weak, and inappropriate institutional arrangements as the critical determinant of poverty and underdevelopment in Africa. He observed that the laws and institutions “promoted opportunism (e.g. corruption and rent seeking), restricted economic freedoms and, subsequently, the ability of individuals to engage freely in exchange impede entrepreneurial activities and consequently wealth creation, and generally endanger sustainable development. According to him, the institutional arrangements that the African countries adopted at independence enhanced the ability of those who had captured and evacuated structures of colonial hegemony to misuse the positions entrusted to them. In the process, they stunted the emergence of an indigenous entrepreneurial class and, subsequently, the creation of wealth that the post-independent society needed to deal with massive and pervasive poverty (Mbaku, Online, 2000). From the above scenario, it appears that the picture of underdevelopment may not be properly understood outside its colonial legacy. This has been the dominant framework of interpretations by scholars of Nigeria and Africa over the past fifty years. This legacy is that of suppliers of raw materials to the metropolises. It is in this dependent role that African economies till date are embedded in the international market. But even with this legacy, available estimates show an intensive growth and development process in Nigeria in the dying days of colonialism. This we earlier noted even spilt over into the early post colonial era. The investigation of dynamic properties of colonial economic development does not fall within the ambient of this work. It suffices to agree with the scholars that the colonial economic legacy was the takeoff point of the independent Nigeria, and that despite all criticisms, the state of the late colonial and early post colonial economies in Nigeria, nay Africa, in the light of today, was fairly sufficient as basis for sustained growth and development. It is therefore, only fair to conclude that the socio-economic development problematic in Africa is a product of double history: the colonial and post colonial. Colonialism laid the foundation of the contradictions in the socio-economic relations of the people, while post colonial decades not so much of bad decisions as bad implementations by squabbling, incompetent and opportunistic leaderships naively styled along the line used by their colonial predecessors, corruption and misplaced priorities alarmingly exacerbated the problem. The past fifty years is wasted opportunity. Indeed instead of continuously pointing accusing fingers at colonialism and discussing how Europe underdeveloped Africa, discussing how Britain underdeveloped Nigeria, our focus both in the classroom and in the praxis should henceforth be on how Nigerians underdeveloped and in fact continues to underdevelop Nigeria. Elections and Development: The Nexus Establishing a nexus between elections and development begins with distinguishing the two. The one, elections is political, and procedural (a process) in nature. It consists of political rules and procedures whose validity depends on the willingness of the political community to observe them. The other as understood here is socio-economic, and an outcome (of a process) embodying issues of substantive importance to the people (in form of socioeconomic transformation. The nexus between the two is that the one, the substantive outcome demands the other, the process. There cannot be the outcome without the process. There cannot be the bread without the baking and the bakery. It has been well documented that the real obstacle to development in Nigeria (Africa) is the absence of institutional arrangements that effectively constrain the state and its agents from engaging in opportunism, and positively engage in activities that enhance the creation of wealth, improve the ability of all individuals within the country to participate fully and effectively in national development and thus quickening growth in socio-economic development variables. We had in an earlier paper (Nwankwo, 2009) contended in the same regard that good governance matters for development in which our key defining variable was system-wide accountability mechanism. Restated otherwise here, weak, inappropriate system-wide accountability mechanism engendered through a poorly executed electoral process is a critical determinant of underdevelopment in Africa. Election as earlier noted has a supreme accountability function and it is this function that links elections to development. The state’s capacity to reform, to implement reforms, and effect development depends on the degree this accountability mechanism is in place. According to Nwankwo (2009) accountability connotes expectation or assumption of account giving: answerability. It constrains the extent to which officials especially elected ones, can wilfully deviate from their responsibility. The emphasis on elected officials is based on the fact that they are supremely and doubly answerable. On the one hand they are horizontally accountable to the relative extent that they should take actions ranging from routine oversight to criminal Nwakwo 087 sanctions over and against those under them for purposes of rendering services to the people. Citation needed here Whether it is invasion of domicile, police brutality or such other forms of human rights abuses that are prevalent in Nigeria, or the non execution according to specification of service delivery and other socioeconomic development programmes, etc. they bespeak of failure of horizontal accountability. In normal circumstances, such failures of horizontal accountability constitute yardstick in vertical accountability, namely, when the elected officials face the people in periodic elections. As noted earlier, that is why the negative concept of electoral defeat was included in the definition of election, namely to emphasise the control or accounting function of democratic elections. Elected public officials that fail to perform, that fail to be responsive, that fail to be horizontally accountable will be removed by the people in any free and fair election. What have happened over the past fifty years in Nigeria as far as elections are concerned does not require much elaboration. Simply put we have had situations where elections never took place or never really took place! “Never really took place” implies situations where elections were organised but hardly deserved the name of democratic election by lacking in credibility and not being free and fair because of a syndrome of various factors. Common to all such situations is that failure of horizontal accountability were deliberately made irrelevant for vertical accountability which would have ensured that those that failed to perform would have been removed from office by the people. The converse would have propelled leaders to deliver on their promises through adequate processing of the people’s input into the system, in the expectation of the people’s future support. A major condition that influences positively or negatively the attitude of the people is the degree of effectiveness of a regime defined in terms of the extent to which the regime is able to meet the expectations of the people within its immediate domain. Meeting the expectations of the people under a democratic system is a product of strategic decision making by political actors within the enabling and restricting institutional environment. This can be guaranteed in any highly participative and competitive environment. In such a situation leaders must have proved themselves to be reelected. Easton’s systems theory is a veritable instrument in this analysis. Because the elected leaders failed to transform inputs in terms of development demands by the people, and knowing fully well that they do not deserve a further support of the people, but determined to hold on to power against the people’s wish, elected leaders throughout the post independent electoral history of Nigeria, disregarded democratic electoral rules and thus truncated vertical accountability: the key function of elections. Power has never really belonged to the people. Post independence elections in Nigeria have been characterised by what Ibeanu (2003) referred to as “primitive accumulation of votes”. By this he meant winning of votes by all means including the use of violence and general disregard of the rule of law. To put it in common man’s language, it is stealing the people’s mandate. The charades of elections in 2007 are the most recent examples when results of elections were written and declared even before the polls were over. If one can win election without people’s vote, then vote is said not to have value. If votes do not have value, people’s confidence in election diminishes. Ibeanu (2007) distinguished three dimensional values of vote: promissory, content and psychological values. Promissory value of votes is used to refer to the promises made by those who ask for the people’s vote to deliver the value of the votes on demand in terms of the programmes and policies on the basis of which they would be given the votes. The central question that this raises is whether the promises made at elections were kept by the elected over the past fifty years. Content value has to do with equality of votes. Do the votes of some count or weigh more than those of the others? Are the people’s preferences through votes count at all or are they thrown away when not in compliance with the preferences of the high and the mighty? Psychological value refers to the value attached to the votes in the minds of the voters: the expectation by the voters that their votes will make a difference. All elections over the past fifty years have to various aggravating degrees recorded negative answers on the three dimensions. The people of Nigeria invested their votes on the promises of successive elected officials to deliver “dividends”. They have instead received on demand a devaluation of their investment – far much less, when at all, than they were promised. Ordinarily, they would have changed their investment portfolio by voting for another. However, they have consistently been unable to do just that, to effect the necessary change. This has been so because content wise the votes of certain persons – presidents, leaders of hegemonic ruling parties, security agents, etc. counted more in delivering electoral outcomes than the people’s votes. Consequently, the people lost confidence in votes and the psychological satisfaction that their votes would matter declined. Voter-turnout declined systematically. In other words, the high de-valorisation of votes negatively impacted the vigour of democracy with consequent implications for development. The thesis here is that the higher the value attached to votes in any polity, the higher the level of development. The converse is equally true: underdevelopment in the post independent Nigeria is linked to high de-valorisation of votes which continuously gave rise to unresponsive leaders that have no fear of people’s sanction, that are not bordered by people’s negative votes. They preferred primitive 088 J. Res. Peace Gend. Dev. accumulation to development since they can and did use their accumulation to set aside possible sanctions by the people at the polls. Primitive accumulation accounts for people’s impoverishment these past fifty years. The nation’s golden jubilee is a celebration of this impoverishment. True the nation has survived as one despite all odds these past fifty years and this is worth celebrating, but this survival has been at less than tolerable level. It is precisely at the level of tolerable existence of the people as an entity that the development problematic is situated. The later is not worth celebrating. Yet the celebration of this unique anniversary offers us an opportunity for reflection, rethinking and re-planning. Critical to it all is making elections to matter. Development demands high valorisation of votes. Nigeria must re-establish, or in fact establish faith in elections. This can be achieved through ensuring that the current electoral reforms have the capacity at least to guarantee content and psychological values of votes. This two has the capacity to compel the promissory value and through enhancing democracy and governance, compel development. What the established nexus implicates is that the establishment of legitimate public authority through the collective will of the people in a competitive and participative environment creates a more favourable and enabling environment for basic governance capabilities that can guarantee development. According to Nwankwo (2009), not only is the exercise of democratic political and civil rights intrinsically valuable in expanding the range of possibilities and choices open to citizens, it is also instrumentally valuable for identifying and operationalising citizen needs and building policies and institutions that will effectively address them. They are indispensable for implementing efficient and sustainable public policies. Simply put, effective practice of democracy, here understood as the permeation of political participation and competition in the political landscape of the polity, is intrinsically linked to socioeconomic development. This linkage is recursive to the relative extent that every achievement developmentally impacts the more on democracy for a further impact on development. Reflecting on this recursive effect, scholars have over the years used socio-economic development variables to develop empirical theories or general frameworks of democratic development and stability. Such theories have over the decades provided social scientists from Aristotle through Montesquieu, Max Weber, Lipset to the present day with general explanations for the failure or success of democratic governance. In a field breaking research, Lipset (1959) investigated the conditions associated with the existence and stability of democratic societies from sociological and behavioural standpoint. He presented a number of hypotheses which he tested with cross national data from 48 countries explicating the social conditions which serve to support a democratic political system. His core conclusion is that “the more well to do a nation, the greater the chance that it will sustain democracy”. Since Lipset this field of research has grown tremendously. Deutsch (1961 ) found a strong relationship between political participation such as voter turnout and aggregate measures of socio-economic development. Curtright (1963) posited a linear relationship between economic and democratic developments, indicating that as countries become more advanced economically they tend to become more advanced politically. Neubauer (1967) found certain basic socio-economic development as necessary to elevate countries to a level at which they can begin to support complex nation-wide patterns of political interaction, one of which may be democracy. Dahl (1971) opined that literacy, education and communication which can be linked to socio-economic development, increase the effective demand for democracy. Halliwell (1994) using data pooled from 125 countries over a period from 1960 – 1985 evaluated the relations between democracy and economic growth and came to the conclusion that specific economic variables have overall positive effect on democracy – a strong tendency for democracy to be chosen and maintained as a system of governance – and a differentiated effects of democratic variables on economic variables. His core measure of democracy in the analysis is political rights and liberties. The wealth of literature in this area is immense. Fundamental to all of them is this attempt to explain how democratic states evolve overtime, to generalise about micro-social prerequisites for political democracy. Their conclusions in the case of most third world countries, nay Nigeria would all point to one direction: “as poor nations with massive socioeconomic development needs and high popular expectations; as poorly integrated nations, with deep ethnic and/or class divisions; and as politically underdeveloped nations, with fragile party system, weak administrative bureaucracies and little experience with the give-and-take of large scale representative institutions, third world nations, at their present levels of development, have little realistic hope of sustaining democratic institutions” (Diamond, 1988,1). Drawing glib analogies from such general frameworks and supported with interpretations of some empirical data, it is usually argued that most African states have not reached the threshold of democracy and “to have expected democracy to flourish would have been historical blindness” (Chabal, 1986.5). Specifically, Huntington (1994, 214) argued that by reason of their poverty or the violence of their politics [third world states were] unlikely to move in a democratic direction”. Chabal in his own argument appears to have re-echoed Lipset (1959) who had earlier posited that given the existence of povertystricken masses, low level of education, an elongated pyramid of class structure, the prognosis for the perpetuation of political democracy in Africa was bleak. In Nwakwo 089 fact Huntington (1994, 218) was convinced that “with few exceptions, the limits of democratic development in the world may have been reached”. Nigeria certainly for Huntington was not part of the few exceptions. However, while she might like to hide under these theories to defend or explain her democratic failures these past fifty years, we note the fact that this relationship, which these studies focus have been so much drummed that they are no longer especially revealing or interesting. In any case these studies do not significantly explain Nigeria’s failures. We need therefore not continue to replicate such studies. Thus we focused here not so much on the extent to which liberal democracy in Nigeria has been or not been successful, nor on the extent to which the socio-economic explanations advanced for its recurrent failures are valid. We focused rather on the extent to which the variables of development that explain the nation’s democratic failures were in fact avoidable. This focus is based on the general assumption that the real world is not a deterministic one. As such democracy can emerge and persist under conditions considered by the scholars as normally adverse to it. As Lipset (1959,103) rightly observed, “political democracy exists and has existed (and can still exist) in variety of circumstances, even though it is most commonly sustained by a limited cluster of conditions”. In fact that Nigeria and many other African states have again and again taken on the challenge of democratising their political systems, as evidenced from the recent seemingly sincere electoral reforms in Nigeria, (even in the face of permanent cleavages and underdevelopment) sufficiently rejects the deterministic verdict. It is a sufficient reason and signal for the need to develop paradigms of democratisation under conditions which are unsimilar to the one underlying the old: a paradigm of democratic development under different conditions. CONCLUSION To conclude, we begin by summarising. Election and development though unrelated in various aspects, above all in terms of process and substance are connected. Development focuses on issues of substantive importance to the people. While such issues of substantive importance that is the realm of development may appear to lie beyond electoral contestation and participation, the relation between the two divide is provided by the fact that under democratic rules, the electorates’ future options are not foreclosed (Whitehead, 1992). Whoever fails to meet the expectations of the people loses claim to rule and will certainly be removed by the people in any democratic elections. Over the past fifty years in Nigeria, however, the electorates’ future options have continuously been foreclosed by inept, irresponsive and irresponsible leaderships. They hold unto power despite their substantive rejection by the people. This phenomenon has had negative implications for development. Measured on key development indicators, instead of development, Nigeria has underdeveloped these fifty years. Till date the definition of poverty by UNDP as deprivation and denial of choices and opportunities most basic to human development as well as lack of the ability to make choices and use available opportunities purposely applies to Nigeria. Measured on the basis of key indicators like hunger, malnutrition, illiteracy, disease, life of misery and squalor, low life expectance, socio-political instability, unemployment, infrastructural decay, Nigeria has remained caught up in detrimental cycle of underdevelopment over the past fifty years. The mediocre performance on these indicators is at the background of the violent conflicts that are afflicting the country. Despite other possible intervening variables that may have accounted for the nations mediocre performance, the situation today would have been far much different if we had responsive leaders who were truly responsible to the electorate through free fair and credible elections. Development demands high valorisation of votes and it is in this sense that election matters for development. A “high political competition can well encourage claims to deep responsibility. It may also give supporters some, if rarely much [power] to keep their leaders to their word (promissory value) by threats of defection. The stratagems of power can thus become the conventions of freedom. A culture of political accountability can emerge. Its calculated moralities can create a community with a competitive interest in its shared history (Lonsdale, 1981138). Dahl (1971) puts it more concretely: if oppositions are granted the right to form political parties, if parties are entitled to participate in elections, if the elections are fair and free, and if the highest office in the Government of the State are held by those who win elections, then competition among political elite makes it likely that the policies of the Government will respond in time to the preferences of a majority of voters. Against the backdrop of the various reforms, even when not deep enough, 2011 may be the decisive beginning of Nigeria’s journey to the promised land of development. REFERENCES Achebe C (1983). The Trouble with Nigeria. Enugu: Fourth Dimension Ajibola WA (1978). Foreign Policy and Public Opinion. Ibadan: Ibadan Uni. Press Anyanwu CN (1999). The Law Maker, federal Republic of Nigeria (1999 – 2003). Abuja: Statecraft Inter Beyme K (1983). “Governments, Parliaments and the Structure of Power in Political Parties”. In Daadler. Mair HP (eds.). Western European Party System Continuity and Change. London:Sage. Bova R (1997) “Democracy and Liberty - The Cultural Connection”. In: J of Democracies 8(1): 112-126 Chabal P. (1986) Political Domination in Africa: Reflections on the 090 J. Res. Peace Gend. Dev. limits of Power, Cambridge: CUP Crowder M. (1978) The Story of Nigeria. London: Faber and Faber Cutright P (1963). “National Political Development. Measurement and Analysis”. In Ame. Sociol. Rev. 28: 253-264 Dahl RA (1971). Polyarchy: Participation and Opposition. New Haven: Yale Uni. Press Diamond L (1988). “Introduction: Roots of Failure, Seeds of Hope” In: Diamond/Linz /Lipset: Democracy in developing countries. Afr. Boulder Colorado, Lynne Rienner Publishers, 2:1 – 32 Ekineh A (1989). Nigeria: Foundations of Disintegration. London: New Millennium Ezeani GE (1987). Massism: Redeeming Nigeria Through Massist Ideology. Yola: Juddy Best Publishers Federal Office of Statistics of Nigeria: Annual Abstracts of Statistics Fed. Rep. of Niger: The 1999 Constitution Goodland R, Ledoc G (1987). “Neo-classical Economics and Principles of Sustainable Development” Ecological Modelling 38. Haggard S, Kaufmann RR (1995). The Political Economy of Democratic Transitions. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press Helliwell JF (1994). “Empirical Linkages between Democracy and Economic Growth”. In: British J of Political Science, 24: 225-248. Huntington S (1991). The Third wave: Democratisation in the Late Twentieth Century. Norman: University of Oklahoma Press Ibeanu O (2003). “Stimulating Landslides: Implications of Primitive Accumulation of Votes for a nascent Democracy”, IDASA Occasional Paper No. 2 Abuja: Institute for democracy in Africa Ibeanu O (2007) “Introduction: Elections and the Paroxysmal Future of Democracy in Nigeria” In: Attahiru Jega and Okechukwu Ibeanu (eds.) Elections and the Future of Democracy in Nigeria. NPSA Publications 1 – 22. Independent National Electoral Commission (INEC) (1998) National Report on the December 5th, 1998 Local Government Elections. Abuja: INEC Independent National Electoral Commission (INEC) (1999), National Report on the February 20th, 1999 National Assembly Elections. Abuja: INEC Independent National Electoral Commission (INEC) (1999), National Report on the February 27, 1999 Presidential Election. Abuja: INEC Joseph R (1991). “Africa: The Rebirth of Political Freedom”. In: Jl of Democracy, 2(4): 11-24 Kasozi AB (1994). The Social Origins of Violence in Uganda. Montreal: McGill-Queen’s University Press Lipset SM (1959). “Some Social Requisites of Democracy: Economic Development and Political Legitimacy”. In: American Political Science Review, 53: 69 -105. Lonsdale J (1981). “States and Social Processes in Africa – A Historiographical Survey”. In: African Studies Review, 24: 139-225. Mbaku JM (Online 2000) “Governance, Wealth Creation, and Development in Africa: The Challenges and the Prospects” http://web.africa.ufl.edu/asq/v4/v4i2a3.htm Neubauer DE (1967). “Some Conditions of Democracy”. In: American Political Science Review, 61: 1002-1009. Nohlen D (1995). “Electoral Systems and Electoral Reform: A Comprehensive Introduction” (=Arbeitspapier Nr. 2, IPW der Uni. Heidelberg)Nohlen D,Nuscheler F (eds.) (1993). Handbuch der Dritten Welt, Bd.4: Westafrika und Zentralafrika, Bonn: Dietz. Nwankwo BO (2003). Institutional Design and Functionality of African Democracies. A comparative Analysis of Nigeria and Uganda, Berlin: Tenea Nwankwo OB (2005). “Political Parties and the Challenges of Democratic Fedralism in Nigeria” in American Jl of Interl Politics and Development, 1(1): 205 – 228. Nwankwo OB (2006). The Making of a Nation: Landmarks in Nigeria’s Constitutional Development. London: Veritas Lumen Price JH (1977). Political Institutions of West Africa, London: Hutchinson. Sartori G (1987). The Theory of Democracy Revisited (Vols2), Chatham, NJ: Chatham House. Whitehead L (1992). “Alternatives to liberal Democracy: A Latin American Perspective.”In: Held, David (ed.): Prospects for Democracy, Cambridge: Polity Press Williams G. (1999). Reforming Africa: Continuities and Changes, in: Africa South of the Sahara (2000 edition), London: Europe Pub. Ltd. Williams G (2000). Reforming Africa: Continuities and Changes, in: Africa South of the Sahara (2001 edition), London: Europe Pub. Ltd. Young C (1994). “The African Colonial State”. In: Comparative Perspective. New Haven: Yale Uni. Press