A research and education initiative at the MIT Sloan School of Management Does Providing Competitive Information to Your Own Customers Increase Sales? Paper 272 April 2010 Guilherme Liberali Glen L. Urban John Hauser For more information, please visit our website at http://digital.mit.edu or contact the Center directly at digital@mit.edu or 617-253-7054 Does Providing Competitive Information to Your Own Customers Increase Sales? by Guilherme Liberali Glen L. Urban and John R. Hauser April 15, 2010 Guilherme (Gui) Liberali is a Visiting Scholar at MIT Sloan School of Management, and Assistant Professor of Marketing, Erasmus School of Economics, Erasmus University Rotterdam, 3000 DR Rotterdam, The Netherlands, (1.781) 632-7674, fax (+31)10-408-9169, liberali@mit.edu. Glen L. Urban is the David Austin Professor of Marketing, MIT Sloan School of Management, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, E40-159, 1 Amherst Street, Cambridge, MA 02142, (617) 253-6615, glurban@mit.edu. John R. Hauser is the Kirin Professor of Marketing, MIT Sloan School of Management, Massachusetts Institute of Technology, E40-179, 1 Amherst Street, Cambridge, MA 02142, (617) 2532929, hauser@mit.edu. This research was supported by the MIT Sloan School of Management, the Center for Digital Business at MIT (ebusiness.mit.edu), and General Motors, Inc. We gratefully acknowledge the contributions of our industrial collaborators, research assistants, and faculty colleagues: Eric Bradlow (Wharton), Michael Braun (MIT), Luis Felipe Camargo (UNISINOS), Daria Dryabura (MIT), Patricia Hawkins (GM), Daniel Roesch (GM), Dmitriy A Rogozhnikov (IBM), Catherine Tucker (MIT), JuanJuan Zhang (MIT). Does Providing Competitive Information to Your Own Customers Increase Sales? Abstract We examine data from a field experiment and a quasi-experiment in which a major US automaker provided competitive information to its own customers. The automaker believed that it was offering excellent vehicles but that consumers would not consider its vehicles because of past experiences. Competitive information took many forms. An Auto Show in Motion made it easy for consumers to test drive competitive vehicles from Chrysler, Ford, General Motors, Honda, Mercedes, Toyota and other manufacturers. eBrochures provided brochures on over 100 competitive vehicles. Auto Choice Advisor provided unbiased purchase recommendations. And a community forum encouraged consumers to discuss buying and owning experiences. In year 1 the automaker provided four treatments to consumers in a 2 x 2 x 2 x 2 field experiment. In year 2, to simulate a national launch, the automaker used an opt-in quasi-experiment with a control cell, a forced-exposure cell, and a pure opt-in cell. In both years data were collected monthly for six months. We model consumer transitions to consideration and purchase using a (hidden) continuous-time Markov process which accounts for potential misclassifications of consumers’ behavioral states. The analyses suggest that both competitive test drives and competitive brochures are effective strategies for increasing consideration and purchase. The treatments are mediated through trust. Neither the online advisor nor the community forum were effective in generating trust, consideration, or sales. Keywords: Automobile Applications, Competitive Information, Continuous-time Markov Processes, Communications, Electronic Marketing, Hidden States, Information Search, Misclassification, Quasi-experiments, Trust 1 Competitive Information to Your Own Customers INTRODUCTION AND MOTIVATION Information is everywhere on the Internet. If a firm does not provide information to its customers, someone else will. This is particularly true in the automotive market. Websites such as Autotrader.com, Cars.com, ConsumerReports.org, Edmunds.com, Kelly Blue Book (kbb.com), and TheAutoChannel.com compete to provide specifications, reviews, prices, and availabilities for most makes and models. Automakers often do not control this information. On the other hand, one of the most comprehensive sources of consumer information, test drives, are offered only by manufacturer-affiliated dealers. Suppose an automaker believes that its vehicles are more reliable and satisfy consumer needs significantly better than key competitors and has evidence that consumers do not share this belief. Suppose that by drawing on experiences with this automaker in the last 10-20 years consumers reject the automaker’s vehicles before searching for information on potential purchases. If consumers never search for information and never test drive an automaker’s vehicles, then those consumers will never buy the automaker’s vehicles. Its sales will suffer. Unfortunately, this scenario described key US automakers in the first decade of the 21st century and was a contributing factor in their bankruptcies. For example, despite the facts that Buick was tied with Lexus for the top spot in J. D. Power’s 2007 vehicle dependability ranking, was the top US brand in 2008 Consumer Reports, and was the number one brand in China, roughly half of all US consumers (and almost 2/3rds in California) would not even consider a Buick. In this paper we analyze an experiment and a quasi-experiment by a US automaker (USAM) to provide competitive information to consumers. USAM provided consumers with the ability to test drive 90 competitive vehicles, get unbiased competitive eBrochures, have access to an unbiased web-based advisor that often recommended competitive vehicles, and join an online 2 Competitive Information to Your Own Customers community forum that discussed both USAM vehicles and competitive vehicles. USAM wanted to test whether such competitive information would increase consideration and purchase of USAM’s vehicles. In the first year USAM randomly assigned treatments in a 2 x 2 x 2 x 2 field experiment. The year-1 results identify which strategies have the most potential. In the second year, USAM used a business-driven quasi-experiment to determine whether or not the marketing actions could be implemented nationwide. To mimic a national launch USAM encouraged consumers to opt-in to treatments. To address opt-in self-selection, USAM used quasi-controls: a control group in which consumers were not given the opportunities for the test drives, brochures, advisors, or communities, and a forced-exposure group in which consumers were given strong incentives to visit the website from which they could opt-in to such competitive information. USAM realized that the impact of competitive information might be indirect. Competitive information might encourage consumers to consider USAM but not affect purchase conditioned on consideration. (This would still increase net purchases because the pool of consumers who consider USAM is now larger.) Theoretically, competitive information should enhance consideration because, according to the evaluation-cost theory of consideration, consumers are more likely to consider a product if a firm lowers the cost of evaluating that product relative to the brands already in the consideration set (Hauser and Wernerfelt 1990). Alternatively, competitive information might increase consideration and purchase by increasing trust in USAM even if there is no direct effect on consideration and purchase. Trust is a common mediating variable (Bart, et al. 2005; Urban 2004). Modeling these indirect effects requires non-conventional analyses. First, to model indirect effects through consideration the model must account for consideration as a latent construct; 3 Competitive Information to Your Own Customers empirical measures might have misclassified “consideration” as “not considered,” or vice versa. Second, because automotive purchases occur over many months, USAM used a panel in which subjects report consideration and purchase monthly for six months both year 1 and in year 2. Third, observed “flows” from “not consider” to “consider” and to purchase (or not) may occur faster than the interval of observation. Our model uses discrete observations from a continuous system to infer the net effect of multiple unobserved paths to purchase. Our primary method of analysis is a continuous-time Markov process (CTMP) with discrete-time observation and subject to misclassifications of behavioral states. We begin by describing USAM’s year-1 experimental treatments and the measurements. We present one- and two-stage CTMP models and address the impact of misclassification analysis. We next describe the year-2 quasi-experiment, examine potential self-selection tests, and compare analyses of the year-2 quasi-experiment to analyses of the year-1 experiment. The results suggest that competitive test drives and competitive brochures enhance consideration and sales, although the effect is indirectly through trust. We close with a discussion of managerial implications. YEAR-1 EXPERIMENTS: COMPETITIVE-INFORMATION STRATEGIES The year-1 panel ran from October 2003 to April 2004. (This was five years prior to the bankruptcies of two US automakers.) Members of Harris Interactive’s panel were screened to be in the market for a new vehicle in the next year, on average within the next 6.6 months, and invited to participate and complete six monthly questionnaires. In total, Harris Interactive enrolled 615 Los Angeles consumers of whom 317 completed all six questionnaires for an average completion/retention rate of 51.5%. USAM did not retain recruitment rate statistics for year 1, but, based on year 2, we estimate an initial recruitment rate of about 40%. Consumers were assigned randomly to experimental cells in the 2 x 2 x 2 x 2 field experiment. 4 Competitive Information to Your Own Customers Competitive Test Drives: Auto Show in Motion Consumers were invited to an event at a California test track to drive vehicles from BMW, Chrysler, Dodge, Ford, General Motors, Honda, Lexus, Mercedes, and Toyota without sales pressure. In returned they received coupons good at Amazon.com and a chance to win $10,000. Figure 1a reproduces information about the test drive, called Auto Show in Motion (ASIM). ASIM had substantial fixed costs to set up the test track, procure and maintain over 100 vehicles, assure safety, and provide staff assistance. Per consumer costs, including recruiting, incentives, and lunch, were in the $50-100 range. ASIM was available in period 4 to 39.1% of the consumers. Insert Figure 1 about here. Customized Brochures In year 1 this experimental treatment provided information about USAM rather than competitive vehicles. (In year 2 USAM used competitive brochures.) Specifically, year-1 consumers received brochures that were targeted to their specific needs as determined by measures prior to the experiments (Figure 1b). The brochures were mailed in either period 2 or 3 to 51.7% of the consumers. Competitive Online Advisor: Auto Choice Advisor Consumers were invited to use a web-based advisor that recommended vehicles based on a series of questions that revealed the consumers’ wants and needs. The web-based advisor, known as the Auto Choice Advisor (ACA), was similar to the advisor described in Urban and Hauser (2004). See Figure 1c. ACA was available in periods 2 through 6 to 49.2% of the consumers. 5 Competitive Information to Your Own Customers Competitive Community Forum Consumers participated in an CommuniSpaceTM online forum that discussed both USAM and competitive vehicles. See Figure 1d. Consumers were free to participate in any of the over 30 dialogues which averaged over 30 comments in each. Consumers could discuss experiences with their buying or ownership experience for any competitor and do so in an unbiased manner. The community was available in periods 2 through 6 to 47.6% of the consumers. Trust Covariate Consumers have varied experiences in the auto market and varied perceptions of USAM. USAM believed that it was possible that competitive information (and brochures) would affect consideration and purchase by increasing consumers’ trust in USAM. Trust measures also enable us to control for past history and to test for indirect effects. USAM measured consumers’ trust using a five-item scale with items such as “I believe that this company is willing to assist and support me.” or “Overall, this company has the ability to meet customer needs.” The items exhibited high reliability: Cronbach’s α = 0.95. Measures Used in the Analyses Dependent measures. In each period consumers reported the vehicles that they were “considering for your next purchase or lease.” They indicated the make-model combinations from a drop-down menu of 348 make-model combinations. USAM was interested in whether or not one of these vehicles was a USAM vehicle. With 348 make-model combinations on a dropdown menu, misclassification was a real concern. The purchase dependent variable was based on purchasing records maintained by USAM. For modeling purposes, we assume that misclassification of the purchase observation is small compared to misclassification of consideration. Covariates. Many automotive consumers are brand loyal. The first of six surveys col- 6 Competitive Information to Your Own Customers lected data on the vehicles consumers owned prior to the experiment. We dummy-code these data as “own USAM,” “own other American vehicle,” and “own Japanese.” The dummy variables are relative to “own European.” USAM measured age with 11 categories, which we dummycode with 10 categorical variables. The covariates do not vary by observation period. Experimentally-assigned treatments versus treatments that were received. Some consumers could not access the treatment(s) to which they were assigned. For example, some consumers experienced technical difficulties with ACA and some could not come to ASIM. Fortunately, the data contain self-reported treatment effects which we use to improve precision on which consumers actually received treatments. The self-reports match up well with the assigned treatments and seem to capture phenomena where consumers were not able to access the treatment. We ran analyses with dummy-coded treatment variables and with dummy-coded selfreports. Because they were similar and provided the same strategic interpretations, we report only the analyses based on the dummy-coded self-reported treatment effects. We now describe the model and use it to analyze the year-1 experiment and the year-2 quasi-experiment. LATENT BEHAVIORAL STATES AND CONTINUOUS TRANSITIONS USAM is interested in whether or not competitive information encourages consumers to consider and/or purchase USAM vehicles. We represent this focus with the Markov diagram in Figure 2. The diagram is Markov because flows among behavioral states depend only on the current behavioral state (and the explanatory variables), not the entire past history of flows. Insert Figure 2 about here. We index continuous time with t and we index behavioral states with i where i = 1, 2, and 3 index “do not consider USAM,” “consider USAM,” and “purchase USAM,” respectively. Let 1 if the consumer is in state i at time t, and let 0 otherwise. (To simplify notation 7 Competitive Information to Your Own Customers we suppress the subscript for consumer.) While consumers flow continuously among states and may make multiple transitions in a given month, we only observe behavioral states at monthly intervals. Let be the observation time for the monthly observation. Because we only ob- serve the result of continuous transitions, we derive an expression for the probability, , that the consumer was in state i at be and in state j at , where . Let ’s. the transition matrix of the Competitive information affects the rate at which consumers flow among states. Let be the instantaneous flow rate during the the ’s. Mathematically for j ≠ i, observation period and let An be the flow matrix of Δ is the probability that the consumer flows from state i to state j in the time period between t and t + Δ for very small Δ during the observation pe- riod. For small Δt the only way to be in state j at time t + Δt is to be there at time t or move there from another state in time Δ . This property gives the following differential flow equation: (1) Δ 1 Δ Δ Following Cox and Miller (1965) and Hauser and Wisniewski (1982) we let Δt → 0 to obtain a differential equation for the transition matrix. (2) The solution to the differential equation requires matrix exponentiation which is a difficult numerical problem. Equation 3 provides the solution to the differential equation and provides two ways by which the solution can be computed. ( exp Λ is the matrix of Eigenvectors of and is the matrix with the exponentiation of the Eigenvalues on the diagonal.) 8 Competitive Information to Your Own Customers (3) exp Λ ! To capture the effect of competitive information, trust, and other covariates we let the flows be a function of these variables. By definition, the off-diagonal elements of tive, so we use logarithms. Let servation period n. Otherwise are posi- 1 if the consumer received experimental treatment k in ob0. Let be the trust as measured at the beginning obser1 period. Let vation period n, that is, as measured at the end of the ℓ be the ℓ covariate. We represent flows by Equation 4 for the feasible behavioral-state transitions in Figure 2. We seek to estimate the unknown parameters: (4) , , , and ℓ log . ℓ ℓ ℓ We code our dependent-variable observations such that served in behavioral state i at and in behavioral state j at 1 if the consumer is ob. Using Equations 3 and 4 we set up the data likelihood. Although medical researchers have developed reversible jump Monte Carlo Markov Chain estimation to obtain estimates of the parameters for moderately-sized CTMP models (e.g., Suchard, Weiss and Sinsheimer 2001), matrix exponentiation presents practical problems for many empirical applications, especially when the number of observed transitions are small compared to the sample size as is the case in our data with USAM purchases. 1 We found maximum likelihood methods to be more stable for the USAM experiments and quasiexperiments (and more common in the CTMP literature). See Kulkarni (1995) for a review of 1 Pn is a stochastic matrix (rows sum to 1) which implies that the rows of An sum to zero. Thus the first Eigenvalue of Pn is 1.0 and describes steady-state behavior. The remaining Eigenvalues are less than 1.0 and describe the dynamic behavior. If tn is too large or too small relative to the dynamic behavior of the system there will be only one non-zero Eigenvalue. The remaining Eigenvalues will be close to zero. Slight numerical errors could make them negative, which would imply imaginary flows when we use the logarithmic representation in Equation 3. This causes problems with a Bayesian sampler. 9 Competitive Information to Your Own Customers computational methods to deal with matrix exponentiation. (Our one-stage models have a running time of 1-5 hours with maximum-likelihood estimation. Two-stage models are quicker.) MODELING POTENTIAL MISCLASSIFICATION OF DEPENDENT MEASURES Consideration is both a transient construct and one that is measured with potential error. For example suppose a consumer is not quite sure whether he or she is seriously considering a USAM vehicle. The consumer who is unsure might say he/she is considering a USAM vehicle in period 2 but not say so in period 3. Even if the consumer is sure about consideration, he/she might miss a vehicle in a drop-down menu of over 348 vehicles.2 Survey noise might cause us to infer phantom flows from “not consider USAM” to “consider USAM” and back. These phantom flows might disguise the effects of the experimental 1 if we treatments, trust, or the covariates. To account for misclassification we define observe that the consumer says that he or she is in state i at the end of the observation period. The true state, and , is not observed. To simplify notation let We seek to infer the probability of correct classification, Pr Pr | | . , and of misclassifications, for j ≠ i. To model misclassification we adopt Jackson, et al.’s (2003) hidden Markov model. To model misclassification we recognize that the likelihood of a series of observed states, , ,…, set of true states, , is equal to the probability that we made those observations conditioned on a , ,…, . If there were no restrictions, then for any observed state the consumer could have been in any true state. For any sequence of observed states, if all transitions were allowed, there is a non-zero probability for any of the 3x3x3x3x3x3 = 729 paths through the true states at times , ,…, . In our model “purchase” is a trapping state and assumed to 2 Toward the end of the decade USAM developed improved methods to measure consideration that mimicked the manner by which consumers choose consideration sets. See Hauser, et al. 2010. 10 Competitive Information to Your Own Customers have negligible observation error, so the number of paths is far less, but not trivial. To form the likelihood, we sum over all feasible true paths. For example, the likelihood that we observe “not consider” at the end of the first observation period and “consider” at the end of the second observation period is given by Equation 5 where Pr (5) Pr , , is a prior probability. Pr | Pr Pr | Pr | Pr | Pr | Pr | Pr Pr | Pr | Pr | Pr | As we expand Equation 5 to all six periods the likelihood gets complicated, but is handled easily by computer. Indeed, Jackson, et al. (2003, p. 197) provide a compact matrix notation to sum the likelihood over all true paths. Based on the data likelihood we estimate the parameters of the CTMP (the β’s) and the misclassification probabilities simultaneously. TESTING THE DIRECT EFFECT OF COMPETITIVE INFORMATION Table 1 summarizes the direct estimation. To simplify Table 1, we do not report ’s for the covariates – none were significant at the 0.10 level. Because of the logarithmic specification, a negative coefficient indicates that a flow rate decreased, not that the flow is negative. Misclassification was moderate; approximately 12% of the consumers were estimated to be misclassified as “consider USAM” when they did not yet consider USAM and approximately 6% were estimated to be misclassified as “do not consider USAM” when they considered USAM. Insert Table 1 about here. Each of the four sets of two columns represents one of the four allowable flows in Figure 2. Table 1 indicates that there is no identifiable direct effect due to the competitive information (the experimental treatments). However, lagged trust significantly increases flows from consideration to purchase and significantly decreases flows from “consider” to “do not consider.” To 11 Competitive Information to Your Own Customers anticipate a two-stage model, we estimated a reduced-form CTMP model with only lagged trust as a variable. The results, shown in the lower portion of Table 1, have similar implications: trust is a key driver of purchase and of maintaining consideration. COMPETITIVE INFORMATION ACTS THROUGH TRUST To examine the indirect effects of competitive information we develop a two-stage model. For the first stage we regress trust on competitive test drives, customized brochures competitive advisors, and competitive community forums. We include lagged trust because the experimental treatments are likely to increase or decrease trust and we include covariates to account for unobserved propensity for trusting USAM. We include dummy variables for observation periods to account for unobserved advertising and other actions by USAM and to account for unobserved environmental shocks. (Period 1 is a pre-measure and the period-2 dummy variable is set to zero for identification.) The period dummy variables also account for any measurement artifact that might boost trust (“Hawthorne” effect). The trust regression is summarized in Table 2. (To simplify exposition we suppress the categorical age variables; none were significant.) Insert Table 2 about here. Table 2 suggests that both competitive test drives (ASIM) and customized brochures increase consumers’ trust in USAM. Given the importance of trust in the first stage (CTMP) this is an important finding. The impact of customized brochures is consistent with other published studies of customization (e.g., Ansari and Mela 2003; Hauser, et al. 2009). The significance of ASIM demonstrates that competitive information is likely to maintain consideration and increase purchases of USAM’s vehicles. We believe that such large-scale field-experiment evidence of the positive effect of competitive information is relatively novel. To examine the second stage of the CTMP analysis, we use estimated trust ( ̂ ) from 12 Competitive Information to Your Own Customers the first stage rather than measured trust ( ) in the CTMP conditional likelihood. These two- stage estimates are limited-information maximum-likelihood (LIML) estimates. LIML estimates are consistent but we need to use bootstrap methods to check the standard errors for the ’s (Berndt, et al. 1974; Efron and Tibshirani 1994; Wooldridge 2002, p. 354, 414). Table 3 reports both the LIML estimates and the means from 1,000 bootstrap replicates. Insert Table 3 about here. The estimates in Table 3, both LIML and bootstrap, are similar to the reduced model in Table 1 confirming the impact of trust on consideration and purchase. 3 The two-stage model confirms that some competitive information (competitive test drives) increases consideration and purchase, but that the effect is through increased trust. This important finding suggests that USAM explore further strategies to increase trust. We discuss such strategies later in the paper. We did not find an effect for the competitive advisor and the competitive forum. This is intuitive for the 2004-2005 time period. Although USAM’s vehicles had improved relative to the early 2000s, ACA was recommending other vehicles (particularly the Japanese vehicles) and USAM did not always get positive reviews in community forums. Before we examine the impact of competitive information in the year-2 quasi-experiments, we detour to examine the relative value of modeling misclassification. THE IMPACT OF MODELING MISCLASSIFICATION IN A CTMP MODEL Many applications in various literatures have modeled misclassification including the di- 3 The LIML and reduced-form estimates are almost identical. The LIML and bootstrap coefficients of lagged trust are not significantly different. The constants representing flows between “not consider USAM” and “consider USAM” do differ, but offset. This difference is likely due to misclassification analysis interacting with the bootstrap procedure. Specifically, because bootstrap randomly selects observations, many observations are repeated in a given replicate causing that replicate to underestimate misclassification. The means of the 1,000 replicates were almost identical to the medians suggesting that outliers were not a problem. The running time is about 250 hours for 1,000 two-stage replicates. 13 Competitive Information to Your Own Customers agnosis of disease progression, the diagnosis of toxoplasmosis infection, the spread of HIV, the probability of workers changing jobs, volcanic activity, and Monte Carlo studies of forecasting error (Aspinall, et al. 2005; Bessec and Bouabdallah 2005; Chen and Sen 2007; Hausman, Abrevaya and Scott-Morton 1998; Jackson, et al. 2003; Rahme, Joseph and Gyorkos 2000; Tzavidis and Lin 2006). We test the impact of modeling misclassification in USAM’s experiment by using 5-fold cross-validation to examine predictive ability. For each of five subsamples we estimate the two-stage CTMP model with 80% of the data and predict behavior for the remaining 20%. Accounting for misclassification improves hit rates significantly from 66.1% to 77.1% (p < 0.001). The coefficients themselves also vary. When we ignore misclassification, the constants and lagged (estimated) trust remain significant in the same pattern as in Table 3, but we underestimate the impact of trust for maintaining consideration. YEAR 2 QUASI-EXPERIMENTS ON COMPETITIVE INFORMATION Buoyed with the success of the year-1 experiment USAM sought to test further the impact of competitive information. The year-2 quasi-experiment further analyzed competitive test drives (ASIM) but expanded the competitive information treatments to include competitive brochures. USAM maintained both the competitive advisor and the community forum even though they had no identifiable effect in year 1. The big difference in year 2 was that USAM sought to test the ability to launch competitive-information strategies on a national basis by allowing consumers to opt-in to the strategies. By its very nature, opt-in makes the test a quasi-experiment requiring USAM to test for potential self-selection. USAM included two quasi-controls. Consumers were assigned randomly to one of three cells. Consumers in the control cell received no treatments. Consumers in the forcedexposure cell were invited to an “Internet study” that included a visit to USAM’s “My Auto Ad14 Competitive Information to Your Own Customers vocate” website at which they could opt-in to competitive information treatments. See Figure 3a. Consumers in the pure opt-in cell received an advertisement inviting them visit the “My Auto Advocate” website. Insert Figure 3 about here. The year-2 panel ran from January to June, 2005. Members of Harris Interactive’s panel were again screened to be in the market for a new vehicle, on average within the next 2.2 years, and invited to participate and complete six monthly questionnaires. (The year-1 sample was restricted to 12-month intenders, the year-2 sample was not.) Incentives were similar to year 1. In total, Harris Interactive invited 6,092 Los Angeles consumers of which 1,720 completed all six questionnaires for an average response/completion/retention rate of 28.2%. This rate was not significantly different across the three conditions. Competitive Test Drives: Auto Show in Motion Consumers were invited to an event at one of three test tracks. Otherwise ASIM was similar to year 1. Opt-in respondents received 20 reward certificates for participating. Competitive Brochures and USAM Booklets In year 2 USAM continued to offer brochures (called eBooklets), but this time on an optin basis. To test competitive information, consumers could also download or obtain a CD with competitive brochures. Although many competitive brochures were available on manufacturers’ websites, USAM’s single-source webpage made it more convenient for consumers to compare vehicles. Opt-in consumers received 5 reward certificates for downloading a USAM brochure. See Figure 3b. 15 Competitive Information to Your Own Customers Competitive Online Advisor: My Product Advisor USAM updated ACA to “My Product Advisor (MPA)” and made it available directly from the “My Auto Advocate” website. Besides an improved interface, MPA had a “garage” at which consumers could store vehicle descriptions. Like ACA, MPA was unbiased. Opt-in consumers received 5 reward certificates for using MPA. See Figure 3c. Competitive Community Forum The community forum was updated and integrated with the “My Auto Advocate” website. Opt-in consumers received at least 5 reward certificates for participating, but could earn up to 20 reward certificates for active participation. See Figure 1d. Trust, Dependent Measures, and Other Covariates Trust, consideration, and purchase were measured as in year 1, as were prior ownership of USAM, other American, and Japanese vehicles. Age was measured directly rather than by categories and sex of the respondent was recorded. EXAMINING ISSUES OF SELF-SELECTION TO TREATMENTS It is possible that consumers who take advantage of competitive information are more likely to be interested in purchasing an automobile in the near future, but this self-selection may or may not translate into greater consideration for or purchase of USAM vehicles. The Effect of Cell Assignment for Non-Participating Consumers Many consumers in the opt-in (35.9%) and forced-exposure (45.0%) cells and all consumers (100%) in the control cell did not participate in the opt-in treatments. If self-selection impacts the dependent measures, then we should have a non-random removal of consumers from the opt-in and forced-exposure cells. If self-selection compromises the quasi-experiment these consumers should be less likely to consider and/or purchase USAM vehicles. To analyze this ef16 Competitive Information to Your Own Customers fect we created dummy variables for experimental cell and estimated a CTMP model with misclassification. There are no significant effects due to cell assignment (all p’s > 0.14 for all dummies for all flows; often much higher). We obtain similar results controlling for trust. Exposure to My Auto Advocate We have already established that the there is no significant difference in net response rate between those consumers who (a) were required to visit “My Auto Advocate” and completed the six questionnaires (forced exposure) and (b) those who could opt-in to “My Auto Advocate” and completed the six questionnaires (p > 0.17). To examine whether “My Auto Advocate” itself had a significant effect on consideration and purchase we repeat the dummy-variable CTMP model with misclassification, but for all consumers. The cell-assignment dummies remain insignificant (all p’s > 0.23) with and without controlling for trust. While these tests do not unequivocally rule out self-selection, they suggest it is reasonable to examine the potential impact of providing consumers with competitive information and to compare the effects to the year-1 experiment. YEAR-2 ANALYSIS OF COMPETITIVE INFORMATION We repeated all year-1 analyses with the year-2 data. As in year 1, none of the quasiexperimental treatments had direct significant effects in the CTMP model and the constants and coefficients of lagged trust in the reduced model were similar to those in the full model. Misclassification was slightly lower than in year 1; approximately 9% of the consumers were estimated to be misclassified as “consider USAM” when they did not yet consider USAM and approximately 3% were estimated to be misclassified as “do not consider USAM” when they actually considered USAM. Accounting for misclassification increased the predictive ability in a fivefold cross-validation from 74.7% to 87.1% (p < 0.001). Because the two-stage LIML and boot17 Competitive Information to Your Own Customers strap estimates are similar to the reduced model we simplify exposition and report only the twostage estimates in Tables 4 and 5. 4 Insert Tables 4 and 5 about here. In year 1 both lagged trust and estimated lagged trust had significant effects on consideration and purchase (e.g., p ≤ 0.03, bootstrap estimates). In year 2 both lagged trust and estimated lagged trust also have significant effects on consideration and purchase (p ≤ 0.05, bootstrap estimates). (The bootstrap standard errors are more accurate than the LIML standard errors.) Increasing trust is clearly beneficial for USAM in year 2 as it was in year 1. Competitive test drives still increase trust in year 2, although the effect is now only marginally significant (p = 0.10). The interesting new implication is that competitive brochures increased trust in USAM significantly in year 2 (p = 0.04). Sex and age are significant in year 2 possibly reflecting unobserved changes in USAM’s product mix or advertising. Overall, the year-2 two-stage model is remarkably similar to the year-1 model despite changes in the experimental treatments, unobserved changes in the environment, the change from an experiment to a quasi-experiment, and a sample that is not limited to consumers who plan to purchase in 12 months. Tables 1 through 5 suggest strongly that competitive information is an effective strategy to increase trust (in USAM) and, through trust, to increase consideration and purchase of USAM vehicles. These quantitative conclusions are consistent with qualitative comments by consumers who participated in the quasi-experiment: 4 All reduced-model and LIML estimates were not significantly different (all p’s > 0.32). Differences in the LIML and bootstrap constants are explained in footnote 3. The mean and median bootstrap estimates are almost identical. One coefficient of lagged trust was significant for the bootstrap estimates, but not for the LIML estimates, however, the value of the coefficient itself is almost identical (0.468 vs. 0.474). 18 Competitive Information to Your Own Customers My Auto Advocate: “I've learned a lot more about USAM. I didn't realize how many dif- ferent models of cars they own. It was eye opening. I enjoyed it and I have a more positive view of USAM than previously.” Competitive test drives: “Please don't stop doing these events, USAM. This was the one and only reason we purchased a USAM car over a Mustang GT or a Dodge Magnum R/T. There was no way we would have test-driven a USAM car had it not been for ASIM. It's the best experience I can imagine for overcoming people's prejudices against USAM and selling them on your many terrific products (like the …). I doubt I'd make the trip to different dealers (…) to drive those models.” Competitive Brochures: “The CD was downright entertaining! I liked how it got a lot of info across in a concise, easy-to-follow fashion, and made the specifics I was seeking easy to find.” MANAGERIAL IMPLICATIONS US automobile manufacturers face challenges as they try to improve sales and profit post bankruptcy. Our analyses have two implications. First, trust is key. Those consumers who trust USAM are more likely to consider and purchase USAM vehicles. Second, competitive test drives and competitive product brochures influence consumers to avoid rejecting USAM vehicles before they gather information. The effect is predominately through increased trust in USAM. USAM’s managers felt the results were consistent with qualitative data and sufficiently compelling to investigate further. Competitive test drives and competitive brochures were not rolled out nationally in large part because of other distractions during the automotive and financial crises at the end of the first decade of the 21st century. Competitive test drives are extremely expensive adding substantially to the cost of selling a vehicle. Competitive brochures are more likely to be cost effective and, with the growth of computer power and Internet use, are becoming more relevant. At minimum USAM’s experiments and quasi-experiments provide evidence that honest competitive compari19 Competitive Information to Your Own Customers sons are effective for firms that are disadvantaged by low consideration despite having good products. As the new USAM seeks to regain profitability they have implemented many strategies to encourage consumers to actively compare USAM vehicles to competitors. In 2009 a series of advertisements starring a well-known sports announcer made explicit comparisons to competitors featuring “surprises” such as good fuel economy. Another campaign was based on “May the Best Car Win.” In the fall of 2009 USAM implemented a policy by which consumers could try vehicles for 60 days and return them if they were not satisfied. USAM also ran successful miniexperiments in which USAM dealers invited customers to test drive competitive vehicles. All of these marketing tactics sought to encourage competitive comparisons and/or increase trust in USAM. SUMMARY If a firm has products that are much better than consumers perceive them to be, our results suggest that consideration and purchase increase if the firm makes competitive information available. (If a firm has inferior products then providing competitive information to consumers is unlikely to be profitable.) Competitive information reduces search and evaluation costs making it more likely for consumers to add another good product to their consideration sets. The firm realizes added benefits if it is transparent that the firm is providing competitive information. “Credit” for providing information likely leads consumers to place more trust in the firm. This appears to be what happened in USAM’s experiments and quasi-experiments. Competitive information increased demand through consideration and purchase and did so by increasing trust in USAM. Managerial, the open question is whether providing competitive information is cost effec20 Competitive Information to Your Own Customers tive. Paying for competitive test drives does not appear to be cost effective, but encouraging consumers to test drive both competitive and USAM vehicles does appear to be cost effective. Providing eBrochures appears to be a cost effective strategy. To analyze the quasi-experiment we used CTMP models to address the data constraint that transitions occur continuously while we only observe the results of these transitions at monthly intervals. While CTMP and related models, including hidden Markov models, have been used successfully to analyze other marketing issues, we are unaware of other applications in marketing that address potential misclassification errors in CTMPs (Ding and Eliashberg 2008; Eliashberg, et al. 2000; Hauser and Wisniewski 1982; Netzer, Lattin and Srinivasan 2008; Roberts, Morrison and Nelson 2004, 2005; Srinivasan and Kim 2009; Weerahandi and Moitra 1995). The analysis of misclassification proved to be a key methodological component of our analyses. CTMP, accounting for misclassification, is a powerful tool. Because flows were sparse in the USAM quasi-experiment, stability issues made maximum likelihood estimation the best numeric technique. When flows are less sparse, matrix exponentiation is more stable numerically and MCMC analysis will be computationally feasible. When there is more data per consumer than in the USAM quasi-experiment, CTMP analyses could be extended to include heterogeneity in flow rates among consumers. Perhaps new data will become available to develop these extensions for CTMP models which account for misclassification. 21 Competitive Information to Your Own Customers REFERENCES Ansari, Asim and Carl F. Mela (2003), “E-Customization,” Journal of Marketing Research, 40, (May), 131-145. Aspinall, W. P., R. Carniel, O. Jaquet, G. Woo, and T. Hincks (2006), “Using Hidden MultiState Markov Models with Multi-parameter Volcanic Data to Provide Empirical Evidence for Alert Level Decision-Support,” Journal of Volcanology and Geothermal Research, 153, 112-124. Bart, Yakov, Venkatesh Shankar, Fareena Sultan, and Glen L. Urban (2005), “Are the Drivers and Role of Online Trust the Same for All Web Sites and Consumers? A Large-Scale Exploratory Empirical Study,” Journal of Marketing, 69, (October), 133-152. Berndt, Ernie K., B. H. Hall, R. E. Hall, and Jerry Hausman (1974), “Estimation and Inference in Nonlinear Structural Models,” Annals of Social Measurement, 3, 653-665. Bessec, Marie and Othman Bouabdallah (2005), “What Causes The Forecasting Failure of Markov-Switching Models? A Monte Carlo Study,” Studies in Nonlinear Dynamics & Econometrics, 9, 2, Article 6. Chen, Pai-Lien and Pranab K. Sen (2007), “Markov Chain Model Selection by Misclassified Model Probabilities,” Communications in Statistics—Theory and Methods, 36, 143–153. Cox, David R. and Hilton D. Miller (1965), The Theory of Stochastic Processes, (London, UK: Chapman & Hall). Ding, Min and Jehoshua Eliashberg (2008), “A Dynamic Competitive Forecasting Model In‐ corporating Dyadic Decision Making,” Management Science, 54, 4, 820‐834. Efron, Bradley and Robert J. Tibshirani (1994), An Introduction to the Bootstrap, (New York, NY: Chapman & Hall/CRC). 22 Competitive Information to Your Own Customers Eliashberg, Jehoshua, Jedid‐Jah Jonker, Mohanbir S. Sawhney, and Berend Wierenga (2000), Marketing Science, 19, 3, 226‐243. Hausman, Jerry A., Jason Abrevaya and Fiona M. Scott-Morton (1998), “Misclassification of the Dependent Variable in a Discrete-response Setting,” Journal of Econometrics, 87, 239269. Hauser, John R., Olivier Toubia, Theodoros Evgeniou, Daria Dzyabura, and Rene Befurt (2010), “Cognitive Simplicity and Consideration Sets,” Forthcoming Journal of Marketing Research, 47, (June). ------, Glen L. Urban, Guilherme Liberali, and Michael Braun (2009), “Website Morphing,” Marketing Science, 28, 2, (March-April), 202-224. ------ and Birger Wernerfelt (1990), "An Evaluation Cost Model of Consideration Sets," Journal of Consumer Research, Vol. 16, (March), 393-408. ------ and Wisniewski, Kenneth J. (1982), “Dynamic Analysis of Consumer Response to Marketing Strategies,” Management Science, 28, 5, 455-484. Jackson, Christopher H., Linda D. Sharples, Simon G. Thompson, Stephen W. Duffy and Elisabeth Couto (2003), “Multistate Markov Models for Disease Progression with Classification Error,” The Statistician, 52, 193-209. Kulkarni, V. (1995), Modeling and Analysis of Stochastic Systems, (London, UK: Chapman & Hall/CRC). Netzer, Oded, James M. Lattin and V. Srinivasan (2008),” A Hidden Markov Model of Customer Relationship Dynamics,” Marketing Science, 27, 2, 185-204. Rahme, Elham, Lawrence Joseph, and Theresa W. Gyorkos (2000), Applied Statistics, 49, 119128. 23 Competitive Information to Your Own Customers Roberts, John H., Pamela D. Morrison and Charles J. Nelson (2004), “Implementing A Pre‐ launch Diffusion Model: Measurement And Management Challenges Of The Telstra Switching Study,” Marketing Science, 23, 2, 186‐191. -----, -----, and ----- (2005), “A Prelaunch Diffusion Model for Evaluating Market Defense Strategies,” Marketing Science, 24, 1, 150-164. Srinivasan, V. and Sang-Hoon Kim (2009), “A Conjoint‐Hazard Model of the Timing of Buy‐ ers' Upgrading to Improved Versions of High‐Technology Products,” Journal of Product Innovation Management, 26, 3, 278‐290. Suchard, Marc A., Robert E. Weiss and Janet S. Sinsheimer (2001), “Bayesian Selection of Continuous-Time Markov Chain Evolutionary Models,” Molecular Biology Evol., 18, 6, 1001-1013. Tzavidis, Nikos and Yan-Xia Lin (2006), “Estimating from Cross-Sectional Categorical Data Subject to Misclassification and Double-Sampling: Moment-based, Maximum Likelihood and Quasi-Likelihood Approaches,” Journal of Applied Mathematics and Decision Sciences, 2006, 1-13. Urban, Glen L. (2004), “The Emerging Era of Customer Advocacy,” MIT Sloan Management Review, (Winter), 45, 2, 77-82. ------ and John R. Hauser (2004), “’Listening-In’ to Find and Explore New Combinations of Customer Needs,” Journal of Marketing, 68, (April), 72-87. Weerahandi, Samaradasu and Soumyo Moitra (1995), “Using Survey Data to Predict Adoption and Switching for Services,” Journal of Marketing Research, 32, 1, 85-96. Wooldridge, Jeffrey M. (2002), “Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data,” (Cambridge, MA: MIT Press). 24 TABLE 1 ONE-STAGE ANALYSIS OF COMPETITIVE INFORMATION CTMP with Misclassification Modeled State at Tn-1: From “Do Not Consider USAM” From “Consider USAM” State at Tn: to Consider USAM to Do Not Consider USAM Full Model p value to Purchase USAM p value to Purchase USAM p value p value Constant 0.005 b 0.10 0.022 b 0.10 0.013 b 0.09 0.084 a 0.01 Lagged Trust -0.043 c 0.84 0.607 c 0.42 -0.470 b 0.10 0.278 a 0.04 Competitive Test Drives -0.071 c 0.97 -2.138 c 0.86 -0.058 c 0.94 -0.359 c 0.50 Customized Brochures 0.747 c 0.28 1.639 c 0.25 -4.832 c 0.60 0.189 c 0.53 Competitive Online Advisor -1.130 c 0.21 6.075 c 0.55 -0.639 c 0.47 -0.138 c 0.64 Competitive Forum 0.365 c 0.57 0.288 c 0.85 0.767 c 0.35 0.185 c 0.53 Constant 0.043 a <0.01 0.001 b 0.10 0.066 a <0.01 0.121 a <0.01 Lagged Trust 0.06 c 0.75 0.556 c 0.63 -0.502 a 0.01 0.255 a 0.04 Reduced Model a Significant at the 0.05 level (shown in bold). b Significant at the 0.10 level, but not 0.05 level (shown in bold italics) TABLE 2 TRUST AS A FUNCTION OF COMPETITIVE INFORMATION (YEAR 1) Key Variables Effect p value Intercept 0.640 b 0.06 Lagged Trust 0.860 a Competitive Test Drives Covariates Effect p value Own USAM 0.000 c 0.84 <0.01 Own American 0.021 c 0.59 0.380 a <0.01 Own Japanese -0.019 c 0.62 Customized Brochures 0.171 a <0.01 Period 3 -0.220 a <0.01 Competitive Advisor -0.057 c 0.39 Period 4 -0.295 a <0.01 Competitive Forum 0.045 c 0.22 Period 5 -0.127 a <0.01 Adjusted R2 0.749 c Period 6 -0.251 a <0.01 a b Significant at the 0.05 level (shown in bold). Significant at the 0.10 level, but not 0.05 level (shown in bold italics) TABLE 3 SECOND-STAGE ANALYSIS BASED ON ESTIMATED LAGGED-TRUST (YEAR 1) CTMP with Misclassification Modeled State at Tn-1: From “Do Not Consider USAM” From “Consider USAM” State at Tn: to Consider USAM to Do Not Consider USAM to Purchase USAM p value LIML p value to Purchase USAM p value p value Constant 0.042 a <0.01 0.001 b 0.08 0.066 a <0.01 0.120 a <0.01 Lagged Trust (estimated) 0.123 c 0.60 -0.380 c 0.65 -0.471 b 0.06 0.275 b 0.06 Bootstrap (1,000 replicates) Constant 0.100 a <0.01 0.001 c 0.36 0.156 a <0.01 0.129 a <0.01 Lagged Trust (estimated) 0.209 c 0.13 -0.130 c 0.69 -0.325 a 0.03 0.275 a 0.01 a Significant at the 0.05 level (shown in bold). b Significant at the 0.10 level, but not 0.05 level (shown in bold italics) TABLE 4 TRUST AS A FUNCTION OF COMPETITIVE INFORMATION (YEAR 2) Key Variables Effect p value Intercept 0.902 a <0.01 Lagged Trust 0.824 a Competitive Test Drives Covariates Effect p value Own USAM 0.132 c <0.01 <0.01 Own American 0.023 c 0.19 0.089 b 0.10 Own Japanese -0.059 Competitive Brochures 0.050 b 0.04 Sex 0.037 a 0.02 USAM Booklets 0.017 c 0.52 Age -0.088 a 0.02 Competitive Advisor -0.020 c 0.39 Age-Sq/100 0.009 a 0.01 Competitive Forum 0.003 c 0.91 Period 3 0.038 c 0.15 Period 4 0.040 c 0.13 Period 5 0.028 c 0.30 Period 6 0.050 b 0.06 Adjusted R2 a 0.700 c b Significant at the 0.05 level (shown in bold). c <0.01 Significant at the 0.10 level, but not 0.05 level (shown in bold italics) TABLE 5 SECOND-STAGE ANALYSIS BASED ON ESTIMATED LAGGED-TRUST (YEAR 2) CTMP with Misclassification Modeled State at Tn-1: From “Do Not Consider USAM” From “Consider USAM” State at Tn: to Consider USAM to Do Not Consider USAM to Purchase USAM p value LIML p value to Purchase USAM p value p value Constant 0.025 a <0.01 0.001 a <0.01 0.099 a <0.01 0.006 a <0.01 Lagged Trust (estimated) 0.989 a <0.01 0.468 c 0.36 -0.425 a <0.01 -0.018 c 0.96 Bootstrap (1,000 replicates) Constant 0.072 a <0.01 0.001 a 0.01 0.188 a <0.01 0.006 a <0.01 Lagged Trust (estimated) 0.614 a <0.01 0.474 a 0.05 -0.362 a <0.01 0.060 c 0.87 a Significant at the 0.05 level (shown in bold). b Significant at the 0.10 level, but not 0.05 level (shown in bold italics) FIGURE 1 YEAR-1 COMPETITIVE-INFORMATION EXPERIMENTAL TREATMENTS (a) Competitive Test Drive (b) Customized Brochures Site contained over 60 dialogues averaging over 60 comments. (c) Competitive Online Advisor (d) Competitive Community Forum FIGURE 2 CONTINUOUS-TIIME FLOW WS AMONG G BEHAVIO ORAL STAT TES FIGURE 3 YEAR R-2 COMPE ETITIVE-INFORMATIO ON QUASI-EXPERIM MENTAL TR REATMENT TS (a a) My Auto Advocate A Ho omepage (Op pt-in) (b) Competitive E-Brrochures (cc) Competitiv ve New-Veh hicle Advisorr (d) Competitive Com mmunity Foru um