+ 2 (,1 1/,1(

advertisement
+(,121/,1(
Citation: 35 Harv. J. L. & Pub. Pol'y 187 2012
Content downloaded/printed from
HeinOnline (http://heinonline.org)
Tue Jul 16 11:21:37 2013
-- Your use of this HeinOnline PDF indicates your acceptance
of HeinOnline's Terms and Conditions of the license
agreement available at http://heinonline.org/HOL/License
-- The search text of this PDF is generated from
uncorrected OCR text.
-- To obtain permission to use this article beyond the scope
of your HeinOnline license, please use:
https://www.copyright.com/ccc/basicSearch.do?
&operation=go&searchType=0
&lastSearch=simple&all=on&titleOrStdNo=0193-4872
ECONOMIC UNCERTAINTY AND THE ROLE OF THE
COURTS
PAUL G. MAHONEY*
This Article addresses economic uncertainty and the role of
institutions in securing property rights. We know a lot more
about the former than we do about the latter. That is to say, we
know about the effects of uncertainty, especially uncertainty
about property rights, on the economy.' We know less about
the extent to which institutional arrangements can guarantee
security of property and less still about whether they can create
secure property rights where such rights do not already exist.
There are very strong theoretical reasons to believe that
property rights are a first-order determinant of the health of the
economy. Adam Smith linked investment and growth to the
security of property. 2 It also seems reasonably clear that the
security of property rights is connected to the structure of government. When we compare societies around the world with
despotic governments to those with limited governments, the
latter usually have better property rights and are usually more
prosperous.3 Examples include the Netherlands before and after independence from Spain in the seventeenth century4 and
Zimbabwe and Botswana today.5
* Dean, David and Mary Harrison Distinguished Professor and Arnold H. Leon
Professor, University of Virginia School of Law.
1. See, e.g., Paul G. Mahoney, The Common Law and Economic Growth: Hayek Might
Be Right, 30 J. LEGAL STUD. 503 (2001); Stewart E. Stark, Property Rules, Liability
Rules, and UncertaintyAbout PropertyRights, 106 MICH. L. REV. 1285 (2008).
2. See ADAM SMITH, AN INQUIRY INTO THE NATURE AND CAUSES OF THE WEALTH
OF NATIONS 294-301 (Edwin Cannan ed., 1976) (1776).
3. See Manuel Vega-Gordillo & Jos6 L. Alvarez-Arce, Economic Growth and Freedom: A Causality Study, 23 CATO J. 199 (2003).
4. MAARTEN PRAK, THE DUTCH REPUBLIC IN THE SEVENTEENTH CENTURY: THE
GOLDEN AGE 2, 4 (Diane Webb trans., 2005).
5. See, e.g., ATO KWAMENA ONOMA, THE POLITICS OF PROPERTY RIGHTS INSTITU-
TIONS IN AFRICA 1-60 (2010); John McClung Nading, Property Under Siege: The
Legality of Land Reform in Zimbabwe, 16 EMORY INT'L L. REV. 737, 765-74 (2002)
(discussing property rights in Zimbabwe).
188
HarvardJournalof Law & Public Policy
[Vol. 35
We can look at the question more systematically, and many
scholars have set out to do just that.6 I will accordingly draw on a
large body of work to which many scholars have contributed.
A simple starting point is whether, in the world today, the
security of property rights is associated with economic prosperity. We cannot answer that question, however, from the
statute books alone. In general, non-Communist countries have
formal protections for property rights. Even if the formal rules
about property are the same in Luxembourg and Paraguay,
however, most observers would share the intuition that property is more secure in Luxembourg.
In addition, I must use the term "property rights" loosely because there are many things a government can do to interfere
with property rights besides outright theft. It can regulate to
the extent that property can no longer be used profitably.7 It
can devalue the currency to the point where paper assets become worthless. It can allow politically favored entities to play
by different rules than everyone else. Thus, I will use the terms
"property rights" and "economic freedom" to refer broadly to
the absence of those forms of interference.
Various organizations and scholars try to measure the de
facto security of property rights. Companies like Political Risk
Services create survey-based measures for private sector clients
who invest abroad. The Heritage Foundation calculates an index of economic freedom that incorporates some of the above
forms of interference with property rights.9 In general, economic freedom scores correlate quite strongly with economic
prosperity.10 Interestingly, the correlation between prosperity
and economic freedom is even stronger than that between
prosperity and measures of political freedoms."
6. E.g., Stark, supra note 1.
7. See Lucas v. S.C. Coastal Council, 505 U.S. 1003 (1992).
8. Economists Stephen Knack and Philip Keefer popularized the use of the PRS
measures. See Stephen Knack & Philip Keefer, Institutions and Economic Performance:
Cross-Country Tests Using Alternative InstitutionalMeasures, 7 ECON. & POL. 207 (1995).
9. See TERRY MILLER & KIM R. HOLMES, HERITAGE FOUND., 2011 INDEX OF Eco-
NOMIC FREEDOM (2011), available at www.heritage.org/index.
10. Id.
11. See ROBERT J. BARRO, DETERMINANTS OF ECONOMIC GROWTH: A CROSSCOUNTRY EMPIRICAL STUDY 49-61 (1997).
No. 1]
Economic Uncertainty and the Courts
189
Compare, for instance, Morocco and Singapore. Both have
parliamentary governments,12 and both governments are somewhat intolerant of dissent.13 The two countries have identical
scores on Freedom House's Indexes of Political Rights and Civil
Liberties, two of the most common measures of political freedom. 14 Singapore, however, scores much higher than Morocco
on the Heritage Foundation's index of economic freedom.15 Singapore is a much wealthier country. Indeed, its per capita GDP
is more than ten times that of Morocco.16
But why does Singapore, which has a similar level of political freedom, have more secure property rights than Morocco,
or, for that matter, Italy? More importantly, could Morocco
become as wealthy as Singapore by altering its governmental
structure in a way that would limit its ability to interfere with
property and other economic rights?
One traditional answer, given by Montesquieu, is to constrain governmental power through institutions such as federalism or an independent judiciary." Governments always are
tempted to interfere with property rights and other economic
freedoms for temporary political advantage, even at the cost of
long-term harm to the economy. Greater constraints on the
government make such interference less feasible and reduce
12. See CIA, Morocco, WORLD FACTBOOK (Oct. 24, 2011), https://www.cia.gov/
library/publications/the-world-factbook/geos/mo.html; CIA, Singapore, WORLD
FACTBOOK (Oct. 21, 2011), https://www.cia.gov/library/publications/the-worldfactbook/geos/sn.html.
13. See, e.g., Susan Waltz & Lindsay Benstead, When the Time is Ripe: The Struggle
to Create an Institutional Culture of Human Rights in Morocco, in HUMAN RIGHTS IN
THE ARAB WORLD: INDEPENDENT VOICES 174 (Anthony Chase & Amr Mzawy eds.,
2006); Seth Mydans, Outspoken SingaporeDissident Dies, N.Y. TIMES, Sept. 30, 2008,
http://www.nytimes.com/2008/09/30/world/asia/30iht-obits.2.16585582.html.
14. See
FREEDOM
HOUSE,
FREEDOM
IN
THE
WORLD
2011
14-15,
http://www.freedomhouse.org/images/File/fiw/FIW_2011_Booklet.pdf
(last visited Nov. 17, 2011).
15. See 2011 Index of Economic Freedom World Rankings: Ranking the Countries,
HERITAGE FOUND., http://www.heritage.org/index/ranking
(last visited Nov. 1,
2011) (ranking Singapore the second and Morocco the ninety-third most free
countries in the world).
16. See, GDP per Capita, WORLD BANK, http://data.worldbank.org/indicator/
NY.GDP.PCAP.CD (last visited Nov. 1, 2011).
17. See 2011 Index of Economic Freedom, supra note 15 (ranking Italy the eightyseventh most free country).
18. See CHARLES DE SECONDAT, BARON DE MONTESQUIEU, THE SPIRIT OF LAWS 80
(Anne M. Cohler et al. eds., 1989) (1748).
190
HarvardJournalof Law & Public Policy
[Vol. 35
the likelihood of government capture. 19 Broadly speaking, that
is the story we tell ourselves about the Framers. They wisely set
up a government with many checks and balances that limit the
federal government's ability to interfere with property and
contract rights. 20
A piece of anecdotal evidence for the governmental constraint theory is the difference between England and France in
the early eighteenth century. After the Glorious Revolution,
England's monarchy was considerably more constrained than
the monarchy of the Sun King and his Bourbon successors in
France. 21 During that period, England developed robust financial markets, improved its commercial markets, and moved
ahead economically while France fell behind. 22
There is, however, an alternative view of the history which
holds that the causation runs the other way. Societies do not
respect property rights and become rich because they have
constrained government; rather, they constrain government
and secure property rights because they are rich.2 3 Once people
accumulate property and insist on a less intrusive and predatory government, their growing prosperity makes it possible
for them to get their way.24
A piece of anecdotal evidence for the theory that prosperity
leads to constrained government is the Korean Peninsula. 2 5 Before the partition of Korea, when the country was under a single government, the North and South had similar levels of economic development. 26 After the Korean War, the country was
19. See J. Bradford De Long & Andrei Shleifer, Princes and Merchants: European
City Growth Before the Industrial Revolution, 36 J.L. & ECON. 673-74 (1993) (considering evidence from pre-industrial Europe and finding that economic development,
proxied by the growth of cities, where large-scale exchange took place, was
greater in areas with less absolutist government).
20. See Barry R. Weingast, The Constitutional Dilemma of Economic Liberty, J.
ECON. PERSPECTIVES 2005, at 89, 89-91.
21. See DOUGLASS C. NORTH, INSTITUTIONS, INSTITUTIONAL CHANGE AND EcoNOMIC PERFORMANCE 138-39 (1990).
22. Id.
23. A careful statement of this hypothesis with supporting empirical results is
Edward L. Glaeser et al., Do Institutions Cause Growth?, 9 J. ECON. GROWTH 271
(2004).
24. In political science, this theory is commonly known as modernization the-
ory. See, e.g., Seymour Martin Lipset, Some Social Requisites of Democracy: Economic
Development and PoliticalLegitimacy, 53 AM. POL. SC. REV. 69, 81-82 (1959)
25. See Glaeser et al., supra note 23, at 272-73.
26. Id.
No. 1]
Economic Uncertainty and the Courts
191
partitioned into North and South Korea, and both initially were
ruled by autocrats. 27 But the North's autocrat decided to pursue
socialism, while the South's autocrat chose to pursue a market
economy. 28 The South grew prosperous and the North grew
impoverished. 29 Eventually, the citizens of South Korea no
longer accepted autocratic rule and created a more limited
form of democratic government.o
Those two stories have different implications for how a
country can go from low to high security of property and from
poverty to wealth. The first suggests that you must tie Leviathan down to create prosperity. The second suggests that you
must be lucky enough to have the right Leviathan, or at least
persuade Leviathan to adopt pro-growth policies, and eventually you will get limited government in the bargain.
My argument so far has relied on anecdotal evidence. Scholars have looked hard for systematic evidence, but unfortunately it is not conclusive. There is an important body of evidence to support the "constraining government causes
prosperity" hypothesis. If we compare countries around the
world, there are quite systematic differences between those
that were colonized by England and those that were colonized
by France, Spain, or other continental powers.31
In particular, former English colonies tend to have larger and
more liquid financial markets and their economies grew faster in
the post-colonial period, from the 1960s to the 1990s, after controlling for the initial level of development. 32 This divergence is important for two reasons. First, the English theory of government,
which it transported to its colonies, stressed limited power and
robust property rights.33 The French and Spanish theory, by con-
27. Id.
28. Id.
29. Id.
30. See id.
31. See Mahoney, supra note 1.
32. See id.; see also Rafael La Porta et al., Law and Finance, 106 J. POL. ECON. 1113
(1998); Legal Determinants of External Finance, 52 J. Fin. 1131, 1137-38 (1997) (providing data set).
33. See John McLaren et al., Property Rights in the Colonial Imagination and Experience, in DESPOTIC DOMINION: PROPERTY RIGHTS IN BRITISH SETTLER SOCIETIES 1-21
(John McLaren et al. eds., 2005).
192
HarvardJournalof Law & Public Policy
[Vol. 35
trast, stressed a strong central state in which the government was
not so constrained in pursuing collective ends. 34
Second and equally important, we do not have to worry
about the possibility of reverse causation. The fact that Australia is a wealthy country today did not cause England, rather
than Spain or France, to colonize it? Wealth, in those results,
does not cause good institutions because it did not cause colonization. Thus, the link between past colonization and present
economic success is evidence in favor of the proposition that
institutional constraints cause wealth.
But a piece of evidence in favor of the "prosperity causes
constraints on government" hypothesis is that many poor
countries in the middle of the past century had more-or-less
despotic governments. In some, like South Korea, Taiwan, and
Chile, the despot chose pro-growth policies and the country
became prosperous relative to its neighbors and later developed more constraints on governmental power. 36
In my view, the evidence itself shows that there are two common packages consisting of institutions, policy choices, and
economic outcomes. One package includes constrained government, generally pro-growth policies, secure property rights,
and prosperity. The other includes unconstrained government,
generally anti-growth policies, low protections for property
rights, and poverty. Each package is common, and in each one
the institutions, policy choices, and economic outcomes are
mutually reinforcing.
Mixing and matching pieces from both packages creates some
tensions. China, for example, has unconstrained government but
relatively pro-market policies, low but improving property
rights, and increasing prosperity, starting, of course, from a very
34. See Rafael La Porta et al., The Economic Consequences of Legal Origins, 46
J.
ECON. LIT. 285, 286 (2008) (contrasting a "strategy of social control that seeks to
support private market outcomes" with one that "seeks to replace such outcomes
with state-desired allocations" and assigning English common law to the first and
continental civil law to the second category).
35. Although it makes sense to assume for our purposes that legal origin was
exogenously determined, we should recognize that colonizers did not select colonies
at random. The selection was determined by the strategies of the European colonizers and the opportunities available to them. See Daniel M. Klerman et al., Legal Origin or Colonial History? (Univ. S. Cal. Law Sch. Law & Econ. Working Paper Series,
Paper 132, 2011), availableat http://aw.bepress.com/usclwps/lewps/artl32/.
36. See Glaeser et al., supra note 23.
No. 1]
Economic Uncertainty and the Courts
193
low level.37 This package is not mutually reinforcing, and China
is likely to face ongoing political conflicts despite the best efforts
of its rulers to hold on to unconstrained power.
Similarly, the American system of checks and balances, federalism, and an independent judiciary does not prevent episodic interference with property rights in the United States. In
recent years, the federal government has pressured creditors in
the Chrysler and General Motors bankruptcies to accept less
than their pre-bankruptcy entitlements, 8 enacted a healthcare
law that requires citizens to buy insurance whether they want
to at prevailing prices or not, 39 and played favorites with certain industry sectors or individual companies. 40 But the recent
outbreaks of such interference produced a powerful popular
backlash that might operate as a more potent constraint than
federalism, bicameralism, or other structural barriers.
Because the literature on economic development is concerned primarily with how to help poor nations out of poverty, 4 1 it has tended to see the demand for good policies and
good institutions as always rising with the level of wealth. History certainly suggests that a country with a middle class is
more likely to demand good institutions than one without it.
The experience of Europe and America over the past century,
however, suggests that the relation between wealth and the
desire for limited government may not be linear at all portions
of the graph.
In particular, once a country reaches a stage of development
in which the marginal voter owns a house, a car, and a flat
37. See Eva Pils, Waste No Land: Property, Dignity, and Growth in Urbanizing
China, 11 ASIAN-PAC. L. & POL'Y J. 1, 2-6 (2010).
38. Douglas Baird argues that given the federal government's role as funder of a
buyer of Chrysler's assets, a secured creditor of General Motors, and a party with
great leverage over other creditors because of their receipt of TARP funds, the
way the bankruptcy proceedings played out was unsurprising and procedurally
unobjectionable. See Douglas G. Baird, Car Trouble (Univ. of Chicago Law & Economics Olin Working Paper, No. 551, 2011). I do not disagree that the government
exercised its leverage the way a private creditor would and in that limited, procedural sense the bankruptcies were not unusual. But it seems equally true, as
David Skeel argues, that the government's decision to create and then exercise
that leverage has created additional risk for private creditors in any politically
sensitive industry. See David Skeel, The Real Cost of the Auto Bailouts, WALL ST. J.,
June 6, 2011, at A19.
39. Patient Protection and Affordable Care Act, Pub. L. 111-148, 124 Stat. 119 (2010).
40. See Skeel, supra note 38.
41. See, e.g., JEFFREY SACHS, THE END OF POVERTY (2006).
194
HarvardJournalof Law & Public Policy
[Vol. 35
screen TV, the marginal voter may become less interested in
growth and more interested in stability. And of course, the
eternal justification for larger and more powerful government
is stability. Perhaps, then, paradoxically, limited government
may be very popular until it produces an extremely high level
of success for its society. 42
42
Hayek similarly suggests that "the very success of liberalism became the cause
of its decline." FRIEDRICH A. HAYEK, THE ROAD TO SERFDOM 23 (Univ. of Chi.
Press, 1994) (1944).
Download